McGahan Porter PDF
McGahan Porter PDF
McGahan Porter PDF
1476-1270[200302];1:1;79–108;031219
Copyright ©2003 Sage Publications (London,Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi)
Abstract
In this paper, we examine the emergence and the sustainability of abnormal profits among
businesses that were part of US public corporations between 1981 and 1994 and that
reported financial results for at least six years. Our results reveal strong asymmetries
between high and low performers. Overall, high performance is more stable than low per-
formance. High performers show profits above the average a decade earlier. In contrast,
low performers show profits that are slightly above average a decade earlier. Industry and
corporate-parent effects influence high performance to a far greater degree than low per-
formance. Low performance is dominated by business-specific effects.
The fields of strategy and organization deal with fundamental questions about
how company profits emerge and persist over time. Strategy researchers
have generated extensive theory on the sources of profitability, including the
industrial-organization, resource-based, property rights, organizational ecology,
and transaction-cost views. For example, resource-based theorists tend to
emphasize the importance of corporate and business-specific effects in the emer-
gence of high performance, and organizational ecologists emphasize the persis-
tence of both high and low performance due to inertia. While there is no
shortage of theories to explain the sources of profitability, there is little empiri-
cal evidence about the trajectory of profitability over extended periods of
time. Mueller (1986), Ghemawat (1991), and McGahan and Porter (1999) are
exceptions.
In this paper, we report the results of a panel study that begins to fill this
gap. Our purpose is to report empirical regularities in the different trajectories
of profitability for those businesses that retained their identities and reported
financial results for at least six years. The analysis distinguishes the influences on
the emergence and sustainability of abnormal profitability of year, industry,
corporate-parent, and business-specific effects. The approach reflects the idea
that industry, corporate-parent, and business-specific levels are all important for
79
80 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
understanding the role of both strategy and organization. Data are drawn from
the Compustat Business-Segment Reports for 1981 through 1994, which cover
the activities of all corporations publicly traded on US equity markets.
Industry effects on the emergence of high and low profitability arise from
structural impediments to competition that similarly affect incumbents. For
example, after its initial public offering in 1986, the Lotus Development
Corporation was a superior performer in the sense that its return on assets in
each year was greater than average. Its performance largely reflected its partici-
pation in the profitable PC applications software industry. The structural
impediments that generated industry effects in the software industry arose
through both strategy and organization. In this case, the decisions and actions of
particular individuals, such as those of Bill Gates, were instrumental in shaping
the industry structure through strategic and organizational choices that gave
rise to shared development tools, licensing policies, and barriers to entry.
Broadly, this paper provides evidence that suggests relationships between
various theoretical explanations for why industry effects arise.
Corporate-parent effects arise when a company’s return in a specific business
is uniquely affected by its pattern of diversification. A negative corporate-parent
effect arises when a diversified firm’s member businesses underperform their
industries on average. For example, the tendency of corporate parents to deploy
resources into related industries may partly explain why poor performance per-
sists in some businesses. This explanation for a negative corporate-parent effect
draws on both the industrial-organization and resource-based views. Like indus-
try effects, corporate-parent effects can be explained theoretically by the
industrial-organization, resource-based, and organizational views (among
others). In general, we allow for the fact that different theoretical explanations
may be relevant for understanding the sources and persistence of the effects.
This paper identifies the effects but does not discriminate among the theoretical
explanations.
A positive corporate-parent effect arises when a diversified firm’s member
businesses outperform their industries. For example, Taco Bell’s profitability
improved during the 1980s after it was acquired by Pepsico, a beverage and
food company with operations in other fast-food businesses. In this case, mem-
bership in the corporate parent improved the profitability of the member busi-
ness in ways that were not available to the average fast-food company, and in
ways that supplemented the improvements in the business-specific effect associ-
ated with a 1984 restructuring.
Business-specific effects arise from differences in the competitive positions
of an industry’s incumbents, and also are rooted in both strategy and organiza-
tion. Throughout this paper, the term ‘competitive positioning’ refers to the
broad variety of factors that influence the relative performance of a specific firm
within an industry compared to its direct rivals within the industry. Southwest
Airlines’ performance during the 1980s was largely due to business-specific
effects based on its particular competitive strategy in the airline industry: it
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 81
paper differs in that it deals with persistence in the entire influence of the indus-
try, the corporate parent, and the specific business, regardless of whether the
influence arose from a fixed effect or from a shock. As a result, the analysis in
this paper deals with a broader set of issues that arise in the development of
strategy and in the effectiveness of organization.
Cubbin and Geroski (1987) used different methods to show endurance in
the firm-specific effects of 217 British manufacturers. Ghemawat (1991)
showed sustainability in the profits of firms covered in the PIMS database. Here,
we separately examine how industry, corporate-parent, and business-specific
effects emerge and how they are sustained. By bringing together research in the
two lines, we aim to shed light on the underlying competitive processes that
shape strategy and organization.
