Exaptation Dynamics and Entrepreneurial Performance: Evidence From The Internet Video Industry
Exaptation Dynamics and Entrepreneurial Performance: Evidence From The Internet Video Industry
Exaptation Dynamics and Entrepreneurial Performance: Evidence From The Internet Video Industry
1, 181–198
doi: 10.1093/icc/dtv052
Original Article
Abstract
This paper explores entrepreneurial strategy by analyzing the Internet video industry. Data on en-
trants to the Chinese Internet video industry from 2006 to 2011 reveal how those that adapt to shifts in
the environment outperform less flexible firms. The paper also shows how exaptive processes,
including strategic commitment to user communities, increase resilience in start-ups that face such
shifts. These findings introduce an expanded view of entrepreneurial strategy by directly linking stra-
tegic choice to venture performance and clarifying the role of exaptation in entrepreneurship.
JEL classification: L26, L82, O31
1. Introduction
In December 2006, YouKu.com officially went live. Together with similar firms, YouKu started as a clone of
YouTube.com and sought to exploit China’s exclusion of YouTube (and other foreign Internet video firms). These
clones shared a common technological base, so they competed by offering different business features toward the end
of becoming the dominant Internet video-sharing firm in China. YouKu began as a pure user-generated content
(UGC) firm whose sole offering was content uploaded by Chinese Internet users, and it enjoyed quick success as the
overall Internet video market in China grew rapidly. However, the UGC business model was severely challenged fol-
lowing regulatory changes mandated by the Chinese government in 2008. YouKu, like many other firms in the indus-
try, was forced to change. Yet unlike many of its peers, YouKu decided to retain the UGC part of its operations even
as it switched to offer professionally produced content (PPC)—that is, content licensed from traditional media produ-
cers such as TV and movie studios—as its main offering. From this petri dish of entrepreneurial competition, YouKu
and a handful of other firms eventually emerged as winners. On 10 December 2010, YouKu.com was listed on the
New York Stock Exchange; it was the world’s first Internet video-sharing company with a successful initial public
offering of stock (Hille, 2012).
YouKu’s story is hardly unique; after all, the business world is replete with examples of firms that succeeded only
after a series of adaptations. Conventional wisdom presumes that the emergence of a competitive advantage requires
parallel developments of new and purposefully developed sets of capabilities or innovations that are tailored to a
changing environment. Yet anecdotal evidence suggests that adaptation is not always purposeful and that ex post
successful features are often alternate uses of original functions. This process is known as exaptation, a concept
C The Author(s) 2016. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of Associazione ICC.
V
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/),
which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
182 K. Ching
borrowed from evolutionary biology. Exaptive features are typically produced by natural selection for a function
other than the one it currently performs, which is then co-opted by the new function. In the management literature,
the same term often refers to the exploitation of an existing body of knowledge so as to a gain a competitive advan-
tage in an emerging industry (Mokyr, 2000; Dew et al., 2004; Cattani, 2005, 2006).
Building on this body of knowledge and extending it to the nascent literature on entrepreneurial strategy, our
study documents how the most successful entrants in China’s Internet video industry emerged. Despite an exogenous
regulatory change that ran counter to the original business model of some firms, their retention of key features in the
model gave them performance benefits when they pivoted to a new business model. Our proposed explanation is con-
firmed by regressions in which entrants are matched by entry timing, ownership, and performance characteristics be-
The literature just cited has increased awareness of the role played by change in the development of firm strategy.
However, the distinction between conscious adaptation and exaptation has been largely overlooked. One reason for
this oversight is the predominance of neo-Darwinian perspectives in management thinking, which has focused on the
development of new strategic functions to improve environmental fitness—a process that depends on the proactive
aspect of adaptation (O’Reilly and Tushman, 2008; Thompson, 2011). The literature on exaptive processes is much
smaller but has become increasingly influential. One line of inquiry in the innovation literature focuses on the inter-
action between exaptive and adaptive processes. Bonifati (2013) argues that exaptation may lead to “degeneracy,” a
property whereby structurally different elements provide overlapping functionalities and thus (as with adaptive proc-
esses) result in firms developing new functionalities. This theme is repeated in Lane (2011), who develops an
well-identified. In the next section, we describe our approach to assembling a data set in which the consequences of
both adaptive and exaptive processes can be reliably assessed.
