The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics: Topics
The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics: Topics
The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics: Topics
Journal of Macroeconomics
Topics
Volume 9, Issue 1 2009 Article 16
∗
Ibmec Rio de Janeiro, [email protected]
Recommended Citation
Marcelo Mello (2009) “Estimates of the Marginal Product of Capital, 1970-2000,” The B.E. Jour-
nal of Macroeconomics: Vol. 9: Iss. 1 (Topics), Article 16.
Abstract
We compute the marginal product of capital (MPK) taking into account cross-country dif-
ferences in the relative price of capital in a large panel including 95 countries over the period
1970-2000. Estimates of the price-uncorrected MPK suggest that the marginal product of cap-
ital is much larger in poor countries than in rich countries throughout the entire sample period.
However, estimates of the price-corrected MPK suggest that differences in the marginal product
of capital between rich and poor countries were significant in the 1970’s, decreased substantially
in the 1980’s, and were negligible in the 1990’s. In fact, the correlation between price-corrected
MPK and GDP per worker is close to zero for most of the 1990’s. Furthermore, we find that in
both rich and poor countries the capital-output ratio is increasing over time, and while the relative
price of capital is slightly decreasing in rich countries it is strongly increasing in poor countries.
Counterfactual reallocations of capital that equalize its rate of return around the world would have
yielded significant output gains in poor countries in the 1970’s, but gains in the 1990’s would have
been negligible. These findings are robust to alternative rich/poor cut-offs. Our results suggest
that international capital markets are largely integrated since the early 1990’s.
∗
Department of Economics, Ibmec/RJ, Av. Presidente Wilson 118/1101, 20030-020, Rio
de Janeiro, RJ, Brazil; phone: (55-21)-4503-4161; fax: (55-21)-4503-4168; e-mail:
[email protected]. I thank seminar participants at the 76th meeting of the Southern Economic
Association in Charleston, South Carolina, and the 63rd, European meeting of the Econometric
Society in Milan, Italy. I would like to thank the editor, Peter Ireland, for encouragement, and two
anonymous referees who provided excellent comments, which led to substantial improvements in
the paper. I would also like to thank Miguel Lebre de Freitas, Marcelo Rezende, Louis Pavia,
and Fernando Veloso for carefully reading the paper and making many useful suggestions. All
remaining errors are mine.
1. Introduction
In the neoclassical growth model with constant returns to scale and perfect
competition, the marginal product of capital (MPK) is computed as
/ , where α is the share of (reproducible) capital in total output, Y is output,
and K is physical capital. If the price of capital differs from the price of output,
then the expression for the MPK should be corrected for differences in the relative
price of capital. More precisely, the expression for the marginal product of capital
is given by / , where PMPK denotes the price-corrected
MPK, / is the inverse of the relative price of capital, and / is the inverse
of the capital-output ratio.
Caselli and Feyrer (2007), henceforth CF, compute the marginal product
of capital with corrections for cross-country differences in the relative price of
capital and the reproducible capital share. Their results suggest that the marginal
product of capital is largely equalized across countries. This finding is important
because it helps explain some fundamental issues. Notably, it addresses why
capital does not flow from rich to poor countries, a question posed by Lucas
(1990).
CF compute the MPK for a single cross-section of 53 countries from the
Penn World Tables (PWT) dataset. As mentioned above, their measure of the
MPK is corrected for cross-country differences in the relative price of capital and
the share of reproducible capital in total output. They observe that the concept of
capital in growth models refers to reproducible capital, not total capital. However,
available measures in the data refer to total capital, which includes reproducible
capital and natural capital. Natural capital includes inputs such as land and natural
resources, which are more abundant in poor countries. Since poor countries tend
have a larger share of wealth in the form of natural capital, the use of total capital
income as a measure of the capital share overestimates poor countries’ MPK.
