Water Management

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

ZEF Bonn 2010

Working
Paper
Series

61 Farhat Naz, Saravanan V. Subramanian

Water Management across Space


and Time in India

Center for Development


Research

Department of
Political and
Cultural Change

Zentrum für Entwicklungsforschung


Center for Development Research

ISSN 1864-6638
ZEF Working Paper Series, ISSN 1864-6638
Department of Political and Cultural Change
Center for Development Research, University of Bonn
Editors: H.-D. Evers, Solvay Gerke, Peter P. Mollinga, Conrad Schetter

Authors addresses

Farhat Naz, Junior Researcher


Center for Development Research (ZEF), University of Bonn
Walter-Flex-Str.3
53113 Bonn, Germany
Tel. 0049 (0)228-73 4979
Email: [email protected]

Dr. Saravanan V. Subramanian, Senior Researcher


Center for Development Research (ZEF), University of Bonn,
Walter-Flex-Str. 3
53113 Bonn, Germany
Tel. 0049 (0)228-73 4918: Fax 0228-731972
E-mail: [email protected]

www.zef.de
Water Management across Space and Time in India
Farhat Naz, Saravanan V. Subramanian

Abstract ii

Abbreviations iii

1 Introduction 1

2 Water management in pre-colonial India 1

3 Water management in colonial India 3

3.1 The Colonial era of canal revolution in the nineteenth century 4

4 Water management in independent India 8

4.1 Large scale irrigation as ‘temples of modern India’ 8

4.2 Small-scale revolution 9

4.2.1 Community-based management 9

4.2.2 Groundwater Revolution – Taming the Anarchy 12

5 Discussion 14

6 Conclusion 16

Appendix 18

References 19

i
Abstract

This paper attempts to give a spatial and temporal overview of water management in India. It traces how
people and the successive regimes made choices across space and time from a wide range of water
control and distribution technologies. The paper divides the water management in India into four
periods: (i) the traditional system of water management before colonial times; (ii) response from the
colonial rulers to manage the complex socio-ecological system; (iii) large scale surface water
development after independence; and (iv) finally, the small-scale community and market-led revolution.
Hence an attempt has been made to describe the water management over the four periods, which has
transformed the irrigation and water management scenario in India. Moreover the paper shows how
development of water management and its practices are linked with the social, religious, economic
development with the rise and fall of the ruling regime. While these different periods attempts to
manage water in different ways, the paper reveals a gap in research towards understanding the ability of
community to integrate by default these diverse technologies to achieve their social goal of survival.

Keywords:
Water Management, Canal Revolution, Groundwater Governance, Watershed Management, Community-
Based Water Management

ii
Abbreviations

APMs Adjustable Proportional Modules


ARWSP Accelerated Rural Water Supply Programme
CADP Command Area Development Programme
CBNRM Community Based Natural Resource Management
CBWM Community Based Watershed Management
CDP Community Development Programme
CGWA Central Ground Water Authority
CGWB Central Ground Water Board
COWDP Comprehensive Watershed Development Program
CPCB Central Pollution Control Board
CPR Common Property Resource
CWC Central Water Commission
DPDP Drought Prone Areas Program
DRDA District Rural Development Agency
DTWs Deep Tubewells
FYP Five Year Plan
GoI Government of India
GoTN Government of Tamil Nadu
IC Irrigation Commission
ICAR Indian Council of Agricultural Research
ID Irrigation Department
IIFM Indian Institute of Forest Management
IMT Irrigation Management Transfer
ISI Indian Standards Institution
IWDP Integrated Watershed Development Project
KVK Krishi Vigyan Kendra
MoA Ministry of Agriculture
MoEF Ministry of Environment and Forest
MoRD Ministry of Rural Development
MoWR Ministry of Water Resources
NABARD National Bank for Agricultural and Rural Development
NASDORA National Authority for Sustainable Development of Rainfed Areas
NGO Non-Government Organization
NIRD National Institute of Rural Development
NWDA National Water Development Agency
NWDPRA National Watershed Development Project for Rural Areas
iii
NWMP National Water Management Project
NWP National Water Policy
PIA Project Implementation Agency
PIM Participatory Irrigation Management
PWD Public Works Department
RCAI Royal Commission on Agriculture in India
RGNDWM Rajeev Gandhi National Drinking Water Mission
RWS Rural Water Supply
SGWA State Ground Water Authority
SID State Irrigation Department
SPCB State Pollution Control Board
SRP Sector Reform Project
STWs Shallow Tubewells
UGC Upper Ganga Canal
UP Uttar Pradesh
WHO World Health Organization
WRO Water Resources Organizations
WUAs Water Users Associations

iv
1 Introduction

India is credited with having a long history of human intervention in the management of water because
of its distinctive climatic binary conditions of intense monsoons followed by prolonged droughts.
Furthermore, rainfall is confined to a few months each year and that too uncertain, erratic and uneven.
Thus, historically making Indian agriculture dependent heavily on various types of irrigation. This
dependence has led people and the successive ruling regimes from pre-colonial to colonial and the post
colonial time, to make choices across space and time, from a wide range of technologies 1 of water
control and distribution.
This review paper aims to explain how water management has been interplay between cooperation as
well as conflict over space and time trajectory in India. Water holds its association to culture and
spirituality along with economic value. This in the process of sacred and profane makes its management
more complex, as various stakeholders and parties are involved with different aspiration. Water
management has been a cautious affair in India due to socio-economic-political and ecological reasons
that has affected water management policies across diverse social groups.
In this paper, water management of India have been classified into four broad periods starting from pre
colonial - colonial to post colonial and to current situation. The paper elaborates on the lines of a)
traditional system of water management before colonial times, b) response from the colonial rulers to
manage the complex socio-ecological system, c) followed by the era of large scale surface water
development after independence, d) and lastly, an era of community- based management and along with
groundwater revolution.
The following section discusses the water management in the pre-colonial times in India, explaining how
kings, feudal lords and local communities managed water as a resource. It further explains why pre-
colonial India was not a ‘hydraulic society’ 2. Section three elaborates the water management under the
colonial rule and how India became a standard bearer for the world in the use of modern science and
engineering in the design of huge and multifarious irrigation structures. Section four illustrates the
Independent India’s water management measures and policies with regard to surface, groundwater and
community based water management in detail. Section five, discusses in brief the reason why in India
water management is a tricky affair. Lastly, section six concludes with an overall summary of the paper.

2 Water management in pre-colonial India

Before the advent of British colonial rule, investments in water development and management were
made in different parts of India. Evidences of this could be found in ancient text, inscriptions, local
traditions and in archaeological remains. Even the Puranas, Mahabharata, Ramayana and various other
Vedic, Buddhist and Jain texts mention about numerous canals, wells, tanks and embankments (Agarwal
and Narain, 1997). Moreover ancient religious texts, commentaries and stone inscriptions provide
references of governing principles such as ethical, moral, spiritual, social and ecological which were
applied to water management during pre-colonial Hindu and Muslim rule in India (Vani, 2009).
The Arthashastra3 one of the ancient historical canon written by Kautilya in the 3rd century B.C, gives a
clear account of water management in the Mauryan Empire. It states that the local communities were

1
Here the word technology is used in sociological sense. It means machines, equipments, productive techniques
associated with them, and type of social relationship dictated by the technical organization and mechanization of
work (Oxford Dictionary of Sociology, 2004).
2
Karl Wittfogel in his book ‘Oriental Despotism’ (1957) mentions that in oriental societies, in order to regulate
water for irrigation and to cope up with natural disasters, hydraulic structures like canals, embankments were build
which created a social order which were characterized by strong organization structure of rule making it a
hydraulic society or state.
3
Arthashastra was the book written by Kautilya the chief adviser to India first emperor Chandragupta Maurya
(321-297 B.C) on politics and statecraft.
1
very well aware about the rainfall regimes, soil varieties, and irrigation techniques in the specific micro-
ecological context. Furthermore Arthashastra mentions that state rendered help, support and promoted
the small water harvesting structures (Agarwal and Narain, 1997).
In the traditional India 4, irrigation/ water structures of all types were built by the order of the kings.
Indian kings encouraged the activity by giving grants like revenue free lands to nobles, ordinary people
and even temples to construct (Agarwal and Narain, 1997) tanks 5, for seeking agricultural prosperity and
to increase the state revenue. For example in the case of the tanks development, for centuries, work was
done by the support of local chiefs with the technical guidance from specialist surveyors and craftsmen.
The villagers made their own institutions for the construction, maintenance and for operation of the
tanks as a common property resource (Bottrall, 1992). Often the tanks were built in a chronological
manner, with smaller systems at the upstream of a catchment and moving with increasing- size towards
downstream. Each successive tank was build in a chain manner and height of each was calculated by
keeping and respecting the rights of upstream and downstream user—thus it was a way of regulating the
amount of the catchment runoff and how much should flow on to others (Ibid). In some areas there
existed supra-village organization, which had the power to mediate over inter-tank water disputes
(Bottrall, 1992; Agarwal and Narain, 1997). Nonetheless, investment and the operation of tank system
was linked to legitimate political overlordship, thereby establishing a link between honor linked caste
hierarchy and tank irrigation works in the articulation of authority at different layer of administrative
levels; making it one of the significant community-management systems in contemporary sense (Mosse,
1999).
Whereas in the larger delta systems of South India, major finance and organization came from the kings
but day-to-day management was entrusted to local cultivators (Ludden, 1978; Sengupta, 1991). Small
community managed schemes were also developed in other parts of India for example tank like -the
ahar-pynes 6 of South Bihar (Pant, 1998). The pynes 7 feed many ahars 8 and numerous distributaries
originated from each other. The irrigation organization was designed in such way that all the irrigators
needed to cooperate in order to get water from a single distributary (ayacut) (Sengupta, 1985). The
landholding of each farmer was fragmented, leading to the formation of small group of people (goam)
for the maintenance of the ahar-pynes (Ibid). Pant (1998) argues that zamindars 9 maintained the ahar-
pyne system as they had the capital and vested interest. In the river diversion system of Himalayan kuhls,
descent and affinity as well as local customs played a key role in the management of the kuhls (Coward,
1990). In multi-village kuhls inter-village coordination for channel repairs and maintenance and water
distribution was practiced (Baker, 2003).
In water-managed agriculture, wells played an important role by supplementing the surface water
irrigation systems in the Northern and Western India. Open-lined and unlined wells were used for
domestic water needs and also for complementing irrigation needs, about which the evidence in the
Vedic literature is available. It was the Satwahanas in the ancient India who introduced the ring wells –
dug wells for irrigation use (Shah, 2009). Whereas privately owned open wells operated manually or
powered animals in the high water table areas of the Upper Gangetic Basin (Whitcombe, 1972). During
the Mughal period some large-scale canal constructions were undertaken but its contribution to
irrigated agriculture was relatively irrelevant (Habib, 1982) and irrigation through wells was far more
important at that time (Habib, 1970). The productivity enhancing potential of well irrigation was quite
acknowledged in the revenue calculus of ancient and medieval rulers and therefore well -construction
was encouraged through incentives and tax remissions. From the time of Arthashastra (third century B.C)
to the Mughal rule during the sixteenth to eighteenth centuries A.D and later on even during the colonial
era, lands irrigated with wells were assessed at a higher rate than the rainfed lands (Hardiman, 1998).
While in the flood prone Eastern Gangetic Plains, agriculture was largely rainfed. Although there was

4
In this chapter, for the pre-colonial India, the word traditional India is being used, that is ancient and the
medieval time period of India.
5
Tank is a man-made reservoir created by a simple earthen construction (the bund) that captures surface run-off.
6
Ahar-Pyne is a floodwater harvesting system.
7
Pynes are channels constructed to utilize the water flowing through the hilly rivers of Bihar.
8
Ahars are rectangular catchments basin with embankments on three sides.
9
Zamindars are the landlords.
2
some partial additional irrigation from surface sources through small private low-lift devices called
‘overflow irrigation’ (Willcocks, 1984). River embankments in the Gangetic delta were built by zamindars
in the pre-colonial period for flood protection during monsoon through deliberate post-monsoon
breaching for flood irrigation (Ibid).
Hence it can be understood that traditional Indian society had a significant technical sophistication with
decentralized institutional arrangement towards water management with well-defined local water rights
(Bottrall, 1992). Moreover, there were various forms of irrigation in pre-colonial India; this could not be
characterized as a ‘hydraulic society’ in the sense used by Karl Wittfogel (Hardiman, 2008). Thus, in
ancient and medieval India, farming was in a way ‘hydro-agriculture’ with a strong role of village
communities rather than hydraulic farming under state domination (Shah, 2009). The next section deals
with the water management in the British India.

