Factors Influencing Capital Structure On Firm's Value: A Study On DSE Listed Companies
Factors Influencing Capital Structure On Firm's Value: A Study On DSE Listed Companies
Factors Influencing Capital Structure On Firm's Value: A Study On DSE Listed Companies
Volume: 3, Issue: 1
Page: 37-51
2019 International Journal of Science and Business
Abstract:
Using a panel of listed companies on the DSE, researcher investigates the
association of capital structure on firm value and investigates the capital
structure of firms in Bangladesh. This current study focuses that the
results of the analysis on the relevance of capital structure on firm value
indicated, there is no statistically significant relationship between firm
value and the capital structure of firms. This analysis was conducted for
the general sample of firms in the study, within industries and by firm
size; however, the results were consistent throughout all the analysis. The
analysis of the Bangladeshi firms’ capital structure indicated that firms in
Bangladesh tend to use more long-term debt than short-term debt. The IJSB
Accepted 13 January 2019
leverage ratios also differed among industries with the Pharmaceuticals & Published 15 January 2019
Chemicals having the highest levels of leverage and the Textile industry DOI: 10.5281/zenodo.2539383
having the lowest levels of leverage. The results of the capital structure
and its determinants analysis indicated that Bangladeshi firms followed a
pecking order theory. The results also indicated that profitability, size,
asset tangibility and tax shield has a statistically significant relationship to
gearing or the firm’s capital structure.
About Author
Md. Edrich Molla, (Corresponding Author), Coordinator & Lecturer of Finance, Department
of Business Administration, Victoria University of Bangladesh, Panthapath, Dhaka
1205, Bangladesh.
1.0 Introduction
There is a considerable number of theories and research on the effect of capital structure on
firm value, size and profitability. The capital structure of the firm refers to the sources of
funding used to finance a firm’s investments. This refers to the choice between equity
financing and debt financing. According to Modigliani and Miller (1958), the value of the firm,
that is, its stock price, does not depend on the capital structure of the firm. This theory by
Modigliani and Miller is based on a set of simplifying assumptions. These assumptions include
no taxes, no transaction costs and no information asymmetry. The theory says that the total
market value of all financial assets issued by a firm is determined by the risk and return of the
firm’s real assets, not by the mix of issued securities. The main idea behind Modigliani and
Miller’s theory is that a rational investor can create any capital structure on his/her own.
Therefore, the firm should not focus much on its capital structure. “If the investor is highly
indebted, the risk and return of the firm’s stock (to the investor) will simply be the same as if
the firm was highly levered” (Byström, 2007). This substitution called homemade leverage
and the finding that a more leveraged firm doesn’t only yield higher returns to the investor
but also a higher risk, is the root of Modigliani and Miller’s theory. There is a theory that
states the value of the firm, in a world with corporate taxes, is positively related to its debt.
This theory, which is known as the trade-off theory, states that profitable firms will tend to
use more debt in order to capture the tax shield offered by debt financing of investments.
According to this theory, in an all-equity firm, only shareholders and tax authorities have
claims on the firm. The value of the firm is owned by the shareholders and the portion going
to taxes is just a cost. The value of the levered firm has three claimants, explicitly: the
shareholders, debt holders and tax recipients (Government). Consequently, the value of the
levered firm is the sum of the value of the debt and the value of the equity. In these instances,
value is maximized with the structure paying the least in the form of taxes (Hillier, et al.,
2015). Other theories on capital structure include the pecking order theory and the market
timing theory. According to the pecking order theory firms prefer internal finance and if
external finance is required, firms issue the safest security first. Specifically, they start with
debt, then possibly hybrid securities then equity as a last resort (Myers, 1984). This assumes
that a firm’s debt ratio will be reflective of its cumulative requirements for external finance.
