Economic Development, Organization & Territory
Economic Development, Organization & Territory
Economic Development, Organization & Territory
Abstract
The emergence of new models of development and the reversal of territorial trajectories have shown the incapacity of old
theoretical models in fitting the changing reality. The emergence of localized networks among firms and external economies has
led to a new paradigm for economic development based on territory.
The paper stresses the existence of different patterns of local development and deals with the key variables for the singling out
their typology.
Résumé
L'émergence de nouveaux modèles de développement et le renversement des trajectoires territoriales ont démontré l'incapacité
des anciens modèles théoriques à comprendre la réalité économique en voie de transformation. L'émergence de réseaux
d'entreprises territorialisés et les économies externes ont conduit à un nouveau paradigme du développement économique qui
est fortement fondé sur le territoire.
Cet article souligne l'existence de plusieurs modèles de développement local et discute les variables clefs pour la construction
d'une typologie de ces modèles.
Garofoli Gioacchino. Economic development, organization of production and territory. In: Revue d’économie industrielle, vol.
64, 2e trimestre 1993. pp. 22-37;
doi : https://doi.org/10.3406/rei.1993.1475
https://www.persee.fr/doc/rei_0154-3229_1993_num_64_1_1475
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT,
ORGANIZATION OF PRODUCTION
AND TERRITORY
I. — INTRODUCTION
Iwill deal, in this paper, with territory and economic development, underlying
the active role of the territory in the process of development. With respect
to these issues, particularly to the relationship between economic development and
territorial organization of production, my departure point is that we need a bridge
between theory and reality, in fact we are in a phase of transformation not only
with reference to economic organization (and world economic scenarios) but also
to economic theory.
With the new models of development there are emerging new actors (local
institutions, local State, collective private subjects/actors,...) that are able to influence
the process of economic and social transformations. These actors have been
forgotten from previous theoretical schemes. Moreover there is the breakdown of
the idea of deterministic laws of development and new opportunities are
emerging. Local communities have some chances (and responsibilities) to promote deve-
The second point of this introduction concerns the relationship between local
and global/international. It could seem a quite strange position to investigate the
role of local economies in a world more and more globalized. But we must take
into account the following two phenomena :
1) The crisis of the fordist model and the decreasing role of the forms of social
regulation at the national level ;
So, the increasing role of external economies and agglomeration advantages and
the internalization of production lead to a contemporary puzzle posed by the
marked reagglomeration of production, in one hand, and the globalization of
economic flows on the other (Scott and Storper, 1990).
Local and international become, then, the two poles of a new dialectics of
development : the firm is then oriented to the local dimension (to turn into account
the stock of techno-scientific and cultural and professional knowledges) and to
the external dimension (looking for stimuli and provocations for the innovation,
the productive differentiation, to organize new networks of exchanges and
collaborations).
The development policy based on the "transfer" of the model based on big
business (by implicitly accepting the theory of automatic mechanisms of income
multiplier and new economic linkages) has characterized the greater part of
government interventions for a number of decades both in developed and developing
countries.
Local specificities are mainly based on localized networks among firms and also
on the specific relationships between economic structure and the environment and
the local "milieu". All this leads to the following points :
— the crucial role of local policies for development (cf., especially, local
solidarities and the forms of social regulation introduced at local level).
Plants and firms vary not only in terms of the output they produce, but also
in terms of their internal structure and their relations to a wider economic milieu.
In particular, they tend to seek out to the maximum possible degree both internal
and external economies. Economies of both types break down into two sub-
categories, related to scale and scope effects.
Internal economies of scale may break down under certain circumstances (e.g.
related to changes in technology or market conditions) giving rise to horizontal
disintegration in which producers of any type become smaller and more
numerous, thus tending to increase external economies of scale. Second, internal
economies of scope also may begin to decay leading to vertical disintegration (or
intensification of the social division of labour), thus promoting external economies of
scope through the proliferation of specialized but interdependent producers (Scott
and Storper, 1990).