CF face two constraints on their dataset. First, to generate estimates of the
reproducible capital share they use data from Bernanke and Gurkaynak (2001),
which is only available for 53 countries. Second, in order to construct a measure
for the reproducible capital share, they use a new dataset from the World Bank
which contains estimates of the components of wealth, including natural capital,
which is available for only one year.1
In this article, we construct a large panel including 95 countries with data
from the PWT 6.1 dataset over the period 1970-2000. We then compute the MPK
using its traditional one-sector formula, and its price-corrected version, i.e.,
corrected for differences in the relative price of capital. Instead of relying on a
1
The data on the components of wealth is taken from the World Bank publication “Where is The
Wealth of Nations?”, released in 2006.
single cross-section, the time series dimension and the broader set of countries
afforded by the panel allows us to examine the dynamics of the marginal product
of capital, the capital-output ratio, and the relative price of capital.
Our main findings are the following: First, over the period 1970-2000, we
find large differences in price-uncorrected MPK across countries. Second, we find
that these differences are substantially reduced once we take into account cross-
country changes in the relative price of capital. In particular, differences in price-
corrected MPK between rich and poor countries were relatively large in the 1970s
however they were negligible in the 1990s. Third, we find that the capital-output
ratio is increasing over time in both rich and poor countries. Fourth, over the
period 1970-2000, the relative price of capital decreases slightly in rich countries,
and it increases strongly in poor countries. Fifth, these findings are robust to
alternative rich/poor cut-offs.2
More specifically, our estimates suggest that the average MPK in poor
countries in the 1970s was 30.4%, while in rich countries it was 13.0%. Over the
1980s and the 1990s, MPK estimates were relatively stable across countries,
being, on average, 12% in rich countries and 24% in poor countries. Furthermore,
we find large differences between rich and poor countries’ price corrected MPK
during the initial years of the sample period. However, these differences decrease
over time, and disappear at the end of the sample period. The average price-
corrected MPK in poor countries in the 1970s was 18.9%, against 13.4% in rich
countries. In the 1980s and the 1990s, the average price-corrected MPK in poor
countries was 14.1% and 12.3%, respectively, against 12.3% and 12.2% in rich
countries, respectively.
The average capital-output ratio increases in both rich and poor countries
over the period 1970-2000. In 1970, the average capital-output ratio in poor
countries was 0.90. It grew at an average rate of approximately one percent per
year, reaching 1.23 in 2000. In rich countries, the initial average capital-output
ratio is 2.11, and it grew at an average rate of three-quarters of one percent per
year, reaching 2.66 in 2000. In addition, the relative price of capital is strongly
increasing in poor countries, with an average growth rate of 0.95% per year, while
it decreases slightly in rich countries, with an average negative growth rate of
0.15% per year.
In poor countries, the combination of an increasing capital-output ratio and
a strongly increasing relative price of capital implies that the ratio / is
decreasing over time. In rich countries / also decreases over time,
however at a much slower rate given the slow growth in the capital-output ratio,
and the smooth path of the relative price of capital. The dynamics of the capital-
2
In section 2, we discuss the criteria to determine the rich/poor cut-off.
output ratio and the relative price of capital explain much of the convergence in
price-corrected MPK across countries.3
Following the methodology in CF, we compute the world price-corrected
MPK, that is, the marginal product of capital that would emerge in a world
characterized by frictionless international capital markets. We then calculate
output gains/losses associated with counterfactual reallocations of capital so as to
obtain MPK equalization across countries.
We find that the gain in world GDP from the equalization of price-
corrected MPK is small, about 0.5% in 2000. Furthermore, the equalization of the
PMPK would have yielded substantial GDP gains in poor countries in the 1970s,
on average, GDP would have increased by 6.1%. However, GDP gains in the
1980s and the 1990s would have been quite small; on average GDP would have
increased by 1.4% and 0.3%, respectively.
Our article is closely related to the literature that highlights the role of the
relative price of capital in the development process. It is particularly related to
Hsieh and Klenow (2007), who show that cross-country differences in the relative
price of capital are the key driving force behind a well-known stylized fact in
growth, namely, the positive correlation between real investment rates and real
income levels across countries. In fact, CF extends the work of Hsieh and Klenow
(2007) by looking at implications of their findings for rates of return on physical
capital across countries.
