Economics of Structured Finance
Economics of Structured Finance
Economics of Structured Finance
In particular, we show how modest imprecision in the parameter estimates can lead
to variation in the default risk of the structured finance securities that is sufficient,
for example, to cause a security rated AAA to default with reasonable likelihood. A
second, equally neglected feature of the securitization process is that it substitutes
risks that are largely diversifiable for risks that are highly systematic. As a result,
securities produced by structured finance activities have far less chance of surviving
a severe economic downturn than traditional corporate securities of equal rating.
Moreover, because the default risk of senior tranches is concentrated in systemat-
ically adverse economic states, investors should demand far larger risk premia for
holding structured claims than for holding comparably rated corporate bonds. We
argue that both of these features of structured finance products—the extreme
fragility of their ratings to modest imprecision in evaluating underlying risks and
their exposure to systematic risks— go a long way in explaining the spectacular rise
and fall of structured finance.
For over a century, agencies such as Moody’s, Standard and Poor’s, and Fitch
have gathered and analyzed a wide range of financial, industry, and economic
information to arrive at independent assessments on the creditworthiness of vari-
ous entities, giving rise to the widely popular rating scales (AAA, AA, A, BBB, and
so on). Until recently, the agencies focused the majority of their business on
single-name corporate finance—that is, issues of creditworthiness of financial
instruments that can be clearly ascribed to a single company. In recent years, the
business model of credit rating agencies has expanded beyond their historical role
to include the nascent field of structured finance.
From its beginnings, the market for structured securities evolved as a “rated”
market, in which the risk of tranches was assessed by credit rating agencies. Issuers
of structured finance products were eager to have their new products rated on the
same scale as bonds so that investors subject to ratings-based constraints would be
able to purchase the securities. By having these new securities rated, the issuers
created an illusion of comparability with existing “single-name” securities. This
provided access to a large pool of potential buyers for what otherwise would have
been perceived as very complex derivative securities.
During the past decade, risks of all kinds have been repackaged to create vast
quantities of triple-A–rated securities with competitive yields. By mid-2007, there
were 37,000 structured finance issues in the U.S. alone with the top rating (Scholtes
and Beales, 2007). According to Fitch Ratings (2007), roughly 60 percent of all
global structured products were AAA-rated, in contrast to less than 1 percent of the
corporate issues. By offering AAA-ratings along with attractive yields during a
period of relatively low interest rates, these products were eagerly bought up by
investors around the world. In turn, structured finance activities grew to represent
a large fraction of Wall Street and rating agency revenues in a relatively short
period of time. By 2006, structured finance issuance led Wall Street to record
revenue and compensation levels. The same year, Moody’s Corporation reported
that 44 percent of its revenues came from rating structured finance products,
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 5
1
If we assume that both securities are identical and denote the probability of observing both claims
default simultaneously by pDD, the default correlation parameter can be computed as (pDD ⫺ pD2)/
(pD*(1 ⫺ pD).
The Economics of Structured Finance 7
promised returns, while the senior tranches, being relatively safe, will have relatively
higher prices and lower promised returns.
A central insight of structured finance is that by using a larger number of
securities in the underlying pool, a progressively larger fraction of the issued
tranches can end up with higher credit ratings than the average rating of the
underlying pool of assets. For example, consider extending the two-bond example
by adding a third $1 bond, so that now three $1 claims can be issued against this
underlying capital structure. Now, the first tranche defaults if any of the three
bonds default, the second tranche defaults if two or more of the bonds default, and
the final, senior-most tranche only defaults when all three bonds default. If bonds
default 10 percent of the time and defaults are uncorrelated, the senior tranche will
now default only 0.1 percent of the time, the middle tranche defaults 2.8 percent
of the time, and the junior tranche defaults 27.1 percent of the time. Thus, by
including a third bond in the pool, two-thirds of the capital—as measured by the
tranche notional values— can be repackaged into claims that are less risky than the
underlying bonds.
Another way to increase the total notional value of highly-rated securities
produced is to reapply the securitization machinery to the junior tranches created
in the first round. For example, in the two-bond case in which defaults were
uncorrelated, the $1 junior tranche defaults with 19 percent probability. However,
if we combine this $1 junior tranche with an identical $1 junior tranche created
from another two-bond pool, we can again tranche the resulting $2 of capital into
two prioritized $1 claims. If there continues to be no correlation among underlying
assets, the resulting senior tranche from this second round of securitization—a
tranche that defaults if at least one bond defaults in each of the two underlying
pools— has a default probability of 3.6 percent, which is once again considerably
lower than that of the underlying bonds. The collateralized debt obligations
created from the tranches of other collateralized debt obligations are typically
called CDO-squared—that is, CDO2.
A key factor determining the ability to create tranches that are safer than the
underlying collateral is the extent to which defaults are correlated across the
underlying assets. The lower the default correlation, the more improbable it is that
all assets default simultaneously and therefore the safer the senior-most claim can
be made. Conversely, as bond defaults become more correlated, the senior-most
claims become less safe. Consider, for example, the two-bond case in which defaults
are perfectly correlated. Since now both bonds either survive or default simulta-
neously, the structure achieves no credit enhancement for the senior tranche.
Thus, in the two-bond example, while uncorrelated risks of default allow the senior
claim to have a 1 percent default probability, perfectly correlated risks of default
would mean that the senior claim inherits the risk of the underlying assets, at
10 percent. Finally, intermediate levels of correlation allow the structure to pro-
duce a senior claim with default risk between 1 and 10 percent.
8 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Credit ratings are designed to measure the ability of issuers or entities to meet
their future financial commitments, such as principal or interest payments.
Depending on the agency issuing the rating and the type of entity whose credit-
worthiness is being assessed, the rating is either based on the anticipated likelihood
of observing a default, or it is based on the expected economic loss—the product
of the likelihood of observing a default and the severity of the loss conditional on
default. As such, a credit rating can intuitively be thought of as a measure of a
security’s expected cash flow.2 In the context of corporate bonds, securities rated
BBB⫺ or higher have come to be known as investment grade and are thought to
represent low to moderate levels of default risk, while those rated BB⫹ and below
are referred to as speculative grade and are already in default or closer to it.
Table 1 reports Fitch’s estimates regarding the 10-year default probabilities of
corporate bonds with different ratings at issuance and gives their corresponding
annualized default rates. These estimates are derived from a study of historical data
and are used in Fitch’s model for rating collateralized debt obligations (Derivative
Fitch, 2006).3 It is noteworthy that within the investment grade range, there are ten
distinct rating categories (from AAA to BBB⫺) even though the annualized default
rate only varies between 0.02 and 0.75 percent. Given the narrow range of the
historical default rates, distinguishing between the ratings assigned to investment
grade securities requires a striking degree of precision in estimating a security’s
default likelihood. By contrast, the ten rating categories within the speculative
grade range (from BB⫹ to C) have default rates ranging from 1.07 to 29.96
percent.
In the single-name rating business, where the credit rating agencies had
developed their expertise, securities were assessed independently of each other,
allowing rating agencies to remain agnostic about the extent to which defaults
might be correlated. But to assign ratings to structured finance securities, the rating
agencies were forced to address the bigger challenge of characterizing the entire
joint distribution of payoffs for the underlying collateral pool. As the previous
section demonstrated, the riskiness of collateralized debt obligation tranches is
sensitive to the extent of commonality in default among the underlying assets, since
collateralized debt obligations rely on the power of diversification to achieve credit
enhancement.
The structure of collateralized debt obligations magnifies the effect of impre-
2
Credit rating agencies stress that their ratings are only designed to provide an ordinal ranking of
securities’ long-run (“through-the-cycle”) payoff prospects, whereas the expected cash flow interpreta-
tion takes a cardinal view of ratings.
3
A comprehensive description of Fitch’s rating model for collateralized debt obligations—the Default
VECTOR Model—including assumptions regarding default probabilities, recovery rates, and correla-
tions is available online. An Excel spreadsheet implementation of the model can be downloaded from
具http://www.fitchrating.com/jsp/corporate/ToolsAndModels.faces?context⫽2&detail⫽117典.
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 9
Table 1
Historical Default Experience of Bonds Rated by Fitch
Investment-grade Bonds
Rating at
issuance AAA AA⫹ AA AA⫺ A⫹ A A⫺ BBB⫹ BBB BBB⫺
10-year default
probability 0.19% 0.57% 0.89% 1.15% 1.65% 1.85% 2.44% 3.13% 3.74% 7.26%
Default rate
(annualized) 0.02% 0.06% 0.09% 0.12% 0.17% 0.19% 0.25% 0.32% 0.38% 0.75%
Speculative-grade Bonds
Rating at
issuance BB⫹ BB BB⫺ B⫹ B B⫺ CCC⫹ CCC CC C
10-year default
probability 10.18% 13.53% 18.46% 22.84% 27.67% 34.98% 43.36% 48.52% 77.00% 95.00%
Default rate
(annualized) 1.07% 1.45% 2.04% 2.59% 3.24% 4.30% 5.68% 6.64% 14.70% 29.96%
4
Recovery rates can vary by type of security, seniority, and the country of origin. Historical recovery rates
are between 40 and 50 percent for senior unsecured corporate bonds in the United States (Derivative
Fitch, 2006; Altman, 2006).