1 China’s Internet censorship policy is extensive and spans a wide variety of laws and administrative regulations.
Scholars have estimated that at least 18,000 Web sites are blocked from within mainland China and the number is al-
ways growing (Edelman and Zittrain, 2005). The government of the People’s Republic of China (PRC) defends this censor-
ing by claiming that, within its own borders, the country has the right to govern the Internet according to its own rules.
(Bristow, 2010).
2 See, for example, “Chinese Borrowing,” The Economist, 7 May 2009.
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 185
3 In this paper, “UGC” and “PPC” are used with reference both to the business model and to the type of content; clarifica-
tion will be provided where confusion might otherwise ensue.
186 K. Ching
content providers (e.g., television and movie studios). In the United States, YouTube is the original UGC firm and
Hulu exemplifies the PPC model.
Although many Chinese sites began as pure clones of YouTube and thus offered only UGC, competing sites that
focused on offering PPC emerged rapidly. Field interviews attest to the dichotomous nature of these two forms of
content and to how they remain the dominant business models competing in this industry. A co-founder of a success-
ful video site described their differences as follows:
UGC and PPC are the two distinct forms of content . . . UGC is content sourced from users while PPC is content pushed to
users. YouTube popularized UGC but PPC had rapidly emerged as another form . . . The state stations had been putting con-
Although the UGC and PPC business models are based on the same technological platform,4 they represent two
distinct modes of firm operation. In particular, maintaining a UGC site requires development of the specific capabil-
ities required to support a viable user community. Thus, UGC Web sites must develop infrastructure to enable the up-
loading and publishing of content by users while also providing incentives to encourage production and contribution
of that content (Milliken and O’Donnell, 2008). In addition, UGC Web sites must curate the content in an arrange-
ment that lends itself to effective marketing; hence such sites must develop the ability to interpret uploaded content
so that it can be properly classified at the outset (Villi et al., 2012).
These infrastructural capabilities—namely, supporting a user base and curating the content—demand significant
investment by the firm, in terms of both financing and time, if its UGC operation is to remain viable (Bharadwaj et
al., 2013). An executive at a PPC site added this perspective:
UGC is a problematic area that we did not want to pursue . . . it is not enough to just host any material, so you need to de-
velop ability to understand the content . . . [PPC] is simpler and more focused.
So in contrast to UGC sites, PPC sites operated on the relatively simple basis of paying original providers for con-
tent and then streaming it. Little or no investment is required to develop a user base, nor is any investment needed for
content analysis or curation. Instead, PPC sites simply relay television or movie content that has been previously
broadcast. In short, UGC and PPC sites rely on completely different sets of capabilities to support their business mod-
els. Prior research on the economics of Internet-based entertainment services point to similar dynamics (Sherman and
Waterman, 2014).
4 Both business models in that period utilized the same Adobe Flash technological platform. Alternative technological
platforms have emerged since the period that we analyze, in particular the growth of HTML5 (and, to a much lesser de-
gree, of QuickTime).
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 187
often to how the 2008 regulatory changes affected the industry and forced them to adapt—and also to how sudden
and unanticipated the change was. As recalled by the co-founder of a previously pure-UGC site:
The 2008 regulations really changed the market . . . it isn’t so much that we were hosting illegal content . . . but the threat is
scary. We hear tales of competitor sites being pulled off-line for hosting undesirable content . . . it really forced us to start
thinking about alternative business models.
Figure 1 shows the distribution of sites in terms of the two models—UGC and PPC—from 2006 to 2011. Time is
represented in units that indicate the number of quarters from the firm’s earliest entry in the data set. For instance,
70% 90
80
60%
70
50%
60
40% 50
30% 40
30
20%
20
10%
10
0% 0
Figure 1. Chinese Internet video firms: Strategy density (percentage using a particular business model)—and patterns of entry and
exit—during 19 consecutive quarters beginning July 2006.
188 K. Ching
change, YouKu was paying well over US$50 million a year in licensing fees to secure PPC content from movie studios
and TV stations (Montlake, 2012). Furthermore, much of this content could not be purchased on an exclusive basis,
unless fees were increased dramatically. This led to sites being distinctly undifferentiated, as they offer highly similar
content from site to site (Epstein, 2010). Together with Chinese audiences’ unwillingness to pay for content, the
video firms were in a bind as to figuring out ways to alleviate competitive pressure while staving off depleting cash.