This article is structured as follows. In section 2, we describe the
construction of the panel. In section 3, we present individual estimates of the
PMPK and its components. In section 4, we present panel estimates of the MPK
and its price-corrected version in both rich and poor countries over the period
1970-2000. In section 5, we present estimates of the gains from MPK and PMPK
equalization. Section 6 presents estimates of the MPK and the PMPK from
alternative panels with different rich/poor cut-offs as a robustness check. Section
7 concludes.
2. The Data
Our benchmark panel contains data on 95 countries over the period 1970-2000
from the PWT dataset version 6.1. We call this panel PWT61_1970. Using their
PWT codes, the input variables are the following: (population),
(real GDP per worker), (real GDP per capita: chain series),
3
Since a time series for the reproducible capital share is not available we have to be silent with
respect to its role in the convergence in PMPKs across countries.
4
The reader is referred to Heston et al. (2004) for details on the definition of these variables. All
our data is available upon request.
5
Ferreira et al. (2008) also construct estimates of the capital stock using the perpetual inventory
method over the period 1970-2000. They perform a number of robustness exercises to check
whether their capital stock estimates are contaminated by a bad initial guess. They find no
evidence that the initial guess compromises estimates of the capital stock series.
6
To be precise, instead of rich vs. poor CF classify countries as either developed (up from
Portugal) or developing (up to Malaysia).
and poor in CF’s sample is the median, which tends to over-represent rich
countries. In section 6, we discuss alternative rich/poor cut-offs.
We assume a constant capital share in order to calculate the MPK and its
price-corrected version throughout the entire panel. We assume α=0.30 in all
countries at all time periods. We justify the assumption of a constant capital share
as follows. First, the benchmark steady-state value of the capital share used in the
literature is α=0.30. Second, the evidence in Gollin (2002) suggests that total
labor share is constant across time and space. Therefore, by residual, we deduce
that the total capital share is constant across time and space. Third, what matters is
whether or not the reproducible capital share is systematically related to GDP per
worker. The correlation between GDP per worker and reproducible capital share
in CF’s sample is 0.35, which is quite low.7 Hence, any bias resulting from
assuming a constant alpha should not be large. Fourth, by assuming a constant
alpha we are able to isolate the effects of two key macroeconomic variables,
namely, the relative price of capital and the capital-output ratio, on the dynamics
of the marginal product of capital.
If indeed poor countries have a smaller share of reproducible capital, then,
as mentioned above, our calculations will overestimate poor countries’ MPK. In
fact, in CF’s sample, the average total capital share in rich countries is 0.305, and
in poor countries is 0.382, while the average reproducible capital share in rich
countries is 0.206, and in poor countries is 0.168. Thus, correcting for the
reproducible capital share reduces MPK estimates in both rich and poor countries.
However, on average, the reduction in poor countries is much larger than the
reduction in rich countries. That is, the MPK in poor countries is overestimated if
computed with the total capital share instead of the reproducible capital share.
3. Individual Estimates
We first present individual estimates of the price-corrected MPK and its
components for selected countries. Presenting individual estimates can serve as a
simple robustness check, because if we observe any unusual pattern, we have
reason to be suspicious. We select four countries classified as rich (U.S.,
Switzerland, Japan, and U.K.), and four countries classified as poor (Mexico,
Brazil, India, and Turkey).8 Figures 1 and 2 display, respectively, the PMPK in
the four rich countries, and in the four poor countries.
7
Table 1 in CF suggests that the correlation between reproducible capital and GDP per worker is
0.70. However, as pointed out by CF, this correlation was computed using data from the World
Bank (2006), and it differs from the correlation between the reproducible capital share and GDP
per worker computed from the data they present in the appendix, which equals 0.35.
8
More precisely, these countries are classified as either rich or poor for most of the 1980s and the
1990s, but not throughout the entire sample period.
20.0%
18.0%
16.0%
14.0%
12.0%
10.0%
8.0%
6.0%
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
US Switzerland Japan UK
35.0%
32.0%
29.0%
26.0%
23.0%
20.0%
17.0%
14.0%
11.0%
8.0%
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
Over the period 1970-2000, the PMPK decreases in both set of countries.
