Coltan, Congo & Conflict: Polinares Case Study
Coltan, Congo & Conflict: Polinares Case Study
Coltan, Congo & Conflict: Polinares Case Study
& Conflict
POLINARES CASE STUDY
The Hague Centre for Strategic Studies No 20 | 03 | 13
HCSS helps governments, non-governmental organizations and the
private sector to understand the fast-changing environment and
seeks to anticipate the challenges of the future with practical policy
solutions and advice.
Coltan, Congo & Conflict
The Hague Centre for Strategic Studies (HCSS)
Rapport No 21 | 05 |13
ISBN/EAN: 978-94-91040-81-8
Project leader:
Marjolein de Ridder
Authors:
HCSS Fraunhofer ISI Raw Materials Group BGR
Artur Usanov Luis Tercero Espinoza Magnus Ericsson Henrike Sievers
Marjolein de Ridder Masuma Farooki Maren Liedtke
Willem Auping
Stephanie Lingemann
This research has received funding from the European Community’s Seventh Framework
Programme (FP7/2007- 2013) under grant agreement n° 244516 (POLINARES project).
© 2013 The Hague Centre for Strategic Studies. All rights reserved. No part of this report
may be reproduced and/or published in any form by print, photo print, microfilm or any
other means without previous written permission from the HCSS. All images are subject
to the licenses of their respective owners.
Table of contents
Executive Summary 9
Introduction 11
5 Policy initiatives 67
5.1 Brief review of policy initiatives 67
5.2 Main challenges facing coltan initiatives 71
6 Conclusion 85
HCSS Report 5
TA B L E O F C O N T E N T S
List of figures
Figure 1 Percentage share of category in tantalum processors’ shipments 17
Figure 2 The tantalum supply chain 19
Figure 3 Regional distribution of the most likely tantalum resources, 2010 20
Figure 4 Major tantalum mining sites 21
Figure 5 Global tantalum production, 1990-2011 (in tonnes of tantalum content) 22
Figure 6 The average year-end nominal tantalite spot price
(in US$ per kg of tantalum content) 26
Figure 7 GNI per capita in DR Congo as a percentage of GNI per capita
in Sub-Saharan Africa 31
Figure 8 Mineral deposits in the DRC 32
Figure 9 Political map of the DRC 34
Figure 10 Armed groups in the eastern DRC 39
Figure 11 Tantalum production in the DRC (in tonnes of tantalum content) 45
Figure 12 Tantalum price and production in the DRC, 2001-2010 (in tonnes) 48
Figure 13 Geographic distribution of tantalum production, 2007-2011 49
Figure 14 Share of the DRC and Rwanda in global production of tantalum 51
Figure 15 Distribution of armed groups’ estimated profits from trade
in 4 major minerals, 2008 56
List of tables
Table 1 Major uses of tantalum by industry 16
Table 2 Distribution of coltan revenues, c. 2000 52
Table 3 Major armed groups and sources of mineral revenue,1998-2003,
(Source: Nest, 2011) 60
Table 4 Major armed groups and sources of mineral revenue 2006-2008 61
Table 5 Exports of conflict minerals from North and South Kivus, in US$’000s 81
Table 6 Major mines for tantalum by state of operations 91
Table 7 Overview of actors involved in DRC conflict 93
HCSS Report 7
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Executive Summary
In the early 2000s, tantalum – a rare metal with some unique properties that
make it an important raw material for information and communication
technologies – suddenly moved from obscure geological publications into a
wide public spotlight. Effective NGO campaigns using catchy slogans, such as
‘No blood on my mobile’, emphasized that consumer demand in the West for
mobile phones, computers, game consoles and other electronic devices, all
of which contain small amounts of tantalum, fueled mass atrocities in the
Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC).
The report was prepared as part of the POLINARES project, which aims to
examine the main global challenges surrounding access to fossil fuels and
mineral resources. First, it provides the main facts and data on tantalum,
such as its properties and uses, the supply chain from mine to metal, and price
developments. Next, the report gives a short historic overview of conflict in the
DRC which is followed by an overview of coltan and tantalum resources and
coltan mining in the country. Then, the report focuses on the specific role of
coltan in the present conflict in the DRC. It analyzes the involvement of armed
groups in the mining and mineral trade and touches upon the debate on greed
and grievances when assessing the motivations of armed groups. Finally, the
report gives an overview of the policy measures that were adopted or proposed
to mitigate the negative effects of coltan mining and trade on the conflict in
the DRC, and analyzes their effectiveness and efficiency.
HCSS Report 9
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The report concludes that the importance of coltan as a source of revenue for
armed groups is often exaggerated. With the exception of a short-lived coltan
boom in 2000-2001, it was never a substantial source of funding for armed
groups. Although armed groups have profited from the DRC’s mineral wealth,
coltan was not the main instigator of the conflict in the DRC and was at most a
contributing factor.
Many policy initiatives aimed at breaking the link between mining, mineral trade
and conflict, including Section 1502 of the Dodd-Frank Act in the U.S., suffer
from problems related to both effectiveness and efficiency. First of all, there is
little convincing evidence that initiatives focusing on limiting the mineral reve-
nue of armed groups are likely to lead to a significant reduction of violence in the
DRC. We believe this is because many conflict mineral policy initiatives assume
that mineral revenues are the main reason behind the continued fighting in
eastern DRC. However, reducing the mineral revenue of armed groups primarily
addresses symptoms of a deeper problem. As long as the underlying reasons for
conflict continue to exist and the right governance structures to address griev-
ances are lacking, rebels will simply shift from trade in minerals to other sources
of revenue, such as taxing agriculture or foreign aid. There are obviously moral
reasons for reducing the mineral revenues of armed groups. However, even in
this case it is important to understand that challenges such as weak governance,
corruption and large compliance costs, might easily undermine their successful
implementation.
The main problem in the DRC is the weakness of governance and the inability
of the state to fulfill its basic functions. In such a context, ending the violence
requires a long-term and comprehensive approach that combines miltary,
political, and economic efforts, with a particular emphasis on building capable
and legitimate institutions, restoring the state’s monopoly on violence, and
promoting economic development that is not based on illegal activities.
Introduction
In the early 2000s, tantalum – a rare metal with some unique properties –
suddenly moved from being the subject of specialized geological and engineering
publications into a wide public spotlight. Effective NGO campaigns using catchy
slogans, such as ‘No blood on my mobile’, claimed that consumer demand in the
West for mobile phones, computers, game consoles and other electronic devices,
all of which contain small amounts of tantalum, fueled mass scale atrocities in
the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC). In the eyes of the general public,
tantalum and coltan, a tantalum-bearing ore that is mined in the DRC, became
the most visible symbol of the link between the deadly conflict in the DRC and
the exploitation of mineral resources.
This case study on the link between coltan mining and armed conflict in DRC
was prepared as part of the POLINARES project funded by the European
Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007- 2013). The overall goal
of the project was to examine the main global challenges surrounding access to
fossil fuels and mineral resources. This study illustrates one particular aspect
of this broader problem; self-imposed constraints on access to certain minerals
in response to public and policy-maker sensitivity to potential links between
mining and human suffering or conflict. This moves away from the more
familiar problem, which was the main focus of past POLINARES projects,
namely when access to minerals is limited by actions of external actors. In the
future, self-imposed constraints on access to minerals may become a more
common instrument to ensure international compliance with basic standards of
environmental stewardship or labor conditions at mining sites. The question of
whether the use of such constraints is appropriate highlights the difficulty of
balancing the mutual economic benefits offered by mining to mineral producing
and consuming countries against the protection of core values concerning the
unacceptability of violence or forced labor.
HCSS Report 11
INTRODUCTION
While this report does not offer any definitive answers to this question, it does
provide an illustration of the difficult trade-offs to be made between economic
and normative concerns through a case study of coltan mining in the DRC and its
connection with the ongoing civil conflict. It also demonstrates that there can be
unintended consequences of policy measures aimed at breaking the links
between coltan mining and conflict.
More specifically this report aims to answer the following research questions:
• What are the main policy initiatives either proposed or put in place and what
are their (potential) impacts?
Tantalum and coltan were selected as the focus of this case study due to the large
amount of public attention that they have received. The fact that they became
the target of highly mediatized NGO campaigns is in itself somewhat puzzling.
Coltan is far from being the most important mineral that is mined in the DRC,
and the DRC has never been the main tantalum supplier to the global market.
This report therefore seeks to redress the largely mediatic coverage of the role
of coltan mining in the DRC conflict, contributing to a more informed analysis
of the relationship between the two.
The report is structured in the following way. Chapter 1 provides the main facts
and data on tantalum. It gives an overview of its properties and uses, discusses
1 For example, one the most prominent sources of data on the minerals market, U.S. Geological
Survey, notes in the ‘Mineral Yearbook 2002’ that ‘data on production [in the DRC] are
speculative and unreliable for estimating’.
the tantalum supply chain from mine to metal, including artisanal mining of
coltan in the DRC. Finally, this chapter touches upon developments in tantalum
prices which were an important trigger for coltan mining in the DRC and had
significant impact on the conflict. Chapter 2 includes background information
on the DRC and a short historic overview of conflict there. Chapter 3 then looks
specifically at coltan mining in the DRC. This chapter gives an overview of coltan
and tantalum resources in the country and it discusses the organization of coltan
mining during the first and second mining booms. Chapter 4 focuses on the
specific role of coltan in the present conflict in the DRC. It analyzes the
involvement of armed groups in mining and mineral trade, exploring the greed
and grievances model of assessing the motivations of armed groups. Chapter 5
gives an overview of the policy measures that were adopted or proposed to
mitigate the negative effects of coltan mining and trade on the conflict in the
DRC, and analyzes their effectiveness and efficiency. Finally, this report greatly
benefited from the expertise and multidisciplinary nature of the POLINARES
research consortium. The Hague Centre for Strategic Studies (HCSS) worked
together with the Bundesanstalt fur Geowissenschaften und Rohstoffe (BGR),
Raw Materials Group (RMG) and Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation
Research (ISI) on this report.
HCSS Report 13
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
Since the 1960s the leading use of tantalum was as a powder or wire for capacitors
within the electronics industry. Capacitators are electrical components that are
used to store energy in an electric field. They are used in the electrical circuits
of many common electronic devices. The tantalum capacitor has a high
capacitance, which is the ability to store an electrical charge, per volume and
weight. This makes tantalum capacitors smaller and lighter than their
alternatives (for example, made from aluminum). Despite their higher price,
tantalum capacitors are widely used in mobile phones, computers and
automotive electronics, where saving on weight and space is important. An
average mobile phone, for example, contains around 40 milligrams of tantalum.
2 See also Luis A. Tercero Espinoza, Case Study: Tantalum in the World Economy: History, Uses and
Demand, POLINARES Working Paper N. 28 (Polinares, March 2012), http://www.polinares.eu/
docs/d2-1/polinares_wp2_chapter16.pdf.
HCSS Report 15
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
Besides capacitors, tantalum is used in many alloys thanks to its high melting
point and resistance to corrosion. It is an essential component of many nickel-
based super alloys, which are used for highly stressed parts, such as the turbine
blades in aircraft engines and land-based gas turbines. Others uses of tantalum
include mill products for sputtering targets and chemicals for audio and video
components. Tantalum is also being used in the medical industry. Its chemical
inertness and non-irritant reaction to living tissue make tantalum ideally suited
for surgical instruments, pacemakers, implants and joint replacements. Table 1
gives an overview of the major uses of tantalum by industry.