It became clear that firms needed to find a way to beat back the pressure while distinguishing themselves from the
pack. Around 2009, certain firms started transitioning from being pure repositories of licensed video content to pro-
ducing the content.5 While they continued to license popular content from studios, they started investing in produc-
tion capabilities and sponsoring artistes to develop content that they owned exclusive license to. This was done for
We suddenly found ourselves with access to users who may have ability to create content, many [of whom] are part of the
artistic young . . . we started engaging them to help us produce professional content that we can license.
Nevertheless, venturing into the world of content production also carries with it significant risk, as the content
needs to conform to SARFT rulings and regulations. 6 UGC sites, however, should have had significance experience
(and expertise) in dealing with SARFT. The potential availability of users as content creators and the experience of
dealing with censors could serve as accidental yet unforeseen assets to enhance delivery of their new business model
as producers of content. These potential capabilities and complementary assets, which derive from supporting and
engaging users, lead one to hypothesize that entrants who successfully transitioned from a UGC to a PPC model will
outperform those that offered only PPC—and so neither invested in users nor benefited from their value as assets.
In summary, the exaptive process of repurposing assets (here, connections with users) for a new scenario (here,
offering SCC) may explain the superior performance of initially UGC firms as they pivot to offering PPC.
5.1 Variables
For our main explanatory variables, we coded the content offered by each firm. The content type we coded corres-
ponded to what was offered in the quarter for which that type was observed in the cached Web page. Thus, quarter
by quarter, firms offering content sourced exclusively from users (YouTube’s original model) were coded as “UGC,”
5 Similar dynamics have also been observed in the US market. YouTube runs a fairly similar program called YouTube
Partners, where they sponsor selected YouTube users to produce content that they own copyrights to. Other examples
include Netflix and Amazon (Prime), which all produce content now after previously existing as mere replay sites.
6 There are numerous anecdotes on self-produced content running afoul of the regulators. For example, the short TV
drama Love Finally produced by Ku6.com was reportedly cited by the authorities for portrayal of adult sexuality while
being self-classified as a “youth drama”.
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 189
whereas firms offering content licensed from TV studios and other professional content providers (Hulu’s original
model) were coded as “PPC”.7
When analyzing firm performance, we examined both interim performance and firm survival. For our firm sur-
vival analysis, the primary outcome variable was coded from measures of failure. Going off-line for six or more con-
secutive months was coded as a Fail (i.e., not surviving). Web sites that came back online after an extended period of
dormancy were few in number: among all sites that went off-line for at least six months, less than 15% were eventu-
ally restored. Our results are robust to the exclusion of these sites.
For our analysis of the interim performance of Internet-based start-ups, traditional financial measures (profitability,
liquidity, cash flow, net worth, etc.) are usually not available. So instead of using a more typical measure of financial
We repeat the same analysis for our interim performance measures. Because we use firm-level fixed effects in our spe-
cifications, time-invariant factors such as UGC_initiallyi are absorbed. Formally, we specify:
Yet the choice of a business model, like any strategic decision, is generally endogenous; that characteristic makes
it difficult to establish the direction of causality between performance and strategic choices. Although the dramatic
shift in regulatory environment lends more confidence than usual to the supposition that strategic choices affect per-
formance (and not vice versa), there remain justifiable concerns about the possibility of significant imbalances among
the different groups of firms. To allay these concerns, we performed a “coarsened exact match” (CEM) procedure
(Iacus et al., 2012) to identify a control for each “treated” firm. In our setup, the treatment group consists of sites
that started with a pure-UGC strategy but later (after the new regulations) adapted by offering PPC; the control
group is made up of sites that started with a PPC strategy. We identified controls based on the following set of
9 Our initial set of analyses presents a detailed look at the failure rates of firms that persisted in using a pure-UGC model.
In the interest of parsimony, we do not present these results in the main paper but instead collect them in Appendix B
(available online). The results confirm that firms retaining their pure-UGC model after the regulatory change are associ-
ated with performance declines; this finding supports our assumption that, as a business model, UGC was indeed disad-
vantaged by the new regulations.