The decrease in rich countries is smooth, while in poor countries it exhibits
9
Although we do not attempt to do this here, it would be interesting to relate the marginal product
of capital with measures of the financial return to capital. Furthermore, it would also be interesting
to relate PMPK differentials with measures of bilateral financial integration. Perhaps, a starting
point in this direction could be the literature on empirical international finance such as Lane and
Milesi-Ferretti (2004), and Portes and Hey (2005).
10
We compute geometric averages.
10
14.2% in 1970 to approximately 11% in 2000, while in poor countries it falls from
33.5% in 1970 to approximately 24% in 2000.11
11
The literature on dynamic Hecksher-Olin models suggests that large cross-country income
differences can be consistent with small interest rate differentials. In this sense, our MPK
differentials might be seen as upper bounds. See Cuñat and Maffezzoli (2004) for details.
11
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
12
One may ask whether the increase in the capital-output ratio comes from an increase in the
saving rate. However, data from the PWT 6.1 suggest that the saving rate in both rich and poor
countries is stable over the period 1970-2000.
12
Figure 4 displays the average relative price of capital in both rich and poor
countries over the period 1970-2000. It increases by 34% over the period 1970-
2000 in poor countries, while it decreases by 4.5% in rich countries.13
The evidence presented above allows us to examine the role of the relative
price of capital and the capital-output ratio in promoting convergence in PMPKs.
In both rich and poor countries the ratio / decreases over time, however it
decreases much faster in poor countries. In rich countries, the capital-output ratio
increases and the relative price of capital decreases slightly. The increase in the
capital-output ratio more than offsets the decrease in the relative price of capital,
so that the ratio / decreases over time. In poor countries, the capital-
output ratio increases by 38% over the period 1970-2000, and the relative price of
capital increases by 34%, which causes a huge decrease in the / ratio.
2.1
1.9
1.7
1.5
1.3
1.1
0.9
0.7
0.5
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
13
This by itself is an interesting fact which warrants further investigation. This is, in fact, a
research project companion to the present article.
13
correlation between GDP per worker and capital-output ratio became stronger
over time. It increased from an average of 0.64 in the 1970s, to 0.70 in the 1980s
and the 1990s.
This finding, namely, the convergence in PMPKs across countries,
suggests that capital transfers across countries could have had a strong impact on
poor countries’ GDP in the 1970s and maybe in the 1980s, but were doomed to
have little economic impact in the 1990s. In the next section, we provide estimates
of the potential gains from counterfactual reallocations of capital, which confirms
this intuition.
j=1, 2, …, J (1)
Consider a situation in which capital was reallocated across countries such that
the PMPK is constant and equal to PMPK*.14 Therefore, the new value of capital
must satisfy
(2)
14
We follow CF and assume that labor is unchanged in the reallocation process.
14
Combining equations (1) and (2), we obtain an expression for the counterfactual
stock of capital in sector in country .
(3)
∑ (4)
∑ /
∑
(5)
Given the PMPK*, we obtain the counterfactual capital stock in country i from
equation (4). With the counterfactual capital stock in hands, we obtain the
counterfactual level of output in country . Further manipulation shows that the
counterfactual level of output in sector in country is given by
(6)
(7)
15
Because CF have country-specific alphas, they obtain a slightly more complicated expression.
They have to recur to a numerical procedure to obtain the PMPK*. In our case, since alpha is the
same for all countries, we can solve directly for the PMPK*.
15
∑
∑ 1 (8)
Figure 5 displays the counter-factual equalized MPK and PMPK over the
period 1970-2000. The MPK* and the PMPK* decline smoothly throughout the
entire sample period, reflecting the strong capital deepening process documented
in section 4. The MPK* and the PMPK* reach, respectively, 13.9% and 12.8% in
2000.