In contrast to the trade -off and pecking order theories of capital structure, Baker and
Wurgler (2002) found that firms with low levels of leverage raised capital when their market
valuations were high as measured by the market-to -book ratio whereas firms with high
levels of leverage raised capital when their market valuations were low. This theory is known
as the market timing capital structure theory. According to research by Kurshev and
Strebulaev (2007), it has been recognized that large firms tend to have higher leverage ratios
than smaller firms. International evidence suggests that in most, though not all countries,
leverage is also cross-sectional positively related to size. Intuitively, firm size should be
relevant or related to leverage for a number of reasons. At the outset, in the presence of fixed
costs of raising external funds, large firms have cheaper access to outside financing. Also large
firms are more likely to diversify their sources of financing. Secondly, size may also be a proxy
for the probability of default because it is often assumed that it is more difficult for larger
firms to fail or liquidate. Firm size may also be an alternative for the volatility of firm assets
because small firms are more expected to be growing firms in industries that are rapidly
expanding and inherently volatile. Another reason for the significance of firm size is the
extent of the hold in the degree of information asymmetry between insiders and the capital
markets which have a tendency to prefer larger firms by virtue of a greater scrutiny they face
from the ever suspicious investors (Strebulaev and Kurshev, 2006). One of the most
encompassing studies that have been conducted on Bangladesh found that companies in the
market tend to follow a modified pecking order. This study looked at Bangladeshi market
(DSE). In this study, it is examined for capital structure dependence on variables such as asset
tangibility, corporate tax, profitability, size and firm age. In terms of finding, some questions
to be explained such as; Has Bangladesh sophisticated institutional and physical capital
markets infrastructure? Is the legal environment encompassing clearly stated and enforced
laws? Are the courts effective in forcing borrowers to honor business contracts?
therefore intended to build upon the work that has been conducted so far and to contribute to
the body of literature with the following questions as per guidelines: i) Is capital structure
irrelevant as per MM I? ii) What is the capital structure (debt-to-equity) of firms per industry
in Bangladesh? iii) How persistent is the equity-debt capital structure? iv) What factors
determine the equity-debt structure divide? v) What is the debt structure in terms of funding
between long term and short term debt? vi) How persistent is the long term-short term
structure?
Hasan, M. B. et al. (2014). Inadequate capital structure decisions can lead to a large cost of
capital thereby lowering the net present value (NPV) of the firm’s investment projects making
the investment projects unacceptable i.e. the underinvestment problem. Efficient capital
structure decisions will lower the firm’s cost of capital and increase the NPV of the firm’s
investment projects leading to more projects being suitable to accept thereby increasing the
value of the firm. Capital structure is a very significant decision for firms to make so that they
can maximize returns to their various stakeholders. Furthermore, the correct capital
structure is important to the firm as it will aid in dealing with the competitive environment
within which the firm operates. As per statement of Modigliani and Miller (1958) an ‘optimal’
capital structure exists when the risks of going bankrupt is offset by the tax savings of debt.
When this optimal capital structure is realized, a firm would be able to maximize returns to
its stakeholders that are higher than returns that would be attained from a firm whose capital
consists of equity only i.e. an all equity firm. Despite the importance that capital structure can
play in adding value to the firm, decade’s worth of theoretical literature and empirical testing
have not been able to give guidance to practitioners with regards to the choice between debt
and equity in their capital structures explained by Frank, M. Z., & Goyal, V. K. (2009). It is
rather baffling to try to logically understand capital structure literature because different
capital structure theories are frequently utterly opposed in their predictions while sometimes
they may be in agreement but have opposing views about why the outcome has been
predicted. It is for this reason that Myers, S. C. (2001) stated that there is no universal theory
of capital structure, only conditional ones. Factors that are of significance in one context may
be of substantial insignificance in another. The notion of financial management can be defined
as a managerial activity, which is highly concerned about controlling and planning of firm’s
financial resources, Pandey, I. M., & Bhat, R. (2007).
Furthermore, the functions of finance encompass a diverse area. These functions comprise
choices on investments, choices on financing, choices on dividends, and choices on liquidity.