3 Water management in colonial India

‘Environments’ are in essence models of the relationship between communities and the
natural world around them, and as such, they are, like all models, ‘made by humans for
specific communities’. (Gudeman, 1986:37).
A quantum leap in irrigation was initiated in 1830s through the works of Sir Arthur Cotton and Major
Proby Cautley in Southern India and Northern India respectively. By this time the East India Company
was ruling most of India and realized the immense opportunity in irrigation to combine the interest of
charity and the interest of commerce (Whitcombe, 2005) in repairing one of the greatest irrigation works
of pre-colonial times, the Grand Anicut in Tanjore 10 and the Jamuna canals 11 in the Delhi region. The
canal systems of Tamil Nadu and the East Jamuna Canal which were improved and extended in the
1820s were the only exceptions to this rule (Hardiman, 2008). In order to have quick economic returns
from water development, colonial government made an attempt on large-scale irrigation projects in the
Deccan region, which was not successful. This initial debacle provoked the British raj to look towards
rehabilitation of traditional irrigation tanks system. Attempts to revive traditional irrigation system
miserably failed due to failure to understand the complex social system involved over its management.
One of the efforts was the revival of the Kudimaramat 12 (Refer Box. 1).

10
This refers to the repair of Grand Anicut on river Cauvery by the Colonial Government.
11
These canals were originally dugout in the regime of Firuz Shah Tughlaq about 600 years ago (Habib, 1982: 49).
12
The term Kudimaramat is a amalgamated of the Tamil word kuti- meaning ‘inhabitant’ or ‘subject’ and the Arabic
word maramat- meaning ‘repairs’ (Mosse, 1999).
3
“Colonial Myth of Kudimaramat”
(Box.1)
In order to bring all the bigger tanks under the direct control of Public Works Departments (PWDs) for repair and
maintenance, a modern centralized administration for irrigation was evolved. The Public Works Department (PWD)
tried to induce kudimaramat (people’s maintenance by donated labor) in the mistaken belief that local
communities would undertake voluntary labor to maintain the tanks as a tradition (Maloney and Raju, 1994;
Mosse, 1999). The colonial government enacted the Madras Compulsory Labour Act of (1858) known as the
Kudimaramat Act and later several Kudimaramat Bills were drafted (1869, 1883) to enforce the custom by law
(Vani, 1992; Mosse, 1999).

Eventually, all this led to more destruction of the traditional management institutions as the Public Works
Department (PWD) did not have the budget or the staff to take care of such widely scattered independent systems
of tanks; besides people were under the impression that state would look after these tanks structure with the
formation of Public Works Department (PWD) (Bottrall, 1992). The Kudimaramat was recreated as a myth; of a
traditional autonomous village institution by the colonial government in order to invent a village tradition in the
image of the state’s planned irrigation administration (Mosse, 1999). The myth was build by the colonial
government that the village communities would undertake voluntary customarily labor of kudimaramat, which they
had abandoned (Agarwal and Narain, 1997). In fact in the pre-colonial time, cultivators did not voluntarily donate
their labor for the maintenance of the tanks but were paid from the funds mobilized at the village level (Ibid).

Nonetheless the kudimaramat tradition of official discourse was recreated in order to fulfill two administrative
crucial aspects. Firstly, diverse local irrigation maintenance practice was empirically fixed and rendered as a
generalized standard, and this was set by engineering standards of efficiency; secondly the government’s demands
on village labor, resources and management acquired the legitimacy of custom (Mosse, 1999: 311-312). But in
spite of all this the colonial government failed to get the support of the villagers for the upkeep of the tanks.

Other factors which added to the ruin of tanks in South India were (a) the colonial commercialization of
dry agriculture in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century’s; (b) the establishment of a
centralized colonial government and building up of technocratic irrigation bureaucracy from 1850s; (c)
the consolidation of British power, its revenue systems and the property law by the 1840s; (d) the
dismantling of the South Indian ‘old regimes’ around 1800 (Mosse, 1999: 307-308).
In Bengal, the traditional irrigation system of building embankments along the flood prone rivers served
the purpose of irrigation as well as flood protection measure. The peasants who required water for
irrigation would simply breach the embankment for diverting water which was termed as ‘overflow
irrigation’ by Willcocks (1984). However with the zamindari settlement of Bengal Presidency, the colonial
engineers were least concerned with the water issues and due to their indifferent attitude they were not
able to understand the principle of ‘overflow irrigation’. The colonial officials were not able to grasp the
zamindari embankments benefit of irrigation as well as flood mitigation functions, and thus they
prohibited its breeching in 1855, and later brought them under their direct control (Sengupta, 1985). For
railways, roads and for flood control British Government constructed many new embankments, which
only led to water logging, drainage problems and loss of irrigation benefits (Ibid). When agricultural
production started declining rapidly in prosperous Bengal, the British Government invited William
Willcocks, a British irrigation expert, to advise them on irrigation development. In a series of lectures
delivered in Calcutta in the 1920s, Willcocks astonished everyone by arguing that the best government
could do was to revive the ancient flood irrigation system of Bengal (Willcocks, 1984).
Thus the colonial rule redefined property relationships, and took absolute control through ownership of
all resources such as land, water, forest, and minerals without understanding how the irrigation systems
functioned. Furthermore there were taxes of all kinds like land taxes, water taxes, well taxes, subsoil
water taxes, canal charges etc (Hardiman, 2008) which imposed immense burden on the communities.

3.1 The Colonial era of canal revolution in the nineteenth century


The failure to understand the traditional irrigation systems to meet the coffins of the British regime,
paved the way for colonial rulers to resort to large-scale publicly funded irrigation development. For
example in the Southern Deltas, the system operation responsibility of structural renovation work started
4
by Sir Arthur Cotton’s on the Grand Anicut on the Cauvery River could not be left to the long established
local institutions (Bottrall, 1992). Grand Anicut reconstruction in 1838 and the Jamuna canals launched
a phase of massive canal construction activity by the colonial ruler which led to a paradigm shift in
irrigation thinking (Shah, 2009).
In the lower rainfall territory of the Upper Ganges Region, the colonial engineers started massive
construction of vast network of new canals and this later became the mode of development (Stone,
1984). The British raj focused first on the ‘productive’ irrigation works on canals that could generate
annual revenues equal to the interest on their capital cost (Stone, 1984: 25) In 1880 Indian Famine
Commission made visible the indirect returns of irrigation work in the form of curtailment of famine
relief expenditure (Stone, 1984). This judicious showing made the British Raj shift to ‘protective’
irrigation works in the form of constructing large-scale storage dams and canals in Bombay Deccan
(Attwood, 2007).
The completion of the Upper Ganga Canal (UGC) in 1847, the first great northwestern scheme, led to the
establishment of the fact that artificial irrigation is best suited for the topography of the area (Stone,
1984); as its simple operational design went hand in hand with the homogeneity of the physical
environment (Bottrall, 1992). The rational supply of water by proportional flow through uncontrolled
watercourse to as many farms with strict upstream control was possible due to the design layout of the
water distribution pattern of the canals (Berkoff, 1990). This was best suited to the three main colonial
objectives: a) the financial (low operational costs, high revenue); b) socio-political (famine and drought
preclusion); and c) administrative (limited field staff with little possibility of conspiring with farmers in
maneuvering the centrally determined water schedules) (Bottrall, 1992).
As a consequence, a new specialist cadre of irrigation engineers were created in order to govern the
canal management with the passing of 1873 North India Canal and Drainage Act. In the canal irrigation
system, Irrigation Department (ID) was vested with all rights such as control over regulation of water
supplies; power to withdrawal of water supplies to non-cooperating farmers etc (Stone, 1984). The
British colonial policy in the nineteenth century drew from an international discourse of water
engineering, which had its roots in transformation of water into a commodity (Worster, 1985). The
outlook of British irrigation engineers towards environment was that of seeing environment as a
mathematically modeled system, which included modeling of flow, distribution and use of water
(Gilmartin, 1995). The capitalist state promoted science and technology ‘to extract from every river
whatever cash it can produce’ and thus transform the water into a commodity (Worster, 1985). The
mathematical creation of an integrated hydraulic environment gave colonial color to colonial India.
Moreover the British regarded the local communities “in a language of ‘naturalism’ that defined them as
parts of the ‘natural’ environment to be modeled and controlled” (Gilmartin, 1995). In 1860s and 1870s,
British irrigation policy though principally inclined for larger strategic, financial and political concerns,
endorsed local initiatives in private or semi private canal buildings by local landlords and tribal chiefs
(Ibid).
For the first time under the British rule, water was carried on a vast scale from one river to another. “For
some engineers (and other administrators), the effective control of the state over the larger environment
simply empowered the state to frame rules of proper irrigator behavior 13 that would enable them to
control people as canal controlled water” (Gilmartin, 1995:224). There emerged a highly centralized
system of irrigation management with a huge bureaucratic structure extending even to Britain.
One of the finest examples of the colonial irrigation policy is that of Punjab ‘canal colonies’, as these
lands were called, which were brought under cultivation by the interlinked irrigation canals. The colonial
engineers in the 1880s, began the construction of a series of interlinked irrigation canals in Western
Punjab which brought about 14 million acres of arid land under agricultural colonization and settlement
(Gilmartin, 2003). The history of Punjab ‘canal colonies’ depicted a complex character of a relationship
between the state, science and nature in a colonial context, by linking science and colonial empire in a
manner to control and commodify the nature in order to tap its productive powers (Ibid).

13
Here ‘proper irrigator behavior’ means farmers following a) the correct rules of irrigating the fields, b) not
wasting water, c) following the rules of proper construction and clearance of village watercourses, and d) not
growing crops which were forbidden like rice in certain areas etc (Gilmartin, 1995).
5
At one level colonial water engineering in the Punjab grew out of the idea of seeing Punjab’s river water
as ‘resource’, open to increase the state control for purposes of productive ‘use’ and ‘development’
(Gilmartin, 2003). As ‘developing’ such resources were critical to enhanced income, it was also critical to
new forms of state power (James Thomason cited in Gilmartin, 2003:5057). With increasingly, state
control over water and then over the land led to new framework of control over the local ‘communities’
comprising Indus basin society.
On the one hand, Northwestern canal schemes were outstandingly successful during the British period. It
enormously increased the agricultural production and incomes in backward areas and the Punjab
settlement became the pioneer of modern agriculture and irrigation (Stone, 1984). Widespread layout of
the canals made it possible for the government to earn considerable superfluous revenue over the costs
of operation, thus leading to high standard of operation and maintenance of the canals (Stone, 1984).
On the other hand, canals schemes have been criticized on the environmental grounds (Whitcombe,
1972; Stone, 1984).
Another example of this kind, is of Nira Left Bank Canal, which was constructed in the Deccan region of
Bombay Presidency as a famine relief work during 1876-85 and was initially conceived for the purpose
of ‘protective irrigation’ (Bolding et al., 1995; Attwood, 2007). In the course of time ‘block system 14’ was
introduced in the Nira canal which was based more or less on the traditional crop rotation system, the
bhandara or phad 15 system, which was practiced in Northern district of Bombay Presidency (Bolding et
al., 1995). The ‘block system’ turned out to be successful with the introduction of sugarcane cultivation
along with food crops in rotation.
Although the canal schemes were highly centralized and bureaucratically controlled, they did serve the
interest of its users 16, due to three main reasons a) firstly, the physical and technical: the environment of
the northwestern plains was best suited for the adoption of supply-driven water rationing system which
was cheap, efficient and equitable; difficult to manipulate and unparticipatory; b) secondly, the political
and social factors: there was lack of strong political forces capable of challenging the authority of the
colonial government on the issue of water rates, throughout that period; c) thirdly, the source of
inducement to perform: although the Irrigation Department (ID) staff were not legally accountable to the
water users, but they were under strong pressure from the higher authorities in the colonial government
to ensure that the canals’ financial and famine prevention goals should be met fruitfully (Bottrall, 1992).
Thus the design and management systems of canals were the product of a long continued process of
learning, adjustment and refinement over a long period of time―a full century from the completion of
the Upper Ganga Canal (UGC) until India independence. In fact many serious canal design mistakes were
made and with the introduction of Adjustable Proportional Modules (APMs) in 1920s a strict controlled
management system became widespread in colonial India in canal management (Stone, 1984; Bottrall,
1992).
From 1900 onwards-colonial engineers started realizing that low cost canal development sites for run-
of-the-river schemes were slowly declining in the NorthWest of India, although new work continued in
Punjab province and was extended into Sind in 1920s and 1930s (Stone, 1984). The construction of the
Sharda canal in central Uttar Pradesh (UP) in 1920s, made visible that in Gangetic Plains, expansion of
canals and its management would be difficult due to higher rainfall, higher water tables areas which
were vulnerable to water logging (Ibid).
For further water development for irrigation, upper river valleys of South India and Deccan for large and
medium canals schemes and in upland areas small surface systems which included tanks and
mechanized groundwater development were identified by the colonial administration (Bottrall, 1992).
Uncertainty of economic returns because of high construction cost of canals due to uneven topography
and rainfall conditions led to only modest upstream canal development in the South and West of India

