ME/MMT: The Currency As A Public Monopoly
ME/MMT: The Currency As A Public Monopoly
ME/MMT: The Currency As A Public Monopoly
for the 19th March 2014 Seminar of Warren Mosler, visiting professor at
University of Bergamo, DAEMQ Department, Lectures of International Monetary Economics
(part of the course taught by Stefano Lucarelli)
Statement of Purpose
The purpose of this paper is to introduce Mosler Economics/Modern Monetary Theory (ME/MMT) to
the Italian academic community. It begins with a brief history of MMT, followed by a description of
the distinguishing aspects of ME/MMT and their application.
Introduction
Warren Mosler, after obtaining his BA in Economics in 1971, entered the financial sector in 1973 as a
loan collector in a small savings bank. In 1976 he was an AVP at Banker’s Trust NYC on their ‘bond
desk’ before moving Chicago in 1978, where he established the government bond department for
William Blair and Co. In 1982 he cofounded Illinois Income Investors, an international investment
company that specializes in fixed income relative value investment strategies, and AVM, institutional
broker/dealer. In 1993 he authored ‘Soft Currency Economics’ with editorial assistance from
economics Professors Mark McNary and Arthur Laffer, which was the beginning of ‘Mosler
Economics (ME)’. In 1996, Professor Pavlina Tcherneva, then an under graduate student, published a
paper that showed how ‘Soft Currency Economics’ was in fact an extension of the existing Post
Keynesian (PK) school of thought:
“In his essay Soft Currency Economics, he draws from his experience as a practitioner in financial
markets in analyzing the underlying forces at work in a modern monetary system.
Interestingly, this analysis incorporates several postulates that can be considered logical extensions of
Post Keynesian monetary thought. Considering the fact that he had no exposure to the Post Keynesian
school of thought before writing his paper, it is fascinating to see the striking similarities between
important aspects of his analysis and Post Keynesian monetary theory. Furthermore, Mosler's work
deserves serious consideration for the valuable insights into the monetary system that are not currently
focused on by the academic world, policymakers, or the general public.”1
However, rather than being incorporated by the Post Keynesians, both Mosler and SCE were, in
general, not well received by Post Keynesians, and most often rejected when not ignored. Those few
who did initially recognize the merits of ‘Soft Currency Economics’ included Professors Bill Mitchell,
Mat Forstater, L. Randall Wray, Stephanie Kelton and Pavlina Tcherneva who. a few years ago, when
ME became popularized as Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), became recognized as MMT professors.
1
Pavlina R. Tcherneva, A Critical Review Of Soft Currency Economics, posted 12/8/96
http://www.epicoalition.org/docs/pavlina.htm
1
In 1998, Professor Alain Parguez, an originator of the theory of the monetary circuit, incorporated the
ME/MMT concepts into that theory, likewise causing a division in that school of thought, where many
adherents also consider themselves Post Keynesians. And Professor Bill Mitchell, who had
independently developed the concept of an employed labor buffer stock in 1978, was likewise all but
rejected by the Australian Post Keynesian community when he began incorporating the monetary
operations aspects of MEMMT.
Several years ago the Italian Journalist Paolo Barnard discovered ME/MMT on the internet. With
further study he recognized ME/MMT’s application to the Italian economy, and set out to popularize
ME/MMT for the further purpose of restoring full employment and a commitment to public purpose in
general.
In February 2012 the world’s first large scale ME/MMT conference was held in Rimini, with some
2,180 people attending the two day event. Barnard subsequently discovered Warren Mosler, and his
2010 book, ‘The 7 Deadly Frauds of Economic Policy’. When Mosler was in Italy for a presentation in
Rimini as a guest of a Mr. Giovanni Zibordi, he met Barnard who arranged a subsequent presentation in
Venice attended by over 400 people. This was followed by further events in Rimini and Cagliari,
attended by more than 2000 people. At the same time, what are now called “ME/MMT Activist Cells”,
began to form independently throughout Italy, working to reverse the course of an Italian economy
suffering severely from the austerity policy that continues to be demanded by the EU. In June 2013, a
tour was arranged in Italy with Warren Mosler and Paolo Barnard making 14 visits in 14 days, from
Sicily to Northern Italy, with presentations to the activists and members of the general community. The
venues at each location were filled to capacity with up to 700 people attending the 3 hour events to
learn about what was happening to the Italian economy and how to fix it. Most recently Mr. Barnard
further popularized ME/MMT as a host on national prime time Italian TV. Currently, there are four
associations promoting ME/MMT in Italy- Rete MMT, Euro Truffa, EPIC, and memmt.
