Doran-Fields Medal
Doran-Fields Medal
Doran-Fields Medal
George J. Borjas
Kirk B. Doran
Abstract: Knowledge generation is key to economic growth, and scientific prizes are designed
to encourage it. But how does winning a prestigious prize affect future output? We compare the
productivity of Fields medalists (winners of the top mathematics prize) to that of similarly
brilliant contenders. The two groups have similar publication rates until the award year, after
which the winners’ productivity declines. The medalists begin to “play the field,” studying
unfamiliar topics at the expense of writing papers. It appears that tournaments can have large
George J. Borjas is the Robert W. Scrivner Professor of Economics and Social Policy at the
Harvard Kennedy School and Research Associate at the National Bureau of Economic
Research; [email protected]. Kirk B. Doran is an Assistant Professor of Economics at
the University of Notre Dame; [email protected]. We are grateful to Noam Elkies, William
Evans, Richard Freeman, David Galenson, Daniel Hamermesh, David Harbater, Larry Katz,
Curtis McMullen, Kannan Soundararajan, Wilfried Schmid, Bruce A. Weinberg, Yoram Weiss,
and Trevor Wooley for comments and suggestions on earlier drafts of this paper, and to Brian
Brinig for excellent research assistance. This paper uses confidential data from the MathSciNet
data archive maintained by the American Mathematical Society. The data can be obtained by
filing a request directly with the American Mathematical Society. The authors would be happy to
Prizes and Productivity: How Winning the Fields Medal Affects Scientific Output
I look forward to proving more theorems. I hope the weight of this prize doesn't
slow me down.
—Stanislav Smirnov, Fields Medalist, 2010
I. Introduction
known about how knowledge is produced, making it difficult to predict which types of incentives
are most effective in eliciting effort from knowledge producers. Prizes are a common incentive
for knowledge production; hundreds of scientific prizes are awarded throughout the world and
across all scientific disciplines. Although these prizes are frequently awarded with the explicit
goal of inspiring more and better scientific work (Scotchmer 2006), a question remains: are they
effective?
A voluminous theoretical and empirical literature examines how the presence of potential
future rewards (whether a promotion to CEO or winning a golf tournament) elicits optimal
efforts from the tournament participants in their effort to win the contest.1 This literature
emphasizes the incentive effects of the prize prior to the completion of the tournament. But what
happens to the productivity of tournament winners after they win the prize?2 Standard models of
labor supply suggest that the post-prize impact of a big win could be significant, especially when
This paper examines the impact of winning the Fields Medal on the post-medal
productivity and research choices of mathematicians.3 The Fields Medal is the most prestigious
award in all of mathematics, awarded every four years to mathematicians under the age of 40.
Borjas and Doran 3
Established by the Canadian mathematician John Charles Fields, the medal is often thought of as
the “Nobel Prize of Mathematics.”4 Inspired by the desire to promote mathematical cooperation
and research around the world, Fields used his position as Chairman of the Organization
Committee of the International Mathematical Congress to bring his idea to fruition. In a memo
appended to the January 12, 1932 minutes of the Committee of the International Congress at
In the same document, Fields explained the motivation for the award: “while [the medal]
was in recognition of work already done it was at the same time intended to be an
encouragement for further achievement on the part of the recipients and a stimulus to renewed
effort on the part of others” [emphasis added]. In other words, not only would the existence of
the prize solicit effort from the participants in this elite tournament, it would also encourage
Using administrative data from the American Mathematical Society (AMS) and the
Mathematics Genealogy Project (MGP), we examine the shape of the age-productivity profile of
these exceptional mathematicians along a number of dimensions, including the number of papers
published, citations received, and students mentored. Our empirical analysis exploits the fact that
only a subset of the great mathematical contributions in the past 80 years resulted in Fields
medals, and that this subset was partly determined by arbitrary factors such as the quadrennial
Our main set of results uses the set of winners from a broader set of prizes for great
mathematical achievement (awards which are themselves good predictors of winning the Fields
“contenders” for the medal. Our analysis compares the research output of the medalists with that
of the losing contenders. The age-productivity profile of the two groups is similar until a
particular mathematician wins the Fields Medal (or does not win it). Remarkably, the
productivity of the Fields medalists declines noticeably relative to that of the contenders in the
more than any other potential event in the mathematics profession. Although the prize money is
itself negligible, the medal can certainly lead to a substantial increase in “wealth” (both in terms
leverage the award in the marketplace. The neoclassical labor-leisure model predicts that the
expansion in the opportunity set should induce the medalists to consume more leisure in the post-
medal period. Moreover, the wealth effect can also lead to a shift in the research strategy pursued
by the Fields medalists: they are now free to “play the field” and pursue topics in different areas
of mathematics (or even outside mathematics) that they may find interesting or worthwhile and
We employ the notion of “cognitive mobility” (Borjas and Doran 2014) to capture the
transition in the space of ideas as knowledge producers move from one research topic to another
over the course of a career. The AMS data classifies each published paper into one of 73 specific
and narrow mathematical fields. It turns out that there is a crucial link between a
Borjas and Doran 5
mathematician’s propensity for cognitive mobility across mathematical fields and the awarding
of a Fields Medal. Specifically, while medalists and contenders have similar cognitive mobility
rates initially, the medalists exhibit a far greater rate of mobility in the post-medal period.
Because cognitive mobility is costly (for example, additional time is required to prepare a paper
in an unfamiliar field), the increased rate of cognitive mobility reduces the medalists’ rate of
output in the post-medal period. The data suggest that about half of the decreased rate of output
is due to the increased propensity for “trying out” unfamiliar fields, often outside pure
mathematics.
Every four years, the greatest mathematicians in the world gather to select and honor new
medalists and to remind them that the Fields Medal is meant to encourage their future
achievement. In fact, the medal reduces the rate of publication and the likelihood that its winners
produce great achievements in pure mathematics. At least in this context, it seems that the net
productivity impact of selecting winners on the basis of a tournament depends crucially on what
happens as the winners adjust their behavior to take advantage of the post-prize expansion in the
opportunity set.
The first Fields Medals were awarded soon after Fields’ 1932 memo. The medals are
traditionally awarded during the opening ceremony of the quadrennial International Congress of
Mathematicians (ICM). In 1936, the medals were awarded to two mathematicians. Because of
World War II, the medals were not awarded again until 1950, when they were again given to two
mathematicians. Since 1950, the Fields Medal has been awarded quadrennially, to two, three, or
The initial moneys available to fund the medals were the result of an accidental surplus of
funds left over after the 1924 ICM. These funds, accompanied by the bequest of Fields himself,
allowed for the granting of two medals. In 1966, an anonymous donor made additional funds
available allowing four medals to be awarded in each of the next two cycles (ICM 1966). As a
result, the number of Fields Medals awarded in any given 4-year cycle was not mainly
determined by how many mathematicians had made fundamental advances in the relevant time
period. Instead, the number often depended on how much income had accumulated in the Fields
Medal account, on the availability of private anonymous donors, and on an upper limit of
(initially) two or (later) four medals to be awarded by any particular Congress (ICM 2006).
As noted earlier, the Fields Medals were designed partly to promote future mathematical
achievement on the part of the recipients. This goal is sufficiently important that it has been
repeated verbatim and expounded upon at nearly every award ceremony. For example, in the
1954 Congress, eminent mathematician Hermann Weyl spoke movingly to the winners: “The
mathematical community is proud of the work you both have done. It shows that the old gnarled
tree of mathematics is still full of sap and life. Carry on as you began!”
From its inception, the committees have interpreted Fields' desire for future
encouragement to mean that the medal should be awarded to mathematicians who are “young”
(ICM 1936), and the word “young” has consistently been interpreted to mean that the medal may
only be awarded to mathematicians under the age of 40 (ICM various issues).5 Most recently, the
2006 committee explicitly stated its requirement that a mathematician qualifies for the Fields
Medal only if he has not yet turned 40 as of January 1 of the year in which the Congress meets
(ICM 2006).