5
The common method for modeling the joint incidence of defaults is known as the copula method
(Schonbucher, 2003). This approach draws a set of N correlated random variables {Xi} from a pre-
10 Journal of Economic Perspectives
specified distribution and then assumes that a firm defaults if its variable, Xi ⫽ xi, is below the p-th
percentile of the corresponding marginal distribution, Fi(xi). Under this scheme, by construction, a firm
defaults p percent of the time and default dependence can be flexibly captured through the proposed
joint distribution for {Xi}. A popular choice for the joint distribution function is the multivariate
Gaussian (Vasicek, 2002), in which default correlation is simply controlled by the pairwise correlation of
(Xi , Xj). Popular off-the-shelf CDO rating toolkits offered by credit rating agencies, such as Fitch’s
Default VECTOR models, Moody’s CDOROM, and Standard and Poor’s CDO Evaluator, all employ
versions of this copula model.
6
For example, collateralized loan obligations tend to be issued in a three-tranche structure with
attachment points of 0 –5 percent, 5–15 percent, and 15–100 percent. Collateralized debt obligations
referencing a commonly used index of credit default swaps on corporate bonds have a more granular
capital structure with two types of junior claims (0 –3 percent and 3–7 percent), two types of mezzanine
claims (7–10 percent and 10 –15 percent), and two types of senior claims (15–30 percent and 30 –100
percent). Tranches that are based on an index of residential mortgage-backed securities have a similarly
granular structure with junior claims having attachment points of 0 –3 percent and 3–7 percent;
mezzanine claims, 7–12 percent and 12–20 percent; and senior claims, 20 –35 percent and 35–100
percent.
The Economics of Structured Finance 11
Table 2
Summary Statistics for CDO and CDO2 Tranches in our Simulation under
Baseline Parameters
CDO
Junior 0%–6% 97.52% 0.59 NR
Mezzanine 6%–12% 2.07% ⬎ 0.99 BBB⫺
Senior 12%–100% ⬍ 0.00% ⬎ 0.99 AAA
CDO2 ([6, 12])
Junior 0%–6% 56.94% 0.93 C
Mezzanine 6%–12% ⬍ 0.00% ⬎ 0.99 AAA
Senior 12%–100% ⬍ 0.00% ⬎ 0.99 AAA
Note: While the parameter values used in our simulation do not map into any particular market, they
were chosen to mimic broadly the types of collateral and securitizations commonly observed in
structured finance markets.
original collateralized debt obligation and the CDO2 tranches to changes in default
correlation for bonds within each collateralized debt obligation. The correlation in
defaults for bonds belonging to different collateral pools remains fixed at zero. The
figure displays the expected payoff as a function of the default correlation, nor-
malized by the expected payoff under the baseline calibration. These values can be
thought of as illustrating the impact of either an error in the modeling assumptions
or an unexpected realization of the default experience on the value of a $1
investment in each tranche.
The top panel shows that the expected payoff of the underlying collateral pool
does not depend on the default correlation. As the default correlation increases
from its baseline value of 0.20, indicating default risk is less diversified than
expected, risk shifts from the junior claims to the senior claims. Consequently, the
expected payoff on the junior tranche rises relative to the baseline value, while the
expected payoff on the mezzanine tranche falls. The effect of changes in default
correlation on the mezzanine tranche of the collateralized debt obligation is
nonmonotonic. The expected payoff declines until the default correlation reaches
a value of 0.80, where the tranche has lost approximately 10 percent of its value
relative to the baseline calibration, and then rises as defaults become perfectly
correlated and risk is shifted toward the senior tranche. In the limit of perfect
default correlation, each tranche faces the same 5 percent chance of default
over five years as we assigned each of the individual securities in the underlying
portfolio.
The bottom panel of Figure 1 shows how shifts in the valuation of the
mezzanine tranche of the collateralized debt obligation are amplified by the
second-generation capital structure of the CDO2. For example, as the pairwise
default correlations within the underlying collateral pool of bonds increase from
12 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Figure 1
Sensitivity of CDO and CDO2 to Changes in Default Correlation
A: CDO
Expected payoff (scaled by baseline payoff)
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Default correlation
B: CDO2
Expected payoff (scaled by baseline payoff)
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Default correlation
Note: Figure 1 explores the sensitivity of the original collateralized debt obligation and the CDO2
tranches to changes in default correlation for bonds within each collateralized debt obligation. The
correlation in defaults for bonds belonging to different collateral pools remains fixed at zero. The figure
displays the expected payoff as a function of the default correlation, normalized by the expected payoff
under the baseline calibration.
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 13
20 to 60 percent, the expected payoff on the mezzanine claim of the CDO2, which
is an investment grade security under the baseline parameters, drops by a stagger-
ing 25 percent.
In Figure 2, we examine the effect of errors in estimates of the probability of
default on the underlying securities on the expected tranche payoffs, while holding
default correlation fixed at the baseline value of 0.20. As the default probability
increases (declines) relative to the baseline estimate of 5 percent, the expected
payoff on the underlying collateral decreases (increases) monotonically, and this
effect is transferred to the tranches of the collateralized debt obligation. The
sensitivity of the tranches to errors in the estimate of default probability is deter-
mined by their seniority. For example, an increase in the default probability from
5 to 10 percent results in a 55 percent decline in the expected payoff for the junior
tranche, an 8 percent decline for the mezzanine tranche, and a 0.01 percent
decline for the senior tranche.
The bottom panel of Figure 2 again illustrates the theme that changing the
baseline parameters has a much starker effect on the CDO2 comprised of the
mezzanine tranches from the original collateralized debt obligations. In this case,
as default probabilities rise, the values of the junior and mezzanine tranches quickly
fall towards zero, and the value of the senior tranche falls substantially as well.
Table 3 provides a complementary illustration of how ratings are affected by
changes in the underlying assets’ default correlation and default probabilities.
Although the expected payoff of the senior tranche of the collateralized debt
obligation is relatively robust to changes in the model parameters, this is somewhat
deceiving. Due to the fine partitioning of investment grade ratings, even modest
changes in the model parameters can precipitate a meaningful rating downgrade
for the senior tranche. For example, the rating of the senior tranche for the
original collateralized debt obligation drops to A⫹ when the default probability
reaches 10 percent and reaches the investment grade boundary of BBB⫺ when the
default probability reaches 20 percent. Again, the CDO2 structure significantly
amplifies the variation in the expected payoffs. When the default probability is
increased to 10 percent, the mezzanine claim of the CDO2, which was initially rated
AAA, sees 50 percent of its expected payoff wiped out and its rating drop all the way
below the rating scale. Even a slight increase in the probability of default on the
underlying securities to 7.5 percent, which would only cause the underlying secu-
rities to be downgraded from BB⫹ to BB⫺, is sufficient to precipitate a downgrade
of the AAA-rated mezzanine CDO2 claim to BBB⫺. Given the plausible uncertainty
in estimates of the underlying model parameters, the “.SF” rating modifiers
recently proposed by regulators for structured finance instruments (U.S. Securities
and Exchange Commission, 2008; Securities Industry and Financial Markets Asso-
ciation, 2008), are perhaps best regarded as warning labels.
Finally, the simulation illustrates that with plausible magnitudes of over-
collateralization (the degree of protection offered by the junior claims—12
percent in our example), the expected payoff on a senior tranche of the original
14 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Figure 2
Sensitivity of CDO and CDO2 to Changes in Default Probability
A: CDO
Expected payoff (scaled by baseline payoff)
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Default probability
B: CDO2
Expected payoff (scaled by baseline payoff)
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Default probability
Note: Figure 2 explores the sensitivity of the original collateralized debt obligation and the CDO2
tranches to changes in the default probability for bonds in each collateralized debt obligation. The
figure displays the expected payoff as a function of the default probability, normalized by the expected
payoff under the baseline calibration.
Table 3
Effect of Changes in Underlying Parameters on CDO and CDO2 Tranche
Ratings
Final rating
CDO
Junior NR D C CC NR NR NR
Mezzanine BBB⫺ BB⫺ B⫹ B⫹ B⫹ CCC CC
Senior AAA A⫹ BBB⫺ BB AAA A⫹ BBB⫺
CDO2 ([6, 12])
Junior C D NR NR NR NR NR
Mezzanine AAA B⫹ C CC BBB⫺ NR NR
Senior AAA AAA AAA AA⫹ AAA AAA B⫺
catastrophe. On the other hand, all tranches of the second generation securi-
tization, the CDO2, are highly sensitive to changes in the baseline parameters.
Even slight changes in default probabilities and correlations can have a sub-
stantial impact on the expected payoffs and ratings of the CDO2 tranches,
including the most senior claims.