ME/MMT is distinguished by its explicit recognition that the currency itself is a public monopoly,
which is the micro foundation of fiat currency. MEMMT then builds the ramifications of that
fundamental understanding. These include, as points of logic, that the object of monopolization- in this
case the currency- is, necessarily, not ‘neutral’; that a monopolist is ‘price setter’ and not ‘price taker’;
that the monopolist has the choice of setting price or quantity; and, critical to public purpose,
unemployment is necessarily the evidence that a currency monopolist is restricting the supply of the
financial assets need to pay taxes and satisfy savings desires.
The Classical economists said that without monopoly markets would clear and there would be
no mass unemployment. That is, it’s only a monopolist, such as a labor union, that causes
unemployment and excess capacity in general. Keynes, on the other hand, said that even in the absence
of monopoly there could be persistent mass unemployment, and then discussed characteristics of the
monetary system that caused this to be the case. This ongoing impasse alone, which has continued
unabated in academia for over 80 years, is sufficient evidence that neither side has yet to recognize that
the currency itself is the monopoly in question.
2
It is ME/MMT that recognizes both sides are correct. The classics were correct in stating it was a
monopoly that was the cause of unemployment. And Keynes was correct in stating that it was the
characteristics of the monetary system as he described them that caused unemployment. And the
reason for the continuing disagreement is simply that neither side has yet to specifically recognize that
the currency itself is a monopoly causing the unemployment in question.
MEMMT is thus distinguished by its explicit recognition that the currency itself is a monopoly, and that
unemployment is the evidence that the currency monopolist is restricting supply. More precisely,
unemployment (as defined) is the evidence the currency monopolist is restricting the supply of net
financial assets denominated in that currency. It is only government spending (or lending) that adds the
financial assets required for the payment of taxes to the economy, and it is payments to that government
that removes those financial assets from the economy.
ME/MMT recognizes that with fiat currency, the funds the government spends are best thought of as
tax credits. Likewise, the funds the government spends that are not immediately used to pay taxes
remain in the economy as ‘monetary savings’ until used to pay taxes in the future. Furthermore, these
tax credits outstanding constitute what is called the ‘national debt’.
Unemployment
Unemployment is defined as people not working who are seeking paid work. And it is taxation that
functions to cause people to seek paid work, presumably to facilitate the government's desire to
provision itself, which it does by spending its otherwise worthless currency to hire those its currency
caused to be unemployed. Furthermore, as previously discussed, income is not used to pay taxes
remains as monetary savings. Therefore it can be said that unemployment is necessarily the evidence
that the government’s spending is insufficient to satisfy the need to pay taxes and the desire to
save. And, consequently, a fiscal adjustment is always an immediate remedy for unemployment. That
is, the government can always do some combination of hiring the people looking for paid work or
lowering the tax that caused the unemployment.
MEMMT further recognizes that a government that imposes taxes and then spends its own tax credits is
not operationally revenue constrained. In fact, as central bank operations reveal, that government
necessarily, from inception, spends (or lends) first, and only then collects taxes or
borrows. Outstanding tax credits (credited but not yet debited for payment of taxes) in most nations
exist, functionally, as central bank liabilities in the form of cash and credit balances at the central bank.
These balances are commonly called reserve accounts and securities accounts. Therefore, the
expression ‘paying it back’ refers to nothing more than the debiting of securities accounts and the
crediting of reserve accounts, all on the books of the central bank. Therefore, any constraints on
spending are necessarily self-imposed and subject to immediate revocation of the government
responsible for the payments. Typically these constraints include budgeting limits, debt ceilings, and
restrictions on treasury transactions with the central bank.
3
With the support of this fundamental understanding of monetary operations, MEMMT dismisses
common financial concerns that include the government ‘running out of money’: the government being
dependent on borrowing its own currency in order to be able to spend; the government facing solvency
issues and not being able to make future payments; and that the national debt (the outstanding tax
credits) is a financial burden for future generations.