This paper encompasses aspects with respects to the financing decision of a company i.e.
deciding on how to obtain funds in order to fulfill the firm’s needs of investments. The study
of capital structure centers around the mix between debt, equity and the range of other
hybrid instruments used to finance the investments of the firm. Capital structure is therefore
concerned with the right hand side of the balance sheet mentioned by Bhaduri, S. N. (2002).
All items on the right hand side of the balance sheet, excluding current liabilities, are sources
of capital employed to finance the real assets required to conduct the business of the firm
observed by Welch, I. (2004). Below is a simplified graphical depiction of the capital
structure. If you want to evaluate the performance of the firm it is important to consider all
interest bearing borrowings as loan capital regardless of whether they are short term or long
term loans claimed by Fama, E., & French, K. (2011). Firms manage their capital structure by
issuing new debt and equity and by settling old debt or repurchasing issued shares. It is
frequently stated that the goal of financial management is to maximize the wealth of the
shareholders or owners of the firm. According to Desai, M. A. et al. (2004) the goal of financial
management is to maximize the current value per share of the existing shares. However, fixed
assets working capital net assets capital equity loans retained profit equity capital overdraft
long-term loans owners only have a residual claim to the assets of the firm and are only paid
once every other stakeholder with a legitimate claim to the firm’s assets has been paid. Since
the lenders, employees and suppliers all have a superior claim on the firm’s assets, it stands
to reason that if the owners’ wealth is maximized then all the other claimants will stand to
gain. The market values of the firm's debt and equity, D and E, add up to total firm value V and
Modigliani and Miller's (1958) Proposition 1 says that V is a constant, regardless of the
proportions of D and E, provided that the assets and growth opportunities on the left-hand
side of the balance sheet are held constant explained by Myers, S. C. (1984).
The market values of the firm's debt and equity, D and E, add up to total firm value V and
Modigliani and Miller's (1958) Proposition 1 says that V is a constant, regardless of the
proportions of D and E, provided that the assets and growth opportunities on the left-hand
side of the balance sheet are held constant according to Myers, S. C. (2001). The Modigliani
and Miller’s (1958) Proposition 1 as captured in the equation below also states that:
VL=VU ………………….. (i)
Where: VL= the value of the levered firm, VU= the value of the unlevered firm. The expression
above states that the value of the levered firm (VL) is equal to the value of the unlevered firm
(VU) (Firer et al, 2008).
interest tax shield. The principal value of debt is the fact that interest payments earned on the
repayment of debt is deductible from corporate income tax. Debt, however, does have
shortcomings that include an increased probability of bankruptcy if the firm failed to service
its obligations, the agency costs earned by the lender to monitor the activities of the firm and
the fact that managers have better prospects of the firm than the investors do, narrated by
Gitman, L. J. (2003). The trade-off theory rationalizes reasonable debt ratios. It says that the
firm will borrow up to the point where the marginal value of tax shields on additional debt is
just offset by the increase in the present value of possible costs of financial distress according
to Myers, S. C. (2001). Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2005) explained this optimal capital
structure is attained when the marginal benefit of an extra unit of debt is offset by the
marginal cost of an extra unit of debt.
Equity
Debt
Financing
Internal
Funds
C D
Investment
Figure 2: The Financing Hierarchy of the Pecking Order, Source: Leary, M. T., & Roberts, M. R.
(2004), Page- 49
Although the pecking order theory is based on the adverse selection based on information
asymmetry, it has been proven that information asymmetry does not need to exist for a
financing hierarchy to arise. It has, however, been shown that other factors such as incentive
conflicts could generate a pecking order behaviour mentioned by Leary, M. T. & Roberts, M. R.