As we show in the next section, a large fraction of collateralized debt obliga-
tions issued over the course of the last decade had subprime residential mortgage-
backed securities as their underlying assets. Importantly, many of these residential
mortgage-backed securities are themselves tranches from an original securitization
of a large pool of mortgages, such that collateralized debt obligations of mortgage-
backed securities are effectively CDO2s. Moreover, since substantial lending to
subprime borrowers is a recent phenomenon, historical data on defaults and
delinquencies of this sector of the mortgage market is scarce. The possibility for
errors in the assessment of the default correlations, the default probabilities, and
the ensuing recovery rates for these securities was significant. Such errors, when
magnified by the process of re-securitization, help explain the devastating losses
some of these securities have experienced recently.
resold in capital markets with the implicit guarantee of the U.S. government. In
contrast, mortgages that do not conform to size restrictions or borrower credit
quality standards are not eligible for purchase by the government-sponsored en-
terprises and are either held by their issuers or sold directly in secondary markets.7
In recent years, issuance of so-called “non-conforming” mortgages has increased
significantly. For example, origination of subprime mortgages—mortgages given to
those below the credit standards for the government-sponsored enterprises— grew
from $96.8 billion in 1996 to approximately $600 billion in 2006, accounting for 22
percent of all mortgages issued that year (U.S. Securities and Exchange Commis-
sion, 2008). During the same period, the average credit quality of subprime
borrowers decreased along a number of measures, as evidenced by rising ratios of
mortgage values relative to house prices, an increased incidence of second lien
loans, and issuance of mortgages with low or no documentation (Ashcraft and
Schuermann, 2008). When house prices declined, the stage was set for a significant
increase in default rates as many of these borrowers found themselves holding
mortgages in excess of the market value of their homes.
Because subprime mortgages were ineligible for securitization by government-
sponsored agencies, they found their way into capital markets by way of “private-
label” mortgage-backed securities, originated by Wall Street banks among others
(Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 2006). These securities carried the dual
risk of high rates of default due to the low credit quality of the borrowers; and high
levels of default correlation as a result of pooling mortgages from similar geo-
graphic areas and vintages. In turn, many subprime mortgage-backed bonds were
themselves re-securitized into what are called collateralized mortgage obligations,
effectively creating a CDO2. According to Moody’s, the share of collateralized debt
obligations that had other “structured” assets as their collateral expanded from
2.6 percent in 1998 to 55 percent in 2006 as a fraction of the total notional value
of all securitizations. In 2006 alone, issuance of structured finance collateralized
debt obligations reached $350 billion in notional value (Hu, 2007).
As it turned out, all of the factors determining expected losses on tranches of
collateralized debt obligations backed by mortgage-backed securities had been
biased against the investor. First, the overlap in geographic locations and vintages
within mortgage pools raised the prospect of higher-than-expected default corre-
lations. Second, the probability of default and the expected recovery values have
both been worse than expected due to the deterioration in credit quality of
subprime borrowers and because of assets being sold off under financial pressure
in “fire sales,” further driving down the prices of related assets. Finally, the preva-
7
Jumbo mortgages have notional values exceeding the conventional loan limit, which was $417,000 for
a single-family home in 2008. Subprime borrowers are defined as those with a FICO credit score below
620, limited credit history, or some other form of credit impairment. Alt-A borrowers have credit scores
sufficient to qualify for a conforming mortgage, but do not have the necessary documentation to
substantiate that their assets and income can support the requested loan amount.
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 17
When credit rating agencies started rating both structured finance and single-
name securities on the same scale, it may well have lured investors seeking safe
investments into the structured finance market, even though they did not fully
appreciate the nature of the underlying economic risks. In the logic of the capital
asset pricing model, securities that are correlated with the market as a whole should
offer higher expected returns to investors, and hence have higher yields, than
securities with the same expected payoffs (or credit ratings) whose fortunes are less
correlated with the market as a whole. However, credit ratings, by design, only
provide an assessment of the risks of the security’s expected payoff, with no
information regarding whether the security is particularly likely to default at the
same time that there is a large decline in the stock market or that the economy is
in a recession.
Because credit ratings only reflect expected payoffs, securities with a given
credit rating can, in theory, command a wide range of yield spreads—that is, yield
in excess of the yield on a U.S. Treasury security of the same duration— depending
on their exposure to systematic risks. For example, consider a security whose
default likelihood is constant and independent of the economic state, such that its
8
Additional information on the Markit ABX indices, including pricing, can be found at 具http://
www.markit.com/information/products/category/indices/abx.html典.
18 Journal of Economic Perspectives
have earned from simply writing such insurance directly—say, by making the
appropriate investment in options on the broader stock market index. In Coval,
Jurek, and Stafford (forthcoming), we provide evidence for this conjecture, show-
ing that senior tranches in collateralized debt obligations do not offer their
investors nearly large enough of a yield spread to compensate them for the actual
systematic risks that they bear.
The fact that corporate bonds and structured finance securities carry risks that
can, both in principle and in fact, be so different from a pricing standpoint casts
significant doubt on whether corporate bonds and structured finance securities can
really be considered comparable, regardless of what the credit rating agencies may
choose to do.
The dramatic rise and fall of structured finance products has been remarkable.
In under a decade, issuance of these products within the U.S. economy grew more
than ten-fold. In the first three quarters of 2005, $25–$40 billion of structured
finance products were issued in each quarter, according to data from the Securities
Industry and Financial Markets Association. In the last quarter of 2006 and the first
two quarters of 2007, issuance of structured finance products peaked at about $100
billion in each quarter. But by the first two quarters of 2008, these quantities had
dropped to less than $5 billion per quarter.
It is easy to see how the events of 2007 and 2008 compelled investors to reassess
the risks they were bearing in structured products. Less obvious is how structured
finance achieved such amazing growth in such a short period of time. Why were
investors eager to purchase structured products and issuers eager to supply them?
As we have argued, the key to understanding the market’s dramatic rise and fall is
to recognize the tendency of pooling and tranching to amplify mistakes in the
assessment of underlying asset default risks and correlations as well as their ability
to concentrate systematic risks in the most senior tranches.
The rapid growth of the market for structured products coincided with fairly
strong economic growth and few defaults, which gave market participants little
reason to question the robustness of these products. In fact, all parties believed they
were getting a good deal. Many of the structured finance securities with AAA-
ratings offered yields that were attractive relative to other, rating-matched alterna-
tives, such as corporate bonds. The “rated” nature of these securities, along with
their yield advantage, engendered significant interest from investors. However,
these seemingly attractive yields were in fact too low given the true underlying risks.
First, the securities’ credit ratings provided a downward-biased view of their actual
default risks, since they were based on the credit rating agencies’ naı̈ve extrapola-
tion of the favorable economic conditions. Second, the yields failed to account for
the extreme exposure of structured products to declines in aggregate economic
20 Journal of Economic Perspectives
conditions (in other words, systematic risk). The spuriously low yields on senior
claims, in turn, allowed the holders of remaining claims to be overcompensated,
incentivizing market participants to hold the “toxic” junior tranches. As a result of
this mispricing, demand for structured claims of all seniorities grew explosively.
The banks were eager to play along, collecting handsome fees for origination and
structuring. Ultimately, the growing demand for the underlying collateral assets
lead to an unprecedented reduction in the borrowing costs for homeowners and
corporations alike, fueling the real estate bubble that is now unwinding.
It seems that few investors were worried that the underlying assets were
overvalued, and those who were had incentives to disregard this possibility. This
changed rapidly when subprime mortgage defaults started increasing. As we dem-
onstrated earlier, errors in default probabilities adversely affect all of the tranches,
with the junior tranches taking the first losses. Moreover, the CDO2 structure,
which was especially common in this market, magnifies these errors, such that even
their senior-most tranches can be significantly impaired.
It is tempting to lay the bulk of the blame for the rise and fall of structured
finance on the credit rating agencies, since it was the agencies that evaluated and
deemed assets created by collateralized debt obligations as “safe.” There is certainly
evidence that the rating agencies made some significant mistakes. For example, in
May 2008, Moody’s acknowledged that it had inadvertently given AAA-ratings to
billions of dollars of structured finance products due to a bug in one of its ratings
models (Jones, Tett, and Davies, 2008). In March 2007, First Pacific Advisors
discovered that Fitch used a model that assumed constantly appreciating home
prices, ignoring the possibility that they could fall. Robert Rodriguez (2007), the
chief executive officer of First Pacific Advisors, describes the discovery:
We were on the March 22 call with Fitch regarding the sub-prime securitiza-
tion market’s difficulties. In their talk, they were highly confident regarding
their models and their ratings. My associate asked several questions. “What are
the key drivers of your rating model?” They responded, FICO scores and
home price appreciation (HPA) of low single digit (LSD) or mid single digit
(MSD), as HPA has been for the past 50 years. My associate then asked, “What
if HPA was flat for an extended period of time?” They responded that their
model would start to break down. He then asked, “What if HPA were to
decline 1% to 2% for an extended period of time?” They responded that their
models would break down completely. He then asked, “With 2% depreciation,
how far up the rating’s scale would it harm?” They responded that it might go
as high as the AA or AAA tranches.