Our research also differs from previous studies because it is based on a
dataset that covers a wide variety of economic sectors over a period that spans
several business cycles. The screened Compustat reports contain information on
agriculture and mining, construction, manufacturing, wholesale and retail
trade, transportation, entertainment and lodging, and the service sector. Many
prior studies, including Schmalensee (1985); Rumelt (1991); Mueller (1977,
1986), and Cubbin and Geroski (1987), covered only the manufacturing sector.
As a result, our findings are more general than those of previous authors.
Finally, our research differs from previous studies in that it includes infor-
mation on segments even if we do not have a series of data on them in every year
from 1981 to 1994. Unlike Mueller (1986) and Waring (1996), we include
businesses on which we do not have a complete series because they prove to
account for a significant portion of activity in the economy. Entries and exits in
the Compustat Business-Segment Reports include acquisitions, divestitures,
and reclassifications. Thus, they often do not represent actual entries and exits
by businesses and should not be interpreted as economic entry and exit. In
McGahan and Porter (1999), we present the results of a number of tests on
selection bias with regard to exits and entries in the Compustat data. Although
we find no evidence of differences in rates of entry by high and low performers,
we do find differences in rates of survivorship for high and low performers. This
difference may be attributable to the viability of operating units or to reporting
bias. Our findings apply only to publicly traded firms, not to all businesses in
the economy. As a consequence of including businesses without a complete
series, our dataset includes information on businesses that are more varied in age
than those examined by previous authors. Our results are also less subject to sur-
vivorship bias than those of previous studies.
Methods
Our analysis involves several steps. First, we calculate the mean profitability and
the year, industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects for each
84 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
business segment in each year. Following McGahan and Porter (1999), we use
sequential, weighted-least-squares techniques to partition profits according to
the following model:
Ai,k,t = m + gt + ai,t + bk,t + fi,k,t (1)
In this equation, the dependent variable is the ratio in percent of operating
income to identifiable assets of the business segment in industry i and corpora-
tion k at time t. The terms m, gt, ai,t, bk,t, and fi,k,t represent the mean, the
year effect, the industry effect, the corporate-parent effect, and the segment-
specific effect, respectively. Industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific
effects differ by year. There is no corporate-parent effect unless a corporation has
more than one segment.
In the sequence of the estimation, we introduce effects in the following
order: mean, year, industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific. Thus, the
segment-specific effects are defined as the residual after introduction of the year,
industry, and corporate-parent effects. As a result, any reporting error that arises
systematically at the year, industry and corporate-parent levels also affects the
measured segment-specific effects. Measurement error in accounting profits and
anomalies in accounting conventions may introduce bias in our assessment of
any of the effects. For example, a change in statutory requirements on pension
plans in a particular year may influence all businesses in the economy and create
a year effect. Similarly, a change in the inventory method of a diversified firm in
a specific year may generate a corporate-parent effect in the year. We have no
hypothesis about the source or direction of bias, and therefore cannot assess its
impact.
Observations are weighted by assets in the calculation of each effect to
assure that effects are not skewed by the influence of small segments.
Rather than report the thousands of estimates, we report a nested ANOVA
on equation (1).1 Abnormal profits are defined for each segment in each year as
the difference between profit and the grand mean; that is, as r i,k,t = Ai,k,t –m =
gt + ai,t + bk,t + fi,k,t.
Second, we present a set of charts that show the path of average abnormal
profits in the emergence and sustainability of high and low performance. The
charts partition abnormal profits by type of effect for segments that eventually
become high and low performers, and for segments that once were high and low
performers. For the emergence analysis, a business segment is classified as a high
performer if the sum of its industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific
effects (i.e., ai,t+bk,t+fi,k,t) is greater than the median for all segments in the
last year for which we have data on the segment, and as a low performer if
the sum (i.e., ai,t+bk,t+fi,k,t) is less than the median in the last year for which
we have data. The partitioning is based on the median rather than the mean
because the median identifies half of the segments as high performers, and half
as low performers. If we were to break the sample by using the mean, then
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 85
Data
December 1977 the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) has required
publicly-traded firms to report operating income, identifiable assets, and sales
by 4-digit SIC (i.e., by business segment). We exclude data prior to 1981
because of the high proportion of missing records in the reports for 1977–1980.
From the Compustat reports for 1981 through 1994, we eliminate records
without a primary SIC designation, and segments in SICs that are not identified
with actual industries (i.e., those described as ‘not elsewhere classified’, ‘non-
classifiable establishments’, or ‘government, excluding finance’). In addition, we
eliminate financial businesses designated as ‘depository institutions’ with SICs
in the 6000s, and segments that are the only organizations in their primary SIC
classifications in a particular year. Following previous authors, we exclude small
segments with sales less than $10 million or with assets less than $10 million
because their financial results are volatile and because they are often created for
the disposition of assets prior to exit, for example.