Monopoly Pricing
Monopolists set two prices. They set the price of how their item exchanges for itself, which is called
the ‘own rate’, and they set the price for how their item exchanges for other goods and services. The
terms of exchange they set for other goods and services is known as the price level.
For a currency monopolist, the own rate is the interest rate it sets for its currency. This interest rate is
generally set by the government’s central bank, most often by committee vote. It is then implemented
through the banking system, with the central bank determining the cost of funds for its member
banks. As the monopoly supplier of net clearing balances for the banking system, the central bank can
either pay interest on excess clearing balances (also known as reserves) or, alternatively, take action to
cause a shortage of clearing balances and then, directly or indirectly, enforce their policy rate by the
interest they charge the banking system for the needed funds.
The price level (whether the government knows it or not) is necessarily a function of prices paid by
government when it spends and/or collateral demanded when it lends. Again, the funds required for
payment of taxes come only from government spending or lending. That means the economy needs the
government’s funds to avoid the penalties for non-payment of taxes, and it is this requirement that puts
the government in the position of dictating the terms of exchange.
In a market economy, as a point of logic the government need only set one price, commonly known as
the ‘price anchor’ or ‘buffer stock’, with all other prices then becoming expressions of relative
value. At one time, for example, most governments set the price of gold as their price anchor, and let
all other prices adjust. However this policy was universally abandoned when it failed to promote
public purpose. Currently for most nations the price anchor is the unemployed. What MEMMT
concludes is that an employed buffer stock is a far superior price anchor than an unemployed buffer
stock, along far superior externalities, all with regard to public purpose.
Trade Fundamentals
MEMMT recognizes that labor is a real cost and an input of production, and not an economic benefit as
commonly assumed. Likewise, exports are real economic costs and imports real economic benefits.
Therefore, public purpose is best served by optimizing the real terms of trade with policy that promotes
as many imports as possible for a given level of exports.
Conclusion
MEMMT presumes the role of government is to establish and sustain public infrastructure for public
purpose, and that the currency is a tool of government for the promotion of public purpose.
Accordingly, what MEMMT offers are fiscal and monetary proposals that sustain employment
4
opportunities for anyone willing and able to work, and that optimize real terms of trade, all in support
of real standards of living.
Warren Mosler
February 24, 2014
Christiansted, USVI
Rites of Passage
Conceived in post WWII politics, and baptized in the political waters of the 90’s, a new common cur-
rency- the euro- assumed its position on January 1, 1999. Representatives of the prospective member
nations masterfully achieved political consensus by both the absence of objectionable clauses and the
inclusion of national constraints, as manifested in the Treaty of Maastricht. During that tumultuous
process, with deep pride, the elders grasped and shielded the credit sensitive heel of the infant
euro. The ‘no bailout’ directive for the new ECB (European Central Bank) emerged as a pillar of the
political imperative to address the ‘moral hazard’ issue that so deeply concerned the political leader-
ship, and, two years later, that same rhetoric of fiscal responsibility continues to ring at least as loudly
when the merits of the EMU (European Monetary Union) are proclaimed. Unfortunately, however well
intended as protection from a genetic proclivity toward fiscal irresponsibility, the naked heel is but a
magnet for the financial market’s arrows of our hero’s mortal demise.
As Apollo’s chariot adeptly carries its conflagration from east to west, the European Monetary Union
carries its members on the path of economic growth. Unlike the path of the sun, however, the path of
an economy continuously vacillates, including occasional dips into negative territory. And, like the
sign most rental car agencies post by the entrance for returning cars about to drive over a one way
bump strip, the new EMU, with its lurking unidirectional bias, could do a service to it members with a
similar posting - WARNING- DO NOT BACK UP!
The euro-12 nations once had independent monetary systems, very much like the US, Canada, and Ja-
pan today. Under EMU, however, the national governments are now best thought of financially as
states, provinces, or cities of the new currency union, much like California, Ontario, and New York
City. The old national central banks are no longer the issuers of their local currency. In their place, the
EMU has added a new central bank, the ECB, to manage the payments system, set the overnight lend-
ing rate, and intervene in the currency markets when appropriate. The EP (European Parliament) has a
relatively small budget and limited fiscal responsibilities. Most of the governmental functions and re-
sponsibilities remain at the national level, having not been transferred to the new federal level. Two of
those responsibilities that will prove most problematic at the national level are unemployment compen-
sation and bank deposit insurance. Furthermore, all previous national financial liabilities remain at the
national level and have been converted to the new euro, with debt to GDP ratios of member nations as
high as 105%, not including substantial and growing unfunded liabilities. These burdens are all very
much higher than what the credit markets ordinarily allow states, provinces, or cities to finance.