It certainly appears that rating agencies did not fully appreciate the fragility of
their estimates nor the possible effects of modest errors in assumptions about
default correlations and probabilities in their credit ratings. But this lack of
understanding was apparently shared by the regulators who tied bank capital
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 21
The investment banks played a dual role of investors and dealers in the
structured finance market. The business offered enormous short-run payoffs, which
seemed too compelling to ignore even if value-destroying in the long-run. The
banks were generally eager to keep the structured finance business going even as
underwriting standards fell. The combination of low capital requirements imposed
on AAA-rated assets and a commonly held perception that they were “safe,” allowed
banks to hold on to any senior tranches that were not sold to investors. But when
the structured finance market collapsed in late 2007, the investment banks found
themselves holding hundreds of billions of dollars of low-quality asset pools, many
of which consisted of leveraged buy-out loans, subprime mortgages, and bonds
from collateralized debt obligations in process—that is, where the tranches had not
yet been sold to other investors.9
There is some evidence that Wall Street executives realized it would end one
day, but in the meantime, they had little incentive to move to the sidelines. In July
2007, the then-CEO of Citigroup, Chuck Prince, acknowledged that the cheap
credit-fueled buy-out boom would eventually end, but that in the meantime, his
firm would continue to participate in structured finance activities (as reported in
Nakamoto and Wighton, 2007): “When the music stops, in terms of liquidity, things
will get complicated. As long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance.
We’re still dancing.”
Finally, the minimum capital requirements for banks set forth in Basel I and II
may have played an important role in the evolution of the structured finance
market. Under these guidelines, banks holding AAA-rated securities were required
to hold only half as much capital as was required to support other investment-grade
securities. As a result of this built-in demand by banks for AAA-rated securities, a
small yield advantage in AAA-rated structured finance securities may have led to a
large increase in the demanded quantity. As discussed in the previous section, the
structured finance machinery enabled the creation of AAA-rated securities that had
a yield advantage over single-name AAA-rated securities, but only by filling these
securities with systematic risks or by rating them incorrectly.
9
For a detailed study of the market for collateralized loan obligations, see Benmelech and Dlugosz
(2008).
The Economics of Structured Finance 23
During the credit crunch from late 2007 and into 2008, the buyers of highly
rated structured finance products largely stopped buying. The initial cause for
this change was that subprime-related securities were experiencing large losses,
which created concerns about structured finance products more generally.
Some practitioners believe that the credit crunch of 2007 and 2008 will work
itself out, as such episodes tend to do, and the market for structured credit will
return as before. We hold the more skeptical view that the market for structured
credit appears to have serious structural problems that may be difficult to
overcome.
As we have explained, these claims are highly sensitive to the assumptions
of 1) default probability and recovery value, 2) correlation of defaults, and
3) the relation between payoffs and the economic states that investors care about
most. Beginning in late 2007 and continuing well into 2008, it became increasingly
clear to investors in highly-rated structured products that each of these three key
assumptions were systematically biased against them. These investors are now
reluctant to invest in securities that they do not fully understand.
The ability to create large quantities of AAA-rated securities from a given
pool of underlying assets is likely to be forever diminished, as the rating process
evolves to better account for parameter and model uncertainty. The key is
recognizing that small errors that would not be costly in the single-name
market, are significantly magnified by the collateralized debt obligation struc-
ture, and can be further magnified when collateralized debt obligations are
created from the tranches of other collateralized debt obligations, as was
common in mortgage-backed securitizations. The good news is that this mistake
can be fixed. For example, a Bayesian approach that explicitly acknowledges
that parameters are uncertain would go a long way towards solving this problem.
Of course, adopting a Bayesian perspective on parameter uncertainty will
necessarily mean far less AAA-rated securities can be issued and therefore fewer
opportunities to offer investors attractive yields.
Additionally, investors need to recognize the fundamental difference be-
tween single-name and structured securities when it comes to exposure to
systematic risk. Unlike traditional corporate bonds, whose fortunes are primar-
ily driven by firm-specific considerations, the performance of securities created
by tranching large asset pools is strongly affected by the performance of the
economy as a whole. In particular, senior structured finance claims have the
features of economic catastrophe bonds, in that they are designed to default
only in the event of extreme economic duress. Because credit ratings are silent
regarding the state of the world in which default is likely to happen, they do not
capture this exposure to systematic risks. The lack of consideration for these
types of exposures reduces the usefulness of ratings, no matter how precise they
are made to be.
24 Journal of Economic Perspectives
y We thank Eli Cohen, Lauren Cohen, Robin Greenwood, Jim Hines, Chris Malloy, Eric Del
Monaco, André Perold, Hyun Shin, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein, and Timothy Taylor for
helpful comments and discussions.
References
Altman, Edward. 2006. “Default Recovery to Default Model.” Review of Financial Studies,
Rates and LGD in Credit Risk Modeling and 21(3): 1339 – 69.
Practice: An Updated Review of the Literature Coval, Joshua, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford.
and Empirical Evidence.” http://pages.stern.nyu. Forthcoming. “Economic Catastrophe Bonds.”
edu/⬃ealtman/UpdatedReviewofLiterature.pdf. American Economic Review.
Altman, Edward, and Jeffrey Swanson. 2007. Craig, Susanne, Randall Smith, and Serena
“The Investment Performance and Market Size of Ng. 2008. “Merrill Aims to Raise Billions More:
Defaulted Bonds and Bank Loans.” http://pages. Firm Dumps Mortgage Assets as Crisis Drags On;
stern.nyu.edu/⬃ealtman/2006%20InvestPerf.pdf. Another Big Write-Down.” Wall Street Journal, July
Ashcraft, Adam, and Til Schuermann. 2008. 29.
“Understanding the Securitization of Subprime Derivative Fitch. 2006. “Global Criteria for
Mortgage Credit.” Federal Reserve Bank of New Collateralized Debt Obligations.”
York Staff Report 318. http://www.newyorkfed. Dichev, Ilia D., and Joseph D. Piotroski. 2001.
org/research/staff_reports/sr318.pdf. “The Long-Run Stock Returns Following Bond
Bank of International Settlements. 2005. “The Rating Changes.” Journal of Finance, 56(1): 173–
Role of Ratings in Structured Finance: Issues 203.
and Implications.” Committee on the Global Fi- Ederington, Louis H., and Jeremy Goh. 1998.
nancial System Publications no. 23. January. “Bond Rating Agencies and Stock Analysts: Who
Available at: http://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs23. Knows What When?” The Journal of Finance and
htm. Quantitative Analysis, 33(4): 569 – 85.
Bank of International Settlements, Basel Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French.
Committee on Banking Supervision, The Joint 1993. “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on
Forum. 2008. “Credit Risk Transfer—Develop- Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics,
ments from 2005—2007.” July. Available at: 33(1): 3–56.
http://www.bis.org/publ/joint21.htm. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 2006.
Beales, Richard, Saskia Scholtes, and Gillian “FDIC Outlook: Breaking New Ground in
Tett. 2007. “Failing grades? Why Regulators Fear Mortgage Lending.” http://www.fdic.gov/
Credit Ratings May Be Out of Their Depth.” bank/analytical/regional/ro20062q/na/
Financial Times, May 17. 2006_summer04.html.
Benford, James, and Erlend Nier. 2007. “Mon- Financial Week. 2008. “S&P President: Struc-
itoring Cyclicality of Basel II Capital Require- tured Finance Business in the Tank.” June 10.
ments.” Bank of England, Financial Stability http://www.financialweek.com/apps/pbcs.dll/
Paper No. 3. article?AID⫽/20080610/REG/660111773/-1/
Benmelech, Effraim, and Jennifer Dlugosz. FWDailyAlert01.
2008. “The Alchemy of CDO Credit Ratings.” Fitch Ratings. 2007. “Inside the Ratings: What
http://www.carnegie-rochester.rochester.edu/ Credit Ratings Mean.” http://www.bankwatchratings.
nov08-pdfs/benmelech_dlugosz.pdf. com/descargas/ratings.pdf.
Bhanota, Karan, and Antonio S. Mello. 2006. Hand, John R., Robert W. Holthausen, and
“Should Corporate Debt include a Rating Trig- Richard W. Leftwich. 1992. “The Effect of Bond
ger?” Journal of Financial Economics, 79(1): 69 –98. Rating Agency Announcements on Bond and
Bharath, Sreedhar, and Tyler Shumway. 2007. Stock Prices.” Journal of Finance, 47(2): 733–52.