After screening and calculating lagged effects, our dataset contains 58,340
observations. These screens and characteristics of the dataset are the same as in
McGahan and Porter (1999). The screened dataset covers a substantial portion
of US economic activity, accounting for about half of non-financial corporate
sales and nearly a quarter of non-financial corporate assets reported to the
Internal Revenue Service (IRS) from 1985 to 1992. We have information on an
average of 4,488 business segments in each year, with 5.7 years of information
on average for each segment. The dataset covers 638 industries, 12,304 business
segments, and 7,005 corporations, of which 1,886 are diversified (i.e., report
information on more than one included segment). Diversified corporations in
our dataset participate in 2.6 business segments on average. The mean ratio of
operating income to identifiable assets among the business segments in the
screened sample is 9.94% with a variance of 248%. The average business seg-
ment has $901.2 million in identifiable assets. There is no statistically signifi-
cant difference in the average size or parent diversification level among
businesses with performance above and below the norm.
Because the average reported business segment is large, and because there
are just 2.6 measured segments per diversified parent, we believe that the aver-
age business segment is larger than a true operating business unit. There is
evidence that firms may aggregate activity beyond the true 4-digit level in their
reports on segments to limit disclosure and because a maximum of only 10 seg-
ments must be reported. The implied aggregation in reported business
segments suggests the pooling of activity that would otherwise be categorized
in more than one 4-digit SIC. Such pooling would tend to dampen industry
effects and enhance business-specific effects because we infer industry profits
from the overly diverse activities of segments categorized in the same 4-digit
SIC and assess the business-specific effects as the residual. If the business units of
diversified firms are related, the pooling also may dampen corporate-parent
effects because we infer the influence of the corporate parent from the profits of
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 87
Empirical results
In this section, we first present the results of a nested ANOVA to verify the
presence of year, industry, corporate-parent, and business-specific effects on high
and low performance. We then introduce and discuss charts that show the emer-
gence and sustainability of high and low performers. Finally, we present the
results of statistical analyses to confirm and expand on the regularities identified
in the ANOVA and in the charts.
Table 1 shows the results of the nested ANOVA on equation (1), which we use
to verify the existence of the various effects. The analysis for all segments shows
that all types of effects are significant at the 1% level except corporate-
parent effects. Industry effects, while significant, may be understated because of
reporting error. We preserve corporate-parent effects in the analysis despite their
lack of significance in the aggregate because of their theoretical importance and
because McGahan and Porter (1997) and McGahan (1999) show a strong rela-
tionship between corporate-parent and industry effects. In a nested ANOVA,
McGahan and Porter (1997) show that the time-invariant portions of year,
industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects add to incremental R2 in
nearly the same proportions as in Table 1.
88
S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Table 1: Sequential analysis of variance of equation (1)a
Source d.f. Incr. R2 F-Statc d.f. Incr. R2 F-Statc d.f. Incr. R2 F-Statc
Figure 1 shows the emergence of high and low performance in the sample. The
vertical axis represents the sizes of effects (as the contribution to the total ratio of
operating income to identifiable assets). The horizontal axis represents the num-
ber of years prior to the final year for which we have data on the segment. For
each segment, we lose the first observation in our statistical analysis of persis-
tence. Thus, we have a maximum of 13 years of data on each segment. Segments
are included in the calculations for the charts even if we do not have a complete
series of data on them. Thus, the plotted averages at the right side of the figure
(above year 0) represent the average of the effects in the last years for which data
is available. The information above the horizontal axis at the year marked 10, for
example, describes the averages for segments 10 years prior to the date (year 0)
at which they are classified as high performers. As a result of this approach,
the averages at the left side of the figure are calculated from fewer observations
than the averages at the right side of the figure. This occurs because segments
enter into the dataset continuously. At the bottom of the chart, we indicate the
number of observations for each year.
In the figure, the average abnormal profits among high and low performers
at year 0 are 9.3% and –11.8%, respectively. These numbers differ from each
other in absolute value for three reasons. First, high and low performers are iden-
tified by reference to the median profitability, not to mean profitability. Second,
various calendar years are represented in the calculation of averages at year 0.
Third, differences in size by assets can generate differences in the average
abnormal profits for high and low performers because the averages are weighted
by assets. One notable feature of the results in Figure 1 is that there is as much
net entry into the low-performing cohort as into the high-performing cohort
during the period, which suggests no systematic distortion associated with
entry. The total number of segments is about 4,000 in each of the final six years
because we restrict the dataset to include only those segments for which we have
six years of data. Most of the entry into the dataset occurs in years 6–12. The
number varies across the last six years because some segments are not observed
in the dataset for six continuous years. Entry can occur for a number of reasons,
including acquisition, the formation of a new company, the entry by an estab-
lished company into a new business, and changes in the conventions for report-
ing by an established company.
Figure 1 reveals several important empirical regularities. On average, a seg-
ment which is ultimately a high performer shows profits significantly greater
than the norm over the entire period for which data are available. Highly profit-
able segments have a history of high performance. This suggests that the causes
of high profit tend to endure and perhaps even accumulate. This result contra-
dicts the theory that high accounting profits occur subsequent to a period of low
or moderate accounting profits during which companies invest for later reward.
Instead, high performance among Compustat segments appears to result from
product- or factor-market imperfections that endure. The figure shows that the
average low performer shows profit slightly above the norm 12 years earlier.