The reasons why horizontal and vertical disintegration may occur are many and
varied, but one general factor of special significance involves the destabilization
and increasing contestability of markets. In these conditions, large batch
production of standardized products combined with vertical integration (over an
extended series of tasks) becomes increasingly inefficient, and levels of disintegration
will tend to rise. The net result is a shift of the production system in the direction
of a complex of smaller specialized plants focusing on small batch outputs and
Summarising this point, it is possible to say that the key element governing the
shape and substance of productive systems is the interplay between internal and
external economies. Combining the two variables we can obtain, for example, the
following four possible alternatives of productive systems (cf. Figure 1) :
Internal economies
Low High
!
External economies
Hierarchical Cooperative
networks links
All this means that not only we are in presence of a plurality of local models
of development but also that predetermined stages of development do not exist
or, in other terms, that general laws of transformation cannot be established.
With this kind of exercise we can only refer to structured possibilities for the
organization of production. These possibilities are in reality defined by and
realized only when they are constituted in the form of historically - and geographically
- specific technological-institutional systems.
d) social actors and social structure (i.e., local vs. external firms, social
structure and prevalence of previous productive relations, reproduction of skills and
entrepreneurial capacities, management culture and norms) ;
f) information system ;
g) regulatory institutions.
(3) For a wider discussion of these points cf., for example, Garofoli, 1991 a ; Scott and Storper, 1990.
1) use of local resources (e.g., work, local historically accumulated capital, entre-
preneurship, specific knowledge of production processes, specific professional tasks
and material resources) ;
Among the endogenous patterns of development we will deal now with the local
systems of small firms which represent the most interesting cases, especially because
they represent the "sublimation" of the model of flexible specialization.
As it has been already stated, the relationship between the economy and the
economic milieu and, in the context of strictly economic relations, the
relationship between firms are determinant elements of the local pattern of development.
3 . A high level of division of labour between firms in the local productive system
that gives rise to very close input-output relations, both intrasectoral and inter-,
sectoral. The high horizontal integration of production depends upon low costs
of transaction among local firms.
4. The large number of local agents (the "plurality of protagonists") and the
lack of a leader or dominant firm. This prevents the formation of a monopsonis-
tic market for subcontracting, avoiding an excessive bargaining power of "mother"
firms and leads to diffuse adoption of "trial and error" behaviour. This implies
a greater likelihood of finding satisfactory solutions to economic problems by at
least some actors, followed by immediate imitation by other actors.
a) outlet markets ;
b) alternative technologies ;
c) new raw materials ;
d) components and intermediate products which could be used in the
production cycle ;
e) new marketing, commercial and financial techniques.
The importance of the model based on the system of small firms and of the
analysis of this model for a new theoretical approach on development lies on the
following issues that have emerged from the research :
a) the crucial role of external economies embodied on the territory, that means
capability to reproduce locally specific knowledges, professional tasks and "savoir
faire" that leads to the possibility to use different forms of organization of
production without taking into account only differences in cost of labour, cost of
capital and land ;
c) the existence of a balance between the rules of the market and the rules of
social regulation at local level, that means introduction of specific institutions for
overcoming some types of market failure and for taking into account the
necessity and the value of social solidarity.
We must consider, moreover, that the model based on the system of small firms
is, in any case, a dynamic model, that means the conditions for the survival of
the system are changing in time. Then, it seems necessary to reflect on the
strategic variables for the strengthening of these local productive systems.
The conditions for survival change constantly : the system of small firms is a
pattern of continuous change and not of mere adaptation, both in the
interrelationships within the area (relationships among firms, interrelationships with the
economic "milieu" and with the institutions) and those with the outside forces
(the market, the other competing areas, the other territorial systems). All this has
obvious consequences on the placing of the local system in the territorial division
of labour. Change and innovation are therefore the conditions for the survival
of the system of small firms. This being the case, it is necessary to transform the
local system, which entails an ability to understand the relative position of the
local system and to predict the scenario in the medium-to-long term. It is difficult
for individual small firms to have this ability, thus it becomes evident that
decisions need to be taken at the consortia level, and that suitable local economic
policies are called for, in order to take more advantage of the relations between the
local institutions and the local economy.
The fundamental conditions for the strengthening of the local productive system
is the achievement of an increasing "systemic" structure which reinforces the eco-
The crucial variables for the strengthening of the local system are both
endogenous (completely controlled within the area) and exogenous.