“Forecasting Default with the Merton Distance Heitfield, Erik. 2008. “Parameter Uncertainty
Joshua Coval, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford 25
and the Credit Risk of Collateralized Debt Obli- 2007. “Citigroup Chief Stays Bullish on Buy-
gations.” Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ outs.” Financial Times, July 9.
abstract⫽1190362. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Hite, Gailen, and Arthur Warga. 1997. “The Development. 2007. “Survey of Investment Reg-
Effect of Bond-Rating Changes on Bond Price ulations of Pension Funds.” http://www.oecd.
Performance.” Financial Analysts Journal, 53(3): org/dataoecd/56/7/38969997.pdf.
35–51. Rodriguez, Robert. 2007. “Absence of Fear.” A
Holthausen, Robert W., and Richard W. speech given at the CFA Society of Chicago, June
Leftwich. 1986. “The Effect of Bond Rating 28. http://www.fpafunds.com/news_070703_
Changes on Common Stock Prices.” Journal of absense_of_fear.asp.
Financial Economics, 17(1): 57– 89. Scholtes, Saskia, and Richard Beales. 2007.
Hu, Jian. 2007. “Assessing the Credit Risk of “Top Rating Proving Crucial to Structured Fi-
CDOs Backed by Structured Finance Securities: nance Sector.” Financial Times, May 17.
Rating Analysts’ Challenges and Solutions.” Jour- Schonbucher, Philipp J. 2003. “Factor Models:
nal of Structured Finance, Fall. Portfolio Credit Risks When Defaults Are Corre-
Hull, John, Mirela Predescu, and Alan White. lated.” Journal of Risk Finance, 3(1): 45–56.
2004. “The Relationship Between Credit Default Securities Industry and Financial Markets As-
sociation. 2008. “Recommendations of the Secu-
Swap Spreads, Bond Yields, and Credit Rating
rities Industry and Financial Markets Association
Announcements.” Journal of Banking and Finance,
Credit Rating Agency Task Force.” http://www.
28(11): 2789 –2811.
sifma.org/capital_markets/docs/SIFMA-CRA-
Jones, Sam, Gillian Tett, and Paul J. Davies.
Recommendations.pdf.
2008. “Moody’s Error Gave Top Ratings to Debt
Tarashev, Nikola, and Haibin Zhu. 2007.
Products.” Financial Times, May 20.
“Modelling and Calibration Errors in Measures
Jorion, Philippe, and Gaiyan Zhang. 2007.
of Portfolio Credit Risk.” Bank of International
“Good and Bad Credit Contagion: Evidence
Settlements Working Paper 230.
from Credit Default Swaps.” Journal of Financial
Tomlinson, Richard, and David Evans. 2007.
Economics, 84(3): 860 – 83. “Rating Charade.” Bloomberg Markets Maga-
Katz, Steven. 1974. “The Price Adjustment zine, July. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/
Process of Bonds to Rating Reclassifications: A marketsmag/ratings.html.
Test of Bond Market Efficiency.” Journal of U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission.
Finance, 29(2): 551–59. 2008. “Summary Report of Issues Identified in
Mason, Joseph, and Joshua Rosner. 2007. the Commission Staff’s Examination of Select
“Where Did the Risk Go? How Misapplied Bond Credit Rating Agencies.” http://www.sec.gov/
Ratings Cause Mortgage Backed Securities and news/studies/2008/craexamination070808.pdf.
Collateralized Debt Obligation Market Disrup- Vasicek, Oldrich. 2002. “The Distribution
tions.” Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ of Loan Portfolio Value.” Working Paper,
abstract⫽1027475. KMV Corporation. http://www.moodyskmv.com/
Merton, Robert C. 1974. “On the Pricing of conf04/pdf/papers/dist_loan_port_val.pdf. (Re-
Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest printed in RISK, December, 15(12): 160 – 62.)
Rates.” Journal of Finance, 29(2): 449 –70. Wansley, James L., John Glascock, and Ter-
Moody’s Investors Service. 2004. “Moody’s Re- rence M. Clauretie. 1992. “Institutional Bond
visits Its Assumptions Regarding Corporate Pricing and Information Arrival: The Case of
Default (and Asset) Correlations for CDOs.” Bond Rating Changes.” Journal of Business
Nakamoto, Michiyo, and David Wighton. Finance and Accounting, 19(5): 733–50.
This article has been cited by:
1. Hao Wang, Yu Wang, Shuang Zhao, Lan-ping Wang, Hui An. 2018. The transnational comparative
study on the potential risks and efficiency of commercial banks based on the weight-limited DEA
model. China Finance Review International 8:4, 441-452. [Crossref]
2. Dan Luo, Dragon Yongjun Tang, Sarah Qian Wang. 2018. Model specification and collateralized debt
obligation (mis)pricing. Journal of Futures Markets 38:11, 1284-1312. [Crossref]
3. Kristoffer Milonas. 2018. Bank Taxes, Leverage, and Risk. Journal of Financial Services Research 54:2,
145-177. [Crossref]
4. Alberto Botta, Eugenio Caverzasi, Daniele Tori. 2018. THE MACROECONOMICS OF SHADOW
BANKING. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19, 1-30. [Crossref]
5. Andreas Blöchlinger. 2018. Credit Rating and Pricing: Poles Apart. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 11:2, 27. [Crossref]
6. Fernando Moreira, Sheng Zhao. 2018. Do credit ratings affect spread and return? A study of structured
finance products. International Journal of Finance & Economics 23:2, 205-217. [Crossref]
7. Natalya Vinokurova. 2018. Failure to learn from failure: The 2008 mortgage crisis as a déjà vu of the
mortgage meltdown of 1994. Business History 69, 1-46. [Crossref]
8. John (X.) Jiang, Isabel Y. Wang, K. Philip Wang. 2018. Revolving Rating Analysts and Ratings
of Mortgage-Backed and Asset-Backed Securities: Evidence from LinkedIn. Management Science .
[Crossref]
9. Zifeng Zhao, Zhengjun Zhang. 2018. Semiparametric dynamic max-copula model for multivariate
time series. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B (Statistical Methodology) 80:2, 409-432.
[Crossref]
10. Richard Stanton, Nancy Wallace. 2018. CMBS Subordination, Ratings Inflation, and Regulatory-
Capital Arbitrage. Financial Management 47:1, 175-201. [Crossref]
11. Servaas Storm. 2018. Financialization and Economic Development: A Debate on the Social Efficiency
of Modern Finance. Development and Change 49:2, 302-329. [Crossref]
12. Razmig Keucheyan. 2018. Insuring Climate Change: New Risks and the Financialization of Nature.
Development and Change 49:2, 484-501. [Crossref]
13. Tobias Broer. 2018. Securitization bubbles: Structured finance with disagreement about default risk.
Journal of Financial Economics 127:3, 505-518. [Crossref]
14. Nils Boesel, Clemens Kool, Stefano Lugo. 2018. Do European banks with a covered bond program
issue asset-backed securities for funding?. Journal of International Money and Finance 81, 76-87.
[Crossref]
15. Natalia Besedovsky. 2018. Financialization as calculative practice: the rise of structured finance and the
cultural and calculative transformation of credit rating agencies. Socio-Economic Review 16:1, 61-84.
[Crossref]
16. Tobias Adrian, Bradley Jones. 2018. Shadow Banking and Market-Based Finance. Departmental
Papers / Policy Papers 18:14, 1. [Crossref]
17. Vincenzo Bavoso. 2017. “High Quality Securitisation and EU Capital Markets Union – Is it Possible?”.
Accounting, Economics, and Law: A Convivium 7:3. . [Crossref]
18. Michael J. T. McMillen. Legal and Regulatory Considerations Pertaining to Islamic Capital Markets
78-158. [Crossref]
19. ROLAND MEEKS, BENJAMIN NELSON, PIERGIORGIO ALESSANDRI. 2017. Shadow Banks
and Macroeconomic Instability. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 49:7, 1483-1516. [Crossref]
20. Craig B. Merrill, Taylor D. Nadauld, Philip E. Strahan. 2017. Final Demand for Structured Finance
Securities. Management Science . [Crossref]
21. Amir Amel-Zadeh, Mary E. Barth, Wayne R. Landsman. 2017. The contribution of bank regulation
and fair value accounting to procyclical leverage. Review of Accounting Studies 22:3, 1423-1454.