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 191
Table 1. Definition and descriptive statistics of the variables, and their correlation
Strategic variables
UGC_only Dummy variable set to 1 if the firm offers UGC only (set to 0 Internet Wayback Machine
otherwise)
PPC_only Dummy variable set to 1 if the firm offers PPC only Internet Wayback Machine
Mixed Dummy variable set to 1 if the firm offers both UGC and PPC Internet Wayback Machine
PPC UGC_ State Invest Age (L) Number of Quarter of Quarter Fail Interest SCC
initially active firms (L) observation of entry (L)
PPC 1
UGC_initially 0.32 1
State 0.14 0.20 1
Invest 0.10 0.24 0.16 1
Age (L) 0.06 0.24 0.09 0.21 1
Number of active firms (L) 0.26 0.00 0.07 0.17 0.03 1
Quarter of observation 0.40 0.05 0.06 0.16 0.29 0.49 1
(continued)
192 K. Ching
Table 1. Continued
PPC UGC_ State Invest Age (L) Number of Quarter of Quarter Fail Interest SCC
initially active firms (L) observation of entry (L)
UGC PPC
The key statistic in this table is that, among firms starting with a pure-UGC strategy and still operating after the
January 2008 regulatory changes, nearly 4 in 10 eventually adapted by offering PPC.
Table 3. Discrete-time estimation results for strategic adaptation and failure of Chinese Internet video firms
Variable (1) (2) (3) Pre-2008 entry Drop UGC-only CEM sample
(4) (5) (6)
Robust standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by firm. CEM ¼ coarsened exact match; (L) ¼ logged.
*P < 0.1, **P < 0.05, ***P < 0.01.
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 193
Table 4. Firm fixed-effects estimation results for the strategic adaptation of Chinese Internet video firms subsequent to
regulatory change
Robust standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by firm; IRR reported for column (4); CEM ¼ coarsened exact match; (L) ¼ logged; N.A. ¼ not applicable;
N.B. ¼ negative binomial.
þ
P < 0.1, *P < 0.05, **P < 0.01, ***P < 0.001.
Interest levels—still fail at a substantially lower rate than do firms that started with an initial PPC strategy.
According to our results, firms that began by using the subsequently disadvantaged UGC business model but that
switched to offering PPC were associated with significant performance gains in comparison with firms that were not
required to switch their business model.
We now turn to analyzing firms’ interim performance. The results of our firm fixed-effects regressions, shown in
Table 4, are in line with our earlier survival analysis. In column (2) of the table we see that, among PPC sites after the
new regulations, those that began as pure-UGC sites and transitioned to also offering PPC enjoyed a 30% increase in
(log) Interest relative to baseline sites; this result is significant at the 5% level. In column (3), we repeat the analysis
but only for firms that entered the industry before the 2008 regulatory change; the results we obtain are similar. In
column (4), the analysis was conducted using a conditional fixed-effects negative binomial regression on the
nonlogged Index. The results exhibit a consistent pattern: the coefficient for the UGC_initially PPC interaction
term remains consistently positive and significant. Column (5) repeats this analysis by dropping sites that stayed as
pure UGC sites; column (6) uses the CEM matched sample of firms. Just as with survival analysis, the same trends
continue to hold.
Overall, these regression results confirm what might seem to be a surprising phenomenon: firms that did not start
with the PPC model end up outperforming firms that always offered PPC only. So despite being disadvantaged by
regulatory changes, firms that adapted and changed their business model to the eventual dominant one do better
than firms that never used anything but the dominant model. The analysis to follow will explicate the mechanisms
driving this phenomenon.
194 K. Ching
The dependent variable is SCC, and the reference group consists of firms that started as pure PPC. Robust standard errors
(given in parentheses) are clustered by firm. Column (2) and (4) are based on the CEM sample.
**P < 0.05, ***P < 0.01.
The results of our firm fixed-effects regressions, shown in Table 6, exhibit a consistent pattern: the coefficient for
the UGC_initially SCC interaction term remains consistently positive and significant. Column (2) repeats this ana-
lysis using the matched sample of firms. The results in essence suggest that SCC is associated with superior perform-
ance, and firms that started with UGC seem to be benefitting more than those that had not. Overall it lends support
for our supposition that exaptive features leftover from firms’ initial foray into the UGC world had lent them capabil-
ities and complementary assets—users in this case—they could exploit in their transition toward producing content.
Overall, the various regression results confirm what might seem to be a surprising phenomenon: firms that did
not start with the PPC model end up outperforming firms that always offered PPC only. So despite being disadvan-
taged by regulatory changes, firms that adapted and changed their business model to the eventual dominant one do
10 We have observed similar dynamics in the United States and international markets recently. YouTube, Vimeo, and other
Internet video firms have been engaging users to create professional, licensed content.
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 195
Table 6. Firm fixed-effects estimation results for the performance of firms post regulatory
change and pivot
The dependent variable is Interest (logged), and the reference group consists of firms that started as pure PPC. Robust stand-
ard errors (given in parentheses) are clustered by firm. Column (2) is based on the CEM sample.