Ceramics & surface Ceramic capacitors, glass coating, High strength Tantalum oxide and
coatings camera lenses and X- ray films yttrium tantalate
Construction Cathode protection systems for large High strength, Tantalum metal
steel structures such as oil platforms resistance to corrosion
and corrosion resistant fasteners such
as screws, nuts and bolts
Electronics Capacitors, surface acoustic wave High and temperature Lithium tantalate,
filters for sensors and touch screen insensitive volumetric tantalum powder,
technologies, hard disk drivers and led capacitance, tantalum ingots and
lights thermodynamic stability tantalum nitride
Metallurgical Furnace parts, super alloys for jet Resistance to high Tantalum metal and
engines and rocket engine nozzles temperatures ingots
Military Missile parts, night vision goggles, Resistance to high Tantalum ingots and
and Global Positioning Systems (GPS) temperatures, High and oxide
temperature insensitive
volumetric capacitance
The fabrication of tantalum capacitors is reported to account for more than 60%
of tantalum demand in the United States (US) today.4 Other sources suggest that
globally the share of tantalum use for capacitors has decreased since 2004 from
42% to 24% while use of tantalum chemicals has increased from 14% to 36 %.5
The share of other categories has remained largely unchanged over the years (see
Figure 1).6
2005 2011
Tantalum
Chemicals
14% mill other
products 11%
other
of
mill 12% tantalum Tantalum
tantalum
products Carbide Chemicals
16%
of 9% 36%
tantalum
17% Capacitor tantalum
Capacitor
-grade ingot
-grade
tantalum 6%
tantalum tantalum
ingot powder
powder tantalum
7% 41%
24% Carbide
7%
Miners
Substitution
Traders
There are substitutes available for most applications of tantalum and its
compounds. The range of capacitance provided by tantalum capacitors, for
example, can be largely but not completely covered by aluminum-, ceramic-
Processors
or niobium-based capacitors. In particular ceramic and niobium capacitors
are replacing tantalum capacitors in many applications. The use of tantalum
Capacitor Sputtering target Alloy
Producers manufacturers producers
4 US Geological Survey, ‘Mineral Commodity Summaries 2012' (US Geological Survey (USGS),
January 24, 2012).
Circuit board Semi-conductor Component
assemblers manufacturers manufacturers
5 Tantalum-Niobium International Study Center and José Isildo de Vargas, Bulletin No 149, ISSN
1019-2026, March 2012, http://tanb.org/webfm_send/166.
6 Figure 1 is based on tantalum processors’ shipment data. Since the tantalum market is
OEM OEM
a relatively small and high-value market, stocks (e.g. of electronic companies) can be
significant. Therefore shipment data must be understood as a proxy for end-use statistics.
Figure 2 The tantalum supply
7 Tantalum-Niobium chain
International Study Center and José Isildo de Vargas, Bulletin No 149.
(Adapted from Global Advanced Metals)
HCSS Report 17
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
Because of the strong competition from other materials for capacitors and
microelectronic applications it is expected that the consumption of tantalum
will not increase substantially in the future. This is supported by data from the
Niobium-Tantalum International Study Center (TIC) on tantalum processors’
shipments, which were at the same level in early 2010 as in 2004.9 This
development is also supported by the global production data of the United States
Geological Survey (USGS), which show that global production in 2010 was more
than 50% less than in 2004 (see Figure 5).
8 US Geological Survey, ’Mineral Commodity Summaries 2012’; Volker Wischnat and Bettina
Renz, ’Wo Keramik Vorsprung Schaff t,’ E&E-Kompendium 2007/2008 (2007): 90–92; Roskill
Information Services, The economics of tantalum. (London: Roskill Information Services, 2009),
10.
9 Tantalum-Niobium International Study Center and José Isildo de Vargas, Bulletin No 149.
Miners
Traders
Processors
OEM OEM
HCSS Report 19
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
South America
41%
(Source:
FIGURE Burt, 2010)DISTRIBUTION OF THE MOST LIKELY TANTALUM RESOURCES, 2010
3: REGIONAL
Orlovka
Tanco
Figure 3 shows the distribution of the most likely tantalum resources by
Ma Ar Kan Yichun
geographic region. The largest indicated and measured (or known) tantalum Nanping
resources in the world are found in South America (106,000), mainly in Brazil;
and in Australia (53,900). Kenticha
Thailand
Malaysia
Pitinga
Reserves are the part of the resources that can be economically extracted using
Mibra
Wodgina
11 USGS, Mineral Commodity Summaries 2012: Tantalum, Mineral Commodity Summaries (USGS,
2012), http://minerals.usgs.gov/minerals/pubs/commodity/niobium/mcs-2012-tanta.pdf.
Lovozero
Orlovka
Tanco
Ma Ar Kan Yichun
Nanping
Thailand
Kenticha Malaysia
Pitinga
Wodgina
Mibra
Marropino Greenbushes
Tantalum mining
The tantalum supply chain starts with the mining of tantalum-containing ores.
Conventional and artisanal and small-scale mining (ASM) takes place around
the world. Figure 4 shows where tantalum mining takes place globally. The Great
Lakes region is the center of tantalum mining in Africa with the DRC being the
largest African producer. Most of tantalum mining in Africa is artisanal and
small-scale. The major exeptions are the Marropino mine in Mozambique and
the Kenticha mine in Ethiopia.
HCSS Report 21
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
1600
1400
1200
Rest of the
1000 World
Africa
800
Brazil
600
Australia
400
200
0
2007
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2008
2009
2010
2011
Figure 5 Global tantalum production, 1990-2011 (in tonnes of tantalum content)
FIGURE 5: GLOBAL TANTALUM PRODUCTION, 1990-2011 (IN TONNES OF TANTALUM CONTENT)
(Source:
(SOURCE:USGS data)
USGS DATA)
700
600
Figure 5 shows the fluctuations in global production over time from 1990 to 2010
and
500
the relative contributions of Australia, Brazil, and Africa. Existing mining
operations respond relatively quickly to changing market conditions (see
400
Appendix A for an overview of past, present and planned mining projects). When
demand
300
and prices are low, mines are closed only to be reopened again when
demand picks up and prices rise. The global economic crisis slowed demand for
200
tantalum and led to the temporary closure of some of the largest tantalum mines.
100
In the fall of 2008 as the global financial crisis reached its apogee, the demand for
0
tantalum from electronic industries started to fall. Consequently this led to the
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
closure of several mines in Mozambique, Canada and Australia. Talison Minerals
Pty (now
Figure 6: Theknown as Global
average year-end Advanced
nominal tantalite Metals), theUS$
spot price (in largest
per kg global producer
of tantalum content) of
1
12 Swiss Metal Assets, ’Dodd-Frank, Australian Cuts Threaten Tantalum,’ Swiss Metal Assets,
February 14, 2012, http://www.swissmetalassets.com.
13 Raw Materials Group, ’Raw Materials Data - Tantalum,’ Raw Materials Data (RMD) - Metals, Iron
Ore and Coal Database, 2012, http://www.rmg.se/index.php?option=com_
content&task=view&id=25&Itemid=89.
1
Price of tantalite ore is typically reported by trade journals in US dollars per pound of tantalum pentoxide content. It was converted by the
USGS into US dollars per tonne of contained tantalum. These, however, are not prices for refined tantalum, which are obviously significantly
higher.
Artisanal mining
Artisanal and small-scale mining (ASM) is done by individuals, family units,
worker cooperatives or small companies with minimal or no mechanization,
often informally or illegally.15 Not every mineral is suitable for artisanal mining.
Geological factors that support economies of scale and mechanization
(uniformity of deposit, width of ore bodies, depth, overburden) tend to render
ASM unprofitable. On the other hand, small deposits and irregular ore bodies
create economic opportunities for ASM.
The most important factor for the economic competitiveness of artisanal mining
is a high value per unit of weight of the ore mined. Coltan is a quite valuable
material in this respect with prices having exceeded US$100 per kg of tantalum
content. It is therefore no coincidence that artisanal mining accounted for more
than a quarter of total global production of tantalum in 2009, which is one of the
highest percentages compared to other metals.16 Since ASM is based on extensive
use of labor, low wages are also essential for its economic competitiveness.
Finally, the factors that make large mining investment more expensive or risky
also make ASM comparatively more attractive. Such factors might include
remote location of deposits, difficult terrain, absence of infrastructure (roads,
electricity, water), and high political risk including lack of rule of law.
14 Globe Metals & Mining, ’Globe Metals & Mining - Tantalum,’ Globe Metals & Mining, 2012,
http://www.globemetalsandmining.com.au/Commodities/Tantalum.aspx#.UIhivVFqCxV.
15 Dorner, U., G.Franken, M.Liedtke and H.Sievers, Artisanal and Small-Scale Mining (ASM),
POLINARES working paper n.19, March 2012., p.1
16 Dorner, U., G.Franken, M.Liedtke and H.Sievers, Artisanal and Small-Scale Mining (ASM),
POLINARES working paper n.19, March 2012., Figure 3.
HCSS Report 23
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
changes in the market comes from the fact that artisanal miners typically do not
have labor contracts with fixed wages but are paid or a fixed percentage of their
production. Economically it means that these entrepreneurs bear all market risks
themselves. If mineral prices drop significantly some of them will abandon
mining because it becomes less attractive and switch to other economic
activities. Thus the supply side of the coltan market in the DRC is close to what
economists call ‘perfect competition’ with many small price-taking producers.
The economic crisis and the shutting down of major mines has had a significant
impact on the relative shares of primary and secondary production. Before 2008,
60% of tantalum supply came from primary concentrates, a further 10% each
from secondary concentrates and from tin slag. The final 20% of global
production was accounted for by scrap recycling. Post-2008, the share of
production coming from primary concentrates dropped sharply to 10% in 2010,
recovering to 27% by 2011. To compensate for the gap, tantalum production from
tin slag and scrap increased.
Concentration
After mining, tantalum-containing ores are concentrated at or near the mine site
to increase the share of tantalum oxide (Ta2O5) in the concentrate. Tantalum ore
traded on international markets should contain a minimum of 30% of Ta2O5. Ores
with lower grades of a minimum 20% Ta2O5 may be acceptable to some buyers.
HCSS Report 25
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
1600
1400
1200
Rest of the
1000 World
Africa
800
longer of any significance.20 Before the early 2000s, the tantalum industry also Brazil
600
held substantial inventories of tantalum ore. Most of these inventories, however,
Australia
have
400now also been exhausted, such as the Global Advanced Metals inventory. 21
200
1.3 Price
0
developments
Like the prices of other minerals, prices for tantalum ore are mainly influenced
2007
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2008
2009
2010
2011
by developments in the supply of and demand for products in which it is used.
Published spot prices for tantalite ore have shown long-term stability
Figure 5 Global tantalum production, 1990-2011 (in tonnes of tantalum content)
interrupted by very sharp price jumps (see Figure 7).
(Source: USGS data)
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
1
Figure 6: The average year-end nominal tantalite spot price (in US$ per kg of tantalum content)
FIGURE 6: THE AVERAGE YEAR-END NOMINAL TANTALITE SPOT PRICE (IN US$ PER KG OF TANTALUM
20 Papp, J.F., ’Niobium (columbium) and Tantalum - 2008.,’ in U. S. Geological Survey Minerals
Yearbook - 2008. (U. S. Geological Survey, 2010), 52.1–52.14.; Roskill Information Services Ltd,
The Economics of Tantalum.
21 Papp, J.F., ’Niobium (columbium) and Tantalum - 2008.’; Roskill Information Services Ltd, The
Economics of Tantalum.
22 Price of tantalite ore is typically reported by trade journals in US dollars per pound of
tantalum pentoxide content. It was converted by the USGS into US dollars per tonne of
contained tantalum. These, however, are not prices for refined tantalum, which are obviously
significantly higher.
1
Price of tantalite ore is typically reported by trade journals in US dollars per pound of tantalum pentoxide content. It was converted by the
USGS into US dollars per tonne of contained tantalum. These, however, are not prices for refined tantalum, which are obviously significantly
higher.
