Summary Derivation of The Demand Curve
Summary Derivation of The Demand Curve
Summary Derivation of The Demand Curve
Humanities Sciences
In this lesson, we are going to derive the demand curve, that downward sloping line that
shows you how, in a market, the quantity demanded declines as the price increases.
This is actually the first in a series of lessons that enables us to think about how markets work,
whether sellers and buyers and as an equilibrium.
The first part, we are going to actually, as I say, derive the demand curve and to do that we are
going to look at the behavior of consumers and the buyers in the market.
Then after we do that, we are going to derive the supply curve, which will focus on firms rather
than consumers, the producers in the market, which would be the sellers.
Then finally, once we derive the demand curve and the supply curve, we are going to think
about equilibrium and efficiency where the buyers and sellers come together in the market.
In addition, we will see why markets work well and, and when they do not.
So remember the demand curve, as I say, is this downward sloping line between the price and
the quantity demanded.
In addition, it is something that's the basic part of the supply and demand model.
But now we want to see, really look at the consumers that underlie that demand curve, the
people that underlie the demand curve and really see why the demand curve has the shape it
has, why it's downward sloping and when it tends to shift.
You could imagine it might be you, might be me, and could be anyone.
Moreover, based on that individual's behavior, we are going to derive that person's demand
curve, and then from the demand curve, we are going to consider many such consumers who
are in the market, and any such individuals in the market.
Moreover, get the market demand curve. Again, by adding up demand curve for many such
individuals will get the market demand curve.
To get to the individuals demand curve, we are going to apply that general economic principle
that people make purposeful choices with limited resources that is the mantra that we have
emphasized as a general principle of economics.
In this case, the people, will not be maximizing their utility, we will call it, subject to a budget
constraint.
Therefore, purposeful choice becomes maximizing utility, which we will describe in a minute.
In addition, the limited resources is going to reflect the fact they have a budget constraint,
which means they only have certain amount that they can spend in a particular period.
When this numerical indicator is higher, for a particular bundle of goods or a certain number
of, of apples and grapes, or pears and oranges.
If it is lower, then the other one, they do not prefer that bundle.
Therefore, the, the higher level of utility compared to another bundle represents preference
for that bundle.
Now to make this work, I want to use an example and I want to imagine that you or someone
else is a consumer deciding how many pounds of grapes to buy, in the, in the supermarket or
how many pounds of bananas to buy in the supermarket.
And so on the horizontal axis of this box I'm labeling first the pounds of bananas.
One, two, three, four, five, and on the vertical, we are labeling the pounds of grapes one, two
three, four, five.
Then inside the box, inside this matrix, we are representing utility that this consumer gets from
these various bundles or combinations of bananas and grapes.
Therefore, for example if, the consumer has one pounds of bananas one pound of bananas or
one pound of grapes that is a utility of 16 by our assumption.
For two pounds of grapes and one pound of banana, utility is 20 so, obviously, the consumer
prefers two grapes, two pounds of grapes to one pound of grapes.
In addition, as you go up, the vertical line there, 16, 20, 23, 25, 26, you see that that is
increasing.
In addition, that means that there is more utility with more pounds of grapes and therefore
the consumer prefers that.
So from 16 to 20 is four.
Those increments sometimes called marginal utility, decline the more grapes you have.
So the margin of utility we call the change in utility as you consume more grapes, declines as
you consume more grapes.
You can look at the utility of bananas just looking in the horizontal direction.
Let us say, so for example, let us look at, I assume you have one pound of grapes and you are
considering different pounds of bananas.
with that one pound of grape over in the lower right hand entry.
and if you go to the right to any of the rows, that increasing utility for bananas.
So that's our example of utility and we're gonna use this to derive the demand curve for this
consumer, any consumer that is considering decisions about grapes and bananas.
And we'll also assume to get started that the price of grapes Is a dollar per pound, and the
price of bananas is a dollar per pound.
So, for example, one pound of banana, one pound of grapes costs
two dollars, that's in the lower right hand column of the table.
And that would cost $10, that's in upper right there of this box.
And all the other points in between are simply the price
purchased, and that gives you the various entries in the table.
Now in addition, what this table shows, is the things that you can't afford.
So you can't consume five pounds of grapes and four pounds of bananas.