*P < 0.1, **P < 0.05.
better than firms that never used anything but the dominant model. Further we present evidence that suggest that
exaptive mechanisms drove the process.
6. Discussion
Leveraging a newly assembled data set of all entrants to the Chinese Internet video industry between 2006 and 2011,
we present both quantitative and qualitative evidence indicating that strong firm performance is more characteristic
196 K. Ching
(1) (2)
(Post 2008)
Dependent variable is Average time spent per video (logged); Robust standard errors clustered by firm in parentheses.
*P < 0.1, **P < 0.05, ***P < 0.01.
of entrants that switched to the eventual dominant strategy than of entrants that started with the dominant strategy.
As a possible explanation of this puzzling empirical result, our evidence further suggests that a firm’s engagement
with the user community before the occurrence of a regulatory shock (a quasi-exogenous shock) plays a unique and
accidental role in their strategic switch—an exaptive process. We document how engagement of the user community
by certain Internet video sites allowed them to build a sustainable performance advantage sufficient even to overcome
the disadvantages entailed by a quasi-exogenous shock to the industry’s regulatory environment.
The empirical observations on which our analysis is based accord with extant literature addressing the importance
of complementary assets that underlie a technology’s commercialization (Teece, 1986). Scholars have emphasized
the role of complementary assets and how their interaction with an environment’s “appropriability” affects the firm’s
strategic choices (Gans and Stern, 2003). The availability and consideration of these firm-level assets cohere with
traditional explanations of industry evolutionary dynamics, yet they also enable a more dynamic approach to the
entrepreneurial strategy process. When making core strategic commitments, a firm is normally most sensitive to the
commercial environment. Nonetheless, its very next concern is typically how best to become adaptive in that environ-
ment by identifying and building (or modifying) the firm’s unique and tailored capabilities, resources, and market
positions that make its chosen strategy sustainable.
Our paper also resonates with the increasing body of knowledge on effectuation theory, as it relates to entrepre-
neurial decision-making. In a fast-moving world that defines most nascent entrepreneurial environments, effectuation
theory predicts that entrepreneurs are more likely to start with the means they have and assess for possible goals
(Sarasvathy, 2009). Our results cohere with this line of thinking as the Internet video firm entrepreneurs adjust and
switch in business models, arriving at an eventual winning model that is radically different from their original goals.
The main limitation of this paper is the endogeneity of strategic choice, which means that the reported results
should be interpreted cautiously. Even so, our work offers a methodological advancement beyond current literature
by controlling for the underlying entrepreneurial opportunity and then using matched sets of firms to run a quasi-
experiment that helps clarify the effects of strategic adaptation. Our results point to the dynamic role of entrepre-
neurial strategy-making. Some threads of the literature depict each firm as a largely unconnected and nonadaptive
entity in that they focus either on initial strategies and products of firms (in their depictions of industry evolution) or
on the entry and selective replacement of organizations. However, the results reported here suggest instead that entre-
preneurial strategy must focus on how firms and managers can best respond to and then exploit environmental
signals.
The results of this paper have implications also for new directions of research that can take advantage of similar
institutional barriers impeding the exploitation of original entrepreneurial ideas. This phenomenon is especially com-
mon in the digital age, where business models can be rapidly copied and modified while leveraging the same techno-
logical platform. There exist clones of collective buying sites (Groupon clones such as Coupang.com), of social media
Web sites (Twitter clones such as Weibo.com), and of social networking sites (Facebook clones such as
RenRen.com). China is an especially rich setting for such study owing to the combination of enforced institutional
barriers (e.g., the country’s Internet firewall) and “softer” barriers (e.g., its culture and language). Studying the devel-
opment of clones of original ideas spawned elsewhere relieves the researcher from having to account for the
Exaptation dynamics and entrepreneurial performance 197
confounding factors encountered in most traditional studies that seek to link strategy and performance (e.g., techno-
logical and founder effects). Hence, our identification powers are increased, making it easier to isolate the causal ef-
fect of strategic variates.
Like any study, ours has certain limitations. First, it offers evidence for exaptive processes yet examines just one
industry context. As such, this paper is more of an instructive industry case study than a strong test of our theories.
Second, the data do not provide a full picture of the firms’ time-variant organizational capabilities and resources—a
consequence of the limitations inherent to this industry setting. Future work could devise clearer measures of tech-
nical capabilities and resources. Nevertheless, as one of the first studies in exaptation that have departed from the
realms of technology toward a more generalized entrepreneurial setting, we see this as a necessary compromise to es-
Supplementary Material
Supplementary material is available at ICC online.