Borjas and Doran 7
The restrictions on the number and age distribution of the Fields medalists introduce
arbitrary variation in which subset of great mathematicians of the past eighty years received the
award and which did not. As a result, many mathematicians who are widely perceived as “great
architects of twentieth-century mathematics,” even for work done at an early age, did not receive
the Fields Medal (Tropp 1976). There are numerous such examples. The American Mathematical
Society said of mathematician George Lusztig: “[His work] has entirely reshaped representation
theory and in the process changed much of mathematics” (AMS 2008, p. 489). Although
“Lusztig's exceptional mathematical ability became evident at an early stage of his career,” and
"it can be no exaggeration to say that George Lusztig is one of the great mathematicians of our
time," he did not receive the Fields Medal (Carter 2006, pp. 2, 42).
Similarly, the Norwegian Academy of Science and Letters (Solholm 2010) cited John
Tate for “his vast and lasting impact on the theory of numbers,” claiming that “many of the
major lines of research in algebraic number theory and arithmetic geometry are only possible
because of [his] incisive contributions and illuminating insights.” Nevertheless, Tate also did not
In fact, considering the number of mathematicians who are regularly lauded by the
various National Academies of Sciences and Mathematical Societies for (re)inventing new
subfields of mathematics, it is clear that the 52 Fields Medals that have been awarded (as of
2013) are insufficient to cover even half of all the great achievements that have made modern
mathematics possible. Hence it should not be particularly surprising that Robert Langlands, a
mathematician whose work specifically inspired and made possible the contributions of at least
two Fields Medalists (Laurent Lafforgue and Ngô Bảo Châu), and who founded the most
Borjas and Doran 8
influential program connecting number theory and representation theory, did not receive the
Historians of the Fields Medal have also documented the “bias” that causes some fields
and styles of mathematics to be better represented among winners (Monastyrsky 2001). For
example, Langlands (1985, p. 212) wrote of mathematician Harish-Chandra: “He was considered
for the Fields Medal in 1958, but a forceful member of the selection committee in whose eyes
Thom [one of the two Fields medalists that year] was a Bourbakist was determined not to have
two. So Harish-Chandra, whom he also placed on the Bourbaki camp, was set aside."6
Similarly, the arbitrary age cut-off and the four-year periodicity of the award work
together to exclude mathematicians who obviously should have received the medal. The New
York Times obituary of Oded Schramm states: “If Dr. Schramm had been born three weeks and a
day later, he would almost certainly have been one of the winners of the Fields Medal…But the
Fields Medals, which honor groundbreaking work by young mathematicians, are awarded only
once every four years and only to mathematicians who are 40 or under. Dr. Schramm was born
on Dec. 10, 1961; the cutoff birth date for the 2002 Fields was Jan. 1, 1962. Wendelin Werner, a
younger mathematician who collaborated with Dr. Schramm on follow-up research, won a Fields
In short, while it is tempting to claim that the 52 Fields medalists are in a class by
themselves, and that there are no losing contenders with equivalent or better early achievements,
this view does not correspond with what mathematicians themselves have written. As the ICM
noted: “we must bear in mind how clearly hindsight shows that past recipients of the Fields’
medal were only a selection from a much larger group of mathematicians whose impact on
mathematics was at least as great as that of the chosen” (ICM 1994). The arbitrariness in the
Borjas and Doran 9
number, timing, and field distribution of Fields medalists means that a similarly great group of
“contenders” should exist that can be contrasted with the winners in a difference-in-differences
strategy to determine how winning the medal influences productivity and research choices.
III. Data
To measure the life cycle productivity of elite mathematicians, we use the comprehensive
data contained in the AMS MathSciNet archives. The AMS provided us with a database that
reports the number of papers published by every mathematician in the world, by field and year,
since 1939. The AMS professional staff assigns each publication in mathematics to one of the
many fields that make up the discipline (and this information will prove useful below). Our
database contains the author-year-field information at the two-digit field level, classifying every
publication over the 1939-2011 period into one of 73 different fields. The database also contains
information on the number of citations received by the papers. It is important to note, however,
that the AMS citation data is incomplete. In particular, it only counts citations in a limited
number of journals (which include the most important journals in mathematics), and only reports
the post-2000 citations received by a paper (regardless of when the paper was published).
We wish to determine what the post-medal career path of Fields medalists would have
looked like had they not been awarded the medal. Because of the capricious events affecting the
selection of the subset of great mathematicians who received the medal, we conjecture that there
should exist a comparison group of mathematicians who did similarly path-breaking work before
the age of 40, but who did not receive the medal and can serve as a control group.7
We use a systematic and easily replicable method for constructing the set of
“contenders.”8 Specifically, our construction of the control group starts out by including the
Borjas and Doran 10
winners of six other major mathematical awards with roughly similar goals as the Fields Medal.
It turns out that winning any one of these prizes is a good predictor for receiving a Fields Medal.
First, we consider the two most prestigious general mathematics prizes (after the Fields
Medal), which tend to be given closer to the end of a mathematician’s career. Both the Abel
Prize and the Wolf Prize cover the entire breadth of the mathematics discipline and are only
given to mathematicians who have made extraordinary contributions. The Abel Prize, which has
a significantly higher monetary value than the Fields Medal (nearly $1 million versus $15,000),
began to be awarded in 2003 to one or two mathematicians a year.9 The Wolf Prize has been
awarded annually since 1978, typically to two mathematicians (although no prize has been
awarded in some years). Any mathematician who won either of these prestigious awards (and did
not win the Fields Medal) is clearly a key formulator of modern mathematics and automatically
In addition to these two general prizes, there are a number of prestigious area-specific
prizes in mathematics. Specifically, we consider the four most prestigious area-specific awards
for: algebra (the Cole Prize of the AMS); analysis (the Bôcher Prize of the AMS); geometry (the
Veblen Prize of the AMS), and the study of Fourier series (the Salem Prize). We add into our
group of potential contenders any mathematicians who won one of these four area prizes before
This algorithm yields the names of 92 potential contenders who contributed significantly
to at least one of the key subject areas of mathematics or to mathematics as a whole, but who did
not receive the Fields Medal. There is a very strong correlation between winning any of these
prizes and winning the Fields Medal: 52 percent of the Fields medalists also won at least one of
these prestigious awards. The predictive power of each prize is as follows: five out of the 13
Borjas and Doran 11
Abel Prize winners also won the Fields; as did 13 out of the 54 Wolf Prize winners; three out of
the 26 Cole Prize winners; four out of the 32 Bôcher Prize winners; four out of the 29 Veblen
Fields Medal in any particular cycle, so that we need to observe the mathematician’s date of birth.
Although the AMS data does not provide this information, we ascertained the birth date (through
internet searches for each mathematician’s curriculum vitae or personal contact) for all Fields
medalists and for almost all of the potential contenders. The systematic archival of publications
by MathSciNet started in 1939, and some mathematicians in our sample published in their
teenage years, so we restrict the study to those born in or after 1920. Further, we exclude the six
potential contenders for whom we could not confirm a date of birth. This leaves us with a sample
of 47 medalists and 86 potential contenders. Appendix 1 presents the combined list of all winners,
a list that includes all the mathematicians mentioned in our historical survey.
There is obviously a great deal of variation in the mathematical significance and timing
of the work of the potential contenders. For example, the narrowness of the area prizes suggests
that the contribution of some of these winners, although very important in that particular area,
may not have the “breadth” required to generate sufficient interest in the broader community of
mathematicians. Similarly, some of the contenders (who perhaps went on to win one of the
general prizes) may have produced their best work after their eligibility for the Fields Medal
ended. Hence we whittle down the list of 86 potential contenders by examining how often other
mathematicians cite the work that the contenders produced during the years they were eligible
A recipient of the Fields Medal cannot have turned 40 after January 1 of the year in
which the medal is awarded. For example, the 2010 medal cycle would have been the last cycle
for a person born anytime between January 1, 1970 and December 31, 1973. Even though the
contenders born in this time frame did not win in their last shot at the medal, the incentives for
“impressing” the Fields Medal committee ended in 2010. Hence we assign the year 2010 as the
“medal year” for these contenders to separate the pre- and post-medal periods. We used a similar
exercise to ascertain the medal year for all the contenders in our sample. A mathematician’s
eligibility period is then given by the years between the mathematician’s first publication and the
medal year.