The first price surge occurred from 1978 to 1980 when average prices rose from
about 66 US$/kg in 1977 to over 284 US$/kg in 1980 (these are nominal average
prices at the end of the year as reported by the USGS). This price hike was largely
brought about by panic buying influenced by shortages of supply and expected
increases in tantalum demand for electronic components. Large tantalum
inventories were built up during this period. The tantalum surplus in
inventories, substitution and recycling of electronic components resulted in
decreasing prices in 1982.23
The second rapid escalation in tantalite prices occured in 1988 when tantalum
prices almost doubled from about 70 US$/kg in 1987 to 135 US$/kg in 1988. This
price peak was due to increased tantalum demand and depleted tantalum
inventories.
The third price boom led to record tantalite price levels in 2000. From 1999 to
2000, prices rose more than six-fold – from 91 to 590 US$/kg due to expectations
of high demand in the electronic industry, over-ordering and apparent shortage.
Again, the price peak was short-lived and prices crashed in 2001, as a result of
excess stocks combined with a downturn in demand from the electronics sector,
due in part to substitution of tantalum capacitors in some applications. As
during the previous coltan boom, large inventories were built up again.
Finally, after the period of quite stable prices in 2001-2010, in 2011 tantalite prices
surged to 340 US$/kg, more than the double level of 2010 or triple of 2009. It is
probably too early to single out specific factors driving the current price surge
but most likely that significant cuts in mine production (see Figure 5) have
played a substantial role.
Price fluctuations have played a major role in the development of coltan mining
in the Congo. The price spike of 2000 had especially significant effect on coltan
mining in the DRC, and the closure of industrial mines in 2008 due to the
economic downturn enabled artisanal mining in the DRC to florish.
HCSS Report 27
K ey facts and figures about coltan and tantalum
Population
The DRC’s population – the third largest in Africa – is estimated at 73.6 million
and is growing rapidly. The population has more than doubled since the last
census of 1985 when it was only 34.7 million. The total fertility rate in the DRC
(i.e. the average number of children that will be born to a woman in her lifetime)
has been falling rapidly but was still six in 2008. 25 The DRC’s population is
ethnically diverse, containing more than 200 distinct ethnic groups. In addition
to French, which is the official language, there are four recognized national
languages – Lingala, Kikongo, Kiswahili, Tshiluba – and various local languages
24 Unless specifically noted otherwise general data on the DRC in this sub-section are from
World Bank’s World Development Indicators database, http://data.worldbank.org/data-
catalog/world-development-indicators
25 CIA World Factbook, https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/
cg.html
HCSS Report 29
T he D emocratic R epublic of C ongo
and dialects.26 Many Congolese have a strong sense of identity based on a their
ethnic (and often sub-ethnic) group.27 Such groups exist in every province of the
DRC. Rivalry between different ethnic groups was at the origin of multiple
rebellions that took place in the early 1960s.
Economic performance
The economic performance of the DRC has been disastrous and the current
standard of living is extremely low. Figure 7 shows the development of gross
national income (GNI) per capita in the DRC as a percentage of GNI per capita in
Sub-Saharan Africa. It shows that in 1963, at the outset of its independence, the
DRC had a GNI per capita that was almost twice as high as the average level for
Sub-Saharan Africa (or more exactly 188%).28 In 2011 had it dropped to just 15%.
200%
180%
160%
140%
120%
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
FIGURE7.7:GNI
Figure GNIper
PERcapita
CAPITA IN DRC
in DR CONGO
Congo as aAS A PERCENTAGE
percentage of GNIOF
perGNI PERin
capita CAPITA IN SUB-SAHARAN
Sub-Saharan Africa
AFRICA (BASED ON WORLD DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS AND AUTHORS’ CALCULATIONS)
(Based on World Development Indicators and authors’ calculations)
26 Ibid
27 Gambino, Tony, Democratic Republic of Congo. Background Case Study for the World
Development Report 2011, March 2, 2011,
28 It should be noted that GNI per capita is a limited measure of living standards. Although in
1960s GNI per capita in DR Congo was relatively high compared to other Sub-Saharan African
countries other development indicators, such as life expectancy or child mortality, indicated
that living standards for most of population in the DRC were not markedly better than in
neighboring countries. A very high concentration of wealth and income in the hands of small
elite is the most obvious explanation for this discrepancy.
The DRC is at the very bottom of various global development rankings. For
example, the DRC had the lowest value of the Human Development Index
published by the United Nations Development Program, which combines
measures of life expectancy, educational attainment, and income.29 Congo’s
infant mortality rate (110.6 per 1,000 of live births in 2011) is the third highest
in the world (only Somalia and Mali have a higher rate). Physical infrastructure
in the DRC remains rudimentary. Poor road systems and large distances make
transport between Congo’s eastern provinces, where coltan is mined, and the
rest of the country difficult and expensive.
Natural resources
At the same time, some observers consider the DRC as a wealthy country because
it has large deposits of various minerals including diamonds, gold, copper,
cobalt, zinc and coltan (see Figure 8).
29 UNDP, Human Development Report 2011. Sustainability and Equity: A Better Future for All,
2011, http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/HDR_2011_EN_Complete.pdf.
HCSS Report 31
T h e D e m o c r at i c R e p u b l i c o f C o n g o
(SOURCE: UN)
The mining industry has been a cornerstone of the Congolese economy since the
colonial times. Historically, the mining industry accounted for 25% of Congo’s
GDP and about three-quarters of total export revenue. Uranium from the DRC
was used at the Manhattan Project in the US to build the first nuclear bomb. In
the late 1980s (and in recent years) the country was the largest global producer
of cobalt and one of the largest of industrial diamonds and copper. However,
economic mismanagement and the degradation of Congolese state institutions
affected the mining sector as well. In 2000, despite the mineral riches of the
DRC, the sector’s share of the GDP dropped to an estimated 6%. 30
30 Coakley, George J. ’The Mineral Industry of Congo (Kinshasa).’ In U.S. Geological Survey
Minerals Yearbook -2002. USGS, 2002.
An explosive mix
Many factors that substantially increase the risk of civil war or violence are
present in the DRC. A comprehensive review of empirical political science
literature by J. Dixon (2009) shows that factors such as a large population, large
territory, ethnic heterogeneity and declining living standards closely correlate
with an increased likelihood of civil war. 31 High infant mortality rate has also
been found to be a reliable proxy for a higher risk of conflict.32
31 Dixon, Jeffery, ’What Causes Civil Wars? Integrating Quantitative Research Findings’,
International Studies Review (2009) 11,p. 707-735.
32 Goldstone, Jack A., Robert H. Bates, David L. Epstein, Ted Robert Gurr, Michael B. Lustik,
Monty G. Marshall, Jay Ulfelder, and Mark Woodward. ’A Global Model for Forecasting
Political Instability.’ American Journal of Political Science 54, no. 1 (January 2010): 190–208.
doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2009.00426.x.
33 World Bank. World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Security, and Development.
Washington DC: World Bank, 2011, table 2.1, p. 81
HCSS Report 33
T h e D e m o c r at i c R e p u b l i c o f C o n g o
Mobutu remained in power for 32 years and renamed the country Zaire in 1971.
During his rule the intensity of conflicts declined but the country was never
really stable. Several rebellions aimed at ousting the dictator from power
emerged at the end of the 1970s. The ‘Shaba rebellions’ out of neighboring Angola
and Zambia in 1977-78, found their origin in the prior secessionist struggle in
Katanga. However, they did not mobilize popular support and were ultimately
defeated by the national army, the Forces Armées Zaïroises (FAZ), assisted by
Western allies.
In the summer of 1996, a crisis erupted when Kivu politicians threatened to expel
a Congolese Tutsi group, the Banyamulenge, from Congo. Locally, Tutsis were
HCSS Report 35
T he D emocratic R epublic of C ongo
In October 1996, the Alliance des Forces Démocratiques pour la Libération du Congo
(AFDL) was formed in Kigali, Rwanda. This armed group was primarily organized
by Rwanda and Uganda, which provided it with training, equipment and bases,
and was commanded by Laurent Kabila.38 As his march across the Congo towards
Kinshasa proceeded, AFDL’s popular support grew. The weakened and
disorganized Zairian army was unable to prevent the invasion. Following AFDL’s
swift advance, Mobuto fled Kinshasa in May 1997 and Laurent Kabila declared
himself the president of the country that was renamed the Democratic Republic
of Congo (DRC).
37 Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights (OHCHR). ’Democratic Republic of the
Congo, 1993 - 2003,’
38 Rwanda, Uganda and Angola provided training, equipment and bases to the ADFL. Schatzberg,
Michael G. ’Beyond Mobuto: Kabila and the Congo.’ Journal of Democracy 8, no. 4 (October,
1997): 70-84.
Over the course of this interstate warfare a stalemate emerged. The DRC was de
facto partitioned. The eastern zone was controlled by the RCD. Kabila controlled
the western provinces. He also incorporated Interahamwe/ex-FAR Rwandan
forces into his army and forged an alliance with Congolese guerillas, the Mai-
Mai. The Mai-Mai, in turn, extended the alliance to Rwandan and Burundian
insurgency groups, who were consequently provided with arms and political
support from Kinshasa.40 On the other end, the Rwanda-Uganda cooperation
faltered, causing the RCD to split violently into factions with rivaling spheres
of influence. Additionally, another rebel movement was created over the course
of 2003, the Mouvement de Libération du Congo (MLC) led by Jean-Pierre Bemba.
With support from Uganda it was soon gaining prominence in northern Congo.41
HCSS Report 37
T he D emocratic R epublic of C ongo
Upon Kabila’s assassination on January 16, 2001, his son Joseph Kabila became
president of the DRC. He caused a breakthrough by actively engaging in the
national dialogue for a new institutional framework. Separate peace treaties were
signed with Rwanda and Uganda. From September 2002 onwards, Zimbabwean,
Angolan, Namibian, Rwandan and Ugandan troops began to pull out from
Congolese territory. This development was welcomed by the international
community, but it also left the eastern provinces in a power vacuum filled by
militias, criminal networks and proxies of foreign state actors.43
In December 2002, in Sun City, South Africa, the Global and Inclusive Agreement
on the Transition in the Democratic Republic of Congo was signed by the
government, MLC, RCD and most of the opposition parties. Based on the
Agreement, a new transitional government, composed of representatives from
armed and unarmed opposition parties would construct the steps towards
general elections. The new constitution was promulgated subsequently on
February 18, 2006. Notwithstanding the fragility of the state of affairs, the
transitional authorities did succeed in organizing the first democratic
presidential and parliamentary elections in 2006, largely funded by donor
nations. Kabila was elected in a second-round vote, judged by international
observers as relatively free and fair, even though some violent clashes occurred.
42 Angola, DRC, Namibia, Rwanda, Uganda and Zimbabwe were signatories to the Lusaka
Ceasefire Agreement.
43 ‘Report of the Panel of Experts on the illegal exploitation of natural resources and other forms
of wealth of the Democratic Republic of Congo.’ United Nations, October 2003, and: ’Interim
report of the Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic of the Congo.’ United Nations,
January 2007.
The local dynamics from 2006 onwards were shaped by a hostile residue of
warring groups (see Figure 10), ethnic tensions, and complete lack of state
services. Defected general Laurent Nkunda and his militia CNDP44 continued to
battle the Congolese army. The Hutu army FDLR45 staged attacks on the civilian
population. Additionally, the Mai-Mai guerilla groups, excluded from the
transition process, did not disarm and also contributed to local instability.
160
140
44 CNDP is the acronym for Congrès National pour la Défense du Peuple, an armed group
dominated by Congolese Tutsis and backed by Rwanda, which was established in 2006.
120
45 FDLR is the acronym of Forces Démocratiques de Libération du Rwanda, a militia which is
composed of ex-FAR and Interahamwe fighters.