[Crossref]
22. Jordan Nickerson, John M. Griffin. 2017. Debt correlations in the wake of the financial crisis: What
are appropriate default correlations for structured products?. Journal of Financial Economics 125:3,
454-474. [Crossref]
23. Hammad Siddiqi. 2017. Certain and uncertain utility: A new perspective on financial innovation.
Economics Letters 158, 7-9. [Crossref]
24. Yun-Ling Wu, Chien-Lin Lu, Ming-Chi Chen, Fang-Ni Chu. 2017. What forces drive the dynamic
interaction between regional housing prices?. International Journal of Strategic Property Management
21:3, 225-239. [Crossref]
25. Augustin Landier, David Sraer, David Thesmar. 2017. Banking integration and house price co-
movement. Journal of Financial Economics 125:1, 1-25. [Crossref]
26. Andrew Ellis, Michele Piccione. 2017. Correlation Misperception in Choice. American Economic
Review 107:4, 1264-1292. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
27. Sanjiv Ranjan Das, Seoyoung Kim. 2017. Managing Rollover Risk with Capital Structure Covenants
in Structured Finance Vehicles. The Journal of Fixed Income 26:4, 92-112. [Crossref]
28. Jess N. Cornaggia, Kimberly J. Cornaggia, John E. Hund. 2017. Credit Ratings Across Asset Classes:
A Long-Term Perspective*. Review of Finance 21:2, 465-509. [Crossref]
29. Giovanni Ferri. 2017. Regolamentazione bancaria: serve un cambio di approccio. ECONOMIA E
DIRITTO DEL TERZIARIO :3, 383-408. [Crossref]
30. Liang Hong. 2017. Estimators of contingent probabilities and means with actuarial applications.
Communications in Statistics - Theory and Methods 46:2, 927-941. [Crossref]
31. Dong Hwan Oh, Andrew J. Patton. 2017. Modeling Dependence in High Dimensions With Factor
Copulas. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 35:1, 139-154. [Crossref]
32. Giovanni Ferri. The Evolution of Banking Regulation in the Post-Crisis Period: Cooperative and
Savings Banks’ Perspective 1-31. [Crossref]
33. Andreas Blöchlinger. 2017. Are the Probabilities Right? New Multiperiod Calibration Tests. The
Journal of Fixed Income 26:3, 25-32. [Crossref]
34. Mahmoud Elamin. 2017. Can Reputation Ensure Efficiency in the Structured Finance Market?.
Theoretical Economics Letters 07:01, 49-62. [Crossref]
35. Alessandro Romano. 1. [Crossref]
36. Dmitriy Krichevskiy, Dhimitri Qirjo. Rational Agents and Irrational Bubbles 113-127. [Crossref]
37. Solomon Y Deku, Alper Kara. Valuation of ABS Under Asymmetric Information 113-129. [Crossref]
38. Thomas Goda, Özlem Onaran, Engelbert Stockhammer. 2017. Income Inequality and Wealth
Concentration in the Recent Crisis. Development and Change 48:1, 3-27. [Crossref]
39. Divya International Monetary Fund. 2017. When Gambling for Resurrection is Too Risky. IMF
Working Papers 17:180, 1. [Crossref]
40. Arjen Siegmann. Policy Lessons from Systemic Risk Modeling and Measurement 239-273. [Crossref]
41. Sanjiv Das, Seoyoung Kim. 2016. The Design and Risk Management of Structured Finance Vehicles.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 9:4, 12. [Crossref]
42. Vincenzo D’Apice, Giovanni Ferri, Punziana Lacitignola. 2016. Rating Performance and Bank Business
Models: Is There a Change with the 2007–2009 Crisis?. Italian Economic Journal 2:3, 385-420.
[Crossref]
43. Edwin Harold Neave. 2016. Why does bank screening matter? Private information and publicly traded
securities. International Journal of Managerial Finance 12:5, 478-497. [Crossref]
44. Alejandro Bernales. 2016. The Success of Option Listings. Journal of Empirical Finance . [Crossref]
45. Alper Kara, David Marques-Ibanez, Steven Ongena. 2016. Securitization and lending standards:
Evidence from the European wholesale loan market. Journal of Financial Stability 26, 107-127.
[Crossref]
46. Philipp Gmehling, Pierfrancesco La Mura. 2016. A Bayesian inference model for the credit rating
scale. The Journal of Risk Finance 17:4, 390-404. [Crossref]
47. Frank Yong Wang, Xu Wei, Li Li. 2016. Investors’ heterogeneity and tranching. Applied Economics
48:38, 3679-3684. [Crossref]
48. Thomas Mählmann. 2016. Market share and risk taking: the role of collateral asset managers in the
collapse of the arbitrage CDO market. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 47:2, 273-303.
[Crossref]
49. Lucyna A. Górnicka. 2016. Banks and shadow banks: Competitors or complements?. Journal of
Financial Intermediation 27, 118-131. [Crossref]
50. Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2016. Systematic Credit Risk and Pricing for Fixed Income
Instruments. The Journal of Fixed Income . [Crossref]
51. Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2016. Systematic Credit Risk and Pricing for Fixed Income
Instruments. The Journal of Fixed Income 26:1, 42-60. [Crossref]
52. Valentina Bruno, Jess Cornaggia, Kimberly J. Cornaggia. 2016. Does Regulatory Certification Affect
the Information Content of Credit Ratings?. Management Science 62:6, 1578-1597. [Crossref]
53. Javier Zapata, Arturo Cifuentes. 2016. On the Stability of Synthetic CDO Credit Ratings. International
Finance 19:2, 201-218. [Crossref]
54. Mette Asmild, Minyan Zhu. 2016. Controlling for the use of extreme weights in bank efficiency
assessments during the financial crisis. European Journal of Operational Research 251:3, 999-1015.
[Crossref]
55. M. Shahid Ebrahim, Aziz Jaafar, Fatma A. Omar, Murizah Osman Salleh. 2016. Can Islamic
injunctions indemnify the structural flaws of securitized debt?. Journal of Corporate Finance 37,
271-286. [Crossref]
56. Jamus Jerome Lim, Terence Tan. 2016. Endogenous transactions costs and institutions in the 2007/08
financial crisis. Journal of Regulatory Economics 49:1, 56-85. [Crossref]
57. Anil K. Kashyap, Natalia Kovrijnykh. 2016. Who Should Pay for Credit Ratings and How?. Review
of Financial Studies 29:2, 420-456. [Crossref]
58. . 349. [Crossref]
59. Eva R. Porras. Contributors to the Bubble Formation and Contagion Process 55-89. [Crossref]
60. Valerio Lemma. Shadow Banking Operations 95-112. [Crossref]
61. Philip Arestis. Main and Contributory Causes of the Recent Financial Crisis and Economic Policy
Implications 1-36. [Crossref]
62. Christopher L. Foote, Paul S. Willen. subprime mortgage crisis, the 324-336. [Crossref]
63. Tobias Adrian, Adam B. Ashcraft. shadow banking: a review of the literature 282-315. [Crossref]
64. Po-Keng Cheng. 2016. Fragile by Design. International Journal of Applied Behavioral Economics 5:1,
48-52. [Crossref]
65. Victor A. Beker. From the Economic Crisis to the Crisis of Economics 183-199. [Crossref]
66. . References 671-699. [Crossref]
67. Simon D. Norton. Bank Failures and Accounting During the Financial Crisis of 2008-2009 425-452.
[Crossref]
68. . Structured Credit 371-388. [Crossref]
69. David M. Zimmer. 2015. Asymmetric dependence in house prices: evidence from USA and
international data. Empirical Economics 49:1, 161-183. [Crossref]
70. Stephen Golub, Ayse Kaya, Michael Reay. 2015. What were they thinking? The Federal Reserve in the
run-up to the 2008 financial crisis. Review of International Political Economy 22:4, 657-692. [Crossref]
71. IGOR MAKAROV, GUILLAUME PLANTIN. 2015. Rewarding Trading Skills without Inducing
Gambling. The Journal of Finance 70:3, 925-962. [Crossref]
72. Emilio Barucci, Andrea Cosso. 2015. Portfolio choices and VaR constraint with a defaultable asset.
Quantitative Finance 15:5, 853-864. [Crossref]
73. Nicola Gennaioli, Andrei Shleifer, Robert Vishny. 2015. Neglected Risks: The Psychology of
Financial Crises. American Economic Review 105:5, 310-314. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
74. 2015. The Journal of Investing 24:2, 35-44. [Crossref]
75. 2015. The Journal of Investing 24:2, 147-162. [Crossref]
76. James Dow, Jungsuk Han. 2015. Contractual incompleteness, limited liability and asset price bubbles.
Journal of Financial Economics 116:2, 383-409. [Crossref]
77. Pepa Kraft. 2015. Do rating agencies cater? Evidence from rating-based contracts. Journal of Accounting
and Economics 59:2-3, 264-283. [Crossref]
78. Bruce G. Carruthers. 2015. Financialization and the institutional foundations of the new capitalism.
Socio-Economic Review 13:2, 379-398. [Crossref]
79. Pepa Kraft. 2015. Rating Agency Adjustments to GAAP Financial Statements and Their Effect on
Ratings and Credit Spreads. The Accounting Review 90:2, 641-674. [Crossref]
80. Frank J. Fabozzi, Dennis Vink. 2015. The information content of three credit ratings: the case of
European residential mortgage-backed securities. The European Journal of Finance 21:3, 172-194.