We calculate the annual rate of citations generated by a potential contender during his
eligibility period by dividing the total number of citations received by papers published in this
period (cumulative as of October 2011) by the number of years in the eligibility period. We then
define the final set of contenders as the 43 mathematicians in this group whose annual eligibility-
period citation rate is above the median. In other words, our final group of contenders represents
“la crème de la crème” of mathematicians who did widely recognized work during the eligibility
Table 1 reports summary statistics for the sample of Fields medalists as well as for the
control group (using both the final list of contenders with above-median citations, as well as the
group of all 86 prize winners).12 The table also reports comparable statistics (when available) for
the AMS archive whose first and last published papers span at least a 20-year period.
Obviously, both the Fields medalists and the contenders publish much more and receive
many more citations than the average mathematician. There is, however, relatively little
Borjas and Doran 13
difference in measured productivity between the final group of contenders and the Fields
medalists. The medalists published 3.1 papers per year during their career, as compared to 3.6
papers for the contenders. The typical paper published by a medalist received 21.0 citations, as
compared to 17.5 citations for the contenders. The average mathematician in both groups was
born around 1950, and they each published their first paper at the early age of 23 or 24.
The table also summarizes the rate of output by age, calculating the average number of
papers published annually by the medalists and the contenders between the ages of 20-39 and 40-
59. The data reveal suggestive differences. The medalists and the contenders published
essentially the same number of papers per year in the early part of the career (3.4 papers), but the
medalists published 1.2 fewer papers per year after age 40. This striking pattern presages the
As noted earlier, despite the plethora of important prizes that a brilliant mathematician
can potentially receive, the prestige of the Fields Medal is substantially greater than that of any
other prize. In fact, the ICM Fields Medal announcement emphasizes that the prestige effect is
far greater than the accompanying monetary award: “The Fields Medals carry the highest
prestige of all awards in mathematics. This prestige does not derive from the value of the cash
award, but from the superb mathematical qualities of the previous Fields Medal awardees” (ICM
2010).
mathematician’s lifetime wealth is not limited to the $15,000 monetary prize. Fields medalists
are likely to see a substantial expansion in their opportunity set, in terms of high-quality job
offers, additional research funding, and many other career opportunities. It is conceivable,
Borjas and Doran 14
therefore, that the wealth effect (which includes money as well as the additional opportunities
allowed by the substantial increase in professional prestige) could be sizable and could alter the
The neoclassical labor-leisure model suggests that the wealth effect should increase the
consumption of leisure by the Fields medalists relative to that of the contenders. As a result, we
should not be surprised if the “weight of the prize” does indeed slow the Fields medalists down.
Moreover, the wealth effect might influence the mathematician’s choice of research topics, either
because the mathematician can now afford to explore topics that are essentially “consumption
goods” or because the medalist feels that he can pursue “riskier” topics. These shifts in research
We initially measure the productivity of the elite mathematicians by the number of papers
published in each year. Figure 1 illustrates the life cycle trend in the average number of papers
published by both the medalists and the control group composed of the subset of contenders who
have above-median citations in the eligibility period. Specifically, the figure plots the average
number of papers published per year by the medalists and the contenders at the prime of their
career, relative to the medal year. The Fields medalists are plotted relative to the year they
actually received the medal (a zero on the x-axis represents the year of the prize); the contenders
are plotted relative to the last year of their eligibility for the medal (a zero on the x-axis
It is evident that the medalists and the contenders had very similar age-productivity
profiles during the eligibility period, publishing around three to four papers per year. The figure
also shows, however, a dramatic drop in the annual rate of output for the medalists that coincides
Borjas and Doran 15
with their receipt of the Fields Medal. A decade or two after the Fields medal, the average
medalist published around 1.5 fewer papers per year than the average contender.15
Of course, these differences could be due to factors that cannot be controlled for by the
graphical analysis, including individual fixed effects, calendar-year effects, and age differences.
We stack the annual data in our panel of medalists and contenders, and estimate the regression
model:
where yit gives the number of papers published by mathematician i in calendar year t; δi and δt
are vectors of individual and calendar-year fixed effects, respectively; T is a dummy variable
indicating if the observation refers to the post-medal period; F is a dummy variable indicating if
mathematician i won the Fields medal; and Z is a set of background characteristics that includes
the mathematician’s age (introduced as a fourth-order polynomial). The data panel contains one
observation for each mathematician for each year between the year of the first publication and
the most recent year of potential activity (if alive) or the year of death. The coefficient α
measures the difference in the annual rate of publication between the post- and pre-medal periods
for the contenders, while the coefficient β measures the relative change in this gap for the Fields
medalists.
The first two columns report coefficients when the control group is formed by the sample of
contenders with above-median citations in the eligibility period. Row 1 reports the simplest
regression model. The estimate of α is small, suggesting no substantial difference in the average
Borjas and Doran 16
annual product of the contenders in the pre- and post-medal periods (after controlling for age and
period effects). The estimate of β is negative and around -1.4, indicating a (relative) drop of
more than one paper per year in the post-medal period for the Fields medalists. In other words,
even after controlling for individual-specific productivity differences and aging effects, there is a
sharp decline in the productivity of the medalists after they were awarded the medal.
The specification changes reported in the remaining rows of Table 1 corroborate this
finding. Row 2 uses the log number of papers per year as the dependent variable, but excludes
from the regression those (relatively few) years where the elite mathematicians did not publish at
all. The log papers regression shows a 24 percent decline in productivity in the post-medal period.
Row 3 reports the coefficient from a quantile regression where the dependent variable is the
median number of papers per year (using bootstrapped standard errors clustered at the
mathematician level). The regression shows a decline of -0.7 papers per year in the post-medal
period. Finally, the last two rows of the table use alternative methods for ascertaining the “medal
year” in the sample of contenders: either at age 36 (the median age at which Fields medalists
actually receive their medal) or age 40 (the maximum age of eligibility). The estimate of the
The last two columns of the table report the estimated coefficients when the control group
includes all 86 members of the sample of contenders (that is, all the prize winners without any
quality cutoff). Regardless of the method used to define the sample of contenders, the regression
coefficients are similar. The data reveals that the Fields medalists produce between 0.9 and 1.4
fewer papers per year in the post-medal period (or roughly a 20 percent decline in productivity)
than would be predicted either from their previous output or from the output of other great
The observed decline in the annual number of publications cannot be attributed to either
the effect of mechanical mean reversion or to an “expectation bias” among the members of the
award committee. Suppose that a mathematician’s observed productivity at a point in time has a
productivity is above some bar at time t will always show an average decline in productivity after
time t due to mean reversion in the transitory component of output. To avoid this type of
contamination, we restricted our analysis to contenders who had reached similarly high
productivity levels in the Fields Medal eligibility period. As a result, any mean reversion should
Second, the award committee members, containing some of the best mathematicians in
the world, surely observe future predictors of productivity among the contenders that we cannot
measure in a publication database, and they may be swayed by this private information in their
discussions. Given the future expectations bias, therefore, it would not be surprising if the
tournament winners do better in the post-tournament period. This bias would imply that our
We suspect, however, that this bias is less likely to be important in the context of the
Fields Medal than in comparable tournaments in “softer” sciences, such as the John Bates Clark
Medal in economics. First, publication lags for ground-breaking papers in pure mathematics can
be considerably shorter than they are in economics. Second, many competing groups of
mathematicians are often working on the next great unsolved problems at once. Not surprisingly,
they often wait until the proof is sufficiently complete before discussing their techniques openly.
