Young 1996
Young 1996
Young 1996
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/27800125?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Lynne Rienner Publishers is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Global
Governance
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Global Governance 2 (1996), 1-24
Institutional Linkages
in International Society:
Polar Perspectives
os?
_ ?_
Or an R. Young
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
2 Institutional Linkages in International Society
In this article 1 take some initial steps toward answering this question.
The first substantive section proposes a set of analytic distinctions among
types of institutional linkages as a means of sorting out a number of dif
ferent phenomena that come into focus under this rubric. The next section
turns to the dynamics of institutional linkages in the sense of probing the
forces likely to give rise to the several types of linkages identified in the
preceding section. The final substantive section adopts a strategic per
spective and looks to the calculations of policymakers faced with opportu
nities to use institutional linkages instrumentally or the necessity of react
ing to such linkages resulting from the actions of others. This account
relies on a number of plausible premises regarding the consequences of in
stitutional linkages; a sustained treatment of the consequences will have to
await another occasion. But if I am right about the significance of link
ages, this topic should soon become a prominent item on the agenda of
regime analysis.
At this early stage, the analysis centers exclusively on classic regimes
or, in other words, interstate arrangements articulated in explicit (although
not necessarily legally binding) agreements. Wherever possible, I draw on
experience with institutional arrangements operating in the polar regions?
the Arctic and the Antarctic?to illustrate the distinctions and the argu
ments presented. Nonetheless, the issues under consideration in this study
of institutional linkages are generic, and the ideas set forth in the follow
ing sections are intended to constitute a first cut at understanding a phe
nomenon that arises throughout international society.
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Or an R. Young 3
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
4 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 5
polar region, Antarctica has been recognized since 1992 as a marpol spe
cial area, a designation that makes it possible to nest special restrictions
regarding vessel-source pollution in this region into the general provisions
of the marine pollution regime. Although no similar action has been taken
so far in the north polar region, a number of actors have suggested using
the marpol special-areas provision as a means of regulating environmen
tal impacts arising from the development of offshore oil and gas reserves
located both in the North American Arctic (e.g., the Beaufort Sea) and in
the Eurasian Arctic (e.g., the Barents Sea).13
For its part, institutional clustering occurs when those engaged in the
formation or operation of differentiable governance systems find it attrac
tive to combine several of these arrangements into institutional packages,
even when there is no compelling functional need to nest the individual
components into a common and more generic framework. The system of
arrangements included in the 1982 convention on the law of the sea, with
its functionally differentiated provisions for navigation, fishing, deep
seabed mining, marine pollution, scientific research, and so forth, consti
tutes a classic case in point. What holds these elements together and makes
it meaningful to treat them collectively as the law of the sea is a common
concern for issues relating to marine areas rather than the presence of an
overarching institutional framework into which the individual components
are nested.14 Much the same can be said about proposals for the develop
ment of a law of the atmosphere, which have surfaced from time to time?
so far with little effect?in connection with the development of specific
regimes for transboundary air pollution, ozone depletion, and climate
change.15
A consideration of recent developments in the polar regions suggests
that there are several possible rationales for creating clustered regimes.
Joining together analytically differentiable issues, such as fishing, offshore
hydrocarbon development, navigation, and pollution control in the Bering
Sea, may prove attractive as a means of achieving success in institutional
bargaining. In effect, the prospect of being able to work out package deals
covering several distinct issues can facilitate efforts to devise constitu
tional contracts that offer net benefits to all the participants.16 In other
cases, institutional clustering may seem attractive as a means of achieving
economies of scale in the operation of regimes once they are in place.
Some such reasoning appears to play a role in the thinking of at least some
supporters of the Canadian Initiative to create an Arctic council whose
coverage would extend to a wide range of functional concerns arising in
the Arctic. Beyond this, clustered regimes will appeal to those seeking to
foster consciousness raising and ultimately the emergence of a shared vi
sion of a given region or cluster of issues as a politically potent construct.