(2004). Titman, S. et al. (1988) also found that transaction costs may also be an important
factor in the pecking order behaviour and this is substantiated by the fact that short-term
debt ratios are negatively related to firm size. This variance in financing practice probably
reflects the high transaction costs that small firms face when they issue long-term debt or
equity claimed by Titman, S., & Wessels, R. (1988).
ii) Does the debt-to-equity ratio differ among industries listed on the DSE? : According to the
capital structure theory the industry within which a firm belongs is likely to have a
substantial effect on the observed leverage levels of the individual firms and also that with
time the firms will tend to converge towards the median industry debt levels. The said
convergence towards the industry median debt level is considered as proof that an optimal
capital structure does exist stated by Bowen, R. M. et al. (1982). To determine the difference
between industry debt-to-equity ratio levels descriptive statistics will be employed, the
hypothesis will be stated as follows:
iii) There is a relationship between debt-to-equity ratio and profitability, size of firm, tax
shield and asset tangibility: The findings of the above study showed that firm size, liquidity,
profitability and sales growth affect the leverage ratios of industrials firms significantly.
Among these factors, firm size and profitability are the most significantly influential factors
on capital structures of industrial firms, and these two factors are negatively correlated with
leverage ratios. Growth factor was found to be statistically significant and positively
correlated with leverage ratios. Liquidity factor is also statically significant but negatively
correlated with leverage ratios. These findings are consistent with most of the capital
structure literature and especially support Pecking Order Theory mentioned by Icke, B. T., &
Ivgen, H. (2011). To determine factors affecting the debt-to-equity ratio levels, the hypothesis
will be stated as follows:
H0: P (ROA, tax shield, market capitalization, asset tangibility) > 0.05
H1: P (ROA, tax shield, market capitalization, asset tangibility) ≤ 0.05
variables exhibited stationarity and unit root was non-existent and were all suitable to
include in the regression analysis.
Summary Sample: 2009-2018
Exogenous variables: Individual effects
User-specified lags: 1
Newey-West automatic bandwidth selection and Bartlett kernel Balanced observations for
each test
Table 2: Unit Root Test Panel Unit Root Test
Cross-
Method Statistic Prob.** sections
Null: Unit root (assumes common unit root process)
AT -325.366 0.0000 82 576
Debt-to-Equity Ratio -5.66143 0.0000 82 576
EPS -4.34689 0.0000 82 576
PE -12.4399 0.0000 82 576
TS -215.158 0.0000 82 576
ROA -17.2426 0.0000 82 576
Market Capitalization -12.6915 0.0000 82 576
Ratio
** Probabilities for Fisher tests are computed using an asymptotic Chi-square
distribution. All other tests assume asymptotic normality.
Note: EPS stands for Earnings-Per-Share, PE stands for Price-Earnings ratio, TS stands for
Tax Shield ratio, AT stands for Asset Tangibility ratio, ROA stands for Return-On-Assets.
Source of Output: E-views 10, Software Tool Pack.
Source of Output: E-views 10, Software Tool Pack.
1.736578
Effects Specification
Cross-section fixed (dummy variables)
R-squared 0.595398 Mean dependent var 3.86071
2
Adjusted R- 0.548820 S.D. dependent var 5.47505
squared 9
S.E. of regression 3.677593 Akaike info criterion 5.54112
3
Sum squared resid 7871.369 Schwarz criterion 6.00948
3
Log likelihood -1732.865 Hannan-Quinn criter. 5.72278
8
F-statistic 12.78285 Durbin-Watson stat 1.07860
9
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000
Note: C stands for the Common Intercept, D2E stands for Debt-To-Equity ratio, TS stands for
Tax Shield ratio, AT stands for Asset Tangibility ratio, S.E stands for Standard Error, S.D is the
Standard Deviation and F-statistic stands for Fischer Statistic.
Source of Output: E-views 10, Software Tool Pack.