Finally, even the private information that a mathematician is out to prove Hilbert's Eighth
Problem is unlikely to influence the Fields Medal committee, as the resulting proof will either be
Borjas and Doran 18
correct or not and the committee cannot determine the validity of the proof in advance. In
contrast, an interesting and fertile research agenda in applied economics can often produce
The AMS data also allows us to examine other output effects of the Fields Medal. Table
3 re-estimates the basic regression model using alternative dependent variables. The dependent
variable in row 1 is the probability that a mathematician publishes at least one paper in a given
year. The relative probability of publishing a paper falls by about 11.8 percentage points for the
medalists in the post-medal period. Row 2 uses the number of citations generated by papers
written in year t as the dependent variable. Although the AMS data only reports the post-2000
citations for a paper regardless of when the paper was published, the calendar year fixed effects
included in the regression model should control for the variation in citations between older and
newer papers.18 The coefficient β is again negative and significant, suggesting a decline of about
Part of the decline in citations is attributable to the fact that the medalists are less likely to
publish (and publish fewer papers when they do publish). Row 3 uses the number of citations per
paper published in a given year as the dependent variable (excluding years when the
mathematician did not publish at all). The material published by the medalists in the post-medal
period is, on average, less citation-worthy than the material published by the contenders. Even if
the typical post-medal paper written by a medalist generates fewer citations, the medalists may
be just as likely to hit a “home run.” We calculated a vintage-specific citation cutoff for papers
published each year using the universe of publications in the AMS database. By definition, a
mathematician hits a “home run” if the number of citations per paper published that year was
above the 99.5th percentile for all mathematicians in the AMS database. Row 4 shows that the
Borjas and Doran 19
(relative) probability that a medalist hits a home run in the post-medal period declines by 15.6
percentage points. At the other extreme, a mathematician may “strike out” and write papers that
are never cited. Row 5 shows that the medalist’s (relative) probability of striking out rises by 5.3
Finally, many of these elite mathematicians devote considerable time and effort to
training the next generation of mathematicians. In fact, biographies and laudations of their
achievements emphasize the training and mentoring of students as evidence of their long-lasting
impact on mathematics. We therefore also examine the impact of the Fields Medal on the
We obtained access to the data in the Mathematics Genealogy Project (MGP), and we
merged the genealogy data with the AMS publication data. The MGP data identifies the
intellectual progeny of the renowned mathematicians in our sample, as well as the year in which
those students received their doctoral degree. We were able to match 104 of the 133
mathematicians using an MGP-AMS match provided by the administrators of the MGP. For 28
of the remaining 29 unmatched mathematicians, we were able to obtain information about the
graduation years and names of their students from name-based searches of their curriculum vitae,
obituaries, or unmatched online MGP entries. The merged data also provides information on the
research output of the students in their post-doctoral career.19 The merged data, therefore, allows
us to examine not only the impact of the Fields Medal on the number of students produced in the
post-medal period, but also the impact on the quality of the students.
We are interested in the relation between the timing of the year in which a student
becomes an elite mathematician’s mentee and the year in which the mathematician receives (or
does not receive) the Fields Medal. The mentoring agreement typically occurs two to four years
Borjas and Doran 20
before the student obtains his or her doctoral degree. We lag the MGP degree date by three years
It turns out that Fields medalists are not only publishing fewer papers in the post-medal
period, and that those papers are relatively less important, but they are also accepting fewer
mentees under their wing. Row 6 of Table 3 reports the relevant coefficients when we estimate
the regression model using the number of mentees as the dependent variable. The regression
shows a (marginally significant) relative decline in the number of mentees accepted by the Fields
medalists of about 0.1 students per year. The last two rows estimate the regression model using
the mentee’s total number of publications and citations over their career to date as dependent
variables. The results show a pronounced decline in the quality-adjusted student output of Fields
attributed to idiosyncratic properties of the method we used to construct the control group of
contenders. In fact, it is easy to show that the results are almost identical if we pursued a
drastically different method for constructing the sample of contenders. In addition to the various
prizes discussed above, the mathematics profession honors a select number of elite
Congress of Mathematicians. The qualifications required for receiving such an invitation are
clearly stated in the memo detailing the program committee’s responsibilities (ICM 2007):
Plenary lectures are invited one-hour lectures to be held without other parallel
activities…The lectures should be broad surveys of recent major developments,
aimed at the entire mathematical community. Plenary speakers should be
outstanding mathematicians and good lecturers. It is the privilege of the PC
[Program Committee] to select the plenary speakers.
Borjas and Doran 21
The program committees in charge of organizing the plenary lectures have typically
scheduled around 20 plenary lectures at each ICM in recent decades. There have been 269
plenary speakers since the 1950 ICM, and these speakers include 34 of the 50 mathematicians
awarded the Fields medals during this period. We again obtained the lifetime publication record
for each of the invited plenary speakers from the AMS archives, and were able to determine the
year of birth for all but eight of the speakers. We then re-estimated the basic regression model in
equation (1) using the group of plenary speakers (who did not win the Fields medal) as the
control group.21
Table 4 summarizes the key results from our replication of the analysis. We illustrate the
including using the group of all plenary speakers as contenders or only the group of plenary
speakers who received an invitation to present a lecture by age 44.22 In addition, the table
illustrates the robustness of the results when these samples are further restricted to only include
mathematicians whose citation rate during the eligibility period placed them in the top half of the
group. Regardless of the exact definition of the control group, the evidence summarized in Table
4 is similar to that discussed earlier (both qualitatively and quantitatively). Fields medalists
publish around one fewer paper annually after they receive the medal; the papers they do publish
get cited less often; and they have a lower probability of hitting a home run and a higher
probability of striking out. Because the evidence is robust to the definition of the control group,
the analysis presented in the remainder of this paper reverts to the simpler definition of a control
group that uses the sample of mathematicians who have received one of the six prestigious
V. Cognitive Mobility
published, citations generated, or students mentored, is lower than would have been expected. A
question immediately arises: what exactly are the medalists doing with their time in the post-
medal period?
implied by the Fields Medal introduces incentives to consume more leisure—along the lines of
the wealth effect in the neoclassical labor-leisure model. As long as leisure is a normal good, the
increase in the opportunity set associated with the Fields medal (which includes the value of the
additional prestige, job offers, grant opportunities, etc.) could lead to the medalists behaving in
the predicted fashion and increasing their consumption of leisure. The increased leisure leaves
In fact, the neoclassical labor-leisure model has a second implication: the Fields Medal
should increase his consumption of all normal goods. A medalist could respond by increasing his
consumption of “enjoyable research” in fields outside of pure mathematics, and perhaps begin to
dabble in such disciplines as biology and economics.23 Moreover, the medalist may now
perceive a freedom to pursue research topics that lead to riskier outcomes than he would have
pursued otherwise.24 These shifts in research interests may also affect productivity.
research topics by the elite mathematicians in our sample. As noted in Borjas and Doran (2014),
knowledge producers who are conducting research on a particular set of questions may respond
to changed opportunities by shifting their time, effort, and other resources to a different set of
Borjas and Doran 23
questions. Cognitive mobility then measures the transition from one location to another in idea
space.
We compare the cognitive mobility rates of the medalists and contenders in the post-
medal period. As noted earlier, the AMS data provides information not only on the annual output
(as measured by papers and citations) of mathematicians, but also categorizes each paper into
one of the 73 fields that make up the discipline of mathematics and related subjects. Because of
the large number of fields, it is obvious that we need to reduce the dimensionality of the space of
ideas in order to operationalize the concept of cognitive mobility in the current context.
Assume that a mathematician’s career begins the year he publishes his first paper. We
can then examine the distribution of a mathematician’s research topics in, say, the first x years of
his career. The AMS data allows us to determine the modal field of the papers published in those
years, as the mathematician was getting his career started and signaling his “quality” to the rest
of the profession.
close to the modal field, while others are unrelated. The notion of cognitive mobility, therefore,
should incorporate the fact that a move between the modal field and any other field may be
“cognitively close” or “cognitively far.” To determine the cognitive distance between any two
fields, we calculated a matrix with elements [fij] showing the fraction of references made by
papers published in field i to papers published in field j.25 To illustrate, suppose that the modal
field was Partial Differential Equations. The three most closely related fields (with the three
largest values of fij) are Partial Differential Equations itself, Global Analysis, and Fluid
Mechanics. These three fields account for 72 percent of all references made by papers published
Borjas and Doran 24
in Partial Differential Equations. At the other extreme, papers published in Partial Differential
Equations never referenced papers published in either General Algebraic Systems or K-Theory.