Reasoning of this sort appears to have played a part in the thinking of
those who developed and promoted the idea of the Barents Euro-Arctic
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
6 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 7
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
8 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 9
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
10 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 11
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
12 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 13
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
14 Institutional Linkages in International Society
society not only serves to reaffirm these basic precepts but also minimizes
the likelihood that issue-specific regimes will get out of hand, precipitat
ing institutional changes capable of triggering a dynamic that ultimately
undermines important tenets of international society as a whole (e.g., the
rule restricting membership to states). The act of embedding regimes, on
this account, constitutes a barrier against piecemeal developments leading
to broader, more systemic changes.
Contrast this with two other perspectives on embeddedness. Tech
nocrats?those who focus on the success of individual regimes on their
own terms while remaining neutral regarding the character of international
society as a whole?approach the issue of embeddedness in a purely in
strumental fashion. They will embrace embeddedness when it seems use
ful as a means of promoting the effectiveness of the regimes they care
about; otherwise they will deemphasize or even ignore it. Negotiators rep
resenting the twelve signatories to the 1959 Antarctic Treaty, for exam
ple, devised a set of provisions generally supportive of the basic tenets of
international society, while at the same time ignoring or setting aside some
of the usual rules pertaining to jurisdiction in order to craft the crucial
compromise?embodied in Article 4?needed to alleviate the problem of
overlapping jurisdictional claims as a barrier to mutually beneficial coop
eration in the region.38 A similar instrumental perspective appears to un
derlie current efforts to provide larger and more autonomous roles for non
state actors in emerging Arctic arrangements, such as the aeps and the
bear, without calling into question the proposition that international soci
ety is fundamentally a society of states.
For their part, those desiring to use the creation of issue-specific
regimes as a vehicle for promoting larger changes in international society
must engage in a continuous balancing act with regard to embeddedness.39
Pushing too hard runs the risk of blighting the prospects for success with
respect to the regime at hand as well as provoking a backlash on the part
of defenders of the faith with regard to the central tenets of international
society. Undue caution, on the other hand, runs the risk of failing to take
advantage of opportunities to use specific regimes as vehicles for reform
ing international society. Choices concerning the proper balance between
these risks will normally vary both as a function of the modus operandi of
different actors and strategic or contextual factors. It is no accident, for ex
ample, that Greenpeace has adopted a more radical posture than the World
Conservation Union (formerly the International Union for the Conserva
tion of Nature and Natural Resources) in seeking to use Antarctica as a
vehicle for promoting larger agendas of nonstate actors or that indigenous
peoples organizations (e.g., the Inuit Circumpolar Conference) have been
particularly active in treating the newly emerging Arctic regimes as op
portunities to attack the underlying norm limiting membership in interna
tional regimes to states. With regard to context, it is interesting to observe
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 15
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
16 Institutional Linkages in International Society
types. But these distinctions are useful for a number of purposes, includ
ing thinking through the virtues of nested regimes.
The advantages of nesting are indisputable in the case of evolving pro
grammatic regimes. The point of such arrangements is to set in motion ac
tivities that are intended to lead to a broadening and deepening of the
regimes in question. This is the genius of lrtap, in which the operation of
em hp and related programmatic mechanisms have led to "tote-board diplo
macy"42 involving the negotiation of a series of protocols dealing with
specific types of airborne pollutants. There are some signs that a similar
dynamic may emerge from the activities of the Arctic Monitoring and As
sessment Programme, the Working Group on the Conservation of Arctic
Flora and Fauna, and the recently formed Task Force on Sustainable De
velopment and Utilization in the case of the aeps.43 But the success of
such evolutionary processes is hardly automatic with regard to specific
regimes. Efforts to nest new elements into the regime for the Mediter
ranean Basin established initially under the 1976 Barcelona Convention
have proved disappointing to many, a situation that eventuated in the rene
gof; non of the convention itself in 1995. Similarly, the addition of the
199 Environment Protocol may turn out to be a unique event in the evo
lution of the Antarctic Treaty System rather than an indication that this ar
rangement is now taking on the character of a programmatic regime.