6.4 Research Hypothesis Two: Does the Debt-To-Equity Ratio Differ Among Industries
Listed on the DSE
Table 4: Debt-To-Equity Ratios by Industry
Ratio Services Food & Engineerin Pharmaceutica Textil Fuel &
(%) & Real Allied g ls & Chemicals e Power
states
2009/12 31 44 49 30 15 42
/31
2010/12 29 34 38 32 15 26
/31
2011/12 36 33 26 43 13 29
/31
2012/12 30 41 29 53 32 34
/30
2013/12 29 38 37 194 14 31
/29
2014/12 53 48 41 210 19 25
/31
2015/12 40 61 42 278 18 21
/31
2016/12 35 43 34 238 10 15
/31
2017/12 32 54 31 228 17 13
/31
2018/12 32 44 38 214 38 10
/30
Average 34.7 44 36.5 152 19 24.6
ratio
Source of Output: E-views 10, Software Tool Pack.
47 International Journal of Science and Business Published By
Email: [email protected] Website: ijsab.com
Volume: 3, Issue: 1, Year: 2019 Page: 37-51 IJSB-International
The table above presents the different debt-to-equity structures per industry. According to
the table above, the Pharmaceuticals & Chemicals industry had the highest levels of debt-to-
equity followed by the Food & Allied sector. The Textile industry had the lowest levels of the
debt-to-equity ratio over the observed period. According to the results presented in the table
above, it can be concluded that the debt-to-equity ratios of the different industries sampled
for this study are heterogeneous; therefore, it is accepted the null hypothesis.
6.5 Research hypothesis three: there is a relationship between debt-to-equity ratio and
profitability, size, asset tangibility and tax shield
According to the regression results presented below, return on assets and asset tangibility
were the only two variables in the model that were significant, meaning that they have
explanatory power over the dependent variable debt-to-equity ratio (proxy for capital
structure). The R squared was significant at the 5% significance level, with the model
explaining 54% of the variation in the capital structure of firms sampled in this study.
stands for Asset Tangibility ratio, S.E stands for Standard Error, S.D is the Standard Deviation
and F-statistic stands for Fischer Statistic.
varied over the observed period. For some industries the patterns had sharp increases and
sharp declines while for some it showed a range bound pattern.
To establish factors that have an effect on the debt-to-equity divide, or simply capital
structure of firms’ researcher employed a panel data regression as in the previous case. All
the models were significant at the 5% level of significance. The findings from the regression
models indicated a negative significant relationship between profitability and the capital
structure of a firm. This is supported by previous research by Gwatidzo, T., & Ojah, K. (2009)
who found a negative significant relationship between profitability and capital structure.
Umar, M. et al. (2012) also found that there was a negative and significant correlation
between gearing and profitability for Manufacturing Small, Medium and Micro Enterprises
(SMMEs) and large sized enterprises (LSEs). The results of the panel regressions indicated a
pecking order behaviour which was also the findings of Gwatidzo, T., & Ojah, K. (2009) as well
as Umar, M. et al. (2012). It could be argued that the results on MM I summarized above are
mostly inconsistent with recent literature and economic theory from across the world. There
is substantial literature that has shown that there is a relationship between firm value and the
capital structure of a firm. This outcome, perhaps, concur with Myers, S. C. (2001) who stated
that there is no universal theory of capital structure, only conditional ones. Factors that are of
significance in one context may be insignificant in another. An interesting future research
agenda would be to find possible explanations for these contrasting results, starting with
verifying differences in test variables alternative and testing techniques deployed in these
studies.
References
1. Bhaduri, S. N. (2002). Determinants of capital structure choice: a study of the Indian corporate
sector. Applied Financial Economics, 12(9), 655-665.
2. Baker, M., & Wurgler, J. (2002). Market timing and capital structure. The journal of finance, 57(1), 1-
32.
3. Bowen, R. M., Daley, L. A., & Huber Jr, C. C. (1982). Evidence on the existence and determinants of
inter-industry differences in leverage. Financial Management, 10-20.