It turns out that we typically do not need to expand the definition of “cognitively close”
beyond 15 fields to capture almost all the references made by papers published in field i. For
example, 77.6 percent of all references made in Partial Differential Equations are to the top 5
fields, 87.4 percent are to the top 10, and 92.5 percent are to the top 15. This clustering around a
very small number of fields is quite representative of the discipline of mathematics. In particular,
93.1 percent of the references in papers published in the median field of mathematics are made to
papers published in only 15 other fields (the respective statistics for the 10th and 90th percentile
Of course, it is not uncommon for elite mathematicians to move within a small (and often
related) set of fields in the early part of their career. To capture this oscillation, we expand the
definition of the “modal field” to include either the most common or the second most common
field in the early part of a mathematician’s career. For each of these two modes, we then
constructed the set of the 15 most related fields. Our cognitive mobility variable then indicates if
the mathematician moved outside the two modal fields and all related fields (in other words, if
the mathematician moved out of the potential maximum of 30 fields that broadly define his
To easily illustrate the trends in cognitive mobility, we first define the “early career
period” as the eligibility period for the Fields Medal (that is, the years before the Fields medalist
won the medal or the years in which contenders were eligible for the medal). We then calculate
the probability that papers published in each year of a mathematician’s career are outside the
comfort zone (or in a different field than the two modal and related fields). Figure 2 plots this
Borjas and Doran 25
measure of cognitive mobility. As before, Fields medalists are plotted relative to the year they
actually received the medal, and the contenders are plotted relative to the last year of eligibility.
The probability that either the medalists or contenders strayed from their comfort zone
prior to the medal year is small, around 5 percent a year for mathematicians in either group. This
similarity, however, breaks down dramatically in the post-medal period. The rate of cognitive
mobility doubled to 10 percent for the contenders, but rose dramatically for the medalists,
quintupling to 25 percent. In short, the data reveal that the awarding of the Fields Medal is
associated with a strong increase in the likelihood that a mathematician tries out fields that are
To determine if this correlation persists after controlling for individual and period fixed
effects, we use the AMS data to construct a panel where an observation represents a paper
published by each mathematician. In particular, let pint be an indicator variable set to unity if the
field of the nth paper published by mathematician i (and published in year t) differs from that of
the modal and related papers in the baseline period. We then estimate the regression model:
Table 5 reports the relevant coefficients (α, β) using several alternative specifications. As
with the illustration in Figure 2, the first row of the table uses the publications in the eligibility
period to define the set of fields that make up the mathematician’s comfort zone. We illustrate
the robustness of our results by using either the two modal fields (and up to 30 related fields), or
just simply the modal field (and its 15 related fields). Regardless of the specification, the
awarding of a Fields medal substantially increases the rate of cognitive mobility. Even after
Borjas and Doran 26
controlling for individual-specific fixed effects, the awarding of the Fields Medal increases the
The next two rows of the top panel conduct sensitivity tests by using alternative
definitions of the “early career” period used to construct the mathematician’s comfort zone. Row
2 uses the first three years of the career, while row 3 uses the first five years. Similarly, the
regressions in Panel B use the entire sample of contenders (without any quality cutoff) to
estimate the model. Regardless of the specification, the awarding of the Fields Medal has a
positive and significant impact on the probability that a mathematician engages in cognitive
mobility.26
The freedom to try out new things, however, does not come cheap. Cognitive mobility,
like any other type of move, can be costly. The mathematician is exiting a field where he has
remarkable technical skills and attempting to prove theorems in areas where his intuition may not
be as strong and where the proofs may require a new set of tools. It would not be surprising,
therefore, it if takes longer to produce a paper after the mathematician has engaged in cognitive
mobility.
Define the duration of a “preparation spell” as the length of time elapsed (in years)
model to measure the relation between the length of the preparation spell for paper n (n > 1) and
cognitive mobility:
where πint gives the length of the preparation spell required to write paper n; pint is the indicator
variable set to unity if paper n involved a cognitive move, and Ci is a variable indicating if
mathematician i is a contender (Ci = 1 – Fi). Table 6 summarizes the estimates of the vector (λF,
λC) using alternative specifications of the model. It is evident that cognitive mobility is
associated with a longer preparation spell for both the medalists and the contenders, and the
effect is numerically important. A cognitive move increases the length of the preparation spell by
In sum, the data indicate that the Fields medalists engaged in more cognitive mobility in
the post-medal period and that cognitive mobility imposes a cost; it takes longer to produce a
paper. This behavior, therefore, will inevitably result in a reduced rate of publication for the
that determines how much of the observed decline in productivity was due to cognitive mobility.
The results in Table 5 indicate that the awarding of the Fields Medal increased the probability of
cognitive mobility for a paper published in the post-medal period by around 15 percent. Both the
medalists and the contenders published four papers per year at the time the medal was awarded
(see Figure 1). Using this rate of output as the baseline, the regression coefficient in Table 5
indicates that the awarding of the medal led to a 0.6 increase (or 0.15 × 4) in the number of
At the same time, Table 6 shows that cognitive mobility increases the length of a
preparation spell by about 0.2 years. Putting these results together implies that the increased
incentive for cognitive mobility in the post-medal period and the longer preparation spell reduces
the amount of “effective” time available in a given year by about 0.12 years (or the 0.6 papers
Borjas and Doran 28
published in an unfamiliar field times the 0.2 longer years it takes to produce such a paper). In
rough terms, therefore, we expect a 12 percent decline in the number of papers that a medalist
published annually in the post-medal period simply because cognitive mobility diverts 12 percent
of his time to other uses (such as learning new skills). As we saw in Table 2, there was a 24
percent decline in annual output. The increased experimentation exhibited by Fields medalists in
the post-medal period can account for about half of the decline in productivity.
It is important to emphasize that the decline in productivity resulting from the wealth
effect that increases leisure is conceptually different from the decline induced by the increased
experimentation. Although the cognitive mover publishes fewer papers, those papers may
provide a social benefit. The medalist is applying his talents to unfamiliar questions, and may
mathematical talent.
In fact, among the great architects of late twentieth century mathematics in our sample,
there are three well-known examples in which a Fields medalist who made extraordinary
subject later in their career. René Thom (and his development of singularity/catastrophe theory),
David Mumford (and the mathematics of vision and pattern theory), and Stephen Smale.
happened soon after Smale proved a pure mathematics result (the Generalized Poincaré
Smale [was]. . . already famous for unraveling the most esoteric problems of
many-dimensional topology. A young physicist, making small talk, asked what
Smale was working on. The answer stunned him: “Oscillators.” It was absurd.
Oscillators—pendulums, springs, or electrical circuits—were the sort of problem
that a physicist finished off early in his training. They were easy. Why would a
great mathematician be studying elementary physics?
Borjas and Doran 29
Even if a young physicist considered Smale’s new choice of topic simplistic and absurd, the
enormity of the mathematician’s previous achievements insulated him from any real loss of
prestige. Smale’s post-medal experimentation built the mathematical foundation of chaos theory.
In fact, Smale went on to make important contributions in biology, astronomy, and even in
theoretical economics.
VI. Summary
A vast literature explores the impact of tournaments, contests, and prizes on the
effects for the efficient design of incentive mechanisms. A working assumption in this literature
is that the labor supply consequences of actually winning a tournament are minimal. This paper
studies the impact of winning a tournament on the productivity and effort choices of tournament
We examine how winning the Fields Medal affects the post-medal productivity and
research choices of mathematicians. The Fields Medal is the most prestigious award in
mathematics, awarded every four years to mathematicians under the age of 40. Using archival
data from the American Mathematical Society and the Mathematics Genealogy Project, we
document the shape of the age-productivity profile of these exceptional mathematicians along a
number of different dimensions, including the number of papers published, citations received,
and students mentored. We find that the age-productivity profile of the Fields medalists and of
the losing contenders is similar until the year in which a particular mathematician wins the Fields
Medal (or does not win it). Remarkably, the rate of output of the Fields medalists declines
We also show that the medalists exhibit a far greater rate of cognitive mobility in the
post-medal period, pursuing topics that are far less likely to be related to their pre-medal work.
unfamiliar field), the increased rate of mobility reduces the medalists’ rate of output in the post-
medal period. The data suggest that about half of the decreased productivity in the post-medal
Hundreds of scientific and technical prizes are awarded around the world. Our evidence
suggests that the post-prize productivity impact of winning a prestigious award can be substantial,
affecting both the quantity and type of research the winners produce. Although some Fields
Medalists may have taken Hermann Weyl’s words to heart and “carried on as they began,” this
was not the typical outcome. The data instead reveal that the increased opportunities provided by
the Fields Medal, in fact, discouraged the recipients from continuing to produce the pure
mathematics that the medal was awarded for, while encouraging time-consuming investments in
Notes: The superscripts indicate the prize awarded to the mathematician; F = Fields Medal; A =
Abel Prize; W = Wolf Prize; C = Cole Algebra Prize; B = Bôcher Prize; V = Veblen Prize; and S
= Salem Prize.