The argument for nesting is far less persuasive, on the other hand, in
the cases of regulative regimes and managerial regimes. Some regimes are
based on sets of rules that are essentially complete and self-contained in
their original form. This is probably a fair characterization of the regime
for the conservation of North Pacific fur seals, which lasted through much
of this century,44 and of the regime for the Svalbard Archipelago, which
was established in the i920s and remains effective today.45 In other cases,
the initial set of rules may grow as a result of experience with a social
practice but in a manner that does not involve nesting of the sort under
consideration here. The recommendations or agreed measures adopted
over the years by the biennial Antarctic Treaty Consultative Meetings, for
instance, are properly construed as prescriptions?albeit ones that do not
require formal ratification on the part of members?that, taken together,
have broadened and deepened this social practice. But it does not seem ap
propriate to describe these new elements as being nested into the original
arrangement in the sense that the 1987 Montreal Protocol and the London
Amendments are nested into the ozone regime or the 1994 sulfur protocol
is nested into lrtap.
As to managerial regimes, the situation is even more straightforward.
Once established, procedures for making collective choices can be used
over and over again. This is obviously true with regard to decisions in
volving the same subject, such as setting annual quotas for specific fish
eries, establishing annual harvest levels for individual species of whales,
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 17
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
18 Institutional Linkages in International Society
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 19
with the inevitable flow of wastes arising from their presence? None of
these questions has a straightforward answer, much less one that is correct.
Assuming that we can develop the knowledge base needed to under
stand institutional intersections, how can we design regimes to cope with
them? There are at least three?not necessarily mutually exclusive?re
sponses to this question. For purposes of discussion, it may help to call
them side agreements, mergers, and procedural devices. Side agreements
involve efforts on the part of those concerned with a specific regime to add
provisions designed to mitigate its unintended?ordinarily negative?im
pacts on other institutional arrangements. Perhaps the best-known recent
case involves the side agreements on environmental issues negotiated in
connection with the North American Free Trade Agreement (nafta).
When overlaps start to affect core interests, however, it seems unlikely
that the negotiation of side agreements will be sufficient to solve the re
sultant problems. In such cases, it may be necessary to merge the regimes
in question, creating a single more comprehensive regime covering two or
more intersecting issue areas. A number of observers have proposed some
thing of this sort for the Bering Sea region in the sense of a single regime
dealing with fish, marine mammals, oil and gas, pollution control, trans
portation, protected natural areas, and indigenous rights in an integrated
manner. Some have begun to talk in similar terms about a comprehensive
regime for the entire circumpolar north.
Attractive as this approach may be in some areas, it is easy to see that
integrated regimes covering numerous issue areas can become so complex
that it is difficult to reach agreement on their terms, much less to admin
ister or operate them successfully once established. Under the circum
stances, a third approach featuring the establishment of procedural arrange
ments designed to resolve conflicts arising from institutional overlaps
becomes attractive. Of course, this is exactly what happens in most do
mestic settings where conflicts of laws are everyday occurrences and both
traditional judicial procedures and administrative law procedures loom
large as mechanisms for sorting out day-to-day problems arising from in
stitutional overlaps. A notable feature of this approach is that the relevant
procedures often rest on some authority that is independent of the laws or
institutional arrangements they are called upon to interpret. This is part of
what is meant by those who speak of an "independent judiciary." Is it pos
sible to imagine a similar development in international society giving rise
to an independent mechanism authorized to resolve conflicts among the
provisions of overlapping regimes in contrast to disputes about the provi
sions of individual regimes? Today, this will seem to many an improbable
development at the international level. But if, as I suggest, the significance
of institutional intersections grows rapidly in the near future, interest in
devising effective means for coming to terms with the resultant conflicts is
sure to rise.