Acknowledgements
For helpful comments, I thank Scott Stern, Fiona Murray, Yasheng Huang, and especially Gino Cattani and Pierpaolo Andriani. The
primary quantitative data in this paper were assembled with the excellent assistance of Ziye An, Angela Mao, and You Wang.
Further, Leon Li helped provide invaluable data for robustness checks. All errors remain mine. I thank the Roberts, Hammond, and
Krasner Fund at MIT for financial support.
References
Artero, J. P. (2010), ‘Online video business models: YouTube vs. Hulu,’ Palabra Clave, 13(1), 111–123.
Bayus, B. L. and R. Agarwal (2007), ‘The role of pre-entry experience, entry timing, and product technology strategies in explaining
firm survival,’ Management Science, 53(12), 1887–1902, http://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1070.0737
Bharadwaj, A., O. A. El Sawy, P. A. Pavlou and N. Venkatraman (2013), ‘Digital business strategy: toward a next generation of in-
sights,’ MIS Quarterly, 37(2), 471–482.
Bogers, M., A. Afuah and B. Bastian (2010), ‘Users as innovators: a review, critique, and future research directions,’ Journal of
Management, 36(4), 857–875.
Bonifati, G. (2013), ‘Exaptation and emerging degeneracy in innovation processes,’ Economics of Innovation and New Technology,
22(1), 1–21.
Boudreau, K. (2010), ‘Open platform strategies and innovation: granting access versus devolving control,’ Management Science,
56(10), 1849–1872.
Boudreau, K. J. (2012), ‘Let a thousand flowers bloom? An early look at large numbers of software app developers and patterns of in-
novation,’ Organization Science, 23(5), 1409–1427.
Bristow, M. (2010), ‘China defends internet censorship,’ BBC News. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/8727647.stm
Carrière-Swallow, Y. and F. Labbé (2013), ‘Nowcasting with Google trends in an emerging market,’ Journal of Forecasting, 32(4),
289–298.
Carroll, G. R. and M. T. Hannan (1989), ‘Density dependence in the evolution of populations of newspaper organizations,’ American
Sociological Review, 54(4), 524–541.
Cattani, G. (2005), ‘Preadaptation, firm heterogeneity, and technological performance: a study on the evolution of fiber optics, 1970–
1995,’ Organization Science, 16(6), 563–580.
Cattani, G. (2006), ‘Technological pre-adaptation, speciation, and emergence of new technologies: how corning invented and de-
veloped fiber optics,’ Industrial and Corporate Change, 15(2), 285–318.
Dew, N., S. D. Sarasvathy and S. Venkataraman (2004), ‘The economic implications of exaptation,’ Journal of Evolutionary
Economics, 14(1), 69–84. http://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-003-0180-x
Edelman, B. and J. Zittrain (2005), ‘Empirical analysis of internet filtering in China,’ Berkman Center for Internet & Society, Harvard
Law School. http://cyber. Law. Harvard. Edu/filtering/china
Epstein, G. (2010), ‘The Google of China also has its own Youtube clone,’ Forbes. http://www.forbes.com/sites/gadyepstein/2010/09/
14/the-google-of-china-also-has-its-own-youtube-clone/
Gannes, L. (2009), ‘YouTube changes everything: the online video revolution,’ in D. Gerbarg (ed.), Television Goes Digital. Springer:
New York, NY, pp. 147–155.
198 K. Ching
Gans, J. S. and S. Stern (2003), ‘The product market and the market for,’ Research Policy, 32(2), 333–350.
Helfat, C. E. and M. B. Lieberman (2002), ‘The birth of capabilities: market entry and the importance of pre-history,’ Industrial and
Corporate Change, 11(4), 725–760.
Hille, K. (2012), ‘Youku and Tudou to merge amid cost rises,’ Financial Times. http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/27d4df96-6c2f-11e1-
8c9d-00144feab49a.html#axzz1sG6myrCm (12 March).
Hsu, D. H. (2006), ‘Venture capitalists and cooperative start-up commercialization strategy,’ Management Science, 52(2), 204.
Iacus, S. M., G. King and G. Porro (2012), ‘Causal inference without balance checking: coarsened exact matching,’ Political Analysis,
20(1), 1–24.
Klepper, S. (2002), ‘The capabilities of new firms and the evolution of the US automobile industry,’ Industrial and Corporate Change,
11(4), 645.