Figure 6 displays the gain in world GDP from the equalization of MPK
and PMPK. The gain in world GDP from the equalization of the MPK is between
2.5% and 3% per year. Gains in world GDP from the equalization of the PMPK
are smaller. On average, they would have been 1.38% in the 1970s, 0.72% in the
1980s, and 0.61% in the 1990s.
19%
18%
17%
16%
15%
14%
13%
12%
11%
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
MPK* PMPK*
16
4%
3%
3%
2%
2%
1%
1%
0%
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
% Gain - MPK % Gain - PMPK
17
12%
10%
8%
6%
4%
2%
0%
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
-2%
-4%
Rich Poor
Figure 7: % GDP gain in Rich and Poor countries from PMPK equalization
6. Robustness Checks
In this section, we perform a series of robustness checks. First, we look at MPK
and PMPK estimates for the year 1996 and compare them with those in CF.
Second, we construct a panel with 49 countries from CF’s sample, and compute
the MPK and the PMPK over the period 1970-2000 using country-specific but
time-fixed estimates of the capital share from Bernanke and Gurkaynak (2001),
and CF’s estimates of the reproducible capital share. Third, we check whether
alternative rich/poor cut-offs alter our findings. For instance, we look at panels in
which countries can be classified as rich, middle-income, or poor, and panels in
which countries are divided into OECD and non-OECD, as alternatives to the
rich/poor classification of section 4. As it is shown below, none of our
conclusions are altered with these alternative rich/poor cut-offs.
Table 5 compares our estimates from section 4 for 1996 with those from
CF. Column (1) reproduces estimates of the PMPK and the PMPK-k from CF,
where PMPK-k denotes the PMPK corrected for the reproducible capital share.
Columns (2) and (3) display PMPK estimates imposing α=0.30 and α=0.185 to
the 53 countries in CF’s sample, respectively.16 Column (4) displays PMPK
estimates from our benchmark panel in section 4. Column (5) displays estimates
from our base panel imposing α=0.185.
16
Recall that 0.185 is the average value of the reproducible capital share in CF’ sample.
18
First, estimates in columns (2) and (4) in which we impose α=0.30 to both
samples, and in columns (3) and (5) in which we impose α=0.185 to both samples
are close, which suggests that correcting for cross-country differences in the
relative price of capital goes much of the way towards PMPK equalization
between rich and poor countries.17 Comparing PMPK estimates in columns (3)
and (5), we observe that our estimate of the PMPK in rich countries is 7.8%,
against 7.7% in CF’s sample, and that our estimate of the PMPK in poor countries
is 7.9% against 7.6% in CF’s sample.
Second, in CF’s sample, correcting the marginal product of capital for
cross-country differences in relative price of capital is not enough to generate
equalization in PMPKs, as can be seen in column (1). Their estimate of the PMPK
in rich countries is 12.6%, against 15.7% in poor countries. Similarly, when CF
corrects for the reproducible capital share only (not shown on table 5), their
estimate of the PMPK in rich countries is 7.5%, against 11.9% in poor countries.
Ultimately, in the case of CF, the correction for both the reproducible capital
share and the relative price of capital is necessary to obtain equalization in MPKs.
Table 5: Comparative Estimates of the MPK and PMPK for the year 1996
CF’s CF’s CF’s PWT_61 PWT_61
estimates sample sample α=0.30 α=0.185
(n=53) α=0.30 α=0.185 (n=95) (n=95)
(n=53) (n=53)
Col. (1) Col. (2) Col. (3) Col. (4) Col. (5)
PMPK
Rich 12.6% 12.4% -- 12.6% --
Poor 15.7% 12.4% -- 12.8% --
PMPK-k
Rich 8.4% -- 7.7% -- 7.8%
Poor 6.9% -- 7.6% -- 7.9%
Note: Estimates in column 1 are taken from CF. Estimates in column 2 are generated using CF’s
sample, and imposing α=0.30 to all countries. Estimates in column 3 are generated using CF’s
sample, and using the average reproducible capital share, α=0.185, from CF. Estimates in column
4 are taken from Panel PWT_61_1970, constructed by the author. Estimates in column (5) are
generated from our panel PWT61_1970, imposing α=0.185 as the capital share.