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
20 Institutional Linkages in International Society
Conclusion
Notes
Oran R. Young directs both the Dickey Center Institute of Artie Studies and the In
stitute of International Environmental Governance at Dartmouth College. He is one
of the principal investigators of the project on International Environmental Com
mitments at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (iiasa) in Vi
enna. A long time student of international institutions, his most recent book is In
ternational Governance: Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society.
1. Oran R. Young, International Governance: Protecting the Environment in
a Stateless Society (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994).
2. Stephen D. Krasner, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Uni
versity Press, 1983); Volker Rittberger, ed., Regime Theory and International Re
lations (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993).
3. Oran R. Young, "The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard
Cases and Critical Variables," in James N. Rosenau and Ernst-Otto Czempiel, eds.,
Governance Without Government: Order and Change in World Politics (Cam
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), pp. 160-194; Peter M. Haas, Robert O.
Keohane, and Marc A. Levy, eds., Institutions for the Earth: Sources of Effective
International Environmental Protection (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993); Marc A.
Levy, Oran R. Young, and Michael Z?rn, "The Study of International Regimes,"
European Journal of International Relations, (September 1995): 267-330.
4. James K. Sebenius, "Negotiation Arithmetic: Adding and Subtracting Is
sues and Parties," International Organization 37 (Spring 1983): 281-316.
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 21
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
22 Institutional Linkages in International Society
19. Richard Herr and Edmund Chia, "The Concept of Regime Overlap: To
ward Identification and Assessment," manuscript, University of Tasmania, 1995,
20. Steve Charnovitz, "gatt and the Environment: Examining the Issues," In
ternational Environmental Affairs 4 (Summer 1992): 203-233; Konrad von
Moltke, "The Maastricht Treaty and the Winnipeg Principles on Trade and Sus
tainable Development," pamphlet published by the International Institute for Sus
tainable Development, Winnipeg, 1995.
21. Oran R. Young, Resource Management at the International Level (Lon
don: Pinter, 1977); David A. Shakespeare, "Recent U.S.-U.S.S.R. Agreements Re
lating to the Bering Sea Region," Arctic Research of the United States 5 (Fall
1991): 37-47; Richard Townsend, ed., Proceedings of the Conference on Shared
Living Resources of the Bering Sea Region (Washington, D.C.: Council on Envi
ronmental Quality, 1991); Natalia S. Mirovitskaya and J. Christopher Haney,
"Fisheries Exploitation as a Threat to Environmental Security: The North Pacific
Ocean," Marine Policy (July 1992): 243-258; William T. Burke, "Fishing in the
Bering Sea Donut: Straddling Stocks and the New International Law of Fisheries,"
Ecology Law Quarterly 16 (1989): 285-310; Broadus and Vartanov, The Oceans
and Environmental Security.
22. P. A. Larkin, "An Epitaph for the Concept of Maximum Sustainable
Yield," Transactions of the American Fisheries Society 106 (1977): 1-11.
23. Kenneth Sherman, "Large Marine Ecosystems," in Encyclopedia of Earth
System Science 2 (New York: Academic Press, 1992), pp. 653-673.
24. Stokke and Tunander, The Barents Region.
25. Monica Tennberg, "The Rovaniemi Process and New International Ac
tors," manuscript, 1993.
26. Jervell, "A Report from Europe's Northern Periphery."
27. Jorgensen-Dahl and Ostreng, The Antarctic Treaty System in World
Politics.
28. Arctic Council Panel, To Establish an International Arctic Council: A
Framework Report (Ottawa: Canadian Arctic Resources Committee, 1991).
29. D. Edmar, "The Antarctic Treaty System and the United Nations," in R.
A. Herr, H. R. Hall, and M. G. Howard, eds., Antarctica's Future: Continuity or
Change? (Hobart: Tasmanian Government Printing Office, 1990), pp. 189-192;
Peter Beck, "The United Nations and Antarctica: Still Searching for the Elusive
Convergence of View," Polar Record 29 (October 1993): 313-320.
