Chapter 1 The Demand Side
Chapter 1 The Demand Side
Chapter 1 The Demand Side
Changes in profit or income growth expectations, uncertainty and the value of collateral can also be shown in
the diagram by a shift of the IS curve (holding the interest rate constant)
1.2 – Modelling
Goods market equilibrium
The aggregate demand for goods and services consists of:
o Consumption demand – Expenditure by individuals on goods and services, on both durable goods (e.g.
car, laptop) and on non-durable goods (e.g. theatre show, food)
o Investment demand – Expenditure on capital goods (e.g. machinery, equipment, housing, infrastructure)
o Demand stemming from government purchases – Government expenditure on salaries, goods and
services
To start, we assume that aggregate consumption is a simple linear function of after-tax or disposable aggregate
income
C=c 0 +c 1 ( y−T )
Where T is total taxes net of transfers
To get to the consumption function we use as the core of the model of the demand side, we make the additional
consumption that taxes are a fixed proportion of income i.e. T = ty, where 0 < t < 1 – the consumption function
then becomes:
C=c 0 +c 1 ( 1−t ) y
This is referred to as a Keynesian consumption function – it consists of a constant term, c 0, which is often
referred to as autonomous consumption, and c 1 (1−t ) y , which shows households spending a fixed proportion of
their disposable income
c 1 is referred to as the marginal propensity to consume (0< c1 <1)
The MPC shows the change in consumption as a result of a change in post-tax or disposable income:
∆C
MPC= Disposable
=c 1 , where y Disposable=( 1−t ) y
∆y
The multiplier
If we substitute the consumption into the equation for aggregate demand:
y D=c0 + c1 ( 1−t ) y + I +G
y−c1 ( 1−t ) y =c 0 + I +G
1
( c0 + I +G )
1−c1 ( 1−t ) ⏟
y=
⏟ autonomous demand
multipler
The IS curve
Deriving the IS equation
We assume the interest rate has an impact on
investment spending, and incorporate this into
the investment function:
I =a 0−a1 r
We can then use k to denote the multiplier and
simplify to achieve a simple equation for the IS
curve:
1
y= [ c + ( a0−a 1 r ) +G ]
1−c1 ( 1−t ) 0
¿ k [ c 0 + ( a0−a1 r ) + G ]¿ k ( c 0 +a0+G )−k a1 r ¿ A−ar
Where A ≡ k ( c 0+ a0 +G ) and a=k a1 Figure 1.6 – Deriving the IS curve
Forward-looking behaviour
The spending decisions of agents in the present are influenced by their expectations of the future – this means
that there is an intertemporal component to both consumption and investment
Households adjust their current spending based on their expected income in the future i.e. if someone knew
they were going to earn a lot more money at a fixed point in the near future, they may borrow in the present,
consume more and pay back the money when they begin to earn more – this behaviour is referred to as
consumption smoothing
Firms make decisions (e.g. purchasing machinery, equipment and premises) based on a business plan that
includes forecast about future demand for their products and input cost- investment is intrinsically forward
looking, as it incurs a cost today, but the stream of benefits occurs in the future
o For example, a firm selling cars to China might choose to build a new factory (i.e. undertake investment)
based on forecasts that Chinese incomes (and their demand for cars) will continue to rise rapidly over
the next 20 years
If the cost of the machine is greater than the present value of the flow of profits from the machine, then it would
be more profitable not to buy the machine, but instead put the money in the bank or in bonds (which earn
interest r
Similarly, if the money to purchase the machine is being borrowed, then if the cost of the machine is greater
than the present value, buying the machine will be unprofitable
On the other hand, if the present value is greater than the cost, then this investment is profitable
Consumption
The permanent income hypothesis (PIH)
This states that individuals optimally choose how much to consume by allocating their resources across their
lifetimes – this includes their assets, and their current and future income
It’s a forward-looking decision, and it will depend on interest rates, asset values, expectations of future income
and expectation of future taxes
An individual with this consumption function will borrow and save to deliver a perfectly smooth
consumption path (in expectation)
The amount they consume each period is equal to the annuity value of expected lifetime wealth and is
called ‘permanent income’
The individual consumes their permanent income and the formula ensures that in expectation, they will be
able to do this forever
Downloaded by Fraser Ralston ([email protected])
lOMoARcPSD|3401303
2.) News or unanticipated changes in income should affect consumption because they require the recalculation of