14
For detail on Block System see ‘Modules for Modernization: Colonial Irrigation in India and The Technological
Dimension of Agrarian Change’ (Bolding et al., 1995).
15
Phad was a community managed irrigation system in which series of dams were built on rivers to divert water for
agriculture use.
16
Users here are the farmers who were getting water for irrigation from the Northwestern canal schemes (Bottrall,
1992).
6
(Ibid). The rehabilitation of tanks by the colonial government was very much undertaken but with little
success and insignificant impact (Sengupta, 1985).
Hence the British had established the commercial viability of canal irrigation by the end of colonial rule
(Whitcombe, 2005). But the performance of Indian agriculture due to canal irrigation facility has been
controversial with scholars such as Mason (2006) glorifying that canal irrigation curtailed famines in
India. Whereas others were of opinion that ‘unbalanced irrigation development’ of focusing irrigation
projects and investment in Punjab, Madras and United Provinces, failed to feed the rest of India and
could not prevent Bengal famine of 1942 leading to the starvation deaths of four million people (Shah,
2009).
The colonial government was more interested in canal construction due to obvious reasons. But in the
state of Gujarat, they encouraged the well construction through tax exemption as they believed that
irrigation could only be carried out effectively in Gujarat from wells (Hardiman, 1998). In Gujarat well
irrigation was the most important source of irrigation even during the colonial times as there were no
major colonial canal projects in this part of India (Ibid). During 1930s about 78 percent of the irrigated
area of British Gujarat was irrigated by wells and only 10 percent by the canals (Desai, 1948). Whereas in
the North-West of India, use of groundwater started increasing slowly through bullock-powered lift from
small private open wells during the 1900s period, but cost per unit of water lifted was high due to higher
labor and energy cost (Stone, 1984; Bottrall, 1992). This resulted in low crop yield and low cost of
surface water in the canal areas became hindrance in the expansion of groundwater development (Ibid).
In the province of Uttar Pradesh (UP) and of Punjab, mechanized tubewells were promoted by the
Agricultural Department. But due to the availability of cheap energy sources cost remained high of
tubewells in comparison to the returns. Colonial research led to the conclusion that the best option for
developing groundwater is to promote large-capacity deep tubewells (DTWs) rather than the shallow
wells. With the passage of time, large capacity deep tubewells (DTWs) scheme was being promoted by
the colonial government and around 1500 public tubewells were installed in Western UP in 1934, with
each well irrigating 150-200 hectare of land (Dhawan, 1982). A significant aspect of the colonial
government at the turn of the century was the creation of Provincial Agriculture Departments with the
aim of providing new professional expertise on issues relating to water and agriculture. Furthermore in
1928 the Royal Commission on Agriculture in India (RCAI) provided fourteen-volume report about
irrigation issues across the geographical regions of India (Bottrall, 1992).
Hence it could be summarized that the main interest of the colonial government was to maximize
revenue generation, which led to massive canal constructions by the British Government. This laid down
the foundation of new irrigation ideology of opening up vast-often unpopulated-areas for farming by
manipulating the large untapped rivers and reconfiguring the basin hydrology. Moreover an unbalanced
irrigation development without regional equity was initiated by having centralized structures for
constructing and managing large irrigation systems on commercial lines. Colonial irrigation in India
successfully advocated that the state in partnership with science can tame the rivers for improving the
human welfare. This ideology survived until the end of the Empire and began dominating the water
management vision in the postcolonial Independent India.
Last two decades before India’s independence were marked by economic recession, approaching end of
colonial empire and World War II. All these three factors contributed to the slowdown in irrigation
development of colonial India. India became a standard bearer for the world in the use of modern
science of engineering in the design of huge and multifarious irrigation structures only during the
colonial era. The modern epoch of construction of big dams had its roots in nineteenth century India
(Postel, 1999), and it was only in colonial period that India experienced its role as a hydraulic society to
some extent with strong centralized bureaucratic control on water development and management.
India’s independence came with partition, which brought about new forms of water management and
strategies to manage water for irrigation and the next section deals with this in detail.

7
4 Water management in independent India

India attained its independence from the British rule in August 1947. With independence came partition
of India and loss of large productive irrigated lands to Pakistan; and bulk of the public irrigation
networks that British had created ended up in Pakistan (Shah, 2009). Government of India’s main aim
after independence was to accelerate development and address the regional disparity of investment, as it
was facing serious food grains shortage and rapid rates of population increase. The slow pace of
irrigation development during the last decades of colonial regime had also aggravated to the current
problem situation of food shortage.

4.1 Large scale irrigation as ‘temples of modern India’


To overcome the food grain shortage, huge investment in large-scale irrigation project was considered to
be the best option to redress all these problems. And this was apparent from the Five Year Plans (FYPs),
which started in 1951. Investment in the large scale surface irrigation was targeted under the first two
plans and giant projects like Bhakra-Nagal, the Damodar Valley and Hirakud projects were undertaken
during that time. Minor Irrigation Projects 17 did receive some attention but the importance was given to
the Major 18 and Medium 19 Irrigation Projects after independence. The large-scale irrigation schemes
were multi-purpose and depended on reservoirs unlike the run-of-the-river irrigation schemes of the
colonial India.
The early post independence era was taking pride in launching vast new projects and large dams were
seen as ‘modern temples of modern India’ keeping in view the vision of Pundit Jawaharlal Nehru, the first
Prime Minister of Independent India. With the zeal of commitment for rapid social progress, the vast new
multi-purpose irrigation projects were projected as a matter of pride in the early post-independence
years. More than 90 percent of public investments in agriculture were allocated for large-scale projects
during the first 40 years after independence (Kishore, 2002). This also led to lobbyism by engineers,
irrigation bureaucrats and contractors who had vested interest in the construction of large dams in the
hydel projects. This further led to a severe deterioration in the quality of programme planning and
project design, during the second Five Year Plan, 1955-60 (FYP) (Hanson, 1966).
These ‘temples of modern India’ were flawed on three counts: a) Firstly, the construction of big projects
at many places led to major delay in project completion due to budget constraints (Hanson, 1966;
Bottrall, 1992). b) Secondly, these projects failed to take into consideration, the complex topographic
environmental condition that was not viable to build and extend canals in areas such as eastern
floodplains, and in Deccan (Bottrall, 1992). c) Finally the old colonial legislation of giving unlimited
powers to the government and the Irrigation Department (ID) continued to be practiced in all matters
relating to surface water development and management, leaving no rights to water users (Ibid).
Although there were few exceptions like the new schemes that were introduced in the North-West of
India, which led to the disappearance of the centralized bureaucratic canal management system
introduced during the colonial time (Bottrall, 1992). The Northwest supply-driven rationing principles
and the delta water management of the South were neither appropriate nor could be implemented due
to the rigidly designed and often incomplete delivery systems. Which was left at the end of the
construction process to meets its failure in other parts of India. The strict formal allocation rules made
Irrigation Department (ID) officials, vulnerable to pressures from influential farmers to mismanage the
distribution of water to their mutual advantage. This in turn led to a large network of corruption
involving local politicians, large farmers, and contractors in influencing the planning and construction
phases of surface water development as well as its managements (Pant, 1981; Wade, 1982). Vote bank
politics centering on relaxations of offering canal water at cheap rates by the local politicians, also
undermined the earlier performance incentives, which were imposed on the scheme managers by the
17
Minor irrigation schemes is the one in which the arable command area is less than 2000 hectares.
18
Major irrigation schemes is the one in which the arable command area is more than 10,000 hectares.
19
Medium irrigation schemes is the one in which the arable command area is more than 2000 hectares but less
than 10,000 hectares.
8
need to raise substantial revenues. Fall of water rates, squeezing of the budgets corresponding to the fall
of the salary levels of the Irrigation Department (ID) staff further added to the mismanagement and poor
performance of big irrigation projects (Chambers, 1988).
Widespread official acknowledgment of large schemes having severe water management problems began
from early 1970s, after the second Irrigation Commission (IC) report was released by Ministry of
Irrigation and Power under the Government of India. But for a long time Irrigation Department (ID)
professed that the main problems of water management is because of the farmers and the need of the
hour is to educate farmers about how to use water effectively and properly (Chambers, 1988). Thus, in
1974-75 Central Government initiated the Command Area Development Programme (CADP) for water
management in the command areas, but the programme did not take account of studying the vital
central issue of system design and management practice (Bottrall, 1992).

4.2 Small-scale revolution


Independent India’s water management can be further divided into small scale community based
management and groundwater revolution which is described in detail in the following sections.