Previously satisfactory performance is typical of segments that subsequently
become low performers. The Appendix contains an analysis of segments for
which we have a complete data series over the period from 1981 to 1994.
Survivorship is associated with higher profits for both high and low performers.
Figure 1 also shows that the influence of industry, corporate-parent, and
segment-specific effects differs markedly for high and low performers. The
influence of year effects is modest and nearly the same for high and low per-
formers, which suggests that the business cycle has little enduring effect on the
emergence of abnormal profits.
For high performers, participation in an attractive industry strongly con-
tributes to abnormal returns. This result supports theoretical explanations that
emphasize the interaction between industry structure and firm positioning as
crucial to the emergence of superior performance. Affiliation with a high-
performing corporate parent is also associated with the emergence of abnormal
returns, although to a somewhat lesser extent. This finding supports the idea
that a corporation’s ability to achieve superior performance through diversifi-
cation may be related to the attractiveness of the other industries in which it
competes. Empirically, industry effects are nearly as great as segment-specific
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 91
We next use statistical methods to develop more precise findings. The analysis
confirms our previous results, and reveals additional regularities. To assess rela-
tive importance, we examined the average and standard deviation by type of
effect for high and low performers in the emergence and sustainability of abnor-
mal profits. Table 2 shows the results. The table indicates that:
• Large low performers show profitability closer to the norm than large high performers.
As a result, abnormal profitability is greater for high performers than low perform-
ers. The average abnormal profitability for high performers is greater in
absolute value than for low performers. This asymmetry is possible because
the effects are calculated by weighting each observation by the size of the
segment.
• Industry effects are especially important to high performance. Industry effects are
greater in size than any other type of effect in the sustainability of high per-
formance, and are nearly as large as segment-specific effects in the emer-
gence of high performance. Emerging high performers tend to participate
in structurally attractive industries, and sustained high performers benefit
from participation in attractive industries that remain attractive. Among
low performers, industry effects are considerably smaller in absolute value
than segment-specific effects in both cases.
94
S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Table 2 Importance of industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects on abnormal profitabilitya
Emergence Sustainability
Abnormal Profitc 5.733 14.153 –3.850 12.268 4.041 15.316 –2.727 11.538
Year 0.121 1.224 0.182 1.214 0.128 1.219 0.179 1.218
Industry 2.099 6.974 –0.486 5.947 1.767 7.108 –0.320 5.787
Corporate-parentd 1.032 6.538 –0.090 5.642 0.765 6.522 0.118 5.627
Segment-specific 2.481 12.546 –3.456 11.743 1.381 13.210 –2.704 11.283
a Includes only segments for which we have at least six years of data
b Average and standard deviation over all years for which we have data
c Sum of year, industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects
d Corporate-parent effects are reported as averages over all corporations, not just diversified corporations
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 95
• Although corporate-parent effects are consistently smaller in absolute value than seg-
ment-specific and industry effects, they contribute positively to high performance.
Among low performers, corporate-parent effects slightly offset other effects. Positive
corporate-parent effects contribute to both the emergence and sustainability
of high performance. High performers tend to belong to corporate parents
that positively contribute to profitability. On average, low performance is
slightly offset by positive corporate-parent effects, although corporate-par-
ent effects on low performers are so small as to be negligible.
• Segment-specific effects are important to both high and low performance, especially to
low performance. In the emergence and sustainability of high performance,
segment-specific effects account for 43% and 34%, respectively, of abnor-
mal profits on average. In the emergence and sustainability of low perfor-
mance, segment-specific effects account for 90% and 99%, respectively, of
abnormal profits on average. Thus, segment-specific effects are important to
high performance, and dominate low performance.
• The effects of the business cycle are not important in the emergence and sustainability
of high and low performance. High and low performance is not materially
influenced by year effects. On average, year effects influence both high and
low performers positively in our sample. (This result is possible because we
have more observations for years at the peaks of business cycles than at the
troughs of business cycles.)
See McGahan and Porter (1997) for an analysis that breaks down the contribu-
tion of industry, corporate-parent and business-specific effects for agriculture &
mining, manufacturing, transportation, wholesale & retail trade, lodging
& entertainment, and services. While the decomposition of variance in Table 2
confirms the results in Figures 1 and 2, it does not provide direct evidence on
the rates at which abnormal profits emerge and are sustained. The next section
provides a direct assessment of the relative rates of change in each type of effect.
Figures 1 and 2 reveal that some types of effects appear to diminish over time
while others appear to accumulate. To explore these regularities, we use a widely
adopted statistical approach to measure the persistence in the incremental com-
ponents of effects. Specifically, we stipulate that for each observation, the year,
industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects each consist of a fixed
component and an incremental component. We also stipulate that the sum of
these effects (which equals the abnormal profit) consists of a fixed component
and an incremental component. For example, the segment-specific effect, fi,k,t,
is assumed to equal fi,k+si,k,t. The fixed component, fi,k, is the average amount by
which an effect differs from zero in every year for which we have data on the
segment. The incremental component, si,k,t, is the additional amount (above or
below the fixed component) that arises in year t.