Borjas and Doran 33
References
American Mathematical Society. 2008. "Leroy P. Steele Prize for Lifetime Achievement, 2008
Steele Prizes." Notices American Mathematical Society 55(4): 486-90.
Anderson, Rolph E., Alan J. Dubinsky, and Rajiv Mehta. 1999. “Sales Managers: Marketing’s
Best Example of the Peter Principle?” Business Horizons 42(1): 19–26.
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1965. Some Aspects of the Theory of Risk Bearing. Helsinki: Yrjö Jahnssonin
Säätiö.
Azoulay, Pierre, Joshua S. Graff Zivin, and Gustavo Manso. 2011. "Incentives and Creativity:
Evidence from the Academic Life Sciences." The RAND Journal of Economics 42(3): 527-54.
Barmby, Tim, Barbara Eberth, and Ada Ma. 2012. “Incentives, Learning, Task Difficulty, and
the Peter Principle: Interpreting individual output changes in an Organisational Hierarchy.”
Labour Economics 19(1): 76-81.
Borjas, George J., and Kirk B. Doran. 2012. “The Collapse of the Soviet Union and the
Productivity of American Mathematicians.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3): 1143-1203.
Borjas, George J., and Kirk B. Doran. 2014. “Cognitive mobility: Labor market responses to
supply shocks in the space of ideas.” Journal of Labor Economics. Forthcoming.
Carter, R. W. 2006. “A Survey of the Work of George Lusztig.” Nagoya Mathematical Journal
182: 1-45.
Chan, Ho Fai, Bruno S. Frey, Jana Gallus, and Benno Torgler. 2013. “Does the John Bates Clark
Medal boost subsequent productivity and citation success?” Working Paper No. 2013-0. Zurich:
CREMA.
Chang, Kenneth, 2008. “Oded Schramm, 46, Mathematician, Is Dead.” New York Times,
September 11.
Ehrenberg, Ronald G., and Michael L. Bognanno. 1990. "Do Tournaments Have Incentive
Effects?" Journal of Political Economy 98(6): 1307-24.
Gleick, James. 1987. Chaos: Making a New Science. New York: Viking-Penguin.
International Congress of Mathematicians, 2007. “Guidelines for the Program Committee (PC)
and the Organizing Committee (OC).” November 21; www.mathunion.org/fileadmin/IMU/PC-
OC-Guidelines.pdf.
Knoeber, Charles R., and Walter N. Thurman. 1994. “Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An
Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production.” Journal of Labor Economics 12(2): 155-79.
Lazear, Edward P. “The Peter Principle: A Theory of Decline.” Journal of Political Economy
112(1): S141-S163.
Lazear, Edward P., and Sherwin Rosen. “Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor
Contracts.” Journal of Political Economy 89(5): 841-64.
Levhari, David, and Yoram Weiss. 1974. “The Effect of Risk on the Investment in Human
Capital.” American Economic Review 64(6): 950-63.
Levin, Sharon G., and Paul E. Stephan. 81. “Research Productivity Over the Life Cycle:
Evidence for Academic Scientists.” American Economic Review 81(1): 114-32.
Main, Brian G. M., Charles A. O'Reilly III, and James Wade. 1993. “Top Executive Pay:
Tournament or Teamwork?” Journal of Labor Economics 11(4): 606-28.
Monastyrsky, Michael. 2001. “Some Trends in Modern Mathematics and the Fields Medal.”
Notes of the Canadian Mathematical Society 33(2): 3-5 and 33(3): 11-13.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1986. "Prizes and Incentives in Elimination Tournaments." American Economic
Review 76(4): 701-15.
Scotchmer, Suzanne. 2006. Innovation and incentives. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Solholm, Rolleiv. 2010. "The Abel Prize to John T. Tate," Norway Post, March 25.
Sparshott, Jeffrey. 2014. "Do Prizes Dent Productivity?" Real Time Economics, Wall Street
Journal, April 14; blogs.wsj.com/economics/2014/04/18/do-prizes-dent-productivity/.
Stern, Scott. 2004. "Do Scientists Pay to Be Scientists?" Management Science 50(6): 835-53.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1969. “The Effects of Income, Wealth, and Capital Gains Taxation on Risk-
Taking.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 83(2): 263-83.
Tropp, Henry S. 1976. "The Origins and History of the Fields Medal." Historia Mathematica
3(2): 167-81.
Borjas and Doran 35
Zuckerman, Harriet. 1996. Scientific Elite: Nobel Laureates in the United States. New
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
Borjas and Doran 36
ENDNOTES
1. Lazear and Rosen (1981) and Rosen (1986) give the classic presentations of the tournament
model. Empirical evidence on the productivity effects includes Ehrenberg and Bognanno (1990),
Knoeber and Thurman (1994), and Main, O’Reilly, and Wade (1993).
2. Some recent studies address this question in the context of job promotions. Lazear (2004)
offers an important discussion of the statistical problems introduced by mean reversion in the
also the related empirical work in Anderson, Dubinsky, and Mehta (1999), and Barmby, Eberth,
and Ma (2012).
3. Zuckerman (1996) documents that the research output of Nobel Prize winners declines after
winning the prize. Her descriptive evidence, however, is likely contaminated by the late age of
the winners and the possibility of mean reversion because the comparison group is less
productive prior to the awarding of the prize. Chan et al. (2013) and Bricongne (2014) present
related studies of the impact of the John Bates Clark Medal on the productivity of economists
and reach conflicting results. The productivity impact of the Clark medal is discussed in more
detail below. Finally, Azoulay, Graff-Zivin, and Manso. (2011) explore the impact of funding at
4. Partly due to jealousy and conflict between Alfred Nobel and the Swedish mathematician
Magnus Gotha Mittag-Leffler, Nobel famously left mathematics out of his list of recognized
disciplines when he founded the prize that bears his name (Tropp 1976). Ironically, Fields and
5. The age restriction has been applied consistently over time. For example, the 1998 ICM
stated: "As all the Committees before us, we agreed, . . . to follow the established tradition and to
interpret the word 'young' as 'at most forty in the year of the Congress’" [emphasis added].
6. The goal of the French Bourbaki group was to write down all of mathematics as a linear
development from general axioms. The arbitrariness of the decision to exclude Harish-Chandra
is doubly ironic: “Harish-Chandra would have been as astonished as we are to see himself
lumped with Thom and accused of being tarred with the Bourbaki brush, but whether he would
have been so amused is doubtful, for it had not been easy for him to maintain confidence in his
own very different mathematical style in face of the overwhelming popular success of the French
variables. The obvious choice of an instrument for winning the Fields Medal is given by the
combination of the quadrennial timing of the award and the age cut-off: some mathematicians
have almost four more years to compete for the Fields Medal than others. While the resulting
variation in the maximum number of “eligible work years” is positively related with winning the
Fields Medal in the sample of contenders constructed below, the Angrist-Pischke multivariate F-
tests of excluded instruments show that the relationship is not sufficiently strong to make it a
8. An alternative empirical strategy would be to rely on statistical matching based on papers per
year or citations per paper to construct a sample of contenders from the universe of all
mathematicians. We did not pursue this alternative approach for two reasons. First, it would be
difficult to operationalize because a key variable in the matching algorithm would be year of
birth (which determines eligibility for the Fields Medal). The birth year would need to be
Borjas and Doran 38
uncovered one at a time through archival research or one-on-one contact for the universe of
potential matches in the AMS data. It turns out that approximating year of birth by year of first
publication leads to a very poor approximation of the end of the eligibility period. Second, we
prefer the approach of actually constructing a relevant group of contenders with “real” people
because it uses the valuable information embedded in the profession’s willingness to publicly
acclaim a particular person’s contributions with a scarce award (or, as discussed below, with an
invitation to present a prestigious lecture). This type of construction likely leads to a better
9. The Abel Prize creates a multi-stage tournament for mathematicians. As in Rosen (1986),
Fields medalists may wish to keep participating in the tournament in order to receive the sizable
monetary award associated with the Abel Prize. The changed incentives, however, are unlikely to
affect our results because the Abel Prize began late in the sample period.