4.2.1 Community-based management


In 1980s attempts were made to bring about reform in the management practices of Irrigation
Department (ID), through the World Bank supported National Water Management Project (NWMP) 20. But
none of these programmes made an effort to address the issue of the Irrigation Department’s (ID) legal
powers, lack of accountability in the system management and the monopolistic control of public funds
assigned for surface water development (Bottrall, 1992). During the early 1990s in India, Participatory
Irrigation Management (PIM) through Irrigation Management Transfer (IMT) to farmers was officially
acknowledged as the best method to bring about efficient utilization of irrigation water, equitable
distribution and sustainable irrigation service (Swain and Das, 2008).
The concept of PIM in India has evolved through three distinct phases a) Firstly in the early 1980s, the
concept was limited to farmers’ participation through their representatives in project management
committees, but this was not very successful; b) In the latter part of the 1980s, farmers’ organization
such as chak (outlet) committees were formed but many of these committees remained only on paper
and became dysfunctional after a while; and c) In the early part of 1990s, the concept of creating
farmers’ organizations and of system turnover to farmers’ was adopted through the World Bank-funded
Water Resources Consolidation Project. Through which thousands of Water Users Associations (WUAs)
were formed to take the responsibility for operation and maintenances of the downstream parts of
irrigation systems, distribution of water among water users and collection of water rates from the
farmers (Maloney and Raju, 1994; Swain and Das 2008).
Nonetheless the implementation of PIM has been a bumpy ride in India due to heterogeneity of farmers,
caste-class differences, physical system inefficiency, half-hearted support from irrigation bureaucracy,
lack of committed local leadership, inadequate capacity building and lack of proper incentives (Swain
and Das 2008). In spite of all this, since independence the expansion of irrigated area by canals has been
significant, from 8.3 million hectares in 1950-51 to 18 million hectares in 1999-00 (GoI, 2006a).
Furthermore in regard to community participation in irrigation management, Government of India had
also launched National Water Policy (NWP) of 1987 putting emphasis on farmer’s participation in the
management of irrigation systems especially in water distribution and collection of water charges
(Randhawa and Sharma, 1997). The National Water Policy (NWP) of 2002 emphasizes on participatory
approach for the management of the water by having cooperation between various governmental
agencies and other stakeholders including women participation in various aspects of planning,
design, development and management of the water resources schemes. Moreover, involving the
local bodies such as municipalities and gram panchayats in the operation, maintenance and
20
For detail see ‘Irrigation Management in South India: The Approach of The National Water Management Project
(Berkoff 1988).
9
management of water infrastructure was done in keeping in view the eventual transfer of
management rights to the user groups (GoI, 2002).
The post independence era has seen impressive increase in the irrigated areas by large surface systems
under state management. But on the contrary, small water surface systems under community managed
continued to decline due to low level of public investment and government measure of increasing its
legal and administrative control over them. For example kuhls system (farmer-managed gravity flow
irrigation) of Himachal Pradesh, ranges from kuhl regimes which operate independently of any state
involvement, to regimes which are totally managed by the Himachal Pradesh Irrigation and Public Health
Department 21 (Baker, 1997). The phads 22 of Maharashtra have been physically absorbed into large new
canal schemes. Whereas in the tank systems, population pressure on the upper catchments resulted in
rapid siltation, denudation and erosion of the areas on which they depended for their run-off. Secondly,
with the expansion of modern groundwater extraction technology along with Green Revolution in 1960-
70s acted as key factors in the dysfunctioning of the tanks (Mosse, 1999).
The micro-watershed based approach to natural resource management has been hampered due to
compartmentalization of various government programmes and the centralization of various programmes
meant for the water development. For example Community Development Programme (CDP) was started
in 1952 with the aim of community participation in the development of the village (Neale, 1983). But it
resulted only in the administrative and developmental functions of a centralized state in the form of
replacement by introducing from the 1960s, centrally sponsored programmes and schemes of individual
departments (Jain, 1985).
Whereas Indian watershed projects started spreading widely in the late 1980s and 1990s with the aim to
develop semi-arid areas that Green Revolution had circumvent (GoI, 1990, 1994a; World Bank, 1990).
Watershed projects approaches have evolved from the highly technocratic, large scale top-down
approach to greater local participation, use of local technologies which resulted in better performance in
terms of conservation and productivity (Farrington et al., 1999; Hanumantha Rao, 2000; Hinchcliffe et
al., 1999). Three extremely successful village level projects initiated in the 1970s: Sukhomajri, Ralegaon
Siddhi and Pani Panchayat which focused on the link between soil conservation and water harvesting are
seen as having the modern roots of the century old assortment of soil and water conservation efforts in
India (Kerr, 2002).
In order to replicate the success of these three projects several large-scale projects were started in
1980s 23 and all these projects operated in relatively poor degraded areas and adopted the technological
approaches of Sukhomajri, Ralegaon Siddhi and Pani Panchayat. But none of them adopted the
institutional arrangements and no or little efforts were made to organize communities as benefits and
cost were unevenly distributed in the watershed development project (GoI, 1990, 1994a; World Bank,
1990). The project fails to take note, that collective action to manage the common pool was tough as
benefits were gradual, incremental and unevenly distributed (World Bank, 2007).
A significant step for participatory and decentralized forms of decision making and fund allocation was
started with the comprehensive common guideline which was evolved for all programmes with the

21
Tensions has been generated within kuhl regimes due to increasing nonfarm employment as those who have
access to new economic opportunities are not very keen to contribute labor in voluntarily cleaning of canals and
other resources required for the upkeep of kuhl irrigation, as that time spent could be used in earning a wage
(Baker, 1997).
22
Phad was a community managed irrigation system in which series of dams were built on rivers to divert water for
agriculture use. The Phad system was prevalent in northwestern Maharashtra and came into existence 300-400
years ago; the Phad system operated on three rivers in the Tapi basin- Panjhra, Mosam and Aram in Maharashtra
(Agarwal and Narain, 1997).
23
Such as, Government of Maharashtra initiated a major watershed scheme called the Comprehensive Watershed
Development Program (COWDEP) for water harvesting (Pangare and Gondhalekar, 1998), Ministry of Rural
Development (MoRD) reorganized its Drought Prone Area Programme (DPAP) around water harvesting in 1987 (GOI,
1994a), World Bank supported Pilot Project on Watershed Development and the Model Watershed Program of the
Indian Council of Agricultural Research (World Bank, 1990; Kerr, 2007), and in late 1980s the Ministry of
Agriculture began the National Watershed Development Project for Rainfed Areas (NWDPRA) which was also on the
lines of World Bank projects (GOI, 1990).
10
recommendation of the Hanumantha Rao Committee in 1994 (Kerr et al., 2000; Kerr, 2002, 2007). The
watershed guidelines of 1994 advocated the need for different institutional arrangements at various
levels to fulfill the task of community based watershed management. It aimed to begin State-NGOs
partnership oriented approach to address environmental problem, to achieve best possible utilization of
natural resources, employment generation, restoration of ecological balance and to alleviate poverty
through Community Based Watershed Management (CBWM) (GoI, 1994b). The 1994 Guidelines were
revolutionary in the respect that they went hand in hand with the literature on Community Based
Natural Resource Management (CBNRM), which at that time focused on local people’s ability to manage
their own natural resources under some enabling conditions (Kerr, 2002).
Over the years many modifications have been made in the 1994 Common Guidelines. In 2001 Revised
Watershed Guideline were introduced, which placed importance to seeking a combination of Government
Organization /Non-Government Organization (NGO) as Project Implementation Agency (PIA) (GoI, 2001).
Whereas Hariyali 24 Guidelines launched in 2003 gave importance to Panchayati Raj institutions by
recognizing it as the implementing authority, rather than forming of watershed committee thus making
watershed programme, come directly under the supervision of the village panchayat 25 (GoI, 2003)
Again some changes in Hariyali Guidelines were made in 2006 under the name of Neeranchal Guidelines
(GoI, 2006b), which aimed at establishing series of institutional structures to govern watershed
management in the country. It created a National Authority for Sustainable Development of Rainfed
Areas (NASDORA), a quasi-independent authority to manage the Central Government-funded watershed
programmes. Recently again in 2008, modifications were made in the New Common Guideline of 2008
(GoI, 2008) which gives prime importance to community participation, by involving all the stakeholders
at the centre of planning, budgeting, implementation, and management of watershed projects. Hence the
New Common Guideline of 2008 emphasize in making community organizations closely associated and
accountable to gram sabha 26 in project activities.
The way community has been conceptualized in watershed programmes has flaws in selecting
community for watershed project. Two inter linked aspects need to be kept in account in order to
understand the way in which the official watershed guidelines and norms conceptualize community. The
first is ‘the unit of operation and implementation of a watershed development programme should be
watershed (that is the entire area that supplies water to a river) (Sangameswaran, 2008). But to avoid
problems of co-ordination between different administrative units, the village is used as the unit of
operation than the watershed (Ibid). Second aspect is on conditions, which are believed to facilitate
collective action for example through size and homogeneity (Sangameswaran, 2008). Thus the choice of
a village as a unit for implementation of watershed programme takes into account the assumption based
on commonalities, that people share a common history, ethnicity, interest and are willing to work for
common goal and at the same time having homogeneity in terms of landholdings, low percentage of
commons land, so that conflict is eliminated in watershed development (Kerr et al., 2002); and villages
which are at least perceived as having no factional relationship and promoting harmony is favored
(Baviskar, 2001; De Souza, 2001; Chhotray, 2004).
Hence the way community is conceptualized in watershed guidelines either ignored the individual
differences in a village, assuming that the common good for the village will override these differences.
Moreover it is believed that the new-institutionalist perspective will facilitate the cooperation of the
village community by developing institutions, which would enable difference to be resolved. Thus the
way community construction is conceptualized in the implementation of the watershed programmes has
serious drawbacks. As mere presence of particular features does not always lead to feeling of
togetherness, sense of belonging and moreover does not result in collective action in spite of purposively
choosing the villages for implementation of watershed project (Sangameswaran, 2008).
The point to note is that watershed is a hydrological unit but not a natural unit of human social
organization (Rhoades 1999; Swallow et al., 2001). The cost and benefits are unevenly distributed which
results from spatial variation and multiple conflicting use of natural resource in watershed. Large

24
Hariyali means greenery.
25
Village panchayat is the elected village governing council.
26
Gram Sabha is the assembly of all inhabitants of a village.
11
proportion of uncultivated common land is often in the upper watersheds and revegetating the
landscape requires protection against erosion which in term leads to cordoning of limits on grazing and
firewood collection (Farrington et al., 1999). The poor, women and landless who are heavily dependent
on these lands are severely affected, whereas the water harvesting benefits are also disproportionately
benefiting those, whose land are near the check dams and these are mostly wealth farmers who own
most of the irrigable land. Projects are unlikely to result in conservation and productivity benefits due to
uneven distribution of benefits, where conformity cannot be achieved or where downstream users and
upstream users work in close harmony and cooperation (Kerr, 2002). Thus the success of watershed
projects to spread beyond some cases and sustained into future as well, requires the knowledge of
importance pertaining to water-sharing. Consequently village level micro watersheds with discernable
hydrological linkages and established social relationship are promoted for watershed than the macro
watersheds covering many villages (Kerr, 2007).
The next section deals with the pump irrigation economy of India with the mechanized groundwater
development in the post independence era.

4.2.2 Groundwater Revolution – Taming the Anarchy


The mechanized lift irrigation from groundwater started in mid 1960s with the advent of new pumping
technology, which made possible to bore deep wells and extract water in large quantities. At the same
time with the advent of Green Revolution a voracious demand for water was created for the high-
yielding hybrid crop varieties (Hardiman, 2007). Green Revolution agrarian technology and the
institutions of groundwater revolution played a significant role in transforming the productivity of India’s
irrigated agriculture. The Green Revolution and Tubewell Revolution went hand-in-hand. In India,
mechanized pump irrigated area has tremendously increased from 6 million hectare in 1950-51 to 33.3
million hectare in 2000 (GoI, 2006a).
In the prosperous canal irrigated areas of the North-west where the revolution began and in other
alluvial areas with easily accessible aquifers, small-capacity shallow tubewells (STWs) under individual
ownership were given preference since the beginning. Whereas promising aspects of deep borewells in
water scarce hard rock areas made the groundwater technology quite popular. This was due to its
capacity to provide water on demand, having good impact on production about twice as high as canals,
per unit of water provided and three times higher than tanks (Chambers et al., 1989). Various public
agencies provided support in the form of credits and subsidies for well installation and the supply of
electricity (Bottrall, 1992). This again benefited the rich farmers, ‘once again, like the canal and dam
technology, affluent sections of society benefited from the tubewells’ (Singh, 1997:53).
Although the well were individually-owned and direct government involvement in tubewell management
was through incentives and disincentives, only with the exceptional cases of Eastern Floodplains, like
Eastern Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, West Bengal where State Irrigation Department (SID) were actively engaged
in installing deep tubewells. For example in Uttar Pradesh which had the largest public tubewell program
among all the Indian states, World Bank introduced two technological improvements during early 1970s:
a) power line to insulate public tubewells from power outages; and b) an 8-shaped buried distribution
system with pucca (concrete) outlets for blocks of eight hectares of the command area (Shah, 2009:28).
These developments benefitted already prosperous canal irrigation regions, especially in North-West of
India. Moreover, private shallow tubewells (STWs) which were dependent on groundwater recharge from
canal seepage were able to offer complementary flexibility which rigid canal supplies lacked, due to the
availability of water on demand from the wells at time at will (Bottrall, 1992). The spread of tubewell
technology went hand-in-hand with the Green Revolution technology in the NorthWest region of India
and projected the region’s experience as the best model for rest of India.
Whereas the spread of private shallow tubewells (STWs) were slow and erratic in the groundwater
abundant Eastern Plains, which led the policy makers believe that unequal and fragmented landholdings
were acting as hindrance in the promotion of tubewell technology. Therefore in many states of India,
large capacity tube wells run by government corporation were introduced which were serving areas of 50
to 150 hectares (Shah, 2009) from the support of World Bank in states like Uttar Pradesh and Bihar. The
main objective behind public tubewell projects was to encourage the use of tubewell and modern
12
mechanical pump irrigation, and promote equity to bring irrigation benefits to poor farmers. Furthermore
tubewell technology was capital intensive and required large farms to make it economically viable, but
majority of the Indian farms were small. In order to avoid the situation where the larger farmers having
tubewell technology become exploitative water lords, and to maintain the parity with canal irrigation,
public tubewell projects supplied water for irrigation at heavily subsidized rates (Ibid).
On the one hand there has been limited evidence of public tubewells projects being superior to private
shallow tubewells (STWs) on equity forum, as tubewells were manipulative in their operation by larger
farmers (Ballabh and Shah, 1989; Shah, 2009). On the other hand despite all these, the projects
demonstrated the ability of the productive value of the modern tubewell irrigation. Private shallow
tubewells (STWs) in 1980s began to get widespread in many parts of India especially in Eastern UP and
West Bengal, and in areas where shallow tubewells (STWs) came up in large numbers competitive
groundwater market developed (Chambers, 1989). Private markets in pump irrigation service soon
emerged and started competing with the public tubewells (Shah, 1993, 2001). Studies of Ballabh (1987)
in Uttar Pradesh, Pant (1984, 1991), Singh and Satish (1988) found the private tubewell owners offering
far more superior irrigation services to their neighbors in and around the public tubewells. In fact
groundwater development in the water-scarce hard rock upland region has been biased towards larger
farmers’ due to high investment costs and absence of surplus water for selling.
The expansion of groundwater irrigation has been largely due to improved drilling and lifting
technologies along with liberal credit provision; lower per unit cost of water pumping, enormous rural
electricity program with subsidized supply of electricity (Marothia, 2003). Therefore with the absence of
effective institutional control measures and checks have led to severe over-exploitation of the
groundwater. Farmers with adequate resources have constructed deep tubewells with submersible pumps
and in the process have been more interested with their private gains and ignoring the social cost of
over-exploitation of groundwater (Joshi and Tyagi, 1991; Dhawan, 1995; Vaidyanathan, 1996).
This in turn has led to gross over-exploitation of groundwater resource in the form of phenomenon
which seems to provide justifiable evidence Garett Hardin’s thesis of ‘tragedy of the commons―that
uncontrolled access to a Common Property Resource (CPR) leads inevitably to its degradation (Hardin,
1968, 1977). However there is no ‘tragedy for the time being for those who have the resources to drill
the wells and purchase water, as it puts them in an excellent position to benefit from the wider scarcity
(Hardiman, 2007: 41). Further under private property regime, water markets have developed in many
parts of India (Shah, 1993). As groundwater is neither a true open access resource, because its ability to
extract water is limited by well ownership, nor it is a Common Property Resource (CPR) because it lacks
an identifiable group of users having co-equal user rights (Ciriacy-Wantrup and Bishop, 1975).
In order to prevent over-exploitation of groundwater, Government of India drafted a Model Bill in 1970
for adoption by the State Governments for groundwater regulation. Although water management is the
overall responsibility of the State Government as per the constitutional provision of India, it falls under
the State subject (Dhiman, 2007). The Model Bill empowered the State Governments to tackle the
drinking water situation and the bill was further revised subsequently in 1972, 1992 and in 1996. The
latest version unveiled in 2005 27 has more influence on legislative activity because groundwater
regulation has become priority in many states. Model Bill gives the State Government, the power and the
authority over groundwater control by imposing the registration of all groundwater infrastructure and;
providing a basis for intruding permits for groundwater extraction in region where groundwater is over
exploited (Phansalkar and Kher, 2006; Cullet and Gupta, 2009). Some states have adopted the
groundwater acts over the past decades 28. The Model Bill included the constitution of State Ground
Water Authority (SGWA) and the modalities for regulation of groundwater resources. Central Ground
Water Authority (CGWA) was constituted under sub section (3) of the environment (Protection) Act,
1986 on 14.01.1997 for the purpose of groundwater development and management 29. The authority has