[Crossref]
81. Andria van der Merwe. Financial Crises and Liquidity Traffic Jams 19-38. [Crossref]
82. Jon Roffe. From Price to the Market 25-36. [Crossref]
83. Jean Louis Arcand, Enrico Berkes, Ugo Panizza. 2015. Too much finance?. Journal of Economic Growth
20:2, 105. [Crossref]
84. Sara Malekan, Georges Dionne. 2014. Securitization and optimal retention under moral hazard.
Journal of Mathematical Economics 55, 74-85. [Crossref]
85. John Ziyang Zhang. 2014. Asset Securitizations and Credit Default Swaps. Financial Markets,
Institutions & Instruments 23:4, 211-243. [Crossref]
86. Ing-Haw Cheng, Sahil Raina, Wei Xiong. 2014. Wall Street and the Housing Bubble. American
Economic Review 104:9, 2797-2829. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
87. Bernardo K. Pagnoncelli, Arturo Cifuentes. 2014. Credit risk assessment of fixed income portfolios
using explicit expressions. Finance Research Letters 11:3, 224-230. [Crossref]
88. Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2014. Forecasting Mortgage Securitization Risk Under Systematic
Risk and Parameter Uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Insurance 81:3, 563-586. [Crossref]
89. Gerard Caprio, Vincenzo D’Apice, Giovanni Ferri, Giovanni Walter Puopolo. 2014. Macro-financial
determinants of the great financial crisis: Implications for financial regulation. Journal of Banking &
Finance 44, 114-129. [Crossref]
90. Erik Mohlin. 2014. Optimal categorization. Journal of Economic Theory 152, 356-381. [Crossref]
91. PAUL S. L. YIP. 2014. THE RISK OF PROPERTY BUBBLES IN HONG KONG
AND SINGAPORE: ANOTHER AFTERSHOCK CRISIS OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL
TSUNAMI?. The Singapore Economic Review 59:03, 1450026. [Crossref]
92. T. Alafita, J.M. Pearce. 2014. Securitization of residential solar photovoltaic assets: Costs, risks and
uncertainty. Energy Policy 67, 488-498. [Crossref]
93. Anna Scherbina, Bernd Schlusche. 2014. Asset price bubbles: a survey. Quantitative Finance 14:4,
589-604. [Crossref]
94. Arndt Claußen, Sebastian Löhr, Daniel Rösch. 2014. An analytical approach for systematic risk
sensitivity of structured finance products. Review of Derivatives Research 17:1, 1-37. [Crossref]
95. Craig H. Furfine. 2014. Complexity and Loan Performance: Evidence from the Securitization of
Commercial Mortgages. Review of Corporate Finance Studies 2:2, 154-187. [Crossref]
96. Jesus Sierra. 2014. International Capital Flows and Bond Risk Premia. Quarterly Journal of Finance
04:01, 1450001. [Crossref]
97. Isil Erel, Taylor Nadauld, René M. Stulz. 2014. Why Did Holdings of Highly Rated Securitization
Tranches Differ So Much across Banks?. Review of Financial Studies 27:2, 404-453. [Crossref]
98. Ingmar Schumacher. 2014. On the self-fulfilling prophecy of changes in sovereign ratings. Economic
Modelling 38, 351-356. [Crossref]
99. . References 161-171. [Crossref]
100. Alan D. Morrison, Lucy White. 2013. Reputational contagion and optimal regulatory forbearance.
Journal of Financial Economics 110:3, 642-658. [Crossref]
101. Hans-Helmut Kotz,, Dorothea Schäfer. 2013. Rating-Agenturen: Fehlbar und überfordert.
Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung 82:4, 135-162. [Crossref]
102. Kristina Lützenkirchen, Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2013. Ratings based capital adequacy for
securitizations. Journal of Banking & Finance 37:12, 5236-5247. [Crossref]
103. Sebastian Löhr, Olga Mursajew, Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2013. Dynamic Implied Correlation
Modeling and Forecasting in Structured Finance. Journal of Futures Markets 33:11, 994-1023.
[Crossref]
104. Lawrence J. White. 2013. Credit Rating Agencies: An Overview. Annual Review of Financial Economics
5:1, 93-122. [Crossref]
105. Marcin Wojtowicz. 2013. CDOs and the Financial Crisis: Credit Ratings and Fair Premia. Journal of
Banking & Finance . [Crossref]
106. Matthias Bodenstedt, Daniel Rösch, Harald Scheule. 2013. The path to impairment: do credit-rating
agencies anticipate default events of structured finance transactions?. The European Journal of Finance
19:9, 841-860. [Crossref]
107. Liang Hong, Jyotirmoy Sarkar. 2013. Contingent means in multi-life models. Scandinavian Actuarial
Journal 2013:5, 340-351. [Crossref]
108. John M. Griffin, Jordan Nickerson, Dragon Yongjun Tang. 2013. Rating Shopping or Catering?An
Examination of the Response to Competitive Pressure for CDO Credit Ratings. Review of Financial
Studies 26:9, 2270-2310. [Crossref]
109. NICOLA GENNAIOLI, ANDREI SHLEIFER, ROBERT W. VISHNY. 2013. A Model of Shadow
Banking. The Journal of Finance 68:4, 1331-1363. [Crossref]
110. Ji Yeol Jimmy Oh. 2013. Ambiguity aversion, funding liquidity, and liquidation dynamics. Journal of
Financial Markets . [Crossref]
111. ANDREW COHEN, MARK D. MANUSZAK. 2013. Ratings Competition in the CMBS Market.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45:s1, 93-119. [Crossref]
112. Gunter Löffler. 2013. Can Market Discipline Work in the Case of Rating Agencies? Some Lessons
from Moody’s Stock Price. Journal of Financial Services Research 43:2, 149-174. [Crossref]
113. Dan Awrey. 2013. Toward a supply-side theory of financial innovation. Journal of Comparative
Economics . [Crossref]
114. Miklós Antal, Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh. 2013. Macroeconomics, financial crisis and the
environment: Strategies for a sustainability transition. Environmental Innovation and Societal
Transitions 6, 47-66. [Crossref]
115. ANTOINE MARTIN, BRUNO M. PARIGI. 2013. Bank Capital Regulation and Structured
Finance. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45:1, 87-119. [Crossref]
116. Doh-Shin Jeon, Stefano Lovo. 2013. Credit rating industry: A helicopter tour of stylized facts and
recent theories. International Journal of Industrial Organization . [Crossref]
117. Mardi Dungey, Gerald P. Dwyer, Thomas Flavin. 2013. Systematic and Liquidity Risk in Subprime-
Mortgage Backed Securities. Open Economies Review 24:1, 5-32. [Crossref]
118. Thomas Mählmann. 2013. Hedge funds, CDOs and the financial crisis: An empirical investigation
of the “Magnetar trade”. Journal of Banking & Finance 37:2, 537-548. [Crossref]
119. Samuel G. Hanson, Adi Sunderam. 2013. Are there too many safe securities? Securitization and the
incentives for information production. Journal of Financial Economics 108:3, 565. [Crossref]
120. Malcolm Baker, Jeffrey Wurgler. Behavioral Corporate Finance: An Updated Survey 357-424.
[Crossref]
121. Anna Scherbina. 2013. Asset Price Bubbles: A Selective Survey. IMF Working Papers 13:45, i.
[Crossref]
122. JIE JACK HE, JUN QJ QIAN, PHILIP E. STRAHAN. 2012. Are All Ratings Created Equal? The
Impact of Issuer Size on the Pricing of Mortgage-Backed Securities. The Journal of Finance 67:6,
2097-2137. [Crossref]
123. Carol Bertaut, Laurie Pounder DeMarco, Steven Kamin, Ralph Tryon. 2012. ABS inflows to the
United States and the global financial crisis. Journal of International Economics 88:2, 219-234.
[Crossref]
124. Christian C. Opp, Marcus M. Opp, Milton Harris. 2012. Rating agencies in the face of regulation.
Journal of Financial Economics . [Crossref]
125. Rebel A. Cole, Lawrence J. White. 2012. Déjà Vu All Over Again: The Causes of U.S. Commercial
Bank Failures This Time Around. Journal of Financial Services Research 42:1-2, 5-29. [Crossref]
126. Efraim Benmelech, Jennifer Dlugosz, Victoria Ivashina. 2012. Securitization without adverse selection:
The case of CLOs. Journal of Financial Economics 106:1, 91-113. [Crossref]
127. Eduardo Pol. 2012. The preponderant causes of the USA banking crisis 2007–08. The Journal of
Socio-Economics 41:5, 519-528. [Crossref]
128. Tobias Adrian, Adam B. Ashcraft. 2012. Shadow Banking Regulation. Annual Review of Financial
Economics 4:1, 99-140. [Crossref]