96 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
ment are treated as exits and subsequent entries. We do not assess the persis-
tence of profitability between years for any segment unless we have data on both
the current and previous year for the segment; as a consequence, we omit infor-
mation on a segment for the year of a change in corporate parent. Our results
should be interpreted carefully as applying only to those segments that retain
their identities for at least six years, and not to all segments in a particular year.
Table 3 shows the results. Panel (a) shows statistics on the emergence of
abnormal profits, and panel (b) shows statistics on the sustainability of abnormal
profits. The first section of each panel shows the average estimates of the fixed
(i.e., fi,k) and incremental components of each effect (si,k,t). The second section of
each panel shows estimated rates of persistence in the incremental components
and the third section shows goodness-of-fit of the persistence estimates.
In several instances, the estimated rate of persistence in the sum of effects is
greater than the estimated rates for each of the constituent effects. For example,
in panel (b), the estimated rate of persistence among high performers in the sum
of effects is 80.6%, which is greater than each of the estimates for the year,
industry, corporate-parent, and segment-specific effects of 65.8%, 76.6%,
71.5%, and 70.8%, respectively. This outcome is possible because the fixed and
incremental components of effects vary asynchronously, so that aggregation
across effects can yield greater stability than in each of the constituent effects.
Mann–Whitney tests indicate that the means are significantly different at the
99% level for high and low performers in every case except for the following: the
year effects, and the incremental component of the corporate-parent effects.
Note that the fixed component of the corporate-parent effects is significantly
different for high and low performers, and that the rates of persistence in the
corporate-parent effects are significantly different for high and low performers.
Thus, we draw our conclusions about the year, industry, corporate-parent, seg-
ment-specific and overall abnormal profits with confidence of their statistical
robustness. In supplementary analyses on both the emergence and the sustain-
ability of abnormal profits, we found no significant correlation between the
fixed components, the persistence rates, the sizes of businesses, and the amount
of diversification.
The results in panel (a) suggest the following regularities in the emergence of
abnormal profits for businesses that maintain their identities for at least six
years:
• On average among businesses that retain their identities for six or more years, low per-
formance accumulates faster than high performance. Panel (a) shows a persistence
rate in abnormal profits for low performers that is greater than for high per-
formers (82.1% vs. 77.4%). This occurs because the incremental compo-
nent of high performance is small on average; high performance is largely
fixed. Persistence in the incremental component is not as relevant to the
emergence of high performance as low performance. The incremental com-
ponents of low performance accumulate over time on average.
Table 3 Estimates of persistence in the incremental components of effects
98
(a) The Emergence of Abnormal Profitsa
S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Average effect c 0.121 0.182 2.099 –0.486 1.032 –0.090 2.481 –3.456 5.733 –3.850
Fixed component d 0.043 –2.249 8.180 0.128 7.673 –11.920 –18.365 –4.445 11.733 –8.794
Incr. component d 0.727 2.989 –5.724 –0.635 –6.735 12.573 20.136 0.487 –1.680 5.752
Estimated persistence rates
Average d 0.642 0.658 0.784 0.744 0.638 0.787 0.717 0.592 0.774 0.821
Standard deviation e 0.005 0.009 0.002 0.006 0.002 0.058 0.020 0.021 0.000 0.000
Goodness of fit f 0.479 0.475 0.880 0.680 0.698 0.362 0.795 0.911 0.936 0.459
Average effect c 0.128 0.179 1.767 –0.320 0.765 0.118 1.381 –2.704 4.041 –2.727
Fixed component d –0.644 –1.966 1.745 7.369 -0.460 –4.697 –2.730 –25.662 –0.742 10.792
Incr. component d 1.377 2.739 0.444 –7.436 1.535 5.232 1.916 24.146 4.926 –10.868
Estimated persistence rates
Average d 0.661 0.643 0.760 0.771 0.643 0.781 0.620 0.712 0.808 0.753
Standard deviation e 0.004 0.006 0.002 0.003 0.028 0.024 0.029 0.015 0.000 0.000
Goodness of fit f 0.472 0.482 0.759 0.873 0.428 0.624 0.809 0.903 0.915 0.457
a Includes only segments for which we have at least six years of data
b Corporate-parent effects reported as averages over all corporations, but corporate-parent persistence rates are reported only for diversified corporations
c The averages of the fixed and incremental components do not sum to the average effect because the components are weighted to reflect the precision of persistence estimates
d Weighted by the inverse of the variance on each estimate
e Weighted by the inverse of the variance on the standard errors
f This measure is the weighted average of the R2 in the OLS regression on each segment; the weights are the inverses of the standard errors
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 99
• Industry effects accumulate over time for the average high performer but not for the aver-
age low performer. In panel (a), the average incremental component of the
industry effect is negative for both high and low performers. Persistence
in the negative incremental component for high performers indicates that
industry effects diverge from the economic mean on average. Persistence in
the negative incremental component for low performers indicates that indus-
try effects for these firms converge toward the economic mean on average.