100
80
60 HCSS Report 39
40
T he D emocratic R epublic of C ongo
DRC President Kabila devised informal bilateral deals with Rwanda’s President
Kagame and their Ugandan counterpart Museveni to open a joint-assault on
specific faction-controlled areas.46 In early 2009, Rwandan forces and the FARDC
launched a joint operation against the FDLR in the Kivu provinces. The operation
only dispersed rebel groups temporarily rather than defeated them. However,
Rwanda put pressure on the CNDP to disarm and arrested its leader Laurent
Nkunda in January 2009. Concurrently, the DRC signed a peace agreement with
the CNDP, which declared the intention to be integrated into the FARDC and to
fight the FDLR.
In April 2012 former CNDP soldiers in the FARDC mutinied and formed a new
armed group, the March 23 Movement (M23), under leadership Bosco Ntaganda.
The group claimed that the Congolese government failed to keep its side of the
agreement on the integration of former CNDP soldiers into the FARDC signed
on March 23, 2009. In November 2012, M23 took over Goma, the provincial capital
of North Kivu. According to the UN expert groups, Rwanda and Uganda have
supported the M23 group with weapons financed by minerals (tungsten and
tantalum), smuggled across the border from mines in the eastern DRC.47 Since
the beginning of the rebellion 500,000 people have been displaced. 48
To sum up, the modern history of the DRC is characterized by repeated outbreaks
of violence and lingering conflict between numerous stakeholders, ranging from
the state and the national army, to various ethnic groups, rival militias and
neighboring countries. The lack of national cohesion at the time that the DRC
46 This idea was made public in the Nairobi Communiqué, a DRC-Rwanda statement on joint
military engagement in the event hostilities fail to cease.
47 Agshin Mehdiyev, ’Letter Dated 26 June 2012 from the Chair of the Security Council
Committee Established Pursuant to Resolution 1533 (2004) Concerning the Democratic
Republic of the Congo Addressed to the President of the Security Council,’ June 26, 2012,
http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=S/2012/348/Add.1.
48 BBC, ’UN to Target DR Congo Rebel Group,’ BBC, October 19, 2012, sec. Africa, http://www.
bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-20013725.
The conflict still continues today and the end of violence in the DRC is not in
sight, with militias and soldiers being regularly involved in massive human
rights abuses against civilians, including sexual violence. The ongoing instability
hampers economic development. The human cost of the conflict has been
unprecedented. For these reasons, the crisis in the DRC has been one of the worst
humanitarian crises in history.
HCSS Report 41
C oltan mining in the D R C
This chapter gives an overview of coltan mining in the DRC. It starts with a
discussion of tantalum resources in the DRC and tantalum mining in the period
before the First Congo War. Next, it discusses the first coltan boom of the early
2000s, and the second coltan boom of 2006-2010. It then focuses on the practical
organization of coltan mining and trading in the DRC.
Precise data on artisanal mining employment in the DRC are not available but it
was estimated that coltan mining and trade employed around 300,000 in the DRC
in 2009. More generally, it has been estimated that artisanal mining (including
that of other minerals) supports up to 16% of DRC’s population.52
Some studies claim that the DRC’s tantalum resources account for more than
60% of global resources. While this claim was effective in drawing public
attention to coltan and its role in the conflict in the DRC, it does not stand up to
HCSS Report 43
C oltan mining in the D R C
scrutiny. Based on the results of earlier geological exploration, Burt estimated the
most likely resources of tantalum in the DRC at 55 million pounds of Ta2O5.53 This
translates into 8% of the world’s resource base. While this number indicates the
presence of significant resources in the DRC, these are far behind the tantalum
resources of Brazil and Australia, which together account for about 60% of the
most likely resources (see Chapter 1).
The troubles in Zaire in the 1980s caused economic difficulties for the company
and the crash of tin prices in 1985 led SOMINKI to close some of its industrial
mines in eastern Congo. In response, SOMNIKI decided to let individual miners
engage in artisanal mining on its concessions. Some of the laid-off workers
became artisanal miners.56 In 1991, Congo’s production reached 57 tonnes of
coltan concentrate or 16 tonnes of tantalum content.57 However, the decline of
state institutions and the deterioration of infrastructure under the rule of
Mobutu led to a sharp fall in production. In 1995 it dropped to just 1 tonne. In the
same year, the Belgian shareholders of SOMINKI sold their shares to a Canadian
53 Burt, Richard, Tantalum – a rare metal in abundance? T.I.C. Bulletin, No.141, March 2010. This
estimate exclude the Manono mine in Katanga province.
54 Tegera, A., M. Sofia and D.Johnson, ’The Coltan Phenomenon: How a rare mineral has
changed the life of the population of war-torn North Kivu province in the East of the
Democratic Republic of Congo’, Pole Institute, 2002
55 Ibid, p.6
56 Pourtier, Roland. The Mining Economy in the Kivu and Its Regional Implications: Report
Following a Mission to North Kivu, South Kivu and Rwanda 17 April-9 May 2004. INICA, 2004.
http://archive.niza.nl/docs/200603061614031069.pdf.
57 USGS
company, Barno.58 With the beginning of the First Congo war in 1996 industrial
mining of tantalum ceased completely (see Figure 11).
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
58 Willum, B., Foreign Aid to Rwanda: Purely Beneficial or Contributing to War? Dissertation,
University of Copenhagen, 2001, p.41
HCSS Report 45
C oltan mining in the D R C
Interviews with miners conducted by the Pole Institute in the early 2000s show
that despite the high risks (low physical safety in mines due to landslides and
collapsing mine walls; insecurity created by armed rebel groups and criminals),
coltan mining was viewed as a more attractive activity than agriculture.60 Coltan
mining also became more profitable than mining other minerals, such as gold or
diamonds. As a result there was a mass exodus of people to coltan mining sites.
The enormous expansion of coltan mining also brought substantial money to
eastern Congo. A local chief commented:
Even children were caught in this fever. Many of them saw coltan mining as
much more promising use of their time then schooling. Thousands of children,
sometimes barely older than twelve, worked in mines. A teacher interviewed in
2000 lamented:
‘We are witnessing the emptying of schools. More than 30% of our
children drop out of school to mine coltan. Teachers also leave
school to mine coltan.’ 62
The boom was very short-lived, however. Prices started to fall rapidly in early
2001 and by August 2001 they crashed to approximately the same level as in 1999
and early 2000, i.e. to their pre-boom level.64 The price collapse had a direct
impact on profitability and attractiveness of artisanal mining of coltan in the
DRC. Many miners went back to agriculture or moved to other sites to mine
cassiterite and other minerals. Others started to treat coltan mining as a seasonal
activity, which they would do during the months of low agricultural
production.65 In 2002, the total coltan production in the DRC dropped by more
than 50% compared to the previous year. The total revenue from coltan mining
and trading activities declined by at least a factor of 10.
63 It typically takes several years to bring a known mineral deposit into production for industrial
mining companies.
64 Willum, B., Foreign Aid to Rwanda: Purely Beneficial or Contributing to War? Dissertation,
University of Copenhagen, 2001, p.47
65 The Kivus: The Forgotten Crucible of the Congo Conflict.
HCSS Report 47
C oltan mining in the D R C
The second coltan boom in the DRC was, to a large extent, driven by increasing
prices for tantalum. Although these price increases were more modest than
during the 2000 boom, they were still substantial enough to stimulate artisanal
production. As was mentioned before, artisanal mining is very flexible and can
react quickly to price incentives, typically much faster than industrial mining.
Figure 12 illustrates that tantalum production in the DRC has positively
correlated with tantalum prices over the last decade.
180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
$50 $75 $100 $125 $150 $175
Tantalum Price, US$ per kg
FIGURE 12: TANTALUM PRICE AND PRODUCTION (IN TONNES) IN THE DRC, 2001-2010
Figure 12.USGS
(BASED ON Tantalum
DATA) price and production in the DRC, 2001-2010 (in tonnes)
70%
66 Nest, Michael, Coltan, Polity Press, 2011, p.27
67 Global Advanced Metals, ‘World’s largest tantalum producer resumes operations’, Rest of the World
60%
January 17, 2011 http://globaladvancedmetals.com/news/announcements/2011/january/
Other Africa
world%E2%80%99s-largest-tantalum-producer-resumes-operations.aspx, accessed
50%
December 17, 2012. DRC
40% Brasil
30% Australia
48 Coltan, Congo & Conflict
20%
60
40
20
0 C oltan mining in the D R C
$50 $75 $100 $125 $150 $175
Tantalum Price, US$ per kg
Figure 12. Tantalum price and production in the DRC, 2001-2010 (in tonnes)
100%
90%
80%
70%
Rest of the World
60%
Other Africa
50%
DRC
40% Brasil
30% Australia
20%
10%
0%
2007 2009 2011
Figure
FIGURE1313:
Geographic distribution
GEOGRAPHIC of tantalum
DISTRIBUTION production,
OF TANTALUM 2007-2011 2007-2011
PRODUCTION,
18,0%
16,0%
3.5 Organization of coltan mining and trading during the booms
14,0%
Coltan mining in the eastern DRC in the early 2000s was done exclusively on an
12,0%
artisanal basis. Artisanal mining refers to mining by individuals and groups with
10,0%
minimal or no mechanization, often informally or illegallyDRC(see Chapter 1).
8,0%
Artisanal mining is often assumed to be synonymous withRwanda
small-scale mining.
6,0%
However, this does not always have to be case. The Basie mine in North Kivu
4,0%
employed at one point no less than 13,000 workers and was the largest cassiterite
mine
2,0% in the DRC, accounting for around 70% of all cassiterite exports from North
Kivu
0,0% and also some coltan.68
1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
Mining
Despite its informal nature, artisanal mining in the DRC ‘is often meticulously
organized on the micro-level, governed by multiple rule systems transcending
statutory and customary spheres.’69 The first step in the mining process is
selecting a mining site (prospecting). This step requires some expertise and
68 Zingg Wimmer, S. and F Hilgert, ’Bisie. A one-year snapshot of the DRC’s principal cassiterite
mine’, IPIS, November 2011, http://www.ipisresearch.be/att/20111128__Bisie_FHilgert_
SZingg.pdf
69 Garrett, Nicholas. ’Observations from the DRC.’ African Analyst, 1/2008. http://www.
resourceglobal.co.uk/documents/Garrett_Af_An_Feb_2008.pdf.
HCSS Report 49
C oltan mining in the D R C
A few publications reported that some mines use forced labor. This has
apparently taken place occasionally but it is unlikely to have been a widespread
practice since there is a sufficient supply of artisanal miners. Mining is still
considered as more attractive than many other occupations in the DRC and
therefore there is little need to coerce people to work in mines.
Trading
Small traders, or petits negociants in Congolese French, visit mines, buy coltan
and transport it using porters to a nearby village. Porters carry the ore in bags
over tens of kilometers, in difficult terrain and in hot and humid climate. Bigger
traders, or gros negociants, consolidate coltan bought from petits negociants and
organize its transportation to main trading centers in eastern DRC – the cities
of Goma and Bukavu. This transportation is often done by small aircraft.
70 Garrett, Nicholas. Walikale. Artisanal Cassiterite Mining and Trade in North Kivu - Implications
for Poverty Reduction and Security. Washington D.C.: Communities and Small-Scale Mining,
2008, p.37
71 Nest, Michael, Coltan, Polity Press, 2011, p.40
0
$50 $75 $100 $125 $150 $175
Tantalum Price, US$ per kg
Figure 12. Tantalum price and production in the DRC, 2001-2010 (in tonnes)
70%
Rwanda is the preferred trade route for exporting coltan from eastern Congo for
Rest of the World
60% reasons. Exports of tantalum concentrates are taxed by the DRC but are
several
Other Africa
not taxed by Rwanda. Therefore, there is a clear economic incentive to smuggle
50%
DRC
coltan
40%
to Rwanda rather than export it legally from the DRC. Imported minerals
Brasil
can be declared as minerals produced in Rwanda if they undergo further
30% Australia
processing that adds 30% to their value.72 Rwanda also has the best transport
20%
connection with eastern Congo. As a result, a significant amount of coltan
exported
10% from Rwanda is likely to be of Congolese origin.73 Figure 14 illustrates
that
0%
since 1999 reported production numbers in DR Congo and Rwanda moved
very closely together.