You certainly can't consume five pounds of grapes and five pounds of
bananas, those are off limits, they are outside of the budget constraint.
So, now what we wanna do is consider how the consumer decides how many pounds
of grapes and bananas to buy at different prices for grapes or, or bananas.
So, take this table and now assumes that the price of grapes is $2 rather than $1.
$1, as in the previous table, the price of bananas is the same, exactly $1.
Budget constraint is still $8, and now in this table I've made
the red items the things that they, the consumer can no longer buy.
get that number, that's the four from the, from the one, that's.
Cost $9 you only have $8 you could get that if the price
of grapes was one dollar but now it's $2, so, it's, it's off limits.
decision when the price of grapes goes from one dollar to two dollar, dollars.
Box shows.
That gives you utility for different pounds of bananas and grapes.
Now, with the price of grapes $1 pound and $8 to spend, we could not get to those levels that
are now in red.
Because they cost more than $8 as in the $9 and $10 entries so their now off limits in terms of
this consumer there outside the budget constraint the black lines are inside the budget
constraint the consumer can afford those, and so now we have an answer to our problem how
many grapes.
How many pounds of grapes, how many pounds of bananas will this consumer consume when
the price of grapes is $1.
Because if you look closely at the table, that's the highest level of utility, 39, this consumer can
get with $8 when the price is a dollar for a pound of grapes and bananas.
Now what we wanna do is say, what if the price of grapes goes up, what's that gonna do to the
decision?
I've now made the items red, which are no longer affordable.
For this consumer because now the price of grapes is $2, and so that $8 doesn't go as far as it
did.
There's more entries that are red, made in red, because they're not affordable in this case.
And now of the non-red entries and non-red levels of utility, we see the highest is 34, and I've
made that in blue, so you can see it.
So, if you think about this, we have a prediction that when the price of grapes went from $1 to
$2 per pound, the consumption of grapes went from 4 to 2.
That is just the demand curve we have been looking for, derived now from this basic principle
of maximizing utility, subject to this budget constraint.
In addition, we can graph this, using the same points and a picture, so that is what this does
now.
You take the price on the vertical axis, and the quantity demanded on the horizontal axis, and
the points we're plotting now, are the ones that we just got from those, from that
maximization of utility problem.
So again to repeat, we found that when the price of grapes is $1, which is marked on the
vertical axis as one, the quantity demand of the grapes was two pounds, and that's shown in
the horizontal axis.
And that's that black dot, and then when they raise the price of grapes to $2, we've found, that
the quantity demanded of grapes goes down to two.
Those are the two black dots, I've connected them with a line to illustrate it's a downward
sloping demand curve.
One was called the income effect, and one was the substitution effect.
the, that would tend to make you wanna consume fewer grapes and fewer bananas.
In addition, there was a substitution effect, because grapes were now relatively more
expensive compared to bananas.
Went from basically the same price, a dollar for a pound of each, and now the price of grapes
rose, so it's twice as much, $2 compared to a pound in the case of bananas.
And in this case decided that the higher price was going to be resulting in fewer grapes
consumed, so for substituted in
Now let's go back, and finally see about shifts in the curve.
there were, there's only $5, is the budget constraint, so we change that 5 to 8.
So I'm taking that utility table, and now I'm making red all the items that are not available in
the sense that it's outside the budget constraint.
You can get to those utility numbers, they require too much money.
And of the remaining non-red items, I've made 32, be the highest possible utility level that's
left over.
And that suggests that two pounds of grapes and three pounds of bananas will be
consumed as the consumer has less to spend, and it's moved from $8 to $5.
And we can graph this, as well and we'll show you a shift in the demand curve.
Which represented a budget constraint with $8, that's the line over to
the right, and when the budget constraint is now moved from $8 to $5, we've seen
the number of grapes consumed, quantity demanded has gone from either from 2 to 4 at the
bottom end there, or from 2 to 1 in the upper end.
So from 4 to 2, or 2 to 1, but they're both shifts in the demand curve, and that occurred
because of the change in the budget constraint less money to spend, less income to spend,
and therefore the demand curve has shifted.
We have shown how higher prices reduce the quantity demanded based on utility
maximization ideas.
In addition, we have shown how the demand curve shifts when income changes, based on the
very sound principles of economics.
Now we are going to consider in the next lesson, yet another way to derive the demand curve,
which has even greater applicability.