Thus, industry effects contribute to the emergence of high performance but
not to the emergence of low performance. The incremental components of
industry effects are also more persistent for high performers than low per-
formers.
• Corporate-parent effects accumulate and contribute to divergence from the mean for
both high and low performers. In panel (a), the incremental components of the
corporate-parent effects take the same signs as the incremental components
of the sum of effects. Thus, corporate-parent effects contribute to the diver-
gence of abnormal profits from the mean. Corporate-parent effects on high
performers are about half as large as industry effects on average, and persist
at a lower rate than industry effects. Corporate-parent effects on low per-
formers are smaller than any other type of effect (including year), although
estimated rates of persistence in the corporate-parent effects on low per-
formers show greater variability than any other type of effect.
• The incremental components of the segment-specific effects persist at a greater rate for
high performers than low performers on average. In the emergence of high perfor-
mance, segment-specific effects diminish over time on average (given the
positive incremental component on average). Panel (a) also shows a positive
incremental component of the segment-specific effect for low performers,
which indicates that segment-specific effects diverge from the mean for the
average low performer. In panel (a), incremental segment-specific effects
persist at 71.7% for high performers and 59.2% for low performers.
Panel (b) shows persistence rates in the sustainability of high and low perfor-
mance for businesses that maintain their identities for at least six years. The
results indicate:
• On average among segments that retain their identities for six or more years, the incre-
mental components of abnormal profits deteriorate at about the same rate for high and
low performers on average. Panel (b) shows a persistence rate in the sum of
effects for high performers that is about the same as for low performers
(80.6% vs. 81.34%). In the sustainability of abnormal profits, the erosion
of the incremental components of high performance occurs at about the
same rate as the erosion of the incremental components of low performance.
The competitive processes that cause regression to the mean in high perfor-
mance appear to have similar effect to the corrective processes that cause
regression to the mean in low performance.
100 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Conclusion
retain their identities for at least six years. Our purpose is to report on empirical
regularities in the influence of year, industry, corporate-parent and business-
specific effects on high and low performance over time. This study differs from
prior research by examining differences in the emergence and sustainability of
abnormal profits, by examining changes in the influence of effects over time,
and by distinguishing differences among high and low performers.
We chart the emergence and sustainability of high and low performance
among a large group of firms engaged in the US economy, and corroborate the
results using statistical methods. In analyzing changes over time, we distinguish
between the incremental and fixed components of abnormal profit and note that
the standard measure of persistence applies only to the incremental components.
We are unable to explore the differences in industry, corporate parent, and busi-
ness-specific factors between business segments that retain their identity for six
years and those that are sold, acquired, closed, or redefined. The persistence rates
reported in this paper apply only to the incremental component of the effects for
business segments with at least six years of longevity. Some previous studies
have reported persistence estimates that have been interpreted more generally.
Because the incremental components of abnormal profit may be quite small,
this misinterpretation can lead to incorrect inferences about the emergence and
sustainability of abnormal profits. To best convey our results, we interpret the
persistence estimates in context of the charts presented earlier.
The analysis reveals the following broad regularities about the process of
competition:
1 Industry effects are more important than business-specific and corporate-
parent effects in the sustainability of high performance. Business-specific
effects are more important than industry and corporate-parent effects in the
emergence and sustainability of low performance, and in the emergence of
high performance.
2 Industry and corporate-parent effects are more important on average to high
performance than to low performance. Business-specific effects are more
important on average to low performance than to high performance.
3 On average, high performance is preceded by high performance, whereas
low performance is preceded by average performance.
4 High and low performance erode at about the same rate.
While our analysis is descriptive, the results are consistent with fundamental
principles of strategy and organization. The emergence of low performance is
distinguished not by a history of poor performance but by the onset of an
adverse competitive positioning in a situation where industry and corporate-
parent effects are neutral on average. The absence of negative industry effects on
low performance suggests that low performance is not triggered by competitive
imitation. Instead, low performance apparently emerges when a competitor that
initially generated an average return suffers from an eroding position relative to
rivals.
102 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
enhanced methods that account for complex relationships between the esti-
mated effects (for example, see Hambrick and D’Aveni, 1988).
The results also indicate important relationships in the causal explanations
favored by theorists aligned with the industrial-organization view, the resource-
based view, property rights explanations, transaction-cost economics, and orga-
nizational ecology. Each theoretical lens may be particularly powerful at a
specific point in the evolution of a business. The greatest promise for further
theoretical study may be in integrating the various explanations and in demon-
strating how they can be related to a broader framework that links strategic and
organizational choices to the industry, corporate, and business-specific context.
The central analyses in our paper raise several questions about patterns of emergence and
sustainability for newly tracked segments and segments on which we have a complete
series of data. In the emergence analysis, for example, the pattern of high performance
suggests that newly tracked segments may enter at the same high rate of profitability as
segments on which we have a complete series of data. In this Appendix, we report
the analyses for segments on which we have complete series and indicate differences in
the results. A principal finding is that the segments on which we have a complete series
have higher profits on average than those on which we do not have a complete
series. Otherwise, the broad patterns reported in the body of the paper for the entire
sample also hold for the segments that are analyzed in this Appendix.