2007 This might be an indirect indication
2009 2011 of ‘leakage’ of
Congolese coltan to Rwanda.
Figure 13 Geographic distribution of tantalum production, 2007-2011
18,0%
16,0%
14,0%
12,0%
10,0%
DRC
8,0%
Rwanda
6,0%
4,0%
2,0%
0,0%
1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
Figure 14: Share of the DRC and Rwanda in global production of tantalum
(Based on USGS data)
72 Bleischwitz, Raimund, Monika Dittrich, and Chiara Pierdicca. ’Coltan from Central Africa,
International Trade and Implications for Any Certification.’ Resources Policy 37, no. 1 (March
2012): 19–29. This is quite common rule in many countries.
73 Nest, Michael, Coltan, Polity Press, 2011, p.23
HCSS Report 51
C oltan mining in the D R C
Chief of mine 10
Gros negociants 13
Comptoir 10
Taxes to RCD-Goma 7
Armed groups 11
Many mines operate as a barter economy, where workers retain a fixed percentage
of the coltan they produce. At these mines coltan replaces money in most
transactions including the purchasing of food supplies, tools and services, i.e. it
serves as a medium of exchange. Porters, like miners are also often paid in coltan.
In some mines, creuseurs are getting paid per kilogram of coltan they produce.
Annual income of artisanal coltan and cassiterite miners in North and South
Kivu provinces has been estimated at US$800. This is relatively low, especially
compared to an income of circa US$2,500 per year in the diamond fields of Kasaï
Occidental and Kasaï Oriental provinces and of US$2,200 per year in the copper
74 Similar share – slightly more than 30% - was obtained for cassiterite mining in eastern DRC.
See Garrett, Nicholas. ’Observations from the DRC.’ African Analyst, 1/2008
belt of Katanga Province.75 These estimates, however, are very approximate. For
example, it was reported that the cassiterite creusers can earn up US$100 on a
productive day. However, when adjusted for the high cost of food at mining sites
(since all food has to be delivered by foot over large distances), it rarely exceeds
on average US$5 per day in real terms.76
HCSS Report 53
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
4 Coltan’s connections to
the conflict in the DRC
The goal of this chapter is to examine the connection between coltan mining and
violence in the DRC. A better understanding of the role of coltan in the Congo
conflicts is essential to assess the effectiveness of policy initiatives aimed at
reducing the violence associated with conflict minerals (see chapter 5). The
chapter analyzes the role of coltan during the First and Second Congo Wars and
the Kivu Conflict in Eastern Congo. It describes how armed groups use the
mining and trading of coltan to finance their activities. This chapter also
discusses some issues related to the motivation of armed groups engaged in
coltan mining and in particular the debate on causes of civil conflict – ‘greed
versus grievances’. The analysis underlines some important nuances to the
widely held views that coltan is the root cause of conflict in the DRC.
It should be stated from the outset that, overall, coltan has been of minor
importance during the conflict, except for brief periods during the tantalum
price booms. Other minerals mined in eastern Congo have generated
substantially higher revenues than coltan. After the end of the first coltan boom
in 2001, many artisanal miners abandoned coltan mining and coltan production
and exports dropped sharply. The main result was that coltan mining and trading
HCSS Report 55
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
Figure 14. Share of the DRC and Rwanda in global production of tantalum
Stages in the supply chain Actors in the supply chain Share of revenue, %
Mining Miners (team of creuseurs) 17
have become onlyChiefofofmarginal
mine importance as a10 source of revenue for armed
Trading groups compared other
Petits minerals and especially
negociants 10to cassiterite.
77
Gros negociants 13
Evidence fromComptoir
the Enough Project, which mainly 10 relied on data from official
Taxesbut
Congolese sources to RCD-Goma 7
adjusted them for underreporting, shows that in 2008
Other licenses and fees 22
coltan accounted only for 6% of estimated profits captured by armed groups
Armed groups 11
from trade in conflict minerals originating in the Kivu provinces (see Figure 15).
Export price in the DRC 100%
Our focus on coltan is related more to the notoriety that coltan received in the
public
Table 2 Distribution debaterevenue,
of coltan rather than on its economic importance. In addition, most
c. 2000
considerations related to the role of coltan in the conflict have direct relevance
(Based on Nest, 2011, Table 2.1)
for other conflict minerals.
Gold
28%
Cassiterite
Wolframite 62%
4%
Coltan
6%
FIGURE 15: DISTRIBUTION OF ARMED GROUPS’ ESTIMATED PROFITS FROM TRADE IN 4 MAJOR
Figure 15. Distribution of armed groups’ estimated profits from trade in 4 major minerals, 2008
MINERALS, 2008
(Source: Enough Project, A Comprehensive Approach to Congo’s Conflict Minerals, April 2009)
(SOURCE: ENOUGH PROJECT, A COMPREHENSIVE APPROACH TO CONGO’S CONFLICT MINERALS,
APRIL 2009)
Although coltan was clearly not the main cause of the outbreak of the First Congo
War, this does not mean that the role of other minerals can be ruled out as an
influence. Even before the AFDL took power in Kinshasa, it started to award
lucrative mineral deals (not involving coltan) to foreign companies in exchange
for cash down payments amounting to an estimated US$70 million.78 This cash
proved to be very important in funding the AFDL’s military efforts especially at
the final stages of the First Congo war. This type of conflict financing, the sale of
‘booty futures’, i.e. exploitation rights to natural resources that combatants only
hope to capture in battle, has unfortunately been quite common in Africa.79 In
the subsequent stages of the conflict in the DRC the reliance on minerals as
source of funding has only increased.
78 Stearns, Jason. Dancing in the Glory of Monsters. Collapse of the Congo and the Great War of
Africa. New York: Public Affairs, 2012., p.287
79 Ross, Michael. ’Booty Futures,’ May 2005. http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/polisci/faculty/ross/
bootyfutures.pdf.
HCSS Report 57
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
As the prices of tantalum started to raise in the year 2000, the RCD tried to
exploit the boom by creating a new trading company, SOMIGL (Société Minière
des Grands Lacs), and granting it an export monopoly on all coltan produced in
RCD-controlled territory. Additionally, a new tax of US$ 10 per kilogram of coltan
exported from RCD territory was imposed. 81 The tantalum price boom helped
to increase the financial means available to the RCD. According to interviews,
in 2000, the RCD rebel government raised up to US$ 1 million per month for
exporting 100-150 tonnes of coltan vs. US$ 200,000 per month for exporting
diamonds.82
The period when coltan brought substantial revenues to armed groups was short-
lived, however. Many negociants refused to accept the lower prices offered by
SOMIGL. It led to the establishment of a black market in coltan and the
smuggling of coltan out of the DRC, which eventually undermined the purpose
for which the SOMIGL was created. Then, in early 2001, tantalite prices started
to collapse. The price drop meant the end of SOMIGL, which was abolished in
March 2001.
80 Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other
Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo (United Nations, April 2001), http://
www.un.org/News/dh/latest/drcongo.htm.
81 Jeroen Cuvelier and Tim Raeymaekers, Supporting the War Economy in the DRC: European
companies and the coltan trade.
82 Karen Hayes and Richard Burge, Coltan Mining in the Democratic Republic of Congo: How
tantalum-using industries can commit to the reconstruction of the DRC.
In addition to backing the RCD rebels, Rwanda also played a more direct role in
coltan exploitation, especially through the activities undertaken by the Rwandan
Patriotic Army (RPA). The army provided protection to the miners and
companies extracting coltan in exchange for sharing their profits. During the
coltan boom, Rwanda even moved prisoners to the Congo, and used them for
mining coltan in exchange for reduced sentences and small cash allowances.
According to the UN Group of Experts, the Rwandan government set up a ‘Congo
Desk’ within the RPA’s External Relations Department, which was tasked with
overseeing the mining of Congolese resources and facilitating trade with Western
companies. Coltan mined in the DRC was often transported to Rwanda’s capital
Kigali with RPA helicopters. The RPA was closely involved in the operations of
companies that were buying and exporting coltan, such as Rwanda Metals and
Grands Lacs Metals.83 It was estimated that the RCD and Rwandan army together
pocketed approximately US$ 10 million of profit from coltan mining.84
Other armed groups besides the RCD and the Rwandan and Ugandan armies also
benefited or tried to benefit from mineral resources. In the early 2000s, coltan
mines in the provinces of North and South Kivu were also controlled by
Congolese Mai-Mai groups and Rwandan Hutu rebel groups (see Table 3).85
Table 3 also shows that coltan was only of one the various sources of mineral
revenue for the armed groups.
83 Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other
Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo (United Nations, April 2001), http://
www.un.org/News/dh/latest/drcongo.htm.
84 Nest, Michael, Coltan, Polity Press, 2011, Table 3.3, p.94
85 Nest, Michael, Coltan, Polity Press, 2011, p.85
HCSS Report 59
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
Pro-government forces
DRC army √ √ √
Zimbabwean army √
Angolan army √
Mai Mai √ √ √ √
Anti-government forces
Rwandan army √ √ √ √ √
Ugandan army √ √ √ √ √
RCD-Goma √ √ √ √ √
RCD-ML √ √ √ √ √
MLC √ √ √
Competition over the control of the coltan mines often led to violent
confrontations between the different armed actors. The number of clashes
between the Rwandan army and the Mai-Mai intensified during the coltan boom
between May and December 2000. Some of Rwanda’s attacks directly targeted
coltan mines with the aim of capturing stocks of mined coltan.86 Clashes over
coltan and gold also took place between the Mai-Mai, the Ugandan army and the
MLC rebel group in the Ituri district of Province Orientale.87
86 Addendum to the report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural
Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo
(United Nations, November 2001), http://www.unhchr.ch/Huridocda/Huridoca.
nsf/%28Symbol%29/S.2001.1072.En?Opendocument.
87 Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other
Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo.
Kivu Conflict
Studies show that armed groups continue to profit from minerals in eastern DRC
during the current stage of the conflict. Table 4 shows that coltan remained one
of various sources of mineral revenue of the armed groups between 2006 and
2008. According to a study in 2009 by IPIS, a Belgian research center, slightly
more than 50% of mining sites in North and South Kivus were controlled by
armed groups.88 The Congolese army, FARDC, is also involved in the illegal
exploitation of natural resources.
Mai Mai √ √ √ √
PARECO √ √ √
FDLR √ √ √ √
CNDP √ √ √ √
88 Spittaels, Steven and Filip Hilger. Accompanying Note on the Interactive Map of Militarised
Mining Areas in the Kivus. Antwerp, Belgium: IPIS, August 2009.
89 These include advocacy groups such as ‘Global Witness’ and ‘Enough’
HCSS Report 61
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
mineral deposits’ is the primary motivation behind the war there.90 However,
many analysts disagree with the notion that the exploitation of natural resources
is the root cause of the conflict. Rather, it is argued that armed groups use trade
in minerals to finance their activities, which enables the groups to survive, and
thus minerals fuel and protract the conflict.91
In the case of such a complex and prolonged conflict as in the DRC, it is not easy
to determine whether trade in minerals serves merely as an instrument to reach
political objectives or whether profiteering is a dominant goal on its own. The
motivations of different armed groups cannot be observed directly. There is
always a large number of interrelated and dynamic factors that affect the
decision-making of such groups. Disentangling and weighting the relative
importance of such factors is an intricate task. A related academic debate on
‘greed versus grievance’ as causes of conflict has not been settled either.