4. Byström, H. (2007). Instantaneous Credit Risk Correlation. The Journal of Fixed Income, 17(2), 5.
5. Chowdhury, A., & Chowdhury, S. P. (2010). Impact of capital structure on firm's value: Evidence
from Bangladesh. Business & Economic Horizons, 3(3).
6. Dayton, C. M. (1992). Logistic regression analysis. Stat, 474-574.
7. DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Stulz, R. M. (2010). Seasoned equity offerings, market timing, and the
corporate lifecycle. Journal of Financial Economics, 95(3), 275-295.
8. Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F., & Hines Jr, J. R. (2004). A multinational perspective on capital structure
choice and internal capital markets. The Journal of Finance, 59(6), 2451-2487.
9. Fama, E., & French, K. (2011). Capital structure choices.
10. Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2005). Financing decisions: who issues stock?. Journal of financial
economics, 76(3), 549-582.
11. Frank, M. Z., & Goyal, V. K. (2009). Capital structure decisions: which factors are reliably
important?. Financial management, 38(1), 1-37.
12. Gitman, L. J., & Joehnk, M. D. (2008). Fundamentals of investing. Pearson Education.
13. Gwatidzo, T., & Ojah, K. (2009). Corporate capital structure determinants: evidence for five African
countries. African Finance Journal, 11(1), 1-23.
14. Hasan, M. B., Ahsan, A. M., Rahaman, M. A., & Alam, M. N. (2014). Influence of capital structure on
firm performance: Evidence from Bangladesh. International Journal of Business and Management,
9(5), 184.
15. Hillier, D., Korczak, A., & Korczak, P. (2015). The impact of personal attributes on corporate insider
trading. Journal of Corporate Finance, 30, 150-167.
16. Icke, B. T., & Ivgen, H. (2011). How Firm Specific Factors Affect Capital Structure: An Emerging
Market Practice–Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE). Middle Eastern Finance and Economics, 13, 90-
102.
17. Kurshev, A., & Strebulaev, I. A. (2007). Firm size and capital structure.
18. Leary, M. T., & Roberts, M. R. (2004). Financial slack and tests of the pecking order’s financing
hierarchy. Unpublished working paper, Duke University.
19. Levin, A., Lin, C. F., & Chu, C. S. J. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and finite-sample
properties. Journal of econometrics, 108(1), 1-24.
20. McGregor, B. F. A. (2014). database.(2014). Supplier of data.[Web]: https://expert. mcgregorbfa.
com/.[Date of access], 10.
21. Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1963). Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction.
The American economic review, 53(3), 433-443.
22. Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of
investment. The American economic review, 48(3), 261-297.
23. Myers, S. C. (2001). Capital structure. Journal of Economic perspectives, 15(2), 81-102.
24. Myers, S. C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. The journal of finance, 39(3), 574-592.
25. Pandey, I. M., & Bhat, R. (2007). Dividend behaviour of Indian companies under monetary policy
restrictions. Managerial Finance, 33(1), 14-25.
26. Ross, S. A., Westerfield, R., & Jordan, B. D. (2008). Fundamentals of corporate finance. Tata
McGraw-Hill Education.
27. Shivdasani, A., & Zenner, M. (2005). How to choose a capital structure: navigating the debt‐equity
decision. Journal of applied corporate finance, 17(1), 26-35.
28. Strebulaev, I. A., & Kurshev, A. (2006). Firm size and capital structure.
29. Titman, S., & Wessels, R. (1988). The determinants of capital structure choice. The Journal of
finance, 43(1), 1-19.
30. Ward, M., & Price, A. (2006). Turning vision into value: Corporate finance for non-financial
executives. Van Schaik.
31. Welch, I. (2004). Capital structure and stock returns. Journal of political economy, 112(1), 106-131.
32. Umar, M., Tanveer, Z., Aslam, S., & Sajid, M. (2012). Impact of capital structure on firms’ financial
performance: Evidence from Pakistan.
Published by