27
For detail see ‘Model Bill to Regulate and Control the Development and Management of Groundwater 2005’,
available at http://www.ielrc.org/content/e0506.pdf.
28
Andhra Pradesh, Goa, Tamil Nadu, Kerala, West Bengal, Himachal Pradesh and Union Territories Lakshadweep and
Pondicherry have enacted and implemented groundwater legislation.
29
For detail see ‘Groundwater Management and Ownership - Report of the Expert Group (Planning Commission,
2007, Government of India, New Delhi).
13
the mandate to notify ‘over-exploited’ 30 and ‘critical’ 31 areas and the regulation of groundwater
withdrawal in those areas. But the authority does not have a broad mandate to regulate groundwater in
general and have not been able to make much difference in the groundwater management (Shah, 2008).
Apart from the legislative activity to manage groundwater, control measures such as electricity reforms
like Jyotirgram 32 scheme (“Lighted Village”) have been introduced. As a silver line, community based
mass movement for rainwater harvesting and recharge has been quite successful in Rajasthan,
Saurashtra of Gujarat, Madhya Pradesh and Andhra Pradesh.
To summarize, the groundwater institutions which we find today in India were embryonic in the early
years of the nineteenth century and are fully operational in contemporary India. The jointly owned wells
in nineteenth century Punjab (Islam, 1997) operated like the tube well companies of North Gujarat (Shah
and Bhattacharya, 1993) and Punjab (Tiwari, 2007) of today. In 2003 India’s National Sample Survey
organization conducted a study on the source of irrigation used by cultivators in Kharif (rainy season
crops) and Rabi (winter crops), by asking 51,770 cultivators from 6,770 villages. The study found out that
69 percent of kharif acreage and 76 rabi acreage were irrigated with wells or tubewells (Shah, 2009).
Therefore mechanized tubewells with small pumps have transformed irrigated agriculture in India
thereby giving a whole new meaning and dimension to the water management. The process of
groundwater development has been institutionally (not hydrologically) independent from surface water
development. The surface water development technology’s management has been Common Property
Resource (CPR) or under state agencies, whereas groundwater is governed by minimal legislation as it
remained open – access, and provides the pump owners with unlimited right to extract water from
aquifers under their land.

5 Discussion

Water management related policies, laws and programmes in postcolonial India have been largely shaped
by the legacy of the colonial times, constitutional developments, with specific rules on surface and
groundwater irrigation and management. This has resulted in different programmes for large-scale
irrigation across community based water management and groundwater development at different spatial
and temporal scale.
The existing institutional arrangement for water resource management in the country is fragmented (see
Fig. 1 in Appendix) with a number of independent organizations dealing with water at the centre and
state levels. At the union level, the water affairs are run by Ministry of Water Resources (MoWR),
agriculture is under the rubric of Ministry of Agriculture (MoA); rural development is conducted through
Ministry of Rural Development (MoRD) and forest affairs being managed by Ministry of Environment and
Forest (MoEF). Each of these ministries has their own research and development sections and policies to
guide their programmes. Interestingly, the MoWR only lays down policy guidelines and programmes for
the development and regulation of country’s water resources 33 (GoI, 2003) and has no institutional
structure to support the implementation of the water resources development programmes at the state
level. Thus creating a vacuum at the level of policy implementation between center and state. The

30
Over-exploited in the context of groundwater means ‘annual groundwater extraction exceeds the annual
replenishable resource and significant decline in long term groundwater levels has been observed either in pre or
post monsoon or both’(Dhiman, 2007).
31
Critical in the context of groundwater means ‘stage of groundwater development is above 90% and within 100%
of annual replenishable resource and significant decline is observed in trend of long term water levels in both pre
and post monsoon periods’(Dhiman, 2007).
32
In 2003, Gujarat government introduced Jyotirgram Scheme, in which villages get 24 hours three-phase power
supply for domestic uses, schools, hospitals and village industries and; farmers get 8 hours of full voltage three
phase power on a announced scheduled, and by 2006 around 18,000 villages have been successfully covered under
this scheme (Shah, 2009).
33
Though the MoWR has about 8 federal-level organizations performing different functions along with 10 ad hoc
boards and commissions having responsibilities for the execution of specific engineering objectives within river
basins (Pitman, 2002:5).
14
exception to this lies with regard to inter-state and international water issues. While the ministry of
water resources remains mainly as an advisory and monitoring role, other ministries related to water
(agriculture, forest and rural development) and agencies (state irrigation departments) play an additional
regulatory role with delegated structures. The vacuum created illustrates the drawbacks and void in the
mechanism of the Ministry of Water Resources, which does not have any validity beyond making policies
and generating information.
State agencies play a major role in development and management of water resources under their
jurisdiction through water related sectoral units (agriculture, forest, rural development, urban
development), other than the Ministry of Water Resources. Though there are diverse departments and
agencies involved over water resource management but their role remains fragmented (World Bank,
1998). Irrigation is the largest user of water in all states. Interestingly, there is no separate department
for irrigation; rather it comes under the state department of public works (PWD). The PWD is mainly
entrusted with constructing roads and governmental buildings, and providing material requirements and
construction of infrastructure for drinking water and irrigation water needs. In a way there is strong
orientation of the PWD towards civil works construction resulting in limited attention to water planning
and management. Though a few states have created a Water Resources Organization (WRO), like Tamil
Nadu and Orissa, they have merely remained in renaming the existing PWD with specialist function of
irrigation management (Thakkar, 1998). Interestingly, in Tamil Nadu the WRO is mainly concerned with
formulating and implementing major, medium and minor irrigation schemes (GoTN, 2005). While
Maharashtra went for a gradual irrigation reform through participation, Andhra Pradesh went ahead
with a ‘Big Bang’ approach driven by political will to reform the state. As a result over 10,000 water
users association were elected throughout the state in June 1997 (Pitman, 2002:10). With strong
sectoral interest among various departments, there is inadequate institutional mechanism for handling
inter-sectoral water issues.
The legal component assumes importance in providing operational backing and enforcement towards
water resources management. India does not have any separate water legislation, but has water-related
legislation dispersed across various sectors between central and state provisions (Saleth, 2004). The
legislation governing water issues fails to recognize the structural system and process for providing
secure, defensible and enforceable surface water rights. The Indian legal system accepts the riparian
rights of the individual to extract surface water from natural systems without disturbing similar benefits
of other riparians, as natural rights 34. With the Indian legal system recognizing statutory means of
governing water, socially embedded rules are left in legal limbo with individuals seeking the time-
consuming and expensive Indian court system for their grievances. The problem is further compounded
with increasing demand from new water resources, such as industrial and environmental needs.
Groundwater, on the contrary, is purely a private good having rights linked with land ownership. All
groundwater existing and found beneath private property (that is land) is fully under the control of the
owner, who is free to extract and use it as he or she sees fit. Regulation of groundwater is limited 35 to a
few states and metropolitan cities. However, regulations through indirect means via the National Bank
for Agricultural and Rural Development (NABARD) and State Electricity Boards have been adopted while
providing electric connections and credit for investments in wells and pump sets. However, such acts
have been frequently by-passed, many times affecting the poor. For instance, Jyotirgram scheme has
shrunk the water markets in Gujarat affecting the livelihood of many people 36. To sum-up, groundwater
is largely governed by farm size, the depth and number of wells, pumping capacity and economic power
(Saleth, 2004:11). In recent years, the advent of rainwater harvesting gives overwhelming rights to
owners having rooftops and open space. There are a number of institutions prescribing water quality

34
This does not apply to waters flowing in irrigation canals and stored in man-made reservoirs, in which case water
can be drawn only with a governance-issued permit.
35
Only Chennai Metropolitan area, state of Maharashtra, Karnataka and Gujarat have enacted ground water
regulation acts (Saleth, 2004).
36
For detail see ‘Groundwater Governance through Electricity Supply Management: Assessing an Innovative
Intervention in Gujarat, Western India (Shah et al., 2008).
15
standards. 37 Unfortunately, there is no coordination among these agencies and more important is the
need to operationalise these standards through monitoring and enforcements. In addition to these, there
are legislations that have indirect influence on water resources, such as those related to land, forest and
environment. The applicability of these legalities often takes the route of conflicts that are conducted
and decided in terms of law. Mosse (1997) provides a clear illustration in the existence of socially
embedded rules in accessing water from tank-irrigated agriculture in South India.
The incongruence in the conceptualization of legally defined institutions (especially government) and the
concrete manifestation of these with socio-and economic life of actors, not only leads to mismatches in
the way these legislations are perceived by statutory Acts, but also represents a struggle in establishing
and protecting existing socially embedded rules over water. Von Benda-Beckman et al., (1997) illustrate
this incongruence in terms of the definition of water, construction and in the complexities involved in
understanding water rights. Firstly, formal institutions especially the state, should define water in terms
of legally defined rules of ‘one water complex’, such as lakes, rivers, streams, well and water for
irrigation. In addition, it can also refer to specific volume or quality. However, water is conceived among
people in terms of its actual use and normatively defined functions. This mismatch in defining water very
often leads people to invest these normative definitions with a specific legal status. Secondly, in the
legal context there are two broad distinctions of water rights; public and private water rights. Though
most rights at the local level have a complex mix of both public and private rights over access to water.
Finally, legally defined rights are very often seen as established ones. Nevertheless, the conditions under
which actor’s access water resources are rarely defined rules.
In view of these complexities, the legislations and regulations made by the national government are only
one part of the motivation for the actors’ behavior. These conventional forms of legislation co-exist and
interact with multiple legal orders such as customary, religious, project and local laws. All of which
provide basis for actors to claim access to water (Von Benda-Beckman et al., 1997), especially in
countries like India that have centuries old archaic management practices. These multiple legal
institutions existing at various levels in the social spectrum help actors in “forum shopping” to one or
another of these legal frameworks to access water (Spiertz, 2000:191). Institutions through which these
legal forms are negotiated and renegotiated are crucial for water resource management (Bruns and
Meinzen Dick, 2000).

6 Conclusion

Water management has been a contentious and tricky affair in India due to socio-economic-political and
ecological reasons. Factors like caste-class differences, heterogeneity of farmers, rural–urban dichotomy,
and extreme different ecological conditions have influenced the water management. To complicate
further, vote bank politics, lack of coordination between irrigation bureaucracy, policy making and
various sectoral departments carrying out their own water programmes, have affected water
management in a diverse manner to people. In this diverse regime, India has been embracing water
management in its water policies, but they remain a mere proposition. The Ministries seize the
opportunity presented by the all-encompassing concept of ‘integrated’ and ‘community-based water
resource management’ to push their ministerial objectives and to overcome financial deficit, together
with their proclaimed adherence to democratic commitment. The state governments have exploited the
concept to remain forefront in ecological and social transformation using a vehicle of centralized single
focus technology mission. While collective action is transformed into private collaboration for local elites
in their continuous search for acquiring power to control. These actors exploit the incongruence
presented by the complex rules and administrative red tapism to achieve their social goal of survival by
exploiting water management technologies. Understanding how these different policies and programs

37
Central Pollution Control Board (CPCB) defines water quality for five different categories of inland and fresh
water that is being followed by the States. The Bureau of Indian Standards establishes drinking water quality under
the Indian Standards Institution (ISI). World Health Organization (WHO) provides guidelines not covered by ISI
standards. In addition, the Environmental Protection Act 1986, Hazardous Waste Rules 1989 and State Pollution
Control Boards (SPCB) have their own regulatory regime.
16
influence water management at the community level is one of the unexplored issues. Its further
examining will offer insights on the ability of the community to integrate different programs and policies
by default given their complex livelihood requirements. The co existence of static and dynamic elements
in the society along with organic and inorganic linkages would pervade through paradox and ambiguities
perturbing the debate. Thus it would invite and stimulate new inquiries emanating from policy makers,
civil society, academia and institutional apparatus of state.

17
Appendix

Fig. 1 ADMINISTRATIVE STRUCTURE OF MAJOR MINISTRIES CONCERNED WITH WATER RESOURCE

Ministry of Rural
Ministry of Water Ministry of Development and Ministry of
Resources Agriculture Employment Environment
and Forest
Nation al

Central Ground Water Indian Council of National Institute of Indian


Board (CGWB) Agricultural Rural Development Institute of
Research (ICAR) (NIRD) Forest
Central Pollution Control
Board (CPCB) Management
Krishi Vigyan
Kendra (KVK)
(IIFM).
Central Water
Commission (CWC)

National Water
Development Agency
Environment
Land Policy Policy/ Forest
Agricultural
Water Policy Policy
Policy

Programme and Funds


Programme and Funds Programme and Funds

Department of Department of Rural Department


Only if there are Agriculture Development and of Forest
State

any major Panchayat Raj


irrigation projects
and inter-state
water issues

Division District Rural Divisional


Agricultural Development Forest Officer
Division
District/

Officers Agency (DRDA)


Blo ck / Sub -

Agriculture Block Development Range Officer


Vacuum Officer Officer
Division

Forest Guard
Sector Specialist Sector Specialist

Village

18
References

Agarwal, Anil and Sunita Narain (eds). 1997. Dying Wisdom: Rise, Fall and Potential of India’s Traditional
Water Harvesting Systems, Fourth Citizen Report on the State of India’s Environment. New Delhi:
Centre for Science and Environment.
Attwood, Donald W. 2007. ‘Small is Deadly, Big is Wasteful: The Impact of Large-Scale Industrial Systems
in Western India’ in Amita Baviskar (ed.) Waterscapes: The Cultural Politics of a Natural Resource.
Delhi: Permanent Black, 11-39.
Baker, J. Mark. 1997. ‘Common Property Resource Theory and the Kuhl Irrigation Systems of Himachal
Pradesh’ in Human Organization 56 (2): 199-208.
――――. 2003. ‘The Politic of Knowledge: British Colonial Codification of “Customary” Irrigation
Practices in Kangra India’ in Himalayan Research Bulletin XXI (2): 26-35.
Ballabh, Vishwa. 1987. Decline of Novel Experiment: A Case Study of Group Irrigation Tubewells in Deoria
District. Anand, India: Institute of Rural Management.
Ballabh, Vishwa. and Tushaar Shah. 1989. Efficiency and Equity in Groundwater Use and Management.
Workshop Report No.3, Anand: Institute of Rural Management.
Baviskar, Amita. 2001. The Dream Machine: Following the Course of the Watershed Mission in Jhabua,
Madhya Pradesh. Paper Presented at the Conference on the Culture and Politics of Water at
University of Delhi, India.
Berkoff, D. J. W. 1988. Irrigation Management in South India: The Approach of The National Water
Management Project. ODI/IIMI Irrigation Management Network Paper 88/2d.
――――. 1990. Irrigation Management on the Indo-Gangetic Plain. World Bank Technical Paper No.
129. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Bolding, Alex., Peter P. Mollinga and Kees Van Straaten. 1995. ‘Modules for Modernization: Colonial
Irrigation in India and The Technological Dimension of Agrarian Change’ in The Journal of
Development Studies 31 (6): 805-844.
Bottrall, Anthony. 1992. ‘Fits and Misfits over Time and Space: Technologies and Institutions of Water
Development for South Asian Agriculture’ in Contemporary South Asia 1 (2): 227-247.
Bruns, B. R. and R. S. Meinzen-Dick. 2000. ‘Negotiating Water Rights: Implications for Research and
Action’ in B.R. Bruns and R.S. Meinzen-Dick (eds) Negotiating Water Rights. Washington:
International Food Policy Research Institute, and New Delhi: Vistaar Publications.
Chambers, Robert. 1988. Managing Canal Irrigation: Practical Analysis from South Asia. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Chambers, Robert., N.C. Saxena and Tushaar Shah. 1989. To the Hands of the Poor: Water and Trees.
London: Intermediate Technology Publications.
Chhotray, V. 2004. ‘The Negation of Politics in Participatory Development Projects, Kurnool, Andhra
Pradesh’ in Development and Change 35(2): 327- 352.
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V. and R.C. Bishop. 1975. ‘Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy’
in Natural Resources Journal 15 (4): 713-728.
Coward, E. Walter Jr. 1990. ‘Property Rights and Networks Order: The Case of Irrigation Works in the
Western Himalayas’ in Human Organization 49 (1): 78-88.
Cullet, P. and Joyeeta Gupta. 2009. ‘India: Evolution of Water Law and Policy’ in Joseph W. Dellapenna
and Joyeeta Gupta (eds) The Evolution of the Law and Politics of Water. Dordrecht: Springer
Academic Publishers, 159-175.
Desai, M.B. 1948. The Rural Economy of Gujarat. Bombay: Oxford University Press.
De Souza, A. 2001. ‘Imagined Communities and Collective Claims: An Ethnographic Study of the
Construction of a Minor Irrigation Tank’. Paper Presented at the Conference on the Culture and
Politics of Water at University of Delhi, India.

19
Dhawan, B.D. 1982. The Development of Tubewell Irrigation in India. New Delhi: Agricole Publishing
Academy.
――――. 1995. Groundwater Depletion, Land Degradation and Irrigated Agriculture in India. New
Delhi: Commonwealth Publishers.
Dhiman, S.C. 2007. ‘Groundwater Regulation’. Paper Presented at National Groundwater Congress, New
Delhi: Central Groundwater Board, Ministry of Water Resources, Government of India.
Farrington, J., C. Turton and A.J. James (eds). 1999. Participatory Watershed Development Challenges for
the Twenty-First Century. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Gilmartin, David. 1995. ‘Models of the Hydraulic Environment: Colonial Irrigation, State Power and
Community in the Indus Basin’ in David Arnold and Ramachandra Guha (eds) Nature, Culture,
Imperialism: Essays on the Environmental History of South Asia. New Delhi: Oxford University Press,
210-236.
――――. 2003. ‘Water and Waste: Nature Productivity and Colonialism in the Indus Basin’ in Economic
and Political Weekly 38 (48): 5057-5065.
Government of India. 1990. WARASA: National Watershed Development Project for Rainfed Areas
(NWDPRA) Guidelines I edition. New Delhi: Ministry of Agriculture.
――――.1994a. Report of the Technical Committee on Drought Prone Areas Programme and Desert
Development Programme. New Delhi: Ministry of Rural Development.
――――. 1994b. Guidelines for Watershed Development. New Delhi: Department of Land Resources,
Ministry of Rural Development, Government of India, accessed on 10/06/09 from
http://dolr.nic.in/fguidelines.htm.
――――. 2001. Guidelines for Watershed Development Revised. New Delhi: Department of Land
Resources, Ministry of Rural Development, Government of India, accessed on 10/06/09 from
http://dolr.nic.in/fguidelines.htm.
――――. 2002. National Water Policy: 2002. New Delhi: Ministry of Water Resources, Government of
India, accessed on 30/12/09 from
http://wrmin.nic.in/writereaddata/linkimages/nwp20025617515534.pdf.
――――. 2003. Hariyali: Guidelines for Watershed Development. New Delhi: Department of Land
Resources, Ministry of Rural Development, Government of India accessed on 10/06/09 from
http://dolr.nic.in/fguidelines.htm.
――――. 2006a. Report of Sub-Committee on More Crop and Income Per drop of Water, Advisory
Council on Artificial Recharge of Groundwater. New Delhi: Ministry of Water Resources, Government
of India accessed on 3/07/2010 from http://mowr.gov.in/writereaddata/mainlinkfile/File722.pdf.
――――. 2006b. From Hariyali to Neeranchal: Report of the Technical Committee on Watershed
Programmes in India. New Delhi: Department of Land Resources, Ministry of Rural Development,
Government of India, accessed on 10/07/09 from
http://www.wassan.org/Policy%20space/Parthasarathy%20Committee.pdf.
――――. 2008. Common Guidelines for Watershed Development Projects. New Delhi: Department of
Land Resources, Ministry of Rural Development, Government of India, accessed on 10/06/09 from
http://dolr.nic.in/fguidelines.htm.
GoTN. 2005. Citizen's Charter: Public Works Department - Water Resource Organization.
Government of Tamil Nadu, accessed on 6/04/06 from http://www.tn.gov.in/citizen/wro-en.htm.
Gudeman, Stephen. 1986. Economics as Culture: Models and Metaphors of Livelihood. London: Routledge
and Kegan Paul.
Habib, Irfan. 1970. ‘Presidential Address (Medieval India)’ in Indian History Congress: Proceedings of the
Thirty –first Session, Varanasi 1969. Patna: Indian History Association.
――――. 1982. ‘Agrarian Economy’ in Tapan Raychaudhuri, and Irfan Habib (eds) The Cambridge
History of India, Volume I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 48-75.
Hanson, A.H. 1966. The Process of Planning—A Study of India’s Five Year Plans 1950-1964. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
20
Hanumantha Rao, C.H. 2000. ‘Watershed Development in India: Recent Experience and Emerging Issues’
in Economic and Political Weekly 35 (45): 3943-3947.
Hardiman, David. 1998. ‘Well Irrigation in Gujarat: Systems of Use, Hierarchies of Control’ in Economic
and Political Weekly 33 (25): 1533-1544.
――――. 2007. ‘The Politics of Water Scarcity in Gujarat’ in Amita Baviskar (ed.) Waterscapes: The
Cultural Politics of a Natural Resource. Delhi: Permanent Black, 40-64.
――――. 2008. ‘The Politics of Water in Colonial India: The Emergence of Control’ in Kuntala Lahiri-
Dutt and Robert J. Wasson (eds) Water First: Issues and Challenges for Nations and Communities in
South Asia. New Delhi: Sage Publications, 47-58.
Hardin, G. 1968. ‘The tragedy of the commons’ in Science 162: 1243-8.
――――. 1977. ‘The Tragedy of the Commons’ in G. Hardin and J. Baden (eds) Managing the Commons.
San Francisco: W.H. Freeman, 16-29.
Hinchcliffe, F., J. Thompson, J. Pretty, I. Guijt and P. Shah (eds). 1999. Fertile Ground: The Impacts of
Participatory Watershed Management. London: Intermediate Technology Publications.
Islam, M. M. 1997. Irrigation Agriculture and the Raj, Punjab, 1887-1947. New Delhi: Manohar Books.
Jain, L. C. 1985. Grass Without Roots: Rural Development Under Government Auspices. New Delhi: Sage
Publications.
Joshi, P.K. and N.K. Tyagi. 1991. ‘Sustainability of Existing Farming System in Punjab and Haryana―Some
Issues on Groundwater Use’ in Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics 46 (3): 412-421.
Kerr, J. 2002. ‘Watershed Development, Environmental Services and Poverty Alleviation in India’ in World
Development 30 (8): 1387-1400.
――――. 2007. ‘Watershed Management: Lessons from Common Property Theory’ in International
Journal of the Commons 1 (1): 89-109.
Kerr, J., G. Pangare, V.L. Pangare and P.J. George. 2000. An Evaluation of Dryland Watershed Development
Projects in India. EPTD Discussion Paper No. 68, accessed on 11/09/09 from
http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/eptdp68.pdf.
Kerr, J., G. Pangare, V.L. Pangare. 2002. Watershed Development Projects in India: An Evaluation. IFPRI
Research Report 127. Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
Kishore, Avinash. 2002. Social Impact of Canal Irrigation: A Review of 30 Years of Research. Paper
Presented at First Annual Partners’ Meet of the IWMI-TATA Water Policy Research Program, Anand
Gujarat.
Ludden, David. 1978. ‘Ecological Zones and Cultural Economy of Irrigation in Southern Tamil Nadu’ in
South Asia 1 (1): 1-13.
Maloney, Clarence and K.V. Raju. 1994. Managing Irrigation Together: Practice and Policy in India. New
Delhi: Sage Publications.
Marothia, Dinesh K. 2003. ‘Institutions for Common Pool Resources’ in Suresh Pal, Mruthyunjaya, P.K.
Joshi and Raka Saxena (eds) Institutional Change in Indian Agriculture. New Delhi: National Centre
for Agricultural Economics and Policy Research, 61-80.
Marshall, Gordon. 2004. Oxford Dictionary of Sociology. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Mason, P. 2006. The Men Who Ruled India. New Delhi: Rupa & Co.
Mosse, David. 1997. ‘The Symbolic Making of Common Property Resources: History, Ecology
and Locality in a Tank Irrigated landscape in South India’ in Development and Change, 28: 467-504.
――――. 1999. ‘Colonial and Contemporary Ideologies of ‘Community Management’: The case of Tank
Irrigation Development in South India’ in Modern Asian studies 33 (2): 303-338.
Neale, Walter C. 1983. ‘Community Development in India: Progress or Rip-Off’’ in Asian Survey 23 (11):
1209-1219.
Pangare, G and S. Gondhalekar. 1998. ‘Evolution of the Watershed Development Program in
Maharashtra’. Proceedings of the National Workshop on Watershed Approach for Managing Degraded