Among the variables which could be controlled within the local system, we can
remember (Garofoli, 1984b and 1992a) :
d) The forms of social regulation, which operate outside the market and depend
upon a useful integration between the institutions and the local economy (cf. Sabel,
Zeitlin, 1982 and 1985 ; Zeitlin, 1985). It is enough to think of the crucial role,
for the development of firms and local system, which can be performed by
quality control systems, technological centres, business services centres established on
the basis of agreements between local public bodies, local institutions and consor-
tia of firms ; centres for professional training and institutions which regulate
competition between enterprises, favouring competition in new products and
processes rather than competition based on cost cutting and, indirectly, labour costs
cutting, that means without brutal price wars.
a) the crucial role played by external economies (mainly linked with the
existence of strategic local specificities - technical and professional knowledges,
relationships among firms, local forms of social regulation, etc. -) ;
e) the crisis of the dualistic interpretations (mainly linked with the idea of the
overlapping of small firm and backward sector), due to the discovery of the
diffuse capability to innovate in small firms and, especially, in systems of small firms.
All this means that territory (or local "milieu") is playing a crucial role in the
process of economic development. In fact local milieu is the place that rules :
c) the local labour market (with the introduction of specific industrial relations) ;
This means that territory (and local milieu) covers the following spheres :
— information ;
— production ;
— labour market ;
— socio-institutional governance.
Inter-firm transactions are quite important not only for the reduction of
transactional costs but also for the increasing social division of labour within a local
area (which stimulates the formation of new firms). Agglomeration is a location
strategy often followed by producers because proximity translates into lower costs
of transaction and wider opportunities for matching needs and capabilities. But
agglomeration alone does not necessary lead to the formation of efficient tran-
Market failures can limit the industry's ability to carry out innovative activity.
It is sufficient to remember the small and medium sized firms' fear to invest in
long-term research projects, or the insufficient level of financial resources for
technical leading firms but small in size. Local specific institutions (like technological
centres) are sometimes necessary to overcome some of these types of market
failures.
In this sense, it is possible to conclude with Scott and Storper (1990) that
regional economic development is open to multiple pathways that depend on the
interplay between economic forces and the politics of place.
The attention to local institutions and local culture is, then, a sort of response
to market failures, due to the presence of externalities, of imperfect information
and so on. The idea that successful reproduction of economic systems cannot
proceed in the absence of institutionalized agencies and collective action holds not
only at the level of the national economy but also (and particularly) at the level
of the local economy and local productive systems.
So we have seen how local institutions and collective actors (both private actors
- i.e. consortia of firms - and public agents) could intervene for the strengthening
of the success elements (and for reducing the weak points) of the local productive
system, through the introduction of specific tools supporting the local economy,
solving for example the problems arisen from the market's failures. This means
not only the introduction of specific forms of local social regulation but also the
constitution of informal links between productive system and local society.
In the same way, local institutions and collective actors should intervene for
the constitution of collaboration networks between different areas and regions
both at the national level but especially at the international one. It is easier, indeed,
to find common problems for areas which belong to different countries than, often,
for areas in the same country or region.
When we will be able to refute and overcome the ideology of the interregional
competition (which has been, in fact, dominant during the 80s) and which is based
upon the competition in attracting floating capital and upon the hypothesis of
the "zero sum game" (that implies the gain in the position in one region
corresponds to a lose for another region) - and that has been stressed by the neo-liberistic
and neo-conservative economic policies, which have stopped the overall demand
at the international level - and we accept an idea of the development process based
upon the "valorization" of unused or badly used resources (Hirschman, 1958)
with the goal of facing social needs not yet satisfied, we will enter in a complete
different scenario. In this case, the overall scenario of regional development should
change radically and the experiences already made in one area could be of great
interest and utility for another area with a similar productive structure or with
similar problems to face, also if we cannot accept the possibility to export
successful models of development. Actual examples of this kind of cooperation are
found in the knowledges and technological transfer programmes - mainly with
intermediate technology more appropriate for developing regions and countries
based on small firms - managed at local level (cf. the French cases in Savoy and
Doubs remembered by Courlet, 1992), in labour training transfer programmes
organized in several Italian areas based on small firms systems (like the experience of
Citer in Carpi), in the constitution of "quality circles" of local productive systems
with interregional discussion groups (like the case of the cooperation agreement
between the industrial districts of Cluses and Lecco still in progress).