future lifetime,Ψ tE
(a) News of a temporary increase in income – if current income y t increases unexpectedly by one unit,
consumption increases by the extent to which this raises permanent income
Since the increase in one unit will be spread over the entire future, the PIH consumption
r
function tells us that permanent income and hence consumption by very little, by times the
1+ r
increase in lifetime wealth
r
The marginal propensity to consume out of temporary income is
1+ r
(b) News of a permanent increase in income – if there is news that income y t is higher from now and for every
future period by one unit, then permanent income and hence consumption rise by the full one unit
This means that the marginal propensity to consume is one
‘Excess smoothness’ of consumption in response to news of permanent income changes would
contradict the simple PIH
The first hypothesis suggests that there should be no change in consumption the time income changes, if the
change in income was known – consumption should have already have been adjusted as soon as the news
arrived of the change in income
o However, studies have shown that some households responded immediately to changes in income – it
was household with low and income that responded the most, underlining the likely role of limits on the
ability of households to borrow – this is referred to as the excess sensitivity of consumption and is
evidence against the PIH
o What has been observed is that when income falls in a predictable way on retirement, consumption falls,
though by not as much
o The fact that there is excess sensitivity to anticipated rises in income and not so much to falls in income
underlines the importance of credit constraints
Excess sensitivity to news about temporary income and excess smoothness to news about permanent income
Studies have found that consumption over-responds to temporary income shocks – in the case of positive
income shocks, this violates the PIH
o The fact that people respond to a windfall by raising spending suggests that discount rates are higher
than assumed in the simple PIH: people appear to be more impatient than the hypothesis assumes
o It is also likely that uncertainty about whether observed income changes are temporary or permanent
prevents households from acting as PIH would predict – for example, if a household mistakenly thought
a temporary change in their current income was permanent, then they would consume more of the
income change than would be consistent with the PIH behaviour
Credit Constraints
If people prefer to smooth consumption but cannot do so, they can’t borrow to bring forward consumption
when their current income is below their expected income – they are facing credit constraints
Because of information problems facing banks in assessing creditworthiness, banks are not always willing to lend
to households without the wealth or collateral to secure a loan that they may need to smooth consumption
Impatience
The PIH households start saving as soon as the news of the fall in future income is received, which allows them
to smooth consumption over the two periods
In contrast, the impatient households fail to reduce current consumption upon receipt of the news, meaning
consumption falls dramatically
when income falls
Investment
Tobin’s q theory of investment
Firm’s choose the amount of investment to undertake with a view to maximise the expected discounted profits
over the lifetime of the project
o The q theory amounts to comparing the benefits from investment in an increase in the capital stock with
the costs of doing so: if the expected benefits exceed the costs, investment should take place
MB of investment a f k
q= =
MC of investment δ +r
Optimal investment occurs when q = 1 i.e. where MB = MC
o If q > 1, the firm should invest to increase the capital stock until q = 1, and vice versa if q < 1
Firms should undertake more investment if there is:
1. An increase in the rate of technology, a
2. An increase in the marginal productivity of capital, f k , which indicates the increase in output the new
capital equipment will produce
3. A reduction in rate of interest, r
4. A reduction in the rate of depreciation, δ . For example, a rise in the expected rate of depreciation (e.g.
as a result of future legislation banning fuel-inefficient cars) would lead to a reduction level of current
investment because would reduce the expected benefits to the firm from additional investment in the
auto industry
Marginal q implies firms adjust their level of investment in each period to equate the marginal benefits and
marginal costs of investment – this does not fit with the real-world data on investment
It is difficult to observe marginal product of capital and a measure of technology