10. There are many other mathematical prizes around the world, but they are far less prestigious
or worse predictors of winning the Fields Medal. For example, none of the winners of the AMS
Cole Prize for Number Theory has ever gone on to win the Fields Medal.
11. An alternative way of defining the final set of contenders would be to calculate the annual
rate of papers published during the eligibility period, and select the 43 mathematicians whose
annual rate of output is above the median. The evidence reported below is similar if we used this
alternative definition. We also accounted for the fact that the nature of the AMS citation data
could imply that the number of citations received by more recent mathematicians may be greater
than the number received by mathematicians active in the 1950s and 1960s. We defined the final
set of contenders based on the above-median ranking of the residual from a regression of the per-
Borjas and Doran 39
year number of citations in the eligibility period on the calendar year of first publication, and the
results are very similar to those reported in the next two sections.
12. We ignore the posthumous publications of the Fields medalists and contenders.
13. Data on the impact of the Fields medal on a winner’s financial wealth are obviously very
limited. Nevertheless, there is some evidence suggesting that the effect may be quite large.
In particular, it is possible to examine the salary history of Fields medalists employed at a
few public universities (where the salary information is publicly released). Our
examination of the salary history of one such winner, employed at a large public university
in the western United States, indicates that the medalist experienced a $120,000 salary
increase (equivalent to a 67 percent raise) between the academic years preceding and
subsequent to the award. The medalist’s salary, in fact, continued to increase rapidly in
subsequent years and was five standard deviations above the mean salary of full professors
in the department six years after the award. This episode suggests that the impact of the
Fields medal on the present value of lifetime wealth (even when income is restricted only
to academic earnings) can be substantial, totaling in the millions of dollars.
14. There are two additional types of productivity effect that may be important, though
hard to measure. First, winning the Fields medal “raises the bar” in terms of what a
medalist perceives to be publishable output (and also in terms of what the mathematical
community expects from him). In particular, the medalist may feel that he has a brand
name to protect and is unwilling to devote his time or effort to smaller topics that could
well lead to publishable, but not seminal, papers. Second, the medalist is likely to be
distracted by competing offers for advice, speeches, etc. As Cédric Villani, a Fields medalist
in
2010,
puts
it,
“Every
Fields
Medal
winner
knows
how
much
the
productivity
decreases
Borjas and Doran 40
after
the
award.
.
.
Just
because
you
are
so
much
invited
and
wanted
by
everybody—for
15. Figure 1 seems to show a small decline in productivity among the Fields Medalists for a
few years prior to the receipt of the medal. This decline is partly an artifact of the three-‐
year moving average used in the figure. In fact, the only unusually low year of output
actually occurs exactly one year before receipt of the Fields Medal. The number of papers
published two years before receipt of the Fields Medal and during the year of the medal
itself is either on or above the trend. We further examined the pre-‐trend issue by
before and after) and interacted this variable with the indicator of whether the
mathematician won the Fields medal. We aggregated the years-‐since-‐medal variable into
three-‐year intervals to obtain a sufficient sample size for each interaction. The regression
revealed that only one of the pre-‐medal interactions was significant (and it was the one
indicating the period at the beginning of the career), and none of the others were even
marginally significant. In contrast, three of the post-‐medal interactions are significant, with
four more being marginally significant. The data, therefore, strongly suggest that the small
decline in productivity observed just before the awarding of the Fields medal is not part of
a consistent pre-‐treatment trend of low output for the treated group.
16. We also examined the robustness of our results to the use of the Abel and Wolf prizes in the
construction of the sample of contenders in two alternative ways: by excluding from the sample
of contenders those mathematicians who won the Abel or Wolf prizes (yielding a sample of 35
contenders) or by only including in the sample of contenders those mathematicians who did win
Borjas and Doran 41
the Abel or Wolf prizes (8 contenders). The interaction coefficient β
is
-‐0.908
(with
a
standard
error of 0.458) in the first case and -‐2.553 (2.015) in the second.
17. During the two-‐year period in which we prepared this study, two related working
papers examining the productivity effect of the Clark medal were also produced. The
evidence in these studies, however, is mixed. Chan et al. (2013) use a statistical matching
approach and find a favorable productivity effect, while Brincogne (2014) constructs a
control group composed of prominent economists and finds that the favorable productivity
effect disappears once the regression controls for individual-‐specific fixed effects in
productivity, suggesting that the net productivity effect of the medal may be slightly
negative. Even if the evidence were less ambiguous, there are a number of issues that
complicate the interpretation of the results from the Clark medal studies. In particular, the
Clark medal is not the last stage of the tournament; there may be well be “forward
expectation bias” influencing the choice of the next Clark medalist; and the additional grant
funding that a Clark medalist will likely generate will be an input in the production function
for subsequent research (grant funding is a much less important input in the production of
pure mathematics).
18. The fact that our citation data only includes citations made after 2000 (regardless of
when the paper was published) prevents us from addressing the possibility that receipt of
the Fields medal may itself cause the medalists' pre-‐medal work to become more highly
cited in the post-‐2000 period than it otherwise would have been. A detailed analysis of this
issue would require much more detailed (and contemporaneous) citation data.
19. For students whose AMS identification numbers are listed in the MGP database, we use the
AMS data to calculate their career papers and citations. Many mathematics doctorates, however,
Borjas and Doran 42
do not publish a single paper in their career (and the mode for those who do is a single
publication with zero citations; see Borjas and Doran 2012). The absence of a publication
implies that the student will never appear in the MathSciNet database. We assume that the
students who do not have an AMS identification number have zero lifetime publications and
citations.
20. The results are similar as long as we lag the degree date by two or more years.
21. It is interesting to note that 39 of the 86 contenders produced by the method based on
receipt of mathematical prizes have also given a plenary lecture, as have 21 of the 43 “final”
contenders with an above-‐median citation rate in the eligibility period.
22. By restricting the sample to plenary speakers who gave their lecture before age 44, we
are indirectly attempting to construct a sample of outstanding mathematicians that
includes those who “just missed” their chance for a Fields medal because of the interaction
between the age restriction and the quadrennial timing of the award.
23. Levin and Stephan (1991) and Stern (2004) suggest that some scientists, particularly
theoretical ones, derive consumption value from doing research they enjoy.
24. Since Arrow (1965) and Stiglitz (1969), it is well known that a wealth increase may prompt a
utility-maximizing agent to undertake riskier investments. Levhari and Weiss (1974) extended
this insight to the human capital framework. As 2010 Fields medalist Stanislav Smirnov notes,
the pursuit of riskier investments raises the possibility that the medalist may be “doing
25. It is not possible to estimate this matrix with the data that the AMS provided us. We instead
purchased citation data from the ISI Web of Science to calculate these distance measures; see the
Borjas and Doran 43
Data Appendix to Borjas and Doran (2012) for details. The calculation of the matrix uses all
26. We also examined the probability that a mathematician conducts research outside pure
“Geophysics,” “Game theory, economics, social and behavioral sciences,” “Biology and other
estimated regression coefficient suggests that the (relative) probability of a Fields medalist
publishing in one of these applied areas in the post-medal period rose by 75 percent.