90 "Faced With a Gun, What Can You Do?" War and the Militarisation of Mining in Eastern Congo.
(Global Witness, July 2009),p.15, http://www.globalwitness.org/library/global-witness-report-
faced-gun-what-can-you-do.
91 This stream is represented for instance in the following publications: Steven Spittaels and
Filip Hilgert, ’Are Congo’s mines the main target of the armed groups on its soil?’; Harrison
Mitchell and Nicholas Garrett, Beyond Conflict: Reconfiguring approaches to the regional trade
in minerals from Eastern DRC; Louise Anten, Strengthening governance in a post-conflict district
of the Democratic Republic of Congo: a study of Ituri; Dominic Johnson, Who's In Charge? Putting
the Mineral Trade in Eastern DRC under International Control: An Overview (Pole Institute, August
2010), http://www.pole-institute.org/documents/pole-mines-En%5B1%5D.pdf; Ruben de
Koning, Artisanal mining and postconflict reconstruction in the Democratic Republic of the Congo,
SIPRI Background Paper (Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, October 2009),
http://books.sipri.org/files/misc/SIPRIBP0910b.pdf; Ruben de Koning, Controlling Conflict
Resources in the Democratic Republic of the Congo, SIPRI Policy Brief (Stockholm International
Peace Research Institute, July 2010), http://books.sipri.org/files/misc/SIPRIPB1007.pdf.
The debate was initiated by a series of influential studies by Paul Collier and
Anke Hoeffler that statistically examined the relationship between civil war
and quantitative indicators of grievance. They found that indicators of
grievance, such as inequality, political oppression, and ethnic and religious
divisions, were not closely associated with a higher risk of civil war. At the
same time, primary commodity exports and other economic variables were
found to have stronger explanatory power. They concluded that ‘factors which
determine the financial and military viability of a rebellion are more
important than objective grounds for grievance.’92
92 Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler. “Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars.” Oxford Economic Papers,
56 (2004): 563–595.
93 For example: Nathan, Laurie. The Frightful Inadequacy of Most of the Statistics: A Critique of
Collier and Hoeffler on Causes of Civil War. Discussion Paper No.11. Crisis States Research
Centre, September 2005. http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/28337/1/dp11.pdf.
94 Ross, Michae L. “What Do We Know About Natural Resources and Civil War?” Journal of Peace
Research 41, no. 3 (2004): 337–356.
HCSS Report 63
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
that both civil war and resource dependence may be independently caused by
some unaccounted third variable, such as weak institutions.
However, in recent years there has been some convergence between these two
theories. Proponents of each agree that both ‘greed’ and ‘grievance’ factors
play a role in conflict. Having conducted a thorough review of existing
literature on conflict and security, the World Bank, which is often associated
with the ‘greed’ theory,95 recently concluded in its World Development Report:
‘explanations for conflict based purely on economic motives are inadequate.’96
The report continued:
Interestingly, the expert groups on the DRC assembled by the UN, whose reports
were instrumental in raising awareness on the role of minerals in Congo’s
conflict, came to differing conclusions with regard to the motivation of armed
groups in eastern DRC in recent years. In 2001 the Panel of Experts stated that ‘[t]
he conflict in the Democratic Republic of the Congo has become mainly about
access, control and trade of five key mineral resources: coltan, diamonds, copper,
cobalt and gold.’98 However, in 2010 the Group of Experts concluded that
95 This is due to the fact that Paul Collier worked for the World Bank when he put forward the
‘greed’ theory.
96 World Bank. World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Security, and Development.
Washington DC: World Bank, 2011.,p.81
97 Ibid., p.81
98 ‘Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other
Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo.’ United Nations, April 2001.
We tend to agree with the latter conclusion and believe that in most cases armed
groups’ involvement in mineral mining and trading in eastern DRC is a symptom
rather than the root cause of the problem. First, it is difficult to deny that various
grievances (access to land, citizenship issues, security threats in neighboring
states, etc.) and consequently political and security goals were at the origin of
the initial outbreak of conflict. Second, such a protracted and deadly conflict as
the one in the DRC, which has been characterized by numerous mass atrocities,
generates its own grievances, and revenge and score setting become driving
forces in their own right. Third, if the presence of mineral resources is the
main motivation for violence in the Kivu provinces, then why in other mineral-
rich provinces in the DRC, such as Katanga or Maniema, has it been
comparatively peaceful?
Finally, for some armed groups minerals were not the largest source of revenues.
For example, the CNDP (Tutsi-based group backed by the Rwanda; it was
99 Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2010/596: Final Report 2010 of
the Security Council Committee Established Pursuant to Resolution 1533 (2004) Concerning the
Democratic Republic of the Congo (United Nations, 2010), 78, http://www.un.org/ga/search/
view_doc.asp?symbol=S/2010/596. However, it also added that "economic motivations are
increasingly driving a significant portion of armed actors", p. 75
100 Dominic Johnson, ’Minerals and Conflict in Eastern DRC,’ July 2009, http://www.pole-institute.
org/site%20web/echos/echo114.htm.
101 IPIS, Mapping Conflict Motives: M23 (Antwerp, Belgium: IPIS, November 2012), http://www.
ipisresearch.be/publications_detail.php?id=390.
HCSS Report 65
C oltan ’ s connections to the conflict in the D R C
integrated into the Congolese army in 2009), derived less than 15% of its revenue
from the mineral trade.102
This illustrates the point that armed groups ‘have no organic link with minerals’
and will switch to exploit agriculture or other natural resources to finance their
activities.103 The 2010 UN report confirms that minerals are not the only source of
revenue used by the armed groups. Other natural resources such as timber, land,
fishing, poaching and charcoal are also used to fund activities of these groups,
diminishing the relative importance of the mineral trade for the armed groups’
survival. 104
At the same time, minerals have been a major (and often the main) source of
revenues for many armed groups. For example, the FLDR (ethnic Hutu militia led
by organizers of the 1994 Rwandan genocide) derived up to 75% of its revenues
from minerals, mostly from gold, and the 85th brigade of the FARDC up to
95%.105 This is because mining, and especially artisanal mining, is a war-resilient
economic activity. Minerals are among the few products that can be produced in
a war-ravaged country without any significant investment or sophisticated
equipment. Mining is more war-resilient especially compared to manufacturing
or technology-intensive services, which are easily disrupted in times of war.
Mining is also more war-resilient compared to another primary economic
activity – agriculture. It is more difficult to cause permanent damage to artisanal
mines than to permanently destroy crops and animals. Minerals can also easily be
sold on the global market for hard currency and are often easy to smuggle across
borders. Furthermore, mining is also geographically concentrated, which makes
it much easier to control. Taxing minerals or controlling mineral production
directly were typically the easiest and the most lucrative ways for armed groups
to raise revenue.
102 Nicholas Garrett and Harrison Mitchell, Trading Conflict for Development. Utilising the Trade in
Minerals in Eastern DR Cong for Development, April 2009, 6.
103 Johnson, ’Minerals and Conflict in Eastern DRC.’
104 United Nations News Centre, ’UN News - DR Congo: UN Experts Outline Sources of Funding
for Armed Rebels,’ UN News Service Section, December 30, 2011, http://www.un.org/apps/
news/story.asp?Cr1=congo&NewsID=40865&Cr=democratic#.UIhgJ1FqCxV.
105 Garrett, Nicholas, and Harrison Mitchell. Trading Conflict for Development. Utilising the Trade
in Minerals in Eastern DR Cong for Development, April 2009, p.6
5 Policy initiatives
106 Didier Verbruggen, Evie Francq, and Jeroen Cuvelier. 2011. Guide to Current Mining Reform
Initiatives in Eastern DRC. Antwerp: International Peace Information Service. http://www.
ipisresearch.be/att/20110412_Guide_Mining_Reform_EDRC.pdf.
107 Michael, Nest. 2011. Coltan. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press
108 Conflict Minerals Disclosure Rule. SEC’s Actions and Stakeholder-Developed Initiatives.
2012. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Accountability Office. http://www.gao.gov/
assets/600/592458.pdf.
109 Summary of In-Region Initiatives That Support Conflict-Free Minerals Sourcing. 2012. Public-
Private Alliance for Responsible Minerals Trade. http://www.resolv.org/site-ppa/files/2012/06/
Summary-of-In-region-Initiatives-09.21.12.pdf.
HCSS Report 67
P olicy initiatives
Nonetheless, there are also substantial differences between them. Some of them
are focused specifically on eastern DRC and coltan, while others are global in
nature and cover all conflict minerals or even all extractive industries. Some of
them have been put forward by international organizations or governments,
while others have been developed by the industry.
110 Gold stands out among other conflict minerals. Gold is at least two orders of magnitude more
expensive per unit of weight than the other three conflict minerals. Very high price makes
gold much easier to conceal and smuggle. Therefore gold might deserve a special attention in
efforts to break the connection between minerals and conflict in eastern DRC.
111 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 2011. OECD Due Diligence
Guidance for Responsible Supply Chains of Minerals from Conflict-Affected and High-Risk
Areas. Paris: OECD Publishing.
guidelines for risk mitigation in the supply chain of tin, tantalum and tungsten.
The Guidance received broad support from international organizations,
governments, the private sector and NGOs. Although the Guidance is not legally
binding, it is an important tool for ‘naming and shaming’ companies that do not
follow its requirements. It also provides a basis for other initiatives aimed at the
supply chain of conflict minerals. The Guidance was endorsed, among others,
by the UN Group of Experts on the DRC in its 2010 report,112 as well as by the
International Conference of the Great Lakes Region in the Lusaca Declaration in
December 2010.
In 2008 the World Bank launched the EITI++ initiative. Whereas the EITI focuses
mainly on revenue transparency, EITI++ goes beyond that to cover all the stages
in the natural resource value chain: from extraction to processing, managing
revenue, and efficient utilization of wealth derived from natural resources. The
main tool of the EITI++ is technical assistance to participating countries on such
issues such as improving the quality of contracts with multinational companies,
monitoring mining operations and the collection of related taxes and royalties,
managing price volatility, and investing revenues effectively for national
development.
112 Final Report of the Group of Experts on the DRC, Submitted in Accordance with Paragraph 6 of
Security Council Resolution 1896 (2009). 2010. UN Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic
of the Congo. http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=S/2010/596, p.86
HCSS Report 69
P olicy initiatives
Industry initiatives
Responding to pressure from the UN, NGOs, and public opinion, industry has
also developed several initiatives. The International Tin Research Institute (ITRI),
a UK-based trade association, proposed the Tin Supply Chain Initiative (iTSCI)
in 2009 to improve the traceability of cassiterite sourced in eastern DRC. Its
practical implementation started in summer of 2010 in South Kivu. It involves
documenting the flow of minerals from mines to exporters (comptoirs), tagging
bags with minerals at mines and keeping a data recording system. After the
Congolese government introduced the mining ban in 2010, the main focus of
the iTSCI moved to Rwanda, where it has achieved some success.113 More recently
it started to re-engage with DRC in particular in the Katanga province.
Other categories
Other initiatives have a supporting and enabling role – they aim to develop tools
and instruments that would facilitate the traceability of minerals. Such tools
should help to improve effectiveness of the implementation of other sourcing
initiatives.
The German Federal Institute for Geoscience and Natural Resource (BGR)
developed a system called Certified Trading Chains (CTC) which draws on the
results of their Analytical Fingerprint (AFP) analysis (see above) which has been
expanded from coltan alone to cover tin and tungsten ore concentrates. Feedback
from these projects has been used to inform the development of a regional
certification system under the International Conference on the Great Lakes
Region (ICGLR). Certification forms an integral part of their Regional Initiative
against the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources (RINR) which aims to foster
113 De Koning, Ruben. 2011. Conflict Minerals in the Democratic Republic of the Congo: Aligning
Trade and Security Interventions. SIPRI. http://books.sipri.org/files/PP/SIPRIPP27.pdf.
good governance in the mining sector across the DRC and its neighboring
countries.114
Some other initiatives will be discussed in more detail in the next sub-section.