In Figure 1, high performers show profits significantly greater than the norm 12
years prior to the date on which they are classified as superior. This regularity raises a
question about whether high performance is immediately evident among segments that
enter the Compustat dataset during the period under study. Figure A1 shows the emer-
gence of high and low performance for only those segments on which we have a com-
plete series. The pattern for high performers is strikingly similar to the pattern for the
full cross-section of high performers. For low performers, however, the pattern is some-
what different. The comparison suggests the following relationships for the average
segment as abnormal profits emerge:
• At the time that a segment is first tracked by Compustat, its abnormal profits are
about the same as the abnormal profits of mature performers in its cohort.
• The low performance that emerges among newly tracked businesses is considerably
more severe than the low performance of mature businesses.
Figure 2, which shows the sustainability of high and low performance, raises the possi-
bility that abnormal profits steadily erode for surviving segments. There is ambiguity in
Figure 2 because surviving segments are grouped with those no longer tracked. (Recall
that segments may be dropped from Compustat because of exit, privatization, merger of
the corporate parent, sale of the division, or reclassification of the division to another
104 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Figure A1 The emergence of abnormal profits among segments with a complete series
SIC.) Figure A2 shows the sustainability of high and low performance for only those
segments on which we have a complete series. A comparison suggests the following rela-
tionships:
• ‘Exit’ among the high performers in the Compustat database occurs after a greater
than average decrease in abnormal returns.
• The high performance of businesses that do not exit is initially better than the aver-
age for all high performers.
• The low performers in the Compustat database that eventually exit show worse
profits than the average among low performers.
• The low performance of businesses that do not exit is initially better than the aver-
age for all low performers.
Survivorship is associated with higher than average profitability for both high and low
performers. The longevity of low performance in both cases suggests that low performers
are locked into their poor positions for several years, making exit difficult. Even long-
tracked low performers recover only to average profitability during the 12-year period
subsequent to their initial classification.
Among high performers, those that exit the Compustat database have seen a large
portion of their abnormally high profits erode prior to their exit. Thus, there is an
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 105
asymmetry between patterns of entry and exit for high performers. Whereas newly
tracked high performers show profits comparable to those of mature high performers,
exiting high performers are less successful.
A comparison of Figures 2 and A2 reveals a higher segment-specific effect among
long-tracked high performers compared to` the average high performer. The favorable
segment-specific effects of exiting high performers diminish quicker than those of sur-
viving high performers. By contrast, the adverse segment-specific effects of exiting low
performers appear to be larger than those of surviving low performers. Figures 2 and A2
suggest the following hypotheses about the sustainability of abnormal profits for the
average business:
• Surviving high performers are distinguished by particularly favorable segment-
specific effects, suggesting an unusually distinctive position.
• Surviving low performers are distinguished by less adverse segment-specific effects
compared to the average low performer.
One interpretation that is consistent with these patterns is that exit from Compustat
occurs for high performers in attractive industries and attractive parents after their com-
petitive positions erode. While exit is a viable option for such segments, it may not be
viable for the typical low performer. Instead, low performers may be forced to reposition
within their industries over a period of several years.
106 S T R AT E G I C O R G A N I Z AT I O N 1 ( 1 )
Notes
We are grateful to Raffi Amit, Pankaj Ghemawat, Belen Villalonga, Geoff Waring, three anony-
mous referees, the editors, and to participants in seminars at the Academy of Management,
Harvard, INSEAD, Stanford, and the University of California at Berkeley for comments and dis-
cussions related to this paper. Special thanks to Arthur Schleifer for extensive discussions about
statistical methods. Thanks to Todd Eckler, Jan Rivkin, and Sarah Woolverton for help in extract-
ing and assimilating data. Boston University’s Systems Research Center, the Boston University
Institute for Leading in a Dynamic Economy (BUILDE) and the Division of Research at the
Harvard Business School provided generous financial support for this project.
1 Equation (1) is not estimable through a sequential ANOVA because the model is fully speci-
fied. Full specification is necessary to capture intertemporal changes in effects. See McGahan
and Porter (1997) for a nested ANOVA on a model in which year, corporate-parent, and
business-specific effects do vary by year.
2 Note that equation (2) can be derived from the following expressions: si,k,t=rSS,i,ksi,k,t–1+ki,k,t
and fi,k,t=fi,k + si,k,t. The derivation requires substitution of si,k,t–1=fi,k,t–1–fi,k into
si,k,t=rSS,i,ksi,k,t–1+ki,k,t, and substitution of the resulting expression for si,k,t into fi,k,t=
fi,k + si,k,t.
3 We adopt the notation that an underlined subscript indicates the average over the obser-
vations denoted by the subscript. There is no information in either the ratio
(fi,k+rSS,i,ksi,k,t–1)/(fi,k+si,k,t) or (di,k+rSS,i,k fi,k,t–1)/fi,k,t because si,k,t=rSS,i,ksi,k,t–1 and fi,k,t=
di,k+rSS,i,k fi,k,t–1; thus, (fi,k+rSS,i,ksi,k,t–1)/(fi,k+si,k,t)=(di,k+rSS,i,k fi,k,t–1)/fi,k,t=100%.