21
Land in India. April 27-29, London: Overseas Development Institute and New Delhi: Ministry of Rural
Development.
Pant, Niranjan, 1981. Some Aspects of Irrigation Administration. Calcutta: Naya Prokash.
――――. 1984. ‘Community Tubewells: An Organizational Alternative to Small Farmers’ Irrigation’ in
Economic and Political Weekly 19 (26): A59-A66.
――――. 1991. Development of Groundwater Markets in Eastern Uttar Pradesh, Indo-Dutch Uttar
Pradesh Tubewell Project. Lucknow, India: Centre for Development Studies.
――――. 1998. ‘Indigenous Irrigation in South Bihar: A Case of Congruence of Boundaries’ in Economic
and Political Weekly 33 (49): 3132-3138.
Phansalkar, S and Vivek Kher. 2006. ‘A Decades of the Maharashtra Groundwater Legislation: Analysis of
the Implementation Process’ in Law Environment and Development Journal 2 (1): 67-83.
Pitman, K. 2002. India: World Bank Assistance for Water Resources Management - A Country Assistance
Management. Washington: Operation Evaluation Department, World Bank.
Planning Commission. 2007. Report of the Expert Group on Groundwater Management and Ownership.
New Delhi: Government of India.
Postel, Sandra. 1999. Pillar of Sand: Can The Irrigation Miracle Last? New York: W.W. Norton and
Company.
Randhawa, V.S and P.B.S. Sharma. (eds). 1997. National Water Policy 1987. New Delhi: National
Academy of Agricultural Sciences.
Rhoades, R. 1999. ‘The Participatory Multipurpose Watershed Projects: Nature’s Salvation or
Schumacher’s Nightmare? In R. Lal (ed.) Integrated Watershed Management in the Global Ecosystem.
Boca Raton: CRC Press, 327-343.
Saleth, M.R. 2004. Strategic Analysis of Water Institutions in India: Application of a New Research
Paradigm. IWMI Research Report 79: 37.
Sangameswaran, Priya. 2008. ‘Community Formation, ‘Ideal Villages and Watershed Development in
Western India’ in Journal of Development Studies 44 (3): 384-408.
Sengupta, Nirmal. 1985. ‘Irrigation: Traditional vs Modern’ in Economic and Political Weekly 20 (45/47):
1919-1938.
Shah, Tushaar. 1993. Groundwater Markets and Irrigation Development: Political Economy and Practical
Policy. Mumbai: Oxford University Press.
――――. 2001. Wells and Welfare in Ganga Basin: Public Policy and Private Initiatives in Eastern Uttar
Pradesh, India. Research Report 54. Colombo: International Water Management Institute.
――――. 2008. ‘Groundwater Management and Ownership: Rejoinder’ in Economic and Political
Weekly 43 (17): 116-119.
――――. 2009. Taming the Anarchy: Groundwater Governance in South Asia. Resource for Future:
Washington DC and International Water Management Institute: Colombo, Sri Lanka.
Shah, Tushaar and S. Bhattacharya. 1993. Farmers Organizations for Lift Irrigation: Irrigation Companies
and Tubewell Cooperatives of Gujarat. Network Paper 26. London: Overseas Development Institute.
Shah, Tushaar, Sonal Bhatt, R.K. Shah and Jayesh Talati. 2008. ‘Groundwater Governance through
Electricity Supply Management: Assessing an Innovative Intervention in Gujarat, Western India’ in
Agricultural Water Management 95: 1233-1242.
Singh, K. K. and S. Satish. 1988. Public Tubewells in Uttar Pradesh: Performance and Management. Paper
Presented at Workshop on the Development and Management of Groundwater Resources in Eastern
Uttar Pradesh, Ghaziabad, India.
Singh, Satyajit. 1997. Taming the Waters: The Political Economy of Large Dams in India. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Spiertz, J.H.L. 2000. ‘Water Rights and legal Pluralism: Some Basics of Legal Anthropological Approach’ in
B.R. Bruns and R.S. Meinzen-Dick (eds) Negotiating Water Rights. Washington: International Food
Policy Research Institute, and New Delhi: Vistaar Publications.

22
Stone, Ian. 1984. Canal Irrigation in British India: Perspectives on Technological Change in a Peasant
Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Swain, Mamata and Deepak Kumar Das. 2008. ‘Participatory Irrigation Management in India:
Implementations and Gap’ in Journal of Developments in Sustainable Agriculture (3): 28-39.
Swallow, B., D. Garrity and M.van Noordwijk. 2001. ‘The Effects of Scales, Flows and Fliters on Property
Rights and Collective Action in Watershed Management’ in Water Policy 3 (6): 457-474.
Thakkar, H. 1998. The World Bank's - The Orissa Water Resources Consolidation Project: A Critique.
Bhubaneshwar: OXFAM.
Tiwari, R. 2007. From Persian Wheels to Submersible Pumps: Social Organization of Shared Groundwater
Irrigation in Punjab. Paper Presented at Annual Partners’ Meet of the IWMI-TATA Water Policy
Research Program, Anand Gujarat.
Vaidyanathan, A. 1996. ‘Depletion of Groundwater: Some Issues’ in Indian Journal of Agricultural
Economics 51(1&2): 184-192.
Vani, M.S. 1992. Role of Panchayat Raj Institutions in Irrigation Management: Law and Policy (Tamil
Nadu and Karnataka). New Delhi: Indian Law Institute.
――――. 2009. ‘Community Engagement in Water Governance’ in Ramaswamy R. Iyer (ed.) Water and
The Laws in India. New Delhi: Sage Publications, 167-212.
Von Benda-Beckman, F., Von. K Benda-Beckman and J.H.L. Spiertz. 1997. ‘Local Law and Customary
Practices in the Study of Water Rights’ in R. Pradhan, Von F. Benda-Beckman, Von K Benda-Beckman,
J.H.L. Spiertz, S.S. Khadka and A.K. Haq (eds) Water Rights, Conflicts and Policy. Sri Lanka:
International Water Management Institute.
Wade, Robert. 1982. ‘The System of Administration and Political Corruption: Canal Irrigation in South
India’ in Journal of Development Studies 18 (3): 287-328.
Whitcombe, Elizabeth. 1972. Agrarian Conditions in Northern India: The United Provinces under British
Rule, 1860-1900, Vol. I. Berkeley: University of California Press.
――――. 2005. ‘Irrigation’ in Dinesh Kumar and M. Desai (eds) The Cambridge Economic History of
India, 1757-1970, Volume 2. Hyderabad: Orient Longman, 677-737.
Willcocks, W. 1984. Ancient System of Irrigation in Bengal. Delhi: B.R. Publishing Corporation.
Wittfogel, Karl. 1957. Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
World Bank. 1990. Staff Appraisal Report, India: Integrated Watershed Development Project. Washington
D.C: World Bank.
――――. 1998. Inter-sectoral Water Allocation Planning and Management -Volume 1 India - Water
Resources Management Sector Review, Rural Development Unit, South Asia Region, World Bank and
Ministry of Water Resources, Government of India, New Delhi.
――――. 2007. Watershed Management Approaches, Principles and Operations: Lessons for Scaling-Up
(draft report). Washington D.C: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, World Bank.
Worster, Donald. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity and the Growth of the American West. New York:
Pantheon Books.