1) The first perspective deals with the question: How important are conflict
minerals to the continuation of violence in eastern Congo? Or, in other words,
if the initiatives are implemented perfectly, will they stop the violence or, at
least, significantly reduce it? This is the question of effectiveness.
114 German Federal Institute for Geosciences and Natural Resources (BGR), ’Mineral Certification
at the BGR,’ BGR, accessed November 12, 2012, http://www.bgr.bund.de/EN/Themen/Min_
rohstoffe/CTC/Home/CTC_node_en.html.
HCSS Report 71
P olicy initiatives
Effectiveness
The thesis that minerals have been vital for financing at least some of the armed
groups operating in eastern DRC is not contentious. Consequently, many
observers argue that interventions that will stop (or substantially decrease) the
flow of revenues to armed groups from the mineral trade should also undermine
either their motivation to engage in violence or their means to do so (or both). As
a result, the level of violence is expected to decline. This, however, is much more
disputable and suggests that the driving factors behind the conflict are more
complex than can be captured by a sole causal motive.
Issues relating to effectiveness largely boil down to the ‘Greed vs. Grievance’
question that was discussed in the previous chapter. Briefly recapping that
discussion we can say that most experts do not see minerals (i.e. ‘greed’) as the
root cause of the conflict in eastern DRC.115 Even many active advocates of conflict
minerals initiatives in the NGO community tend to agree that minerals are just
one of several drivers of the conflict.116
Armed groups need financial resources to sustain themselves, and this remains
true whether profit is their primary motive or not. The most observable methods
that armed groups use to profit from minerals are controlling the sites where
minerals are mined and levying taxes and fees on mineral production and
miners.117 If armed groups can no longer bring coltan and other minerals from
those mines to the international market (as proposed in many initiatives) it
would automatically have a negative effect on the financial resources available
to armed groups. In practice, however, armed groups seem more likely to change
the tactics they use to profit from minerals rather than to cease violence.
115 For example, De Koning, Ruben. 2011. Conflict Minerals in the Democratic Republic of the
Congo: Aligning Trade and Security Interventions. SIPRI, and Nest, Michael. 2011. Coltan.
Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.
116 A Comprehensive Approach to Congo’s Conflict Minerals. 2009. Washington D.C.: The Enough
Project. http://www.enoughproject.org/files/Comprehensive-Approach.pdf.
117 IPIS estimates that armed groups directly controlled slightly above 50% of all mines they
identified and mapped. See: Spittaels, Steven , and Filip Hilger. 2009. Accompanying Note on
the Interactive Map of Militarised Mining Areas in the Kivus. Antwerp, Belgium: IPIS. https://
docs.google.com/viewer?url=http://ipisresearch.eu/download.php?id%3D267.
If armed groups continue to control trade routes they can shift the burden of
taxation to the mineral trade rather than production. They can also tax supplies
to miners. This has been happening already in several areas of eastern DRC. For
example, a report by the IPIS mentions that the FDLR supplied the Misisi gold
mines in the Fizi district of South Kivu with goods and foodstuffs, trading them
for gold, which they sell in Tanzania.118 An off-site taxation by ex-CNDP soldiers
that controlled some of the major roads to Goma and taxed all passing transports
is another example of situations where rebels do not have to control mines
directly to benefit from mineral trade.119 Organized looting could also become
more attractive for armed groups. After the FARDC (the Congolese armed forces)
conducted several military operations against the FDLR and certain Mai-Mai
militia and managed to take control over some mining areas from these groups
in 2009-2010, there was a reported increase in looting attacks on mines and
villages that these groups previously controlled.120 In these looting attacks the
resident population is often brutalized and inventories of minerals and other
goods are taken. FARDC elements sometimes are also involved in looting, hiding
their identity by pretending to be rebels.121
Even if the conflict mineral initiatives are successful in reforming the mineral
trade in eastern DRC it is likely that armed groups will simply try to switch from
minerals to other sources of funding. Examples from countries (often from
Africa) affected by internal conflict suggest that there are numerous potential
opportunities to raise revenues besides minerals, ranging from timber and
agricultural products to kidnapping and piracy.122 In Sudan’s civil war it was food
aid that sometimes sustained fighting.123 Remittances from diaspora and other
types of transfers from abroad might also become a more important source of
HCSS Report 73
P olicy initiatives
revenue.124 Arguably, under current conditions in eastern DRC minerals are the
most profitable way for armed groups to raise funds, but other money-making
opportunities may become more attractive if conditions change.
The impact of a shift in the financing sources of armed groups on the level of
violence is uncertain but the possibility that violence increases instead of
decreases cannot be excluded. It should be noted that the continuation of conflict
does not require substantial funds, especially if immediate profits are not the
main motivation for armed groups. The most widely employed weapons in the
Rwandan Genocide in 1994 were very cheap machetes.
Efficiency
The discussion over effectiveness assumed that policy initiatives would be
implemented successfully, work as intended and reach their objectives. However,
in the real world implementation issues often undermine the effectiveness of
policy initiatives. It is therefore useful to look at the most notable challenges to
their successful implementation.
The most profound challenge for any policy initiative in the DRC is the fact that
government effectiveness in the DRC is very low while the level of corruption is
very high. According to the World Bank’s governance indicators, the DRC’s scores
on both of these indicators were among the worst in the world: the DRC was in
the bottom 3% of all countries in 2011.125 Neighboring countries – with the
exception of Rwanda - are not doing much better. Under these conditions the
ability of the Congolese state to implement any significant reform is severely
limited. This is extremely problematic since the involvement of Congolese public
institutions and agencies is essential for implementing a scheme for conflict-free
minerals. Weak institutions and corruption undermine the integrity of any such
scheme. Without international effort and assistance to improve government
effectiveness and to fight corruption, it is unlikely that interventions aimed at
banning conflict minerals will work well. To assess how likely it is that proposed
initiatives will be implemented as intended in a context of weak governance and
corruption, it is it is instructive to look at two examples, the mining ban and the
Kimberly Process.
124 Rwanda has played a significant part in supporting some of the rebel groups in eastern Congo.
125 World Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators, http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/pdf/
c248.pdf
One visible outcome of the ban was closer involvement and control over mineral
production and trade by the FARDC and its individual officers. FARDC managed
to take control of some mines that were previously under the control of other
armed groups. This, however, did not lead to the cessation of mining activity.
FARDC and police officers were sometimes paid to turn a blind eye to continued
activity in the mines under their control. Mines in remote areas that were under
control of other armed groups, such as the FDLR, also often continued
production. The output of the illegal mines was smuggled to neighboring
countries.
At the same time, the mining ban had a negative economic impact on artisanal
miners. It also affected many people and businesses who supplied miners with
goods and services, including farmers, traders, transport companies, etc. Around
mining sites instances of malnutrition, diseases, school drop-outs increased as
well as the number of thefts, robberies, armed attacks and murders.127 Given the
importance of artisanal mining in eastern DRC, these outcomes could have been
easily anticipated.
The mining ban was lifted on March 10, 2011, six months after it was introduced.
It had brought little if any improvements in security. The results of the ban can
126 Description of the impact of the mining ban is largely based on: Geenen, Sara. 2012. ’A
Dangerous Bet: The Challenges of Formalizing Artisanal Mining in the Democratic Republic of
Congo.’ Resources Policy 37 (3) (September): 322–330. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2009.00426.x.
127 Geenen, Sara. 2012. ’A Dangerous Bet: The Challenges of Formalizing Artisanal Mining in the
Democratic Republic of Congo.’ Resources Policy 37 (3) (September): 322–330.
doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2009.00426.x.
HCSS Report 75
P olicy initiatives
The experience with the mining ban has at least two important implications for
other initiatives related to conflict minerals. First, the mining ban was relatively
easy to implement as it was a blunt instrument affecting all mining sites (not just
rebel-held) and all exports. As a consequence, the mining ban was far more easy
to administer than any other more selective conflict mineral initiative where
administrative discretion is going to be higher and less visible, hence creating
more opportunities for corruption. Despite this fact, the enforcement of the ban
was patchy and the level of corruption among officers and state officials involved
in mineral trade increased, according to many sources. Second, following the
logic that minerals are at heart of the conflicts in eastern Congo, the mining ban
should have drastically reduced violence by stopping the flow of funding to
armed groups. In reality, this did not happen.
in Angola and the Revolutionary United Front (RUF) in Sierra Leone, hugely
benefited from the trade in blood diamonds.
The main element of the KP is the Kimberley Process Certification Scheme which
was created in 2003. Only participants in the scheme can legally trade diamonds
with each other. Rough diamonds crossing international borders should be
transported in tamper-resistant containers and accompanied by a government
validated KP certificate. Although participation in the scheme is voluntary, it
became de facto mandatory for any diamond-producing country that wishes to
export its rough diamonds to the international market, since all major importers
of diamonds are members of the KP.
How successful was the KP in achieving its goal? Its official web site claims the
following:
The joint efforts of governments, industry leaders and civil society representatives
have enabled the Kimberley Process (KP) to curb successfully the flow of conflict
diamonds in a very short period of time. Diamond experts estimate that conflict
diamonds now represent a fraction of one percent of the international trade in
diamonds, compared to estimates of up to 15% in the 1990s. That has been the KP’s
most remarkable contribution to a peaceful world…130
Indeed, conflict diamonds currently represent only a small part of the total trade.
This however, seems more a coincidence rather than a direct result of the KP. Two
main conflicts where blood diamonds played a very substantial role ended before
the KP Certification Scheme came into force. And in both cases it seems that
military actions were more instrumental than economic sanctions directed at
conflict diamonds:
• In Sierra Leone the decisive point was the British military intervention in 2000
and the capture of the RUF’s leader, Foday Sankoh, by Sierra Leonean forces
that left the RUF in disarray. In January 2002, Sierra Leonean President Kabbah
declared the eleven-year long Civil War officially over.
130 http://www.kimberleyprocess.com/web/kimberley-process/kp-basics
HCSS Report 77
P olicy initiatives
• In Angola the civil war ended soon after government troops killed Jonas
Savimbi, founder and leader of UNITA, on February 22, 2002. Less than a
month later the government announced suspension of all military operations
and UNITA rebels agreed to a cease-fire. UNITA officially demobilized its
armed forces in August 2002 and became a political party.
Despite the self-acclaimed success of the KP, many of its participants express a
general feeling of dissatisfaction with the scheme. 131 Interviews with
representatives of the diamond industry, NGOs and government officials indicate
that the perceived lack of enforcement is considered the most prominent
weakness.132 The issue of corruption was also mentioned as one the main
problems in the KP. In 2004 it was exposed that diamonds from the DRC were
being smuggled to the Republic of Congo (Congo-Brazzaville) where they were
falsely certified by government officials as being produced in that country.133
Fake certificates from DRC, Angola, Ghana and other countries continue to
surface and plague the enforcement of the KP.134
The current debates around the KP raise a very important question: what if
human rights violations are conducted by the state authorities? This is not an
abstract question for eastern DRC. The Congolese armed forces are closely
involved in the mineral mining and trade, especially after the mining ban.
This involvement has often been accompanied by illegal taxation of miners,
corruption, and in some cases human right abuses. Banning the trade in minerals
131 Holger , Meyer. 2010. ’Business, Boycott and Bureaucracy: The Kimberley Process Certification
Scheme and the Global Quest for Conflict-Free Diamonds .’ http://stockholm.sgir.eu/uploads/
SGIR%20Holger%20Meyer%20Kimberley%20Process.pdf.