4 Consider, for example, equation (2) for business segment i,k in 1989. The equation stipu-
lates that fi,k,89 is a function of ki,k,89. Now consider equation (2) for the same segment in
1990. This equation indicates that fi,k,90 is a function of fi,k,89, but we cannot claim that the
two records are independent, because fi,k,89 is correlated with ki,k,89 in the prior record.
Thus, the estimate of the coefficient on fi,k,t is systematically biased.
5 See Waring (1996) and McGahan and Porter (1999) as well as Nickell (1981). We con-
ducted several simulations to verify Nickell’s approach, and found that it performed quite
well except for extreme OLS estimates. We therefore limited the Nickell corrections to
absolute values less than or equal to one. Thanks to Geoff Waring for discussions about this
approach.
6 The variance of each of the OLS estimates of persistence, which we here denote rx,i,k (where x
may signify year, industry, corporate-parent, segment-specific, or the sum of effects) is given
by var(rx,i,k)=
[var(xi,k,t)–est(rx,i,k)2var(xi,k,t–1)]/[(n–2)var(xi,k,t–1)] where n represents the number of years of
data for the segment.
7 In the calculation of goodness-of-fit, the weights are the inverses of the variances of the sam-
pling variances, which we obtain from Var(vx,i,k)=2Fx4/(n–1) and est(Fx2)=
(n Var(xi,k,t)–est(rx,i,k)2 n Var(xi,k,t–1))/(n–2), where Fx is the standard deviation of the popula-
tion parameter rx,i,k and vx,i,k is the sampling variance of the estimate of rx,i,k (see Hald,
1952: 203 and Kendall, 1952: 229). Thanks to Arthur Schleifer for this derivation.
References
Cubbin, J. and Geroski, P. (1987) ‘The Convergence of Profits in the Long Run: Inter-firm and
Inter-industry Comparisons’, Journal of Industrial Economics 35(4): 427–42.
M C G A H A N & P O RT E R : A B N O R M A L P RO F I T S 107
Furman, Jeffrey L. and McGahan, Anita M. (2002) ‘Turnarounds’, Managerial and Decision
Economics 23(4–5): 283–300.
Ghemawat, Pankaj (1991) Commitment: The Dynamic of Strategy. New York: Free Press.
Hald, A. (1952) Statistical Theory with Engineering Applications. New York: Wiley & Sons.
Hambrick, Donald C. and D’Aveni, Richard (1988) ‘Corporate Failure as a Downward Spiral’,
Administrative Science Quarterly 33(April): 1–23.
Kendall, Maurice G. (1952) The Advanced Theory of Statistics, Vol. I, 5th edn. London: Charles
Griffen & Co.
McGahan, Anita M. (1999) ‘The Performance of US Corporations: 1981–1994’, Journal of
Industrial Economics 47(4): 373–98.
McGahan, Anita M. and Porter, Michael E. (1997) ‘How Much Does Industry Matter, Really?’,
Strategic Management Journal 18(4): 15–30.
McGahan, Anita M. and Porter, Michael E. (1999) ‘The Persistence of Shocks to Profitability:
Comparing the Market-Structure and Chicago Views’, Review of Economics and Statistics 81(1):
43–53.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1977) ‘The Persistence of Profits Above the Norm’, Economica 44 (November):
369–80.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1986) Profits in the Long Run. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nickell, Stephen (1981) ‘Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects’, Econometrica 49(6):
1417–26.
Rumelt, Richard (1991) ‘How Much Does Industry Matter?’, Strategic Management Journal 12(3):
167–85.
Schmalensee, Richard (1985) ‘Do Markets Differ Much?’, American Economic Review 75(3):
341–51.
Waring, Geoff (1996) ‘Industry Differences in the Persistence of Firm-Specific Returns’, American
Economic Review 86(5): 1253–1265.
Anita M. McGahan is Professor and Chairman of the Strategy & Policy group at the
Boston University School of Management and a Senior Institute Associate at the Harvard
Institute on Strategy and Competitiveness. She has experience at Morgan Stanley and
McKinsey & Company, and was recently named one of five international experts on the
strategic use of technology by CIO magazine. McGahan is the author of over 60 articles and
case studies on industry transformation and competition, and is currently writing a book
entitled How Industries Evolve. Recent publications include ‘What Do We Know About
Variance in Accounting Profitability?’ with Michael E. Porter in Management Science (July 2002)
and ‘Turnarounds’ with Jeffrey L. Furman in Managerial and Decision Economics (June–August,
2002). Address: 595 Commonwealth Avenue, Boston, MA 02215, USA. [email:
[email protected]]
launched his second major body of work on competitiveness and economic development.
Porter’s third major body of work deals with the relationship between competition and
society.The holder of eight honorary doctorates, Porter has won numerous awards for his
books, articles, and public service in several fields. Address: Soldiers Field, Boston, MA 02163,
USA. [email: [email protected]]