23
Irit Eguavoen
ZEF Development Studies The Political Ecology of Household Water in Northern
edited by Solvay Gerke and Hans-Dieter Evers Ghana
Vol. 10, 2008, 328 p., 34.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
Center for Development Research (ZEF), 8258-1613-1
University of Bonn
Charlotte van der Schaaf
Shahjahan H. Bhuiyan Institutional Change and Irrigation Management in
Benefits of Social Capital. Urban Solid Waste Burkina Faso. Flowing Structures and Concrete
Management in Bangladesh Struggles
Vol. 1, 2005, 288 p., 19.90 EUR, br. ISBN 3-8258- Vol. 11, 2009, 344 p., 34.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
8382-5 8258-1624-7
Veronika Fuest Nayeem Sultana
Demand-oriented Community Water Supply in Ghana. The Bangladeshi Diaspora in Peninsular Malaysia.
Policies, Practices and Outcomes Organizational Structure, Survival Strategies and
Vol. 2, 2006, 160 p., 19.90 EUR, br. ISBN 3-8258- Networks
9669-2 Vol. 12, 2009, 368 p., 34.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
Anna-Katharina Hornidge 8258-1629-2
Knowledge Society. Vision and Social Construction of Peter P. Mollinga, Anjali Bhat, Saravanan V.S. (Eds.)
Reality in Germany and Singapore When Policy Meets Reality. Political Dynamics and
Vol. 3, 2007, 200 p., 19.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3- the Practice of Integration in Water Resources
8258-0701-6 Management Reform
Wolfram Laube Vol. 13, 216 p., 29.90 EUR, br., ISBN 978-3-643-
Changing Natural Resource Regimes in Northern 10672-8
Ghana. Actors, Structures and Institutions Irit Eguavoen, Wolfram Laube (Eds.)
Vol. 4, 2007, 392 p., 34.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3- Negotiating Local Governance. Natural Resources
8258-0641-5 Management at the Interface of Communities and the
Lirong Liu State
Wirtschaftliche Freiheit und Wachstum. Eine Vol. 14, 248 S., 29.90 EUR, br., ISBN 978-3-643-
international vergleichende Studie 10673-5
Vol. 5, 2007, 200 p., 19.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3- William Tsuma
8258-0701-6 Gold Mining in Ghana. Actors, Alliances and Power
Phuc Xuan To Vol. 15, 256 S., 29.90 EUR, br., ISBN 978-3-643-
Forest Property in the Vietnamese Uplands. An 10811-1
Ethnography of Forest Relations in Three Dao Villages Thim Ly
Vol. 6, 2007, 296 p., 29.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3- Planning the Lower Mekong Basin: Social Intervention
8258-0773-3 in the Se San River
Caleb R.L. Wall, Peter P. Mollinga (Eds.) Vol. 16, forthcoming
Fieldwork in Difficult Environments. Methodology as
Boundary Work in Development Research
Vol. 7, 2008, 192 p., 19.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
8258-1383-3
Solvay Gerke, Hans-Dieter Evers, Anna-K. Hornidge
(Eds.)
The Straits of Malacca. Knowledge and Diversity
Vol. 8, 2008, 240 p., 29.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
8258-1383-3
Caleb Wall
Argorods of Western Uzbekistan. Knowledge Control
and Agriculture in Khorezm
Vol. 9, 2008, 384 p., 29.90 EUR, br. ISBN 978-3-
8258-1426-7
ZEF Working Paper Series, ISSN 1864-6638
Department of Political and Cultural Change
Center for Development Research, University of Bonn
Editors: H.-D. Evers, Solvay Gerke, Peter P. Mollinga, Conrad Schetter

Nr. 1 Evers, Hans-Dieter and Solvay Gerke (2005). Closing the Digital Divide: Southeast Asia’s Path Towards a
Knowledge Society.
Nr. 2 Bhuiyan, Shajahan and Hans-Dieter Evers (2005). Social Capital and Sustainable Development: Theories
and Concepts.
Nr. 3 Schetter, Conrad (2005). Ethnicity and the Political Reconstruction of Afghanistan.
Nr. 4 Kassahun, Samson (2005). Social Capital and Community Efficacy. In Poor Localities of Addis Ababa
Ethiopia.
Nr. 5 Fuest, Veronika (2005). Policies, Practices and Outcomes of Demand-oriented Community Water Supply in
Ghana: The National Community Water and Sanitation Programme 1994 – 2004.
Nr. 6 Menkhoff, Thomas and Hans-Dieter Evers (2005). Strategic Groups in a Knowledge Society: Knowledge
Elites as Drivers of Biotechnology Development in Singapore.
Nr. 7 Mollinga, Peter P. (2005). The Water Resources Policy Process in India: Centralisation, Polarisation and
New Demands on Governance.
Nr. 8 Evers, Hans-Dieter (2005). Wissen ist Macht: Experten als Strategische Gruppe.
Nr. 8a Evers, Hans-Dieter and Solvay Gerke (2005). Knowledge is Power: Experts as Strategic Group.
Nr. 9 Fuest, Veronika (2005). Partnerschaft, Patronage oder Paternalismus? Eine empirische Analyse der Praxis
universitärer Forschungskooperation mit Entwicklungsländern.
Nr. 10 Laube, Wolfram (2005). Promise and Perils of Water Reform: Perspectives from Northern Ghana.
Nr. 11 Mollinga, Peter P. (2004). Sleeping with the Enemy: Dichotomies and Polarisation in Indian Policy Debates
on the Environmental and Social Effects of Irrigation.
Nr. 12 Wall, Caleb (2006). Knowledge for Development: Local and External Knowledge in Development Research.
Nr. 13 Laube, Wolfram and Eva Youkhana (2006). Cultural, Socio-Economic and Political Con-straints for Virtual
Water Trade: Perspectives from the Volta Basin, West Africa.
Nr. 14 Hornidge, Anna-Katharina (2006). Singapore: The Knowledge-Hub in the Straits of Malacca.
Nr. 15 Evers, Hans-Dieter and Caleb Wall (2006). Knowledge Loss: Managing Local Knowledge in Rural
Uzbekistan.
Nr. 16 Youkhana, Eva, Lautze, J. and B. Barry (2006). Changing Interfaces in Volta Basin Water Management:
Customary, National and Transboundary.
Nr. 17 Evers, Hans-Dieter and Solvay Gerke (2006). The Strategic Importance of the Straits of Malacca for World
Trade and Regional Development.
Nr. 18 Hornidge, Anna-Katharina (2006). Defining Knowledge in Germany and Singapore: Do the Country-
Specific Definitions of Knowledge Converge?
Nr. 19 Mollinga, Peter M. (2007). Water Policy – Water Politics: Social Engineering and Strategic Action in Water
Sector Reform.
Nr. 20 Evers, Hans-Dieter and Anna-Katharina Hornidge (2007). Knowledge Hubs Along the Straits of Malacca.
Nr. 21 Sultana, Nayeem (2007). Trans-National Identities, Modes of Networking and Integration in a Multi-
Cultural Society. A Study of Migrant Bangladeshis in Peninsular Malaysia.
Nr. 22 Yalcin, Resul and Peter M. Mollinga (2007). Institutional Transformation in Uzbekistan’s Agricultural and
Water Resources Administration: The Creation of a New Bureaucracy.
Nr. 23 Menkhoff, T., Loh, P. H. M., Chua, S. B., Evers, H.-D. and Chay Yue Wah (2007). Riau Vegetables for
Singapore Consumers: A Collaborative Knowledge-Transfer Project Across the Straits of Malacca.
Nr. 24 Evers, Hans-Dieter and Solvay Gerke (2007). Social and Cultural Dimensions of Market Expansion.
Nr. 25 Obeng, G. Y., Evers, H.-D., Akuffo, F. O., Braimah, I. and A. Brew-Hammond (2007). Solar PV Rural
Electrification and Energy-Poverty Assessment in Ghana: A Principal Component Analysis.
Nr. 26 Eguavoen, Irit; E. Youkhana (2008). Small Towns Face Big Challenge. The Management of Piped Systems
after the Water Sector Reform in Ghana.
Nr. 27 Evers, Hans-Dieter (2008). Knowledge Hubs and Knowledge Clusters: Designing a Knowledge Architecture
for Development
Nr. 28 Ampomah, Ben Y., Adjei, B. and E. Youkhana (2008). The Transboundary Water Resources Management
Regime of the Volta Basin.
Nr. 29 Saravanan.V.S.; McDonald, Geoffrey T. and Peter P. Mollinga (2008). Critical Review of Integrated Water
Resources Management: Moving Beyond Polarised Discourse.
Nr. 30 Laube, Wolfram; Awo, Martha and Benjamin Schraven (2008). Erratic Rains and Erratic Markets:
Environmental change, economic globalisation and the expansion of shallow groundwater irrigation in
West Africa.
Nr. 31 Mollinga, Peter P. (2008). For a Political Sociology of Water Resources Management.
Nr. 32 Hauck, Jennifer; Youkhana, Eva (2008). Histories of water and fisheries management in Northern Ghana.
Nr. 33 Mollinga, Peter P. (2008). The Rational Organisation of Dissent. Boundary concepts, boundary objects and
boundary settings in the interdisciplinary study of natural resources management.
Nr. 34 Evers, Hans-Dieter; Gerke, Solvay (2009). Strategic Group Analysis.
Nr. 35 Evers, Hans-Dieter; Benedikter, Simon (2009). Strategic Group Formation in the Mekong Delta - The
Development of a Modern Hydraulic Society.
Nr. 36 Obeng, George Yaw; Evers, Hans-Dieter (2009). Solar PV Rural Electrification and Energy-Poverty: A
Review and Conceptual Framework With Reference to Ghana.
Nr. 37 Scholtes, Fabian (2009). Analysing and explaining power in a capability perspective.
Nr. 38 Eguavoen, Irit (2009). The Acquisition of Water Storage Facilities in the Abay River Basin, Ethiopia.
Nr. 39 Hornidge, Anna-Katharina; Mehmood Ul Hassan; Mollinga, Peter P. (2009). ‘Follow the Innovation’ – A
joint experimentation and learning approach to transdisciplinary innovation research.
Nr. 40 Scholtes, Fabian (2009). How does moral knowledge matter in development practice, and how can it be
researched?
Nr. 41 Laube, Wolfram (2009). Creative Bureaucracy: Balancing power in irrigation administration in northern
Ghana.
Nr. 42 Laube, Wolfram (2009). Changing the Course of History? Implementing water reforms in Ghana and South
Africa.
Nr. 43 Scholtes, Fabian (2009). Status quo and prospects of smallholders in the Brazilian sugarcane and ethanol
sector: Lessons for development and poverty reduction.
Nr. 44 Evers, Hans-Dieter, Genschick, Sven, Schraven, Benjamin (2009). Constructing Epistemic Landscapes:
Methods of GIS-Based Mapping.
Nr. 45 Saravanan V.S. (2009). Integration of Policies in Framing Water Management Problem: Analysing Policy
Processes using a Bayesian Network.
Nr. 46 Saravanan V.S. (2009). Dancing to the Tune of Democracy: Agents Negotiating Power to Decentralise
Water Management.
Nr. 47 Huu, Pham Cong, Rhlers, Eckart, Saravanan, V. Subramanian (2009). Dyke System Planing: Theory and
Practice in Can Tho City, Vietnam.
Nr. 48 Evers, Hans-Dieter, Bauer, Tatjana (2009). Emerging Epistemic Landscapes: Knowledge Clusters in Ho Chi
Minh City and the Mekong Delta.
Nr. 49 Reis, Nadine; Mollinga, Peter P. (2009). Microcredit for Rural Water Supply and Sanitation in the Mekong
Delta. Policy implementation between the needs for clean water and ‘beautiful latrines’.
Nr. 50 Gerke, Solvay; Ehlert, Judith (2009). Local Knowledge as Strategic Resource: Fishery in the Seasonal
Floodplains of the Mekong Delta, Vietnam
Nr. 51 Schraven, Benjamin; Eguavoen, Irit; Manske, Günther (2009). Doctoral degrees for capacity development:
Results from a survey among African BiGS-DR alumni.
Nr. 52 Nguyen, Loan (2010). Legal Framework of the Water Sector in Vietnam.
Nr. 53 Nguyen, Loan (2010). Problems of Law Enforcement in Vietnam. The Case of Wastewater Management in
Can Tho City.
Nr. 54 Oberkircher, Lisa et al. (2010). Rethinking Water Management in Khorezm, Uzbekistan. Concepts and
Recommendations.
Nr. 55 Waibel, Gabi (2010). State Management in Transition: Understanding Water Resources Management in
Vietnam.
Nr. 56 Saravanan V.S., Mollinga, Peter P. (2010). Water Pollution and Human Health. Transdisciplinary Research
on Risk Governance in a Complex Society.
Nr. 57 Vormoor, Klaus (2010). Water Engineering, Agricultural Development and Socio-Economic Trends in the
Mekong Delta, Vietnam.
Nr. 58 Hornidge, Anna-Katharina, Kurfürst, Sandra (2010). Envisioning the Future, Conceptualising Public Space.
Hanoi and Singapore Negotiating Spaces for Negotiation.
Nr. 59 Mollinga, Peter P. (2010). Transdisciplinary Method for Water Pollution and Human Health Research.
Nr. 60 Youkhana, Eva (2010). Gender and the development of handicraft production in rural Yucatán/Mexico.
Nr. 61 Naz, Farhat, Saravanan V. Subramanian (2010). Water Management across Space and Time in India.

You might also like