Borjas and Doran 44
Table 1
Summary Statistics
Contenders with
All Fields above-median All
Variable: mathematicians medalists citations contenders
Lifetime papers 31.8 116.5 126.4 106.4
Notes: The summary statistics for “all mathematicians” are calculated using the group of
mathematicians in the AMS database who had at least 20 years of experience before ending their
publication career; in other words, those whose most recent publication is at least 20 years after
their first publication. The group of “contenders” is composed of persons who were awarded at
least one of six other mathematics prizes (the Abel, Wolf, Cole Algebra, Bôcher, Veblen, and
Salem Prizes), but were not awarded the Fields Medal. The group of contenders with “above-
median citations” is composed of the contenders who had above-median per-year citations
Borjas and Doran 45
during the eligibility period for the Fields Medal. The years included in the "papers per year"
calculations across different age groups begin with the year of the first publication and end at age
Table 2
Impact of the Fields Medal on the number of papers published per year
Sample of contenders
Contenders with above-
median citations
All contenders
Post-medal
Post-medal
Post-medal period × Post-medal period ×
Specification:
period
Fields Medal
period
Fields Medal
1. Number of papers
0.119
-1.378
-0.157
-0.918
(0.548)
(0.676)
(0.291)
(0.435)
2. Log number of papers
-0.074
-0.244
-0.093
-0.173
(0.089)
(0.105)
(0.065)
(0.090)
3. Papers, quantile regression
-0.421
-0.665
-0.314
-0.756
(0.283)
(0.256)
(0.150)
(0.161)
Number of papers:
4. Contenders’ post-medal
0.160
-1.395
-0.166
-0.914
period begins at age 36
(0.494)
(0.656)
(0.279)
(0.435)
5. Contenders’ post-medal
0.266
-1.440
0.069
-0.987
period begins at age 40
(0.545)
(0.681)
(0.286)
(0.436)
Notes: Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at the individual level. The
regressions using the sample of contenders with above-median citations have 3,269 observations
(2,719 observations in the log papers regressions); the regressions using the sample of all
contenders have 5,213 observations (4,109 observations in the log papers regressions). In rows 1-
3, the contenders’ post-medal period begins the year they are no longer eligible to receive the
Fields Medal.
Borjas and Doran 47
Table 3
Impact of the Fields Medal on other annual measures of productivity
Sample of contenders
Contenders with above-
median citations
All contenders
Post-medal
Post-medal
Post-medal period × Post-medal period ×
Dependent variable:
period
Fields Medal
period
Fields Medal
1. Published at least one paper
0.030
-0.118
-0.002
-0.092
(0.041)
(0.047)
(0.030)
(0.044)
2. Number of citations
-1.146
-44.182
5.448
-44.493
(13.480)
(14.645)
(8.826)
(12.631)
3. Citations per paper
2.204
-11.000
2.560
-10.716
(3.351)
(3.145)
(2.739)
(2.866)
4.
Probability
of
a
“home
run”
0.062
-0.075
0.054
-0.075
(0.035)
(0.034)
(0.027)
(0.031)
5.
Probability
of
a
“strikeout”
0.009 0.053
0.022 0.058
(0.024) (0.028)
(0.021) (0.026)
6. Number of mentees
-0.016
-0.126
-0.017
-0.137
(0.078)
(0.074)
(0.054)
(0.058)
7. Number of papers
1.430
-3.981
0.883
-4.932
published by mentees
(3.194)
(2.522)
(2.364)
(1.828)
8. Number of citations -12.676 -56.309
-17.963 -60.682
generated by mentees (44.334) (37.395)
(29.630) (29.787)
Notes: Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at the individual level. The
regressions using the sample of contenders with above-median citations have 3,269 observations;
the regressions using the sample of all contenders have 5,213 observations. The sample sizes for
the regressions reported in rows 3-5 are 2,719 and 4,109 observations, respectively; and the
sample sizes for the regressions reported in rows 5-7 are 2,999 and 4,797, respectively. A “home
run” occurs when the number of citations per paper published in a given year is above the 99.5th
percentile for all mathematicians in the AMS database; a “strikeout” occurs when the number of
Table 4
Impact of the Fields Medal Using ICM Plenary Speakers as Control Group
Sample of contenders
Plenary speakers with
All plenary speakers
above-median citations
Post-medal
Post-medal
Post-medal period × Post-medal period ×
Specification:
period
Fields Medal
period
Fields Medal
A. Contenders invited to be
plenary speakers at any age
1. Number of papers
0.096
-‐1.076
-‐0.091
-‐0.955
(0.189)
(0.356)
(0.291)
(0.432)
2. Log number of papers
-‐0.014
-‐0.239
-‐0.059
-‐0.183
(0.043)
(0.080)
(0.059)
(0.088)
3. Citations
8.998
-‐50.058
3.749
-‐47.642
(7.305)
(9.698)
(11.742)
(14.952)
4. Citations per paper
1.217
-‐10.950
0.257
-‐10.012
(2.011)
(2.709)
(3.035)
(4.013)
5. Probability of a “home run” 0.030
-‐0.078
0.034
-‐0.066
(0.019)
(0.029)
(0.029)
(0.032)
6. Probability
of
a
“strikeout”
0.006
0.073
0.011
0.048
(0.152)
(0.024)
(0.018)
(0.023)
B.
Contenders
invited
to
be
plenary
speakers
by
age
44
1. Number of papers
0.039 -0.906
-0.029 -1.130
(0.338) (0.448)
(0.584) (0.685)
2. Log number of papers
-0.063 -0.161
-0.092 -0.188
(0.067) (0.089)
(0.095) (0.107)
3. Citations
0.587 -39.978
-8.096 -37.961
(10.427) (12.928)
(14.276) (15.344)
4. Citations per paper
0.386 -8.993
0.672 -9.019
(2.756) (2.876)
(3.912) (3.468)
5. Probability of a “home run” 0.040 -0.065
0.060 -0.072
(0.026) (0.038)
(0.035) (0.035)
6. Probability
of
a
“strikeout”
0.011 0.030
0.023 0.023
(0.017) (0.026)
(0.024) (0.025)
Notes: Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at the individual level. The
sample sizes for the regressions reported in rows 1 and 3 of Panel A are 9,011 and 5,133
observations, respectively; and the sample sizes for the regressions reported in all other rows are
Borjas and Doran 49
7,505 and 4,396, respectively. The sample sizes for the regressions reported in rows 1 and 3 of
Panel B are 4,745 and 3,171 observations, respectively; and the sample sizes for the regressions
reported in all other rows are 3,966 and 2,655, respectively. A “home run” occurs when the
number of citations per paper published in a given year is above the 99.5th percentile for all
mathematicians in the AMS database; a “strikeout” occurs when the number of citations per
Table 5
Impact of the Fields Medal on the probability of cognitive mobility
Notes: Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at the individual level. The
“baseline field” is defined by the set of the (one or two) modal fields and all related fields in
which the mathematician published during the baseline period (either the entire eligibility period,
the first three years, or the first five years of his career). The dependent variable is a cognitive
mobility indicator set to unity if the field of publication for each paper during the
mathematician’s career is not in the baseline field. The regressions in Panel A have 10,911
Table 6
Cognitive mobility and the duration of the preparation spell
Notes: Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at the individual level. The
length of the preparation is the length of time elapsed (in years) between any two consecutive
papers in a mathematician’s career. The “baseline field” is defined by the set of the (one or two)
modal fields and all related fields in which the mathematician published during the baseline
period (either the entire eligibility period, the first three years, or the first five years of his career).
The dependent variable is a cognitive mobility indicator set to unity if the field of publication for
each paper during the mathematician’s career is not in the baseline field. The regressions in
Panel A have 10,821 observations; the regressions in Panel B have 14,495 observations.
Borjas and Doran 52
Notes: The group of “contenders” is composed of persons who were awarded at least one of six
other mathematics prizes (the Abel, Wolf, Cole Algebra, Bôcher, Veblen, and Salem Prizes) and
have above-median per-year citations during the eligibility period for the Fields Medal, but were
not awarded the Fields Medal. We smooth out the trend by using a 3-‐year moving average
Figure 1
Average number of papers published annually by the Fields medalists and the contenders (three-
year moving average)
Borjas and Doran 53
Notes: The group of “contenders” is composed of persons who were awarded at least one of six
other mathematics prizes (the Abel, Wolf, Cole Algebra, Bôcher, Veblen, and Salem Prizes) and
have above-median per-year citations during the eligibility period for the Fields Medal, but were
not awarded the Fields Medal. Cognitive mobility indicates if a paper published at any point
during the mathematician’s career differs from the “baseline fields” in the eligibility period for
the Fields Medal. The “baseline field” is defined by the set of the two modal fields and all related
fields in which the mathematician published during the eligibility period. We smooth out the
trend by using a 3-‐year moving average centered on the middle year in the interval.
Figure 2
The probability of cognitive mobility for the Fields medalists and the contenders (three-year
moving average).