17
As mentioned above, in CF’s sample the correlation between reproducible capital share and
GDP per worker is 0.35. On the other hand, the correlation between the relative price of capital
and GDP per worker in their sample is -0.70, and the correlation between GDP per worker and the
capital-output ratio is 0.74. This suggests that the relative price of capital and the capital-output
ratio play a much bigger role in equalizing the marginal product of capital than the reproducible
capital share.
19
18
We initially started with the 53 countries from CF’s sample. However, CF has no data on
reproducible capital share for Hong Kong, and we could not obtain a complete set of data for
Algeria, Mauritius, and Singapore. Therefore, we also excluded these countries and end up with 49
countries.
20
21
25%
23%
21%
19%
17%
15%
13%
11%
9%
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1995
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
22
2.5
1.5
0.5
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1995
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
K/Y - Rich K/Y - Middle-Income K/Y - Poor
23
2.5
2.3
2.1
1.9
1.7
1.5
1.3
1.1
0.9
0.7
0.5
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1995
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Pk/Py - Rich Pk/Py - Middle-Income Pk/Py - Poor
Figure 10: The relative price of capital in Rich, Middle-Income, and Poor
countries
In the second panel we consider, we divide the panel into OECD and Non-
OECD countries. We use the same set of OECD countries as did Mankiw et al.
(1992). Therefore, our OECD sample consists of the following 21 countries: U.S.,
Canada, U.K., Ireland, Portugal, Spain, France, Belgium, Netherlands, Italy,
Austria, Switzerland, Denmark, Sweden, Norway, Finland, Greece, Turkey,
Japan, Australia, and New Zealand.19
Figure 11 displays estimates of the PMPK in OECD and non-OECD
panel. According to Figure 11, the PMPK in OECD and non-OECD countries
exhibit the same convergence pattern observed previously. In particular, there
were large differences in PMPK in the 1970s until the mid 1980s. However,
already in the second half of the 1980s, we observe converge in the PMPKs across
OECD and non-OECD countries.
Figures 12 and 13 display the evolution of the capital-output ratio, and the
relative price of capital, respectively, over the period 1970-2000. The capital-
output ratio increases by 26% in OECD countries and by 39% in non-OECD
19
Mankiw et al. (1992) also include Germany in their OECD sample. However, we do not have
data on GDP per worker for Germany before 1990, and therefore had to exclude Germany from
the OECD list. Since we also exclude Luxemburg (because Mankiw et al. , 1992, also did), we end
up with 93 countries in this panel.
24
24%
22%
20%
18%
16%
14%
12%
10%
2.1
1.9
1.7
1.5
1.3
1.1
0.9
0.7
0.5
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Figure 12: The relative price of capital in OECD and non-OECD countries
25
2.5
1.5
0.5
7. Conclusion
We compute the MPK and the price-corrected MPK in a panel of 95 countries
over the period 1970-2000. We also calculate the MPK and its price-corrected
version under frictionless international capital markets. We then compute the
welfare gains associated with failure to attain MPK equalization.
26
References
Caselli, F., and J. Feyrer, (2007) “The Marginal Product of Capital”, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 122(2): 535-568.
Gollin, D., (2002) “Getting Income Shares Right”, Journal of Political Economy,
110 (2): 458-474.
27
Heston, A., R. Summers, and B. Aten, (2004) Penn World Table Version 6.1,
Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania
(CICUP).
Hsieh, C., and P. Klenow, (2007) “Relative Prices and Relative Prosperity”,
American Economic Review, 97(2): 562-585.
Hsieh, C., C. Bai, and Y. Qian, (2006) “The Return to Capital in China”,
Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 61-101.
Lucas, R. E., (1990) “Why doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?”,
American Economic Review, 80(2): 92-96.
Portes, R., and H. Rey, (2005) “The Determinants of Cross Border Equity Flows”,
Journal of International Economics, 65(2): 269-296.
World Bank, (2006), “Where is The Wealth of Nations?”, The World Bank.
28