5
Since inception a little over two years ago the euro-12 national governments have experienced moder-
ate GDP growth, declining unemployment, and moderate tax revenue growth. Fiscal deficits narrowed
and all but vanished as tax revenues grew faster than expenditures, and GDP increased at a faster rate
than the national debts, so that debt to GDP ratios declined somewhat. Under these circumstances in-
vestors have continued to support national funding requirements and there have been no substantive
bank failures. Furthermore, it is reasonable to assume that as long as this pattern of growth continues
finance will be readily available. However, should the current world economic slowdown move the
euro-12 to negative growth, falling tax revenues, and concerns over the banking system’s financial
health, the euro-12 could be faced with a system wide liquidity crisis. At the same time, market forces
can also be expected to exacerbate the downward spiral by forcing the national governments to act pro-
cyclically, either by cutting national spending or attempting to increase revenue.
For clues to the nature and magnitude of the potential difficulties, one can review the US Savings and
Loan crisis of the 80’s, with the difference being that deposit insurance would have been a state obliga-
tion, rather than a federal responsibility. For example, one could ask how Texas might have fared
when faced with a bill for some $100 billion to cover bank losses and redeem depositors? And, once it
was revealed that states could lack the borrowing power for funds to preserve depositors insured ac-
counts, how could any bank have funded itself? More recently, if Bank of America’s deposit insurer
and lender of last resort were the State of California rather than the Federal Reserve, could it have
funded itself under the financial cloud of the state’s ongoing power crisis and credit downgrade? And,
if not, would that have triggered a general liquidity crisis within the US banking system? Without de-
posit insurance and lender of last resort responsibilities the legal obligation of a non-credit constrained
entity, such as the Federal Reserve, is systemic financial risk not ever present?
*Will the euro-12 economy slow sufficiently to automatically increase national deficits via the reduc-
tion of tax revenues and increased transfer payments?
*Will such a slowdown cause the markets to dictate terms of credit to the credit sensitive national gov-
ernments, and force procyclical responses?
*Will the markets allow national governments with heavy debt burdens, falling revenues and rising ex-
penses the finance required to support troubled banks?
*Will depositors lose confidence in the banking system and test the new euro-12 support mechanism?
*Can the entire payments system avoid a shutdown when faced with this need to reorganize?
Conclusion
Water freezes at 0 degrees C. But very still water can be cooled well below that and stay liquid until a
catalyst, such as a sudden breeze, causes it to instantly solidify. Likewise, the conditions for a national
liquidity crisis that will shut down the euro-12’s monetary system are firmly in place. All that is re-
quired is an economic slowdown that threatens either tax revenues or the capital of the banking sys-
tem.
6
A prosperous financial future belongs to those who respect the dynamics and are prepared for the day
of reckoning. History and logic dictate that the credit sensitive euro-12 national governments and
banking system will be tested. The market’s arrows will inflict an initially narrow liquidity crisis,
which will immediately infect and rapidly arrest the entire euro payments system. Only the inevitable,
currently prohibited, direct intervention of the ECB will be capable of performing the resurrection, and
from the ashes of that fallen flaming star an immortal sovereign currency will no doubt emerge.
http://www.moslereconomics.com/mandatory-readings/soft-currency-economics/
http://www.moslereconomics.com/mandatory-readings/full-employment-and-price-stability/
http://www.moslereconomics.com/mandatory-readings/a-general-analytical-framework-for-the-
analysis-of-currencies-and-other-commodities/
http://www.moslereconomics.com/mandatory-readings/the-natural-rate-of-interest-is-zero/
http://moslereconomics.com/2010/10/04/exchange-rate-policy-and-full-employment/
http://www.epicoalition.org/docs/Pavlina_2007.pdf
http://www.moslereconomics.com/?p=8968