129. Taylor D. Nadauld, Michael S. Weisbach. 2012. Did securitization affect the cost of corporate debt?.
Journal of Financial Economics 105:2, 332-352. [Crossref]
130. M. Pagano, P. Volpin. 2012. Securitization, Transparency, and Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies
25:8, 2417-2453. [Crossref]
131. JOHN M. GRIFFIN, DRAGON YONGJUN TANG. 2012. Did Subjectivity Play a Role in CDO
Credit Ratings?. The Journal of Finance 67:4, 1293-1328. [Crossref]
132. Nigel F. B. Allington, John S. L. McCombie, Maureen Pike. 2012. Lessons not learned: from the
collapse of Long-Term Capital Management to the subprime crisis. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics
34:4, 555-582. [Crossref]
133. Anna Scherbina, Bernd Schlusche. 2012. Asset Bubbles: an Application to Residential Real Estate.
European Financial Management 18:3, 464-491. [Crossref]
134. Nicola Gennaioli, Andrei Shleifer, Robert Vishny. 2012. Neglected risks, financial innovation, and
financial fragility. Journal of Financial Economics 104:3, 452-468. [Crossref]
135. Thomas Mählmann. 2012. Did investors outsource their risk analysis to rating agencies? Evidence
from ABS-CDOs. Journal of Banking & Finance 36:5, 1478-1491. [Crossref]
136. Mami Kobayashi, Hiroshi Osano. 2012. Nonrecourse financing and securitization. Journal of Financial
Intermediation . [Crossref]
137. Michael B. Gordy, Søren Willemann. 2012. Constant Proportion Debt Obligations: A Postmortem
Analysis of Rating Models. Management Science 58:3, 476-492. [Crossref]
138. Stephen Morris,, Hyun Song Shin. 2012. Contagious Adverse Selection. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 4:1, 1-21. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
139. W.S. Frame, L.J. White. Industrial Organisation of the US Residential Mortgage Market 37-48.
[Crossref]
140. Tobias Adrian, Adam B. Ashcraft. Shadow Banking: A Review of the Literature 1-29. [Crossref]
141. Cassio Neri, Lorenz Schneider. 2011. Maximum entropy distributions inferred from option portfolios
on an asset. Finance and Stochastics . [Crossref]
142. Kimberly J. Cornaggia. Financial Distress and Bankruptcy 351-370. [Crossref]
143. Josh Lerner, Peter Tufano. 2011. The Consequences of Financial Innovation: A Counterfactual
Research Agenda. Annual Review of Financial Economics 3:1, 41-85. [Crossref]
144. Marvin Goodfriend. 2011. Money Markets. Annual Review of Financial Economics 3:1, 119-137.
[Crossref]
145. Edward I. Altman, T. Sabri Öncü, Matthew Richardson, Anjolein Schmeits, Lawrence J. White.
Regulation of Rating Agencies 443-467. [Crossref]
146. Andrew K. Rose, Mark M. Spiegel. 2011. Cross-country causes and consequences of the 2008 crisis:
Early warning. Japan and the World Economy . [Crossref]
147. Gregory Connor, Thomas Flavin, Brian O’Kelly. 2011. The U.S. and Irish credit crises: Their
distinctive differences and common features. Journal of International Money and Finance . [Crossref]
148. Andrea Micocci. 2011. Marx and the Crisis. International Journal of Political Economy 40:3, 72-87.
[Crossref]
149. Giovanni Calice. 2011. The subprime asset-backed securities market and the equity prices of large
complex financial institutions. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 21:4,
585-604. [Crossref]
150. Anthony Meder, Steven T. Schwartz, Eric E. Spires, Richard A. Young. 2011. Structured Finance
and Mark-to-Model Accounting: A Few Simple Illustrations. Accounting Horizons 25:3, 559-576.
[Crossref]
151. Bruce G. Carruthers, Jeong-Chul Kim. 2011. The Sociology of Finance. Annual Review of Sociology
37:1, 239-259. [Crossref]
152. ANIL SHIVDASANI, YIHUI WANG. 2011. Did Structured Credit Fuel the LBO Boom?. The
Journal of Finance 66:4, 1291-1328. [Crossref]
153. Donald R Chambers, Michael A Kelly, Qin Lu, Adam Biesenbach, Angela King, Kuni Natsuki, Qi
Sun. 2011. CDO Squareds: The Case of Subprime Mortgages. The Journal of Structured Finance
17:2, 96-113. [Crossref]
154. David M. Zimmer. 2011. The Role of Copulas in the Housing Crisis. Review of Economics and Statistics
120224102436000. [Crossref]
155. Helge Peukert. 2011. Dysfunctional aspects of contemporary financial markets: diagnosis and
prescription. European Journal of Law and Economics . [Crossref]
156. Heski Bar-Isaac,, Joel Shapiro. 2011. Credit Ratings Accuracy and Analyst Incentives. American
Economic Review 101:3, 120-124. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
157. John M. Griffin,, Dragon Yongjun Tang. 2011. Did Credit Rating Agencies Make Unbiased
Assumptions on CDOs?. American Economic Review 101:3, 125-130. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
158. Jie He,, Jun Qian,, Philip E. Strahan. 2011. Credit Ratings and the Evolution of the Mortgage-Backed
Securities Market. American Economic Review 101:3, 131-135. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
159. Bernd Skiera, Manuel Bermes, Lutz Horn. 2011. Customer Equity Sustainability Ratio: A New Metric
for Assessing a Firm's Future Orientation. Journal of Marketing 75:3, 118-131. [Crossref]
160. Paul Calem, Christopher Henderson, Jonathan Liles. 2011. “Cherry Picking” in Subprime Mortgage
Securitizations: Which Subprime Mortgage Loans Were Sold by Depository Institutions Prior to the
Crisis of 2007?. Journal of Housing Economics . [Crossref]
161. Eliana Balla, Robert E. Carpenter, Breck L. Robinson. 2011. Assessing the Effectiveness of the Paulson
“Teaser Freezer” Plan: Evidence from the ABX Index. Journal of Economics and Business . [Crossref]
162. Kaushik Basu. 2011. A simple model of the financial crisis of 2007‐2009, with implications for the
design of a stimulus package. Indian Growth and Development Review 4:1, 5-21. [Crossref]
163. Radu Vranceanu. 2011. Four myths and a financial crisis. Thunderbird International Business Review
53:2, 151-171. [Crossref]
164. Andrei Shleifer,, Robert Vishny. 2011. Fire Sales in Finance and Macroeconomics. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 25:1, 29-48. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
165. Emiliano Brancaccio, Giuseppe Fontana. The Conventional Views of the Global Crisis: A Critical
Assessment 39-62. [Crossref]
166. Christopher L. Foote, Paul S. Willen. Subprime Mortgage Crisis, the 1-12. [Crossref]
167. Georges de Menil. 2010. Reflections on the Great Recession of 2008–09 *. Asian Economic Papers
9:3, 162-173. [Crossref]
168. Helge Peukert. 2010. Notes and Communications: The Financial Crisis: Origins and Remedies in a
Critical Institutionalist Perspective. Journal of Economic Issues 44:3, 830-838. [Crossref]
169. Andrei Shleifer, Robert W. Vishny. 2010. Unstable banking☆. Journal of Financial Economics 97:3,
306-318. [Crossref]
170. Christian Calmès, Raymond Théoret. 2010. The impact of off-balance-sheet activities on banks
returns: An application of the ARCH-M to Canadian data. Journal of Banking & Finance 34:7,
1719-1728. [Crossref]
171. Joan O'Connell. 2010. The 2007 crisis and countercyclical policy. Studies in Economics and Finance
27:2, 148-160. [Crossref]
172. Donald R Chambers, Michael A. Kelly, Qin Lu. 2010. The Role of the Constant Recovery
Assumption in the Subprime Bubble. The Journal of Alternative Investments 13:1, 30-40. [Crossref]
173. Lawrence J. White,. 2010. Markets: The Credit Rating Agencies. Journal of Economic Perspectives
24:2, 211-226. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
174. Oliver Faltin-Traeger,, Kathleen W. Johnson,, Christopher Mayer. 2010. Issuer Credit Quality and
the Price of Asset Backed Securities. American Economic Review 100:2, 501-505. [Citation] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
175. Bruce G. Carruthers. Knowledge and liquidity: Institutional and cognitive foundations of the subprime
crisis 157-182. [Crossref]
176. Rudolf Richter. 2009. Who Listened? Unappreciated Teachings of New Institutional Economics
Related to the Financial Crisis 2008. Kredit und Kapital 42:4, 473-485. [Crossref]
177. Gillian G.H. Garcia. 2009. Ignoring the lessons for effective prudential supervision, failed bank
resolution and depositor protection. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 17:3, 186-209.
[Crossref]
178. Efraim Benmelech, Jennifer Dlugosz. 2009. The alchemy of CDO credit ratings. Journal of Monetary
Economics 56:5, 617-634. [Crossref]
179. Lawrence White. 2009. THE CREDIT-RATING AGENCIES AND THE SUBPRIME
DEBACLE. Critical Review 21:2, 389-399. [Crossref]
180. Amadou N. R. Sy. 2009. The Systemic Regulation of Credit Rating Agencies and Rated Markets.
IMF Working Papers 09:129, 1. [Crossref]
181. Folarin Akinbami. The global financial crisis: Causes, effects and issues to consider in the reform of
financial regulation 167-190. [Crossref]