132 Ibid, p. 69
133 Nest, Michael. 2011. Coltan. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press, p.134
134 http://www.kimberleyprocess.com/web/kimberley-process/enforcement
135 ‘Why We Are Leaving the Kimberley Process - A Message from Global Witness Founding
Director Chairman Gooch.’ 2011. Global Witness. http://www.globalwitness.org/library/why-
we-are-leaving-kimberley-process-message-global-witness-founding-director-charmian-
gooch.
from such mines may make the Congolese government reluctant to cooperate
with any such an initiative.
136 Elving, Alexander. 2012. The Kimberley Process. POLINARES Working Paper n.64. http://www.
polinares.eu/docs/d4-1/polinares_wp4_chapter14.pdf.
137 Security and Exchange Commission, SEC Adopts Rule for Disclosing Use of Conflict Minerals,
http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2012/2012-163.htm
HCSS Report 79
P olicy initiatives
uses minerals from the DRC or adjoining countries, it has to submit a report to
the SEC describing the due diligence it exercises to prevent sourcing conflict
minerals. The report has to be audited by an independent external party.
The compliance costs of Dodd-Frank 1502 are going to be significant. The SEC
estimated that the initial cost will be approximately $3 billion to $4 billion, and
the annual cost of ongoing compliance between $207 million and $609 million.
One natural benchmark to compare these costs is the revenue from conflict
minerals in eastern DRC. The total exports of the 3Ts from eastern DRC in 2008
(peak year) were approximately US$170 million, which is below the SEC’s lowest
estimate of the annual compliance cost. Adding gold exports, which are mainly
informal and not well captured in official data, will increase the total revenue
from exports. However, it does not change the conclusion that all exports of 3Ts
and gold from eastern DRC (this includes exports from areas that are under
government control and relatively peaceful) are less than the average estimate
of the annual compliance costs. It should be also kept in mind that armed
groups’profits from mineral trade are significantly smaller than the export
revenues from eastern DRC. Thus, even ignoring the much larger initial cost of
compliance, Dodd-Frank 1502 does not offer a very compelling proposition in
terms of cost-effectiveness.
138 Securities and Exchange Commission. 2012. ’Final Rule: Conflict Minerals’. Securities and
Exchange Commission. http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/2012/34-67716.pdf, p.299
TABLE 5 EXPORTS OF CONFLICT MINERALS FROM NORTH AND SOUTH KIVUS, IN US$’000S
This raises the question: who is going to bear the cost of compliance? Most likely
the costs will be split between different stakeholders – consumers (through
higher prices for final products), companies (through additional cost of
compliance and, as a result, lower profits), etc. More importantly, a substantial
part of the costs will be incurred by Congolese miners as well as miners from
neighboring countries. This will happen primarily in the form of lower prices
paid by buyers of minerals from these countries (since buying from the DRC and
its neighbors will mean that a company has to produce and submit to the SEC a
Conflict Minerals Report). Imposing costs on the people who are the least able to
bear them is one unfair potential outcome of Dodd-Frank 1502.
The issues of costs and fairness would be more easily acceptable if Dodd-Frank
1502 would substantially reduce violence in eastern DRC. This, however, is far
from certain and leaves the opposite effect, an increase in violence, as just as
plausible. It is interesting to note that the SEC does not tackle this central
question: how likely is it that the legislation is going to solve the root problem?
It is unclear how Dodd-Frank 1502, even if it were successful in fulfilling its
immediate goal – excluding conflict minerals from legal trade (and it is far from
obvious that it would), will end the conflict in the DRC. Two SEC commissioners
who voted against the rule raised the same issue. One of them, Troy Paredes,
stated ‘there is a failure to assess whether and, if so, the extent to which the final
rule will in fact advance its humanitarian goal as opposed to unintentionally
making matters worse.’139
139 ‘Statement at Open Meeting to Adopt a Final Rule Regarding Conflict Minerals Pursuant to
Section 1502 of the Dodd-Frank Act by Commissioner Troy A. Paredes.’ U.S. Security and
Exchange Commission. http://www.sec.gov/news/speech/2012/spch082212tap-minerals.htm.
HCSS Report 81
P olicy initiatives
The most likely outcome of the SEC rule will be a defacto ban on coltan and other
conflict minerals from the DRC by companies listed on US exchanges.
Companies that are not subjected to Dodd-Frank 1502 will still be able to buy
coltan and other minerals from eastern DRC and their negotiating power will
have increased. As a consequence, the price for coltan from Central Africa will be
lower, other things being equal. The price differential between coltan from the
DRC (and neighboring countries) and tantalum-bearing ores sourced elsewhere
will be one manifestation of the Dodd-Frank 1502 compliance costs. The lower
price will decrease the flow of mineral revenues to armed groups, but Dodd-
Frank 1502 is unlikely to fully stop it.
It seems that many initiatives are looking for an easy (although definitely not
cheap) way around the difficult problems present in eastern DRC rather than
trying to address their root causes directly. It should not be assumed that security
in eastern DRC can be established just by banning conflict minerals. Banning
conflict minerals should be, in the best case, a useful instrument to put
additional pressure on armed groups rather than the primary objective of policy
interventions. Armed groups can still operate at will in eastern DRC not because
they have access to profits from the mineral trade but because government forces
are unable to provide law and order. Congolese armed forces remain weak (as was
vividly illustrated by the M23 rebellion at the end of 2012) and corrupt (the cases
of their active involvement in illicit profiting from the mineral trade are abound
and well documented).
Dealing with armed groups requires a mix of military and political approaches,
which should take the centre stage in efforts to bring security to eastern DRC.
One important element in this respect is to improve the capabilities of the
Congolese armed forces (at least some of the units). Without more capable and
law-abiding armed forces in the DRC, hopes for peace and security are likely to
remain wishful dreams. This is why helping the DRC government to train its
armed forces may be necessary.
HCSS Report 83
C onclusion
6 Conclusion
The DRC has been called a ‘geological scandal’ because the country is endowed
with enormous mineral riches. These mineral riches could have driven the
country’s economic development and contributed to rising living standards for
its population. However, decades of mismanagement, corruption and conflict
has made the DRC a country with some of the lowest human development
indicators worldwide. The link between mining and conflict in the DRC makes
the country probably the most extreme example of the ‘resource curse’. This
report aimed to contribute to a better understanding of the role of minerals in
the conflict in the DRC. The report focuses on one mineral in particular, namely
coltan, which has become the most widely known symbol of the link between
deadly conflict in the DRC and the exploitation of mineral resources by armed
groups. Coltan is mined to produce tantalum, a rare metal with unique
properties that has become a key enabler of information and communication
technologies.
This case study has been conducted as part of the POLINARES project, an
EU-funded research project exploring global challenges in the competition for
access to natural resources an proposing new collaborative solutions. This report
looks at the general aim of the POLINARES project from different angles. The
first angle is to look at competition over resources in the DRC as potential cause
of armed conflict, the most extreme case of competition. The second perspective
illustrates that access to minerals is not an absolute goal and can be constrained
by self-imposed actions if it conflicts with other objectives. Finally, the report
analyzed several policy approaches and solutions that have been proposed by the
international community in order to ease the problems surrounding coltan
mining in eastern DRC. The analyses included an assessment of their (potential)
impact, both in terms of efficiency and effectiveness
Regarding competition and conflict, this report concludes that mineral resources
have not been the main cause of the Congo conflict. However, they became
HCSS Report 85
C onclusion
First of all, our analysis finds obstacles to the effectiveness of the policy
initiatives. Armed groups are opportunistic in terms of sources of funding.
Minerals have so far been the easiest and most available source of revenue.
Rebels rely on the territory they control to extract the means to sustain
themselves. If trade in minerals is banned and will no longer provide enough
income to finance their activities, rebels will shift to other (probably less
profitable) sources of revenue, e.g. by taxing agriculture or foreign aid. As a
consequence, there is little convincing evidence that initiatives focusing on
limiting mineral revenue will lead to a significant reduction of violence in the
DRC. Second, even under the assumption that the proposed initiatives would
be effective, i.e. if they would cease the conflict by reducing the mineral
revenues of armed groups if implemented perfectly, there are issues related
to the efficiency of the proposed initiatives. Our analysis shows several
challenges that undermine the implementation of the initiatives, including
weak governance, corruption and compliance costs.
We conclude that the limited results offered by existing policy initiatives are due
to the fact that that they are merely addressing symptoms of a deeper problem.
As long as the underlying reasons for conflict continue to exist and the right
governance structures to address grievances are lacking, the envisaged effects
of the policy measures remain limited.
The main problem in the Congo is the Congolese state itself, especially its armed
forces. The DRC government lacks control over large parts of its territory; it
cannot ensure security and protection of its population. Furthermore, the
Congolese army has conducted war crimes and been involved in illegal
exploitation of mineral resource including coltan. Unless the DRC state
institutions can fulfill their basic functions, including security provision,
attempts to solve conflict through measures aimed at minerals only are unlikely
to succeed. The weakness of governance in the DRC is the main barrier to the
efficient implementation of policy initiatives.
HCSS Report 87
A ppendix A : Tantalum mining
Appendix A: Tantalum
mining
HCSS Report 89
A ppendix A : Tantalum mining
HCSS Report 91
A ppendix A : Tantalum mining
Alliance of the Democractic Forces AFDL DRC AFDL was a coalition of Congolese dissidents supporting president Kabila
for the Liberation of Congo
Allied Democratic Forces ADF Foreign: Ugandan Islamist rebel force whose presence has been reported in the
Uganda Beni territory of North Kivu Province since 1995; the overall objective of
ADF is to overthrow the Government of Uganda and to place a Muslim in
power
Mouvement de Liberation du Congo MLC Foreign: Ugandan-backed militia force fighting against the Congolese government;
Uganda today it is the largest opposition party in the DRC
Rassamblement Congolais pour la RCD Foreign: Rwandan and Ugandan backed rebel group aiming at overthrowing
Democratie Uganda, president Kabila
Rwanda
Forces de Résistance Patriotique FRPI DRC Beni-based armed militia in the Ituri Province; fighting for the rights of the
d'Ituri Ngiti ethnic group; counterweight to the UPC in the Ituri conflict
Union des Patriotes Congolais UPC DRC Political and militia group in Ituri; fighting for the rights of the Hema ethnic
group
March 23 Movement M23 DRC Rebel military group based in eastern areas of the DRC, it aims at
establishing a parallel administration in the DRC
National Congress for the Defense of CNDP DRC CNDP is a Congo-based rebel group that was one of the most destructive
the People groups in eastern Congo; since 2009 it is officially integrated in the FADRC
Democratic Forces for the Liberation FDLR Foreign: The most politically significant and militarily
of Rwanda Rwanda
powerful armed group in eastern Democratic Republic of the Congo; it
consists mostly of Hutus fighting against Tutsi for more influence in the
region
Mai–Mai rebellion DRC Several armed sub-groups operate under the name Mayi-Mayi; rebels
resist to be integrated in the FADRC and aim to defend their territory
against other armed groups
Lord's Resistance Army LRA Foreign: Ugandan rebel group led by Joseph Kony; its political agenda is unclear; it
Uganda attacks civilians in the border area of Uganda, the DRC, South Sudan and
the Central African Republic
Congolese Army, led by President FADRC DRC
Kabila
Ugandan Army, led by President UPDF Foreign:
Museveni Uganda
143 Insight on Conflict, “DR Congo: Key People and Parties,” Insight on Conflict, accessed October 30, 2012, http://
www.insightonconflict.org/conflicts/dr-congo/conflict-profile/key-people-and-parties/; Group of Experts on the
Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2011/738: Final Report 2011 of the Security Council Committee Established
Pursuant to Resolution 1533 (2004) Concerning the Democratic Republic of the Congo (United Nations, 2011),
http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=S/2011/738.
HCSS Report 93
The Hague Centre Lange Voorhout 16 [email protected]
for Strategic Studies 2514 EE The Hague www.hcss.nl
The Netherlands