30. E. F. Roots, "Co-operation in Arctic Science: Background and Require
ments," in Franklyn Griffiths, ed., Arctic Alternatives: Civility or Militarism in the
Circumpolar North (Toronto: Science for Peace/Samuel Stevens, 1992), pp.
136-155. At this writing, iasc is exploring the idea of seeking associate member
ship in icsu in contrast to scar's status as a scientific committee of icsu.
31. Erik Franckx, Maritime Claims in the Arctic: Canadian and Russian Per
spectives (Dordrecht, Netherlands: Martinus Nijhoff, 1993).
32. Young, International Governance, chap. 4, 5.
33. Edward A. Parson, "Protecting the Ozone Layer," in Haas, Keohane, and
Levy, Institutions for the Earth, pp. 27-73.
34. Marc A. Levy, "European Acid Rain: The Power of Tote-Board Diplo
macy," in Haas, Keohane, and Levy, Institutions for the Earth, pp. 73-132.
35. Oran R. Young, Arctic Politics: Conflict and Cooperation in the Circum
polar North (Hanover, N.H.: University Press of New England, 1992).
36. Young, Resource Management at the International Level.
37. Alf Hakon Hoel, "Regionalization of International Whale Management:
The Case of the North Atlantic Marine Mammals Commission," Arctic 46 (June
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Oran R. Young 23
1993): 116-123; David D. Caron, "The International Whaling Commission and the
North Atlantic Marine Mammal Commission: The Institutional Risks of Coercion
in Consensual Structures/' American Journal of International Law 89 (1995):
154-174.
38. H. Robert Hall, "International Regime Formation and Leadership: The
Origins of the Antarctic Treaty" (Ph.D. diss., University of Tasmania, 1994).
39. Paul Wapner, "Politics Beyond the State: Environmental Activism and
World Civic Politics, World Politics 47 (1995): 311-340.
40. Lawrence Susskind, Environmental Diplomacy: Negotiating More Effec
tive Global Agreements (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).
4L James K. Sebenius, "Designing Negotiations Toward a New Regime: The
Case of Global Warming," International Security 15 (Spring 1991): 110-148.
42. Levy, "European Acid Rain."
43. For evidence of the evolution of the Arctic Environmental Protection
Strategy, see the WWF Arctic Bulletin, a publication of the WWF Arctic
Programme.
44. Natalia S. Mirovitskaya, Margaret Clark, and Ronald G. Purver, "North
Pacific Fur Seals: Regime Formation as a Means of Resolving Conflict," in Young
and Osherenko, Polar Politics, pp. 22-55.
45. Elen Singh and Artemy Saguirian, "The Svalbard Archipelago: The Role
of Surrogate Negotiators," in Young and Osherenko, Polar Politics, pp. 56-95.
46. David G. Victor and Julian E. Salt, "From Rio to Berlin: Managing Cli
mate Change," Environment 36 (December 1994): 6-15, 25-32; D. G. Victor and
J. E. Salt, "Keeping the Climate Treaty Relevant," Nature 373 (26 January 1995):
280-282.
47. James R. McGoodwin, Crisis in the World's Fisheries: People, Problems,
and Politics (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1990).
48. Per Ove Eikeland, "Multispecies Management of the Barents Sea Large
Marine Ecosystem: A Framework for Discussing Future Challenges," Fridtjof
Nansen Institute Report, 1992..
49. Sherman, "Large Marine Ecosystems."
50. Elliott A. Norse, ed., Global Marine Biological Diversity: A Strategy for
Building Conservation into Decision Making (Washington, D.C.: Island Press,
1993).
This content downloaded from 129.252.86.83 on Sat, 11 Jun 2016 08:53:01 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms