Socialism
Socialism
Socialism
-
"*W TO*'
A NATIONAL GENERAL COMPANY
This low-priced Bantam Book
has been completely reset in a type face
designed for easy reading, and was printed
from new plates. It contains the complete
text of the original hard-cover edition.
NOT ONE WORD HAS BEEN OMITTED.
PRINTING HISTORY
Saturday Review edition published January 1972
2nd printing June 1972
3rd printing October 1972
Bantam edition published September 1973
Contents
The Preconditions of
the Dream
but what basis was there now for ethics and philosophic
truth?
There was, the nineteen-year-old Karl Marx wrote to
his father, a basic contradiction in German philosophy
between "what is and what should be." It could not be
resolved, he came to realize, in the mind of some
thinker, for he would be locked within the limitations
of his own consciousness. But there was, Marx eventu-
ally said, a social class that was forced by the condi-
tions of its daily life to fight for a self-interest which
was also the common interest of mankind. Therefore,
that which should be — Utopia, socialism, the highest
values of the West — was no longer the construct of a
professor's imagination. Rather it was a living, breath-
ing tendency of social reality itself, incarnated in the
struggle of the proletariat. Thus there were temporal
preconditions to the eternal truth about what man
should be, and now they were actually being fulfilled.
The importance of this insight to socialism past,
present or future — cannot be exaggerated. Marx's own
—
hope that the working class would rapidly turn the
values of German classical philosophy into social real-
ity has, of course, been long since disappointed. Never-
theless, there is either a trend toward socialism among
the people as they are — not the people as they should
—
be or else socialism is a fraud and a delusion. In this
chapter I will probe these preconditions as they ap-
peared historically in dreams and abstractions, in Utopia
and philosophy. Then, in the final chapter, I will show
that they still may be fulfilled in reality, even though
in ways not imagined in the philosophy of Karl Marx. 1
14 SOCIALISM
were Chinese Utopias in the first years of the Christian
era, and in eleventh-century China there was even a
brief experiment with the welfare state under the Em-
peror Shen Tsung.
But the Western Utopian tradition that was the pro-
found influence upon European socialism begins with
the Hebrews and the Greeks. It was simultaneously
revolutionary and conservative, basically other-worldly,
and yet perceived one of the most crucial aspects of
socialism —
the relationship between abundance and the
new society.
A nomadic people who lived in between the two
highly developed cultures of Egypt and Babylon, the
Israelites made an extraordinary intellectual leap to
monotheism, in part because they were so backward.
Their life in the desert was, as Max Weber has pointed
out, so primitive that they did not even have the tools
and the artistic tradition to make an icon of their deity.
So when they came into contact with the learning and
sophistication of their neighbors, their God was able to
skip over the stage of polytheism precisely because he
was imageless. Then when the tribes settled down, they
acquired a parasitic court, a new business class and an
impoverished peasantry and proletariat.
So in the crisis of the eighth century B.C. the prophets
emerged to summon the people back to the simpler
virtues of the desert faith, denouncing the capitulation
to riches and privileges that had estranged Israel from
its God. "Woe to those who decree unrighteous de-
human precondition.
Saint-Simon was a planner and a technocrat. He
objected to capitalism because it allowed parasitic cou-
pon-clippers to share in the wealth of the actual
producers and he proposed a rational allocation of in-
vestment funds through a central bank. Given this em-
phasis, Saint-Simon was not particularly concerned
about democratic participation or a mass movement.
He himself tried to win both Napoleon and Louis
XVIII to his ideas, and after his death in 1825 his dis-
ciples attempted to convert Louis Philippe when he
came to power in 1830. In this elitist aspect Saint-
Simon's ideas became the ideology of the most promi-
nent bankers and entrepreneurs around Napoleon III.
One of them, the banker Isaac Pereire, has been de-
scribed by Alexander Gershenkron as having "con-
tributed so much, perhaps more to the spread of the
modern capitalist system in France" than anyone else,
and yet he remained "an ardent admirer of the Saint-
Simonian doctrine" until his death.
This vignette is more than a curiosity for it illu-
strates an important tendency in socialist history. In
many of the original definitions of socialism certain-—
ly in Saint-Simon's and even in Marx's —
there was an
analysis of the inefficiency and waste of capitalist so-
ciety and an insistence upon how much more produc-
tive socialism would be. It was quite possible for a
French banker —
or a Russian or a Chinese dictator to —
abstract this element and turn it into the definition of
socialism. So what becomes crucial, in regard to Saint-
Simon and to socialism in general, is not simply the
abstract socialist scheme, but who reads it, and for what
purpose.
The French working class read Saint-Simon in a com-
pletely differentway than the bankers. It seized upon
his use of the word "association," the notion that the
producers themselves would run the enterprise, and
took up his hatred of the unearned income of passive
capitalists. So an essentially technocratic theory was
32 SOCIALISM
converted by the workers into an authentic socialist
perspective. Like the German Anabaptists with their
revolutionary Plato, they had made an extremely per-
ceptive misreading of Saint-Simon's ideas. They ig-
nored his elitism and emphasis upon efficiency; they
embraced his hatred of parasites who did not work but
received profits; and they translated his vision of an
"association" under the tutelage of bankers and plan-
ners into an argument for ownership of the means of
production by the direct producers. In the process they
turned a humane technocrat into a quasianarchist.
The fate of Robert Owen, the great British Utopian,
was similar to Saint-Simon's. He was a most effective
businessman who by providing various benefits for the
workers in his factory at New Lanark made a profit
of £160,000 in four years. Owen taught that a bad
—
environment like that found in all the plants in the
—
England of his day resulted in bad character. He
wanted to have cooperation in model factories, rather
than the competition of the existing system. Since he
himself had proved that such a course was not only
moral but good business, he sought to interest capital-
ists, bishops and politicans in his ideas, with some
early success.
It was a strange accident that forced Owen to turn
to the working class. He made the mistake of speaking
openly of his skeptical views on religion. Polite society,
which could tolerate talk of a profitable cooperation
between workers and management, would not permit
godlessness. At that point, the only audience open to
him was at the bottom of society, and so this essentially
conservative man became the founding father of Brit-
ish trade unionism and socialism. In part, that hap-
pened because he changed his point of view; in part,
because the workers changed it for him in the reading
they made of his views.
Thus in The Report to the County of Lanark in
1821 Owen described how
the productivity of capital-
ist society was advancing more rapidly than the work-
ers' means of subsistence. The producers, he said, draw-
The Preconditions of the Dream 33
ffl
festo and, above all, in Das Kapital, and not just in the
early writings. 1
n
Between 1848 and 1850 Marx and Engels changed
their minds about their basic political orientation no
less than three times. The Communist Manifesto was a
great, and contradictory, document which advocated
an alliance with the very bourgeoisie whose death sen-
tence it pronounced. When the course of action de-
rived from this ambiguous analysis proved a failure,
Marx became a disillusioned and bitter ultra-Leftist.
But then in 1850 reality forced itself upon him and he
once more turned to the work of elaborating a tactic
for the mass movement.
The two years between 1848 and 1850 were the
period of Marx's anti-democratic temptation, and the
dictatorial Marxists have celebrated them ever since.
In fact, he never did become a partisan of revolution
from above, even in his angriest hours, and by late
1850 he had begun deepen his democratic strategy
to
for socialist revolution. So if Marx's memory is to be
was not the poor who were first attracted to the so-
cialist ideal, but the labor elite of the artisans. They
were the ones who felt themselves directly threatened
by the growth of a system that would degrade them to
the level of "ordinary" workers. There were others who
responded to this new word not because it summoned
them to a struggle against capitalism, but because they
defined it as a means of fighting the emerging time-
clock rationality of industrial society. This was to be the
source of important confusions. For if socialism were
opposed to economic calculation rather than to capital-
ism itself, then the good society would be unable to
plan or to create wealth with modern methods and
lay the material basis for a system of genuine equality.
It was in these years when "socialism" appealed to
philanthropic businessmen, conservative artisans fear-
ful of industrial progress, opponents of industrialism it-
self, feudal aristocrats, bankers, preachers, revolution-
52 SOCIALISM
ary conspirators and gentle cooperators that Marx and
Engels made the idea precise. They located socialism
in the future, not in the idealized medieval past; they
based it upon the unprecedented productivity of means
of production centralized by the bourgeoisie rather than
upon Utopian colonies; they therefore insisted that the
revolution would not divvy up the social wealth but
rather subject it to democratic ownership and put it to
social use. And they saw that this transformation would
come about not through the charity and reasonable-
ness of the rulers, but as a result of the class struggles
of the vast majority.
These things are brilliantly defined in the first two
sections of the Manifesto. The third section described
the various anti-socialist "socialisms." Then the final
section— which is only eleven paragraphs long, but
deals with the critical problem of tactics— advocates a
united front with the very bourgeoisie whose funeral
has just been announced. In England, Marx says, the
Communists will ally with the Chartists, a working-
class movement seeking a more perfect bourgeois de-
mocracy. In the United States they are to back the
agrarian reformers whose key demand was free land,
i.e., private property, in the West. In France the Com-
ni
IV
politicaleconomy of capital.
Meanwhile the French labor movement was also
growing, but under the most ironic of auspices. After
the economic downturn in the late fifties, Napoleon
III attempted to win support among the workers by al-
lowing them a certain freedom of union organization.
The followers of Proudhon took advantage of this im-
perial concession (and were promptly denounced by the
Blanquists for selling out). Then in 1862 Armand
70 SOCIALISM
Levy, a journalist on the Right wing of the labor move
ment, asked the "Red Prince," Jerome Bonaparte, for
financial aid to send a French workers' delegation to
the Exposition being held that year in London. The
Blanquists once again denounced this contact with
the ruling class, but many Proudhonists went along.
The resultant meetings between the French and British
trade unionists were a major factor in the establish-
ment of the International Workingmen's Association
(IWMA), the "First International," in 1864.
was this most un-Marxian united front of British
It
labor, which was politically oriented toward the bour-
geois radicals, and French followers of Proudhon, who
traveled with aid from the Bonapartes and were for
state aid to decentralized associations of producers,
that Marx made the focus of his politics for the next
several years. This tactic, which outraged all the purists
at the time, laid the basis for the historic identification
of socialism and trade unionism that persists in Europe
to this day. Marx formulated it most brilliantly and
explicitly in the "Inaugural Address" to the in IWMA
1864.
One section of that document gives a particularly
vivid measure of how far he had traveled from the
bitter days of defeat in 1849 and 1850, but more than
that it gives to a perennial problem for
Marx's answer
radicals: What
the relationship between immediate
is
what it is not.
In the true radicalism of Marx in this period,
fact,
as in the 840s, was that he was courageous enough to
1
II
m
The German Social Democracy survived Bismarck's
"socialism" and flourished. By the 1912 elections they
had won a third of the seats in the Reichstag, made a
84 SOCIALISM
de facto alliance with the Liberals, and in effect create
a Grossblock, an electoral united front of the working
class and bourgeois Left. The unions, which had onlj
300,000 members in 1 892, enrolled two and a hal:
million workers in 1913. The party organization and
press were the wonder of the socialist world and the
Germans were the dominant factor in the Second In-
ternational. It seemed that history was providing a mag-
nificent confirmation of the Marxian perspective.
Yet when the decisive test came in August, 1914, the
German socialists, along with most of their comrades
around the globe, betrayed their solemn and repeated
anti-war promises. The proletarians turned out to be as
patriotic as the bourgeoisie and some of the most funda-
mental assumptions of Marx and Engels were thus re-
futed in historic practice. The reasons for this shift are
so complex that an entire library could be devoted to
analyzing them. What is particularly relevant here is an
outline of those factors involved in this fateful mo-
ment that throw light on the future of socialism itself.
First of all, the capitalist economies of the second
half of the nineteenth century were not as crisis-ridden
as Marx and Engels initially thought they would be.
The period in which Marx and Engels became in-
—
volved in politics the second quarter of the century
—was marked by particularly violent economic crises.
And there was tremendous social dislocation as a result
of the migration from rural areas and the destruction
of handicraft industry. This was the reality that was
imperfectly recorded in the Manifesto. Yet during the
time when Marxist influence spread, in the last quarter
of the century, real wages were going up and there
was tremendous industrial expansion. So, as Fritz Stern-
berg formulates the paradox, "in the same period in
which Marxism became of primary importance for the
European working classes, their conditions of life and,
above all, the general trend of development, was not
in the least in accordance with the laws of capitalism
as analyzed by Marx."
At the very end of his life Engels was quite aware
The Unknown Karl Marx 85
Das Kapital
n
Das Kapital begins its study of the existential reality
behind capitalisteconomic categories with dry-as-dust
definitions and a tightly argued and abstruse analysis
of the "fetishism of commodities." This is because the
book proceeds from the abstract to the concrete.
On the face of it, that is a preposterous order to fol-
low, since it is obvious that thinking always moves from
the concrete to the abstract. But there is a method in
Marx's apparent madness and he described it carefully
in an introduction to the Critique of Political Economy
(which was not actually published until 1903, after his
death). He wrote, "It seems to be the correct procedure
Das Kapitai 103
L
104 SOCIALISM
these simplifying assumptions are progressively dropped
once they have helped in the understanding of the so-
cial whole as "a rich totality of many conceptions and
relationships."
Marx's method is of interest on its own terms but it
is stressed here for a special reason. This interpretation
of Das Kapital begin with the conclusion of Vol-
will
ume the chapter on the "Historic Tend-
I. It is there, in
ency of Capitalist Accumulation"
—
"a magnificent his-
torical generalization," Gershenkron calls it — that one
finds a statement of the reality that the earlier abstrac-
tions explicate. And since there is so much confusion
about Marx's meaning in the opening pages, particu-
larly about the definition of that confusing term "value,"
it is legitimate to begin with the more realistic, and
C-C.
C-M-C.
with the use value to be created but only with the profit
to be realized. Now the transaction could be described
as:
M-C-M'.
M-C-M'
in
II
This was, as
Socialist Party to affiliate formally with it.
Taft has recognized, a ''major change" in AFL strategy.
One might even argue that it amounted to a repeal of
the 1894 decision against independent labor political
action. And, in fact, the CPPA led to the La Follette
campaign of 1924, again with the socialists as a public-
ly acknowledged component of the coalition.
The significance of this development has been ob-
scured by a number of factors. The unions were dis-
appointed by their 1924 venture in political indepen-
dence; the Socialist Party was split over the Russian
Revolution; and employers became more subtle in
their anti-unionism in the twenties. So from 1924 to
the Great Depression the AFL reverted back to Gom-
pers' voluntarism. But as the subsequent history of the
movement was to show, this was only an episode. The
main trend, which emerged so strongly in the thirties,
was toward labor political action.
Thus American workers had to organize unions on a
class basis in order to defend their' economic interests,
for agrarian Utopias provided no real solution to their
problems. Then, even though Samuel Gompers labored
valiantly that it might be otherwise, they were forced
to involve themselves in politics on that same class ba-
sis. In the process, they were not at all like German
m
But what, then, of those shoals of apple pie and roast
beef?
One answer is that they did not exist, at least not to
the extent that Sombart and his devotees believed. This
point is worth emphasizing in some detail because it
relates to a crucial contempory misunderstanding: that
the America of the 1970s has given an adequate stan-
dard of living to the majority of its people. That, as
Chapter X
will show, is simply not the case: and, as this
section will demonstrate, it never was. Secondly, to the
extent that the United States did enjoy some material
advantages as against Europe, it is psychologically sim-
plistic to assume that this would automatically make the
citizen here more content. This is an important reality
to examine historically since it is so relevant to all the
end-of-ideology theories which claim that affluence is
now rendering both the class struggle and socialism
obsolete.
Finally, there are two key factors that do account
for what is unquestionably exceptional in American
socialist history. Friedrich Engels was one of the first to
state them, simply but cogently: "There are two cir-
cumstances that have, for many years, kept the full
consequences of the capitalist system in America from
coming to the light of day. These are the easy avail-
ability of cheap land and the huge immigrations." The
first of these has already been analyzed, the second will
figure prominently in what follows.
To begin with a fundamental fact: The typical Amer-
ican never did gorge himself on roast beef and apple
pie. He still doesn't.
The American Exception 155
cial legislation.
So the first problem with the abundance interpreta-
tion of American labor history —
and the supposed con-
tentment that made the workers impervious to socialist
—
appeals is that the facts do not support it, or do so
only when is so qualified as to be almost use-
the theory
less for explaining anything. Secondly, even to the
limited extent that wages in the United States were bet-
ter than in Europe —
mainly for the relatively small
minority of skilled, organized workers — there is no rea-
son to believe that a higher standard of living neces-
sarily makes for docile workers.
Under feudalism and in the early days of capitalism
economic crisis took a brutally obvious form: recession
and starvation went together. In the Hungry Forties of
the nineteenth century in England Chartist protest in-
creased in bad times and all but disappeared when
prosperity returned in 1850. In those days a depression
usually began in the agricultural sector as a result of a
poor harvest. That made food in short supply, and by
contracting the domestic market, threw men in the cities
out of work at the same time. But after the 1850s, ex-
treme hunger and economic crisis no longer necessarily
went together since the industrial sector was becoming
dominant and high unemployment was sometimes even
accompanied by a fall in the cost of living. At this point
the modern, specifically capitalist kind of radicalization
began to appear: the insurgency took place after the
dark days, not during them, for "the long-term de-
pression factors . .helped to accumulate inflammable
.
VII
n
In 1896, the year after Engels died, these issues moved
from theory to politics. The London Congress of the
SocialistInternational —
the "Second International,"
which claimed direct descent from Marx's International
—
Workingmen's Association took a straightforward po-
sition on favored the "full right of self-
colonialism. It
determination for all nations" and held that "whatever
manner of religious or civilizing pretext colonial policy
might have, it is always only in the interest of the
capitalists." That was the last time the issue was ever
to seem so uncomplicated.
Between 1896 and World War I socialists appeared
as enthusiastic champions, and bitter opponents, of cap-
italist imperialism. There were those who declared so-
cialism had no place in the colonies; those who, in the
name of the Left, supported imperialism; and those
who were revolutionary and intransigent foes of co-
lonialism. Yet no one had any solution to the basic
problem: how to find a democratic and humane way to
industrialize economically backward countries. Even so,
every one of the positions the socialists took was to
have an influence on history, and most of them still
inspire millions today.
One approach to colonialism was simplicity itself: it
held that socialism has nothing to say to the majority
of mankind.
It was in 1909 that Enrico Ferri, the Italian crim-
inologist and a member of the Italian Socialist Party,
went to Argentina. He lost little time in telling his
comrades there that they had no business being social-
ists. Socialism, he said, was a European importation in
182 SOCIALISM
ardor of the European workers. It was, rather, the un-
foreseen and complex development of capitalism itself,
a process in which colonialism played a role, but not
necessarily a decisive one (all the ramifications of this
analysis will not become apparent until later chapters
dealing with the Third World)
The second issue the socialists confronted in this de-
bate arose out of a discussion of the Belgian Congo. It
involved nothing less than defining a political stance
for which there was no precedent in Marxian thought
or any other socialist theory. Today, almost three quar-
ters of a century later, social democrats are still strug-
gling with the problem.
In the classic Marxist scenario the socialists were to
move quickly from powerlessness to power. The
wretched of the earth would win the final conflict and
abruptly transform the entire social order, from bottom
to top. As time went on, Marx and Engels moved
away from this insurrectionary vision and considered
the possibility of a peaceful democratic road to social-
ism in England, the United States, France and Hol-
land. But they never analyzed what their followers
should do when they won not power, but an increment
of power within a system that still remained capitalist
This, as Chapter XI will document, was to be the cen-
tral problem for the social democrats when they tried
to deal with the Great Depression of the thirties, and
it plagued the Wilson Government in the England of
I • Lenin
— —
impasse that he had poignantly, almost, it seems to
me defined? He gave two answers. First, in On Co-
operation he confessed that "there has been a radical
modification of our whole outlook on socialism. The
radical modification is this: formerly we placed and had
to place, the main emphasis on political struggle, on
revolution, on the winning of political power, etc. Now
the emphasis is changing and shifting to peaceful, or-
ganizational, 'cultural' work." So now, there are two
main tasks: to reorganize the machinery of state and to
carry out educational work among the peasants (the
workers, those classic heroes of the Marxian vision, have
vanished). "This cultural revolution," Lenin concludes,
Revolution from Above 203
II • Stalin
Socialist Capitalism
—
humane and therefore more stable as they have—
done, and another thing to create socialism. The ultra-
Leftists of various persuasions have a simple way out
of this difficulty they propose to make a revolution on
:
m
It was in the late fifties and early sixties that the Euro-
pean socialists faced up to the contradictions of their
experience. In a series of programmatic revisions in
Britain, Germany, Sweden, Austria and other coun-
tries, there was an attempt to bring theory into some
minimal relationship with practice.
Basically, as my analysis will indicate in this chapter
and inChapter XII, the revisions went too far: they
made socialism indistinguishable from intelligent Amer-
ican liberalism, a program for the humanization, but
not the transformation, of capitalism. That modest goal
is something very much worth fighting for, and those
commentators who saw no difference between Labour
and the Tories in the 1970 British elections were made
to look rather silly when the Tories celebrated their
victory by an attack upon social services. But valuable
as the social democratic reforms are, they do not add
Socialist Capitalism 249
W J?p
Special
V1
7An their
Party Congress in November,
statement of this
new Basic Pr °g ram ad °Pted
1 959.
The aim of social democratic economic
at a
policy," the
program proclaims, "is ever-increasing
prosperity and a
just division of the fruits
of the people's economy, a fife
m freedom without demeaning dependence and without
exploration." Th,s aim is
endangered by the concen-
tration of economic power
in capitalist society in which
jroge organizations dispose
of millions and command
tens of thousands of workers.
But the objection to this
T£LV V n hat
lthiaiK
d be made
?^l
Where
an °y anti-monopoly
the bi g enterprises predomi-
£?f\
nate there is no free competition."
Moreoever, "through
cartels and combines, the big enterprises
still more in-
i T
P ST and the cor Porate leaders win an
ZfhZ over the state and politics
influence
which is compatible
with democratic principles.
They usurp the state power.
Economic power becomes political P
power."
Dt the trad itional
thpri ™ \F°u '? socialist program
S?!r^ d h3Ve been
tl0n ° f S
a demand ^
the widespread
h enterP™es. The Godesberg Pro-
S£?T T
h?W VCr ° fferS a different a roach to
S * ?
gle against
' PP
concentrated economic power.
the strug-
"Private
property in the means of
production has a right and
Socialist Capitalism 253
— —
That bourgeois or "French" revolution which
Galbraith seeks cannot possibly take place in most of
the Third World. Under special circumstances, as in
Iran, it is conceivable that oil revenues can be used
to sponsor industrialization coupled with land reform,
—
but even that produces a highly statified in this case,
—
monarchical variant of capitalism. In general, how-
ever, there are massive historic reasons that preclude
a capitalist development with or without American aid
(more precisely, as Chapter XII will show, American
trade and aid policy has been a barrier to moderniza-
tion in the poor lands).
But then, couldn't these countries settle for a slow
rate of growth? Raul Prebisch of the United Nations'
Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD)
posed and dealt with that question at a New Delhi
meeting. He asked, "Could they not be content with a
relatively moderate pace, like that of the industrial
centres during their historic development?" And
answered, "The historic experience of these countries
can never be repeated, either as concerns the pace of
development or in any other respect. Perhaps it would
be possible to repeat it if we could revert to the produc-
tion techniques of a century ago, if we could prevent
news of the new forms or private consumption and so-
cial well-being from spreading continuously —
a devel-
opment which is the natural outcome of communication
techniques —and if we could turn back the clock and
erase the progress which the masses of the people have
achieved in their political and social development."
What Prebisch was describing is one of the cruelest
facts of contemporary life: that the preconditions for
modernization are becoming progressively more and
more expensive. Russia in 1913 was probably below
the level of development of most South American coun-
tries today, yet the prospects for industrialization there
were much more propitious. The necessary investments
in technology have become much more massive since
1913; political movements are more demanding; and,
above all, there is a highly developed global division
268 SOCIALISM
of labor which is hostile to the industrialization of
poor lands. When the Western European countries, the
United States, Australia and Japan emerged as capitalist
powers, the world was not already dominated by an-
other group of even stronger nations. Capital, Barbara
Ward has estimated, is sixty times more costly to the
developing countries of the twentieth century than it
was to the new capitalisms of the nineteenth.
Gunnar Myrdal reports that in Southeast Asia, "in-
stead of a rising demand for exports aiding the early
stages of industrialization as in most Western coun-
tries,exports must be pushed by systematic government
action." Indeed, the subordinate position of these na-
tions on the world market accounts for much of their
economic structure and partly explains the absence of
a strong, indigenous bourgeoisie. For, as we have seen
in Chapter VI, to the degree that the original capitalist
powers invested in the colonies and semi-colonies, they
created enclaves of modernity. Therefore the local
capitalist was more often than not a collaborator with
foreign money rather than an innovating entrepreneur
on his own.
Russia had undergone the beginnings of a capitalist
development prior to the October Revolution in 1917.
Its industry was, to be sure, heavily under the in-
fluence of foreign capital and had some of the
characteristics of an enclave, yet it was not basically
subordinated to some metropolitan economy as in the
case of the colonies and semi-colonies. In this setting
the scarce entrepreneurial talents could be united in
very large industrial units, as Alexander Gershenkron
has documented. Russia had, in short, arrived quite
late on the capitalist scene, yet it still might have de-
veloped in the authoritarian, German-Japanese variant
of that mode. It was located midway between Oriental
despotism and Western capitalism.
But in the Third World nations that became formal-
ly independent after World War II, or as with the Latin
Republics, began to search for economic independence
at that point, the circumstances were not so positive.
The Substitute Proletariats 269
n
Peasants were the mass basis of the Chinese Revolu-
tion —
but it was not a peasant revolution for which they
The Substitute Proletariats 271
m
There is another class that has been nominated by some
theorists as a substitute proletariat in the socialist revo-
lution: the urban poor.
The poor, it must be remembered, are not at all
equivalent to the working class. The workers are usual-
ly subjected to the discipline of modern methods of
production and have a natural tendency, arising out of
their conditions of labor, to organize themselves into
collective associations. The poor are unemployed or
—
The Substitute Proletariats 285
IV
i
The Substitute Proletariats 289
VI
II
ni
326 SOCIALISM
One might try to explain this phenomenon in tradi-
tional— non-class —American terms by saying that the
unions were simply acting as an interest group. How-
ever, interest groups do not identify with a single party
but try to put pressure on both the Republicans and
Democrats (they often have a prominent vice president
belonging to each of the major parties). They empha-
size their specific demands, not their long-term support.
But labor had clearly made an on-going, class-based
political commitment and constituted a tendency —
labor party of sorts —
within the Democratic Party.
The way in which this development transcended the
interest-group approach can be seen clearly in some of
the back-room politicking over the reapportionment of
the state legislatures. Everett McKinley Dirksen, the
Republican leader in the Senate, was very anxious to
repeal the Supreme Court's one-man/one-vote ruling as
applied to the state houses. So he offered to go along
with the unions in promoting their most self-interested
goal, the repeal of the Federal authorization for state
"right to work" laws, if labor would moderate its sup-
port for reapportionment. If the unions had been act-
ing as an interest group, they would have snapped up
Dirksen's offer, since it would have guaranteed passage
of a law that was explicitly in their favor. But they
chose to maximize a much more long-term perspective
and to stick to their support for reapportionment.
Labor's orientation toward playing a role in the
center of American politics, where one-man/one-vote
was so important, had prevailed over narrow organi-
zational concerns. The unions, in short, had created a
social democratic party, with its own apparatus and
program, within the Democratic Party. But how, then,
can it be explained that this mass movement has re-
mained invisible for so many intellectuals?
Part of the answer is semantic. The unions changed
their philosophy and their actions, but kept most of
the old labels. Yet, as soon as one probes a bit, it be-
comes evident that the laborites were using, in Leon
Samson's perceptive insight, socialist definitions of
The Invisible Mass Movement 327
n
Neo-capitalism, for all its sophistication, cannot make
desperately needed social investments, plan compre-
hensively and massively or cope with either poverty
or affluence. Socialism can. This section will seek to ex-
plain how.
In the process, I will use a dangerous distinction. One
begins with the specific problems that have just been
identified and seeks a solution to them which, while
structurally altering the capitalist society, will take
place within some of the limitations that society im-
Beyond the Welfare State 357
370 SOCIALISM
New York Authority, its independence from democrat
control, that has allowed it to use its resources fc
creative anti-social purposes like increasing pollution
This point is central in John Kenneth Galbraith's cri-
—
has identified a serious problem the Scylla represented
by the Post Office, the Charybdis represented by the
—
Port Authority it is impossible for society to carry out
liberal reform, to plan and to allocate social costs prop-
erly, unless it asserts a decisive interest over the huge
corporations. That means that there will indeed be an
ever-present danger of inefficiency, dullness, poor ser-
vice and all the rest. But that risk is to be infinitely pre-
ferred to the one incurred by leaving the corporate
structure in its present, irresponsible form. There are,
in short, no "perfect" solutions to these enormous prob-
lems, and any intelligent person can foresee difficulties
in any proposal. Nevertheless, the public corporation
with both the right to internal financing and the re-
sponsibility to democratically elected representatives of
the people is, with all the problems admitted, a right
step in the best direction.
Moreover, there are many instanceswhere coopera-
and neighborhood forms of ownership are relevant.
tive
The problems that have just been discussed arise pri-
marily in the giant decisive enterprises that are so
large-scaleand basic to national planning that the state
must assert a major interest in them. But there are a
great many less complicated economic functions which
—
can be carried out by to use the phrase Marx bor-
—
rowed from the Proudhonist tradition the "associated
producers." In the United States, for instance, the New
Deal promoted rural electrification by providing relative-
ly cheap credit to local cooperatives, and in this way
electricitywas brought to the rural areas (the notion
of central-state financial aid to such small units is one
that can be found throughout nineteenth-century social-
ism: in Proudhon, Louis Blanc, Lassalle and the Bel-
gian socialists among others).
In this context, the idea of functional socialization is
not simply a political necessity; it is also an opportunity
for innovation. In the old apocalyptic proposals for the
sudden and decisive nationalization of all basic industry
there was little room for promoting diversity and a va-
riety of institutional forms. But in proceeding to so-
372 SOCIALISM
property over a period
cialize the specific functions of
of time there is much more of a chance for originality
and imagination.
With the rise of pollution as an issue, the Govern-
ment has been pushed into monitoring the levels of
mercury in food and into banning the use of cyclamates
and other additives. There is even evidence in the
United States, for all its explicit anti-socialism, that a
campaign that would thus assert public control over the
corporation might be politically popular. As I noted
earlier, Ralph Nader and his colleagues have organized
extremely effective campaigns to limit the sovereign
power of the big companies and forced safety reforms
in the automobile industry. In the Nader campaign to
gain public representation on the General Motors board
there has been a growing realization, among the young
in particular, that "private" choices with public conse-
quences must be socialized. Indeed, it seems to me that
Nader, who is a reformer acting empirically, has in
many ways raised more radical questions, and possibili-
ties, than the European social democrats. His lead
should be carefully followed. 7
There is still another avenue of socialist action, and
it, like the Nader campaign, may also be quite popu-
376 SOCIALISM
benefits for a huge majority. If all the artful outlived
rationales for favoring the rich can be shown to be
what they are, masses would support their abolition.
So there are three main areas of transitional pro-
grams moving in the direction of a socialist democrati-
zation of economic power: the socialization of invest-
ment; the progressive socialization of the functions of
corporate porperty, and then that of property itself;
the employment of tax policy as an instrument for social
justice. Each one of these structural reforms corre-
sponds to a need in the society which can be docu-
mented and more to the political
in the official reports,
point, several of them could become quite popular with
the majority of the people.
There is, then, still very much meaning to the idea
of socialism as it relates to the middle distance. After
examining how we must go beyond the world market
as well as the welfare state, i.e., socialism's relevance
to the Third World, I will turn to the far future. For if
socialists no longer imagine an existing society of total
perfection, they must hold fast to a vision of a new
order which can animate all the approximations of it. 8
XIII
—
they must be sent overseas. For —
and this is a crucial
point "surplus capital will never be utilized for the
purpose of raising the standard of living of the masses
in a given capitalist country, for this would mean a
decline in profits for the capitalists. ."
. .
But the prices of the one group go up, and of the other,
down, and the only characteristic that is common to the
prices is that they are respectively those of rich and
those of poor countries."
In the late sixties and early seventies there seemed to
be a countertrend, a shift back toward investment in
the Third World. To the extent that it took place, it was
one more example of advanced capitalism manipulating
poor countries in order to maximize the profits of the
rich. Multinational corporations began to set up plants
in places like Singapore, Taiwan, Mexico and Korea,
where labor is much cheaper than in Europe and the
386 SOCIALISM
United States. They then used these installations as
bases for exports, sometimes to the affluent market it-
self. In this way they are able to flee the relatively high
wages which the workers have won in the metropolitan
centers.
Once again, these investments are made according to
the same principles that guided the imperial expansion
of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries: to fit
the convenience and increase the profits of the already
rich nations. Thus, the industries chosen to get capital
in such undertakings must be labor-intensive and not
depend on economies of scale, i.e., must be backward
in comparison with the plants that are built in the home
country. The emphasis is on textiles, clothing, furniture
and other wood products, lathes and other simple ma-
chine tools. This can indeed promote the Gross National
—
Product of a developing nation as it has rather dra-
matically in Taiwan and South Korea — but it mis-
shapes the economy and makes it the adjunct of a
foreign power rather than an entity moving toward
autonomous self-induced growth. And although it may
well have beneficial side effects, the process is one more
example of the exploitation of poverty.
In other words, in every period of Western capitalist
involvement with the Third World the overriding con-
sideration has been the wealth of the advanced nation,
not the health of the poverty-stricken. First, the colonial
lands were assigned the role of producers of raw ma-
terials and agricultural products; after World War II
(or even somewhat earlier), when that no longer suited
the needs of the big powers, their exports were allowed
to languish; and in the late sixties and early seventies,
when investment in cheap labor in Asia and Latin
America was seen as a way of escaping union wages
back home, the corporations seemed again prepared to
export some capital, not to help with economic devel-
opment, but in many cases to distort it by subordinat-
ing the needs of impoverished people to those of the
rich.
So the details can be debated but the main trend is
Beyond the World Market 387
was why Lenin could argue that the big capitalist powers
had to expand into the colonial world. And once one
admits, as Mandel and Magdoff do, that this is no longer
the dominant trend, then the Leninist analysis falls and
it is no longer bourgeois sentimentality to suggest that a
n
But if capitalism, and particularly a capitalism being
m
In order to aid in economic development the advanced
countries must reject the priorities of the world market
that have guided their aid and trade policies. Socialists
in these countries, therefore, must take the lead in at-
tacking and fundamentally modifying the global calcu-
lus of profit that now misallocates international re-
sources.
Here again, it would be much more exhilarating to
396 SOCIALISM
propose to do away with the capitalist system, national-
ly and internationally, and proceed to constitute the
Parliament of Man. That, to put it mildly, is not on the
political agenda in the West, and even if it were, the
details of that grand vision are even more vague than
the principles the Left has had so much difficulty in ap-
plying within capitalist society. So if socialists content
themselves with incantations of a coming world apoca-
lypse, that is a way of turning one's back on the
hungry.
What is minimally required and politically possible is
a restructuring of the world market itself. Such a reform
would be the international equivalent to the New Deal
or the changes wrought by the British Labour Party
after World War II. The internationaleconomy, like
domestic America and Britain in the under
thirties, is
the rule of laissez-faire. Now there must be a welfare
world instead.
In order to advance in that direction it is necessary
to confront, and basically modify, one of the contradic-
tions of capitalism. As a producer, the businessman
buys labor power and it is therefore very much in his
interest to keep wages down, to destroy unions, to limit
or oppose taxes and government spending, and so on.
As a seller, however, the very same businessman wants
as large a market as possible. If he pays low wages him-
self, he still wishes, so to speak, that other businessmen
will be lavish with their employees so that they will be
able to buy his product. Historically, business's unques-
tioned dominance of Western capitalism was based on
cutting costs and keeping wages low. It was the labor
and socialist movements in Europe and the liberals in
the United States who finally demonstrated, in theory
and in practice, that high mass consumption was in the
interests of the rich as well as the poor. The conserva-
tives were, to be sure, only partly convinced: their
Keynesianism is reactionary and seeks to stimulate the
economy by providing tax windfalls to wealthy individ-
uals and corporations rather than by social spending. Yet
everyone but the neanderthals now understands the
Beyond the World Market 397
state.
But if capital, then, is not going to push for the in-
dustrialization of the world, what about labor? The an-
swer to this question is not an easy one. It is quite pos-
sible to write a scenario in which the organized workers
join with business in order to perpetuate the privileges
of the affluent economies in the global division of labor.
And it is also quite possible that those same workers,
400 SOCIALISM
Within a year there was a fairly vivid, practical dem-
onstration of what the point raised at Eastbourne
might mean. During a fight between British auto work-
ers and the Ford company's operation in that country,
4
the leaders of the International Metal Workers Federa-
tion met with Prime Minister Edward Heath. So it was
that Leonard Woodcock, the president of the American
United Automobile Workers, joined with Hugh Scanlon
of the British engineering unions and Jack Jones of the
transport workers. This international delegation was try-
ing to counter a Ford threat to move his factory out of
England if wages went up. At a conference of the In-
ternational Metal Workers Secretariat of the Interna-
tional Confederation of Free Trade Unions (ICFTU)
shortly before the encounter with Heath, Victor Feath-
er,the general secretary of Britain's Trades Union Con-
gress,had declared that if governments did not control
the giant multinational companies, the companies will
soon control them.
The Economist, Britain's sophisticated, pro-business
weekly, summarized these trends in 1971: "The de-
velopment of international union strength," it said,
"should now probably be a steady process. In some
ways, the multinational companies will be their own
worst enemies. Just as the international consumer is en-
couraged to identify with products from specific mul-
tinationals, so are workers increasingly identifying
themselves as, say, 'Ford' workers, irrespective of what
national subsidiary of Ford they work in. Thus in-
creasingly the demand for parity of work conditions
and reward between the international branches of the
same multinational will become a spontaneous one." If
this assessment turns out to be accurate, then the mul-
tinational corporation may make an enormous contri-
bution to the internationalist consciousness of the work-
ers of the world.
So it is possible within a society transitional between
capitalism and socialism to make structural reforms that
—
could enormously benefit the Third World and pos-
sible that socialist mass movements could make such
Beyond the World Market 401
IV
planning.
The international corporations have been engaged in
just such global calculations for some time now. There
is no reason that the techniques that have been em-
quire totalitarianism.
In this very brief survey, then, the most important
conclusion is that an alternative to both capitalist and
totalitarian modernization is not only necessary, but
perhaps even possible. The capitalist road to the Third
World future leads backward, for it reproduces and
strengthens the very economic relationships that are the
cause of underdevelopment. The Communist road, out-
side of Russia, may well be impractical as well as un-
conscionably terroristic, for poverty-stricken societies
may not have the energy to respond even to coercion.
So it is quite possible that socialist values, like equality
and democratic participation, have a special relevance
in Asia, Africa and Latin America. Contrary to what so
many in the West have thought for so long, a radical
concern for the individual may be an economic im-
perative in these areas of the world.
VI
Socialism
II
i
Socialism 435
Socialism 439
m
The socialist vision, then, could be made relevant to
the twenty-first century. That would mean that masses
of men and women would seek to construct a society
in which compulsory work and money would both tend
to disappear. These ultimates are important in that
they define a goal to be approximated — and also be-
cause they concern the political choices that must be
made tomorrow. If, for example, one is very clear about
the need to make more and more goods and commodi-
ties free, then that will affect how one designs a health
insurance program.
In 1971, for instance, Richard Nixon's medical pro-
posals were designed to leave existing structures intact
by contracting out the society's responsibility to private
insurance companies (although it should be noted that
ten years earlier Nixon would have probably de-
nounced his own plan as "socialized medicine"). The
bill proposed by Senator Kennedy and supported by
the unions, on the other hand, actually aimed at chang-
ing medical practices and relied on general government
revenues for financing. The Kennedy proposal was not,
to be sure, socialist, but an understanding of the social-
ist ideal helps greatly in making people realize that
it is the infinitely preferable of the two liberal options.
that desert and tell him that in the city there are public
water fountains and that children are even sometimes-
allowed to turn on the fire hydrants in the summer and
to frolic in the water, he would be sure one wer^ crazy.
For he knows, with an existential certitude, that it is
human nature to fight over water.
Mankind has lived now for several millennia in the
desert. Our minds and emotions are conditioned by
that bitter experience; we do not dare to think that
things could be otherwise. Yet there are signs that we
are, without really having planned it that way, march-
ing out of the desert. There are some who loathe to
leave behind the consolation of familiar brutalities;
there are others who in one way or another would like
to impose the law of the desert upon the Promised
Land. It may even be possible that mankind cannot bear
too much happiness.
It is also possible that we will seize this opportunity
and make of the earth a homeland rather than an exile.
That is the socialist project. It does not promise, or
even seek, to abolish the human condition, for that is
impossible. It does propose to end that invidious com-
petition and venality which, because scarcity allowed
no other alternatives, we have come to think are in-
separable from our humanity.
Under socialism, there will be no end to history—
but there may be a new history.
Notes
Chapter I
Chapter II
Chapter HI
Chapter IV
Chapter V
1. Wassily Leontiev, 'The Significance of Marxian Eco-
nomics for Present-Day Economic Theory," in
Marx and Modern Economics, ed. David Hor-
rowitz (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1968),
p. 94. Paul Samuelson, "Wages and Interest: A
Modern Dissection of Marxian Economic Models,"
American Economic Review (December, 1957,
Vol.XLVII, No. 6), pp. 884 ff.; Marx as minor:
ibid., p. 911; natural resources: ibid., p. 894. Gotha
Program: MEW, XIX, p. 15 (see also MEW, XIII,
p. 618, and Das Kapital, MEW, XXIII, p. 218).
Critique of Samuelson: Fred M. Gottheil, Ameri-
can Economic Review (September, 1960); reply by
Samuelson: ibid. Marx in 1843: MEW, I, pp. 231
and 370. Max Adler, Die Solidarische Gesellschaft
(Vienna: Europa Verlag, 1964), p. 12.
2. Theories of Surplus Value: MEW, XXVI, Pt. 1, pp. 12
ff.; p. 366. Labor theory of value as pro-capitalist:
Chapter VI
Chapter VH
1. Marx to Engels, October 8, 1858: MEW, XXIX. Das
Kapital, Vol. 1867 Introduction: MEW, XXIII,
I,
Chapter VIII
Chapter IX
p. 71.
3. Blum: VOeuvre de Leon Blum, 1945-1947 (Paris:
fiditions Albin Michel, 1968), pp. 284 and 273.
Andre Philip, Les Socialistes (Paris: Seuil, 1967),
p. 90. Faure: quoted, ibid., p. 76. Cole on De
Man: History of Socialist Thought, Vol. V, p.
189; Landauer, op. cit., p. 1405. Henri de Man,
Cavalier Seul (Geneva: Editions du Cheval Aile,
1948), pp. 163 ff. Deat and Marquet: Philip, op.
cit., p.74. Lichtheim on Deat: Marxism in Modern
France, 2nd edition (New York: Columbia Uni-
versity Press, 1968), p. 41, n. 12. Epitaph:
Sturmthal, op. cit., p. 5. Ralph Miliband, The
State in Capitalist Society (London: Weidenfeld
and Nicolson, 1969), p. 99.
4. Nationalizations after World War II: Michael Kidron,
Western Capitalism Since the War (Baltimore:
Penguin Books, 1970), pp. 24 ff. Kautsky, Das
Erfurt er Programm (Stuttgart: Dietz Verlag,
1892). Jaures on state: quoted in Philip, op. cit.,
p. 45. 1910 resolution: ibid., pp. 36-37. Jaures
and nationalization, 1894: Jaures et le Socialisme
des Intellectuels (Paris: Georges Lefranc Aubier,
1968), p. 31. Otto Bauer, quoted in Norbert Leser,
Notes 475
Zwischen Reformismus und Bolshewismus (Vien-
na: Europa Verlag, 1968), p. 147. British mines:
Cole, History of Socialist Thought, Vol. IV, Pt. I,
p. 416. Geneva Conference: ibid., p. 328. Sidney
Webb, Fabian Essays in Socialism (Gloucester,
Mass.: Peter Smith, 1967 [originally 1889]), pp.
68-69. Engels on Fabians: MEW, XXIX, p. 8.
Clause Four: quoted: Paul Foot, The Politics of
Harold Wilson (London: Penguin Books, 1968), p.
123. Ralf Dahrendorf, Society and Democracy in
Germany (New York: Doubleday and Company,
1963), p. 167. Andre Philip, La Gauche, Mythes
et Realites (Paris: Georges Lefranc Aubier, 1964),
p. The Accidental Century (New York: The
71.
Macmillan Company, 1965), Chap. III. Post-1945
British nationalization: C. A. R. Crosland, The
Future of Socialism (London: Jonathan Cape,
1956), p. 484. Steel ^nationalization: Paul Foot,
op. cit., p. 189; The Economist (January 31,
1970). Macmillan and nationalization: Macmillan,
op. cit., p. 232; Foot, op. cit., p. 341, n. 1. Douglas
Chapter X
1. John Galbraith, Economic Development,
Kenneth
Sentry ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company,
1964), p. 4. Iran: see Walter Z. Laquer, The
Struggle for the Middle East (New York: The
Macmillan Company, 1969), pp. 31 ff. Raul Pre-
bisch, UNCTAD, Second Session, New Delhi, 1968
(New York: United Nations, 1968), p. 417; see
also Fernando H. Cardoso, "The Industrial Elite,"
in Elites in Latin America, ed. Seymour Martin
Lipset and Aldo Solari (New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 1967), p. 95. Russia in 1913: Charles
K. Wilber, The Soviet Model and Underdeveloped
Countries (Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press, 1969), p. 14 and Table 1-2, p.
15. Gunnar Myrdal: Asian Drama: An Inquiry in-
to the Poverty of Nations (New York: Pantheon
Books, 1968), Vol. II, p. 717. Alexander Ger-
Notes 477
shenkron, Continuity in History and Other Essays
(Cambridge: Belknap, 1968), p. 137. On Weber:
Seymour Martin Lipset, "Values, Education and
Entrepreneurship," in Lipset and Solari, op. cit.,
p. 4. Gunnar Myrdal, The Challenge of World
Poverty (New York: Pantheon Books, 1970), p.
83.
2. Mao Tse-tung, Selected Works (hereafter cited as SW)
(London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1954), Vol. Ill,
p. 215. Hong Kong Weekly quoted in Ygael
Gluckstein, Mao's China (London: Allen and Un-
win, 1957), p. 193. On the 1928-1937 period and
the Kuomintang, cf. Barrington Moore, The Social
Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston:
Beacon Press, 1966), pp. 187 ff.; and Michael
Harrington, Communist China: A Socialist Analy-
sis (New York: Young People's Socialist League,
1962 [mimeo]). On inflation in China in 1949:
Gluckstein, op. cit., p. 103; Chang Kia-ngau, The
Inflationary Spiral (New York: John Wiley, 1958),
passim. Mao on classes in the Chinese Revolution:
SW, III, p. 220. On China in the 1920s, see Harold
Isaacs, The Tragedy of the Chinese Revolution,
rev.
ed. (Stanford: Stanford University Press,
1951). Communists and workers: Benjamin
Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of
Mao (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press,
1952), p. 97. Mao on peasantry and proletariat
(1939): SW, III, pp. 87 ff. Engels on the peasants
(1892): MEW, XIX, p. 58. Marx, The Eighteenth
Brumaire: MEW, VIII, p. 198. Karl Kautsky,
"Triebkrafte der Russischen Revolution," Die Neue
Zeit, Vol. 25, Bd. 1, No. 10 (1906), p. 330.
Manifestes, Theses et Resolutions des Quatres
Premiers Congres Mondiaux (Paris: Bibliotheque
Communiste, 1934 [reprinted, Paris: Maspero,
1969]), pp. 78-79. Sultan-Galiev: Leonard
Schapiro, The Communist Party of the Soviet
Union (New York: Random House, 1960), p.
348. Harold Isaacs, op. cit., p. 312. Roger Garaudy,
Le Probleme Chinois (Paris: 10/18, n.d.), p. 86.
Mao (1928): SW, I, p. 66; 1935: ibid., p. 156;
478 SOCIALISM
1937: ibid., p. 265. 1939: ibid., Ill, pp. 88 and
220. "On Coalition Government": SW, IV, p.
294. On Tientsin, see M. Y. Wang, "The Stalinis
State in China," New International Vol. XVII, No.
2 (March-April, 1951), p. 101. Leon Trotsky,
"Peasant War in China," translation in Bulletin of
Marxist Studies (New York: Socialist Worker
Party, 1957), p. 15.
3. On cooperatives in 1952: Richard Lowenthal, "De
velopment versus Utopia in Communist policy,* 1
Chapter XI
p. 7.
Chapter XII
Chapter XIII
*** SOCIALISM
Accelerated Development: Report of the Commit- 1
tee for Development Planning (New York:
United]
Nations, 1970), p. 1. Birth control research: Part-
ners in Development, p. 199. NICB estimate:
San- J
ford Rose, "The Rewarding Strategies of
Multi- \
Nationalism," Fortune (September 15, 1958). Ibid.,
p. 101. World GNPs: War Peace Report (October, 1
1968), p. 5. Rumanian transaction and the "take-
]
out" tactic: "The Rewarding Strategies," 101. p.
Ambassador George W. Ball, "Making World I
Corporations into World Citizens," War Peace Re-
\
port (October, 1968), p. 10. Jean-Jacques
Servan-
Schreiber, The American Challenge, trans. Ronald 1
Steel (New York: Atheneum, 1968).
7. Toward a Democratic Left, Chapter IX. Marshall Plan!
and oil: Gunnar Myrdal, Challenge to World
\
Poverty, p. 337. World Bank, 1956-1957: May I
Day Manifesto, pp. 78-79. Lima meeting: The 1
Economist (May 22, 1971), p. 92. Nixon aid mes- 1
sage: The New York Times (April 22, 1971). I
Jerome Levinson and Juan de Onis, The Alliance I
that Lost Its Way (Chicago: Quadrangle Books, I
1970), p. 159. World Bank and oil: Tanzer, The 1
Political Economy of Oil, p. 27. Thomas Balogh, I
The Economics of Poverty (London: Macmillan, 1
1966), p. 29. Copenhagen Meeting: The Wall
\
Chapter XIV
1. Sidney Hook, Towards the Understanding of Karl Marx
(New York: The John Day Company, 1933), p.
14. Stanley Moore, "Utopian Themes in Marx and
Mao," Monthly Review (June, 1969).
2. Owen: G. D. H. Cole, History of Socialist Thought,
Vol. I, p. 94. Keynes, Essays in Persuasion (New
York: W. W. Norton and Company, 1963), p. vii.
Crosland, The Future of Socialism (London: Jona-
than Cape, 1956), p. 417. Kenneth Boulding, "Is
Scarcity Dead?" The Public Interest (Fall, 1966).
Richard Nixon, "Message on the Environment,"
The New York Times (February 11, 1970). Robert
Heilbroner, Between Capitalism and Socialism, pp.
280 and 284, n. 1. John J. Wells, "Will the Earth
Reach an Energy Ceiling?" The Wall Street Journal
(January 6, 1971). Fuller, The New York Times
(March 27, 1971).
3. Marx on consumption under capitalism: MEW, XXVI,
Pt. 1 (Theorien iiber den Mehrwert, I) pp. 145-
146; MEW, XXV(Das Kapital III), p. 310. Weber
and Veblen: S. M. Lipset, Revolution and Counter-
Revolution (New York: Anchor Books, 1970),
p. 171.
4. Marx on the middle class: MEW, XXVI, Pt. 2, p. 576.
Kautsky, Bernstein und das sozialdemokratische
Programm (Stuttgart: Dietz Verlag, 1899), pp.
129 ff. Bad Godesberg Congress: Protokoll (Bonn:
SPD, n.d. [1959]), p. 29. Herbert Marcuse, One
Dimensional Man (Boston: Beacon Press, 1964),
p. 256.
5. 1965 work force: Manpower Report of the President,
490 SOCIALISM
7969 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing
Office, 1969), Table E-8, p.235. Department of
Labor, U.S. Manpower in the 1970s (Washington,
D.C.: Government Printing Office, n.d. [1970]).
"Moderate Standard": Rudolph Oswald, The
Federationist (February, 1969). Labor and 1968
elections: Theodore H. White, The Making of the
President, 1968, p. 365. Marx on affluence: MEW,
VI, p. 402. Rossow Report: Michael Harrington,
"Don't Form a Fourth Party," The New York
Times Magazine (September 13, 1970). John H.
Goldthorpe, David Lockwood, Frank Bechhofer,
and Jennifer Piatt, The Affluent Worker in the Class
Structure (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1969), passim and pp. 162, 190. Australia: G. D. H.
Cole, History of Socialist Thought, Vol. Ill, Pt.
2, Chap. XXIII, and Vol. IV, Pt. 2, Chap. XXVIII.
Michigan survey: Washington Report (April 12,
1971). Daniel Bell, "The Corporation and Society
in the 1970s," The Public Interest (Summer, 1971),
p. 31. AFL-CIO: Executive Council statement
(August 17, 1971, mimeo). C. A. R. Crosland,
"A Social Democratic Britain," Fabian Tract 404,
London, 1971, p. 8.
6. 1980 Labor market: United States Manpower Report
Thorstein Veblen, The Engineers and the Price
System (New York: The Viking Press, 1933), pp.
28 and 69. Serge Mallet, La Nouvelle Classe
Ouvriere (Paris: Seuil, 1969), pp. 16-17. Alain
Touraine, he Mouvemente de Mai ou le Com"
munisme Utopique (Paris: Seuil, 1968), pp. 162-
168. CFDT: Le Monde (May 10-11, 1970);
UExpress (May 18-24, 1970). John Kenneth
Galbraith, The New Industrial State (Boston:
Houghton Mifflin, 1967). Daniel Bell, "Notes on
Post-Industrial Society," The Public Interest (Win-
ter, 1967), p. 27. Sweden: Vorwarts (Bonn)
(February 25, 1971).
7. Kenneth Kenniston, Young Radicals: Notes on Con-
temporary Youth, pp. 263-264. Bruno Bettelheim,
"Obsolete Youth," Encounter (September, 1969).
"A Talk with Walter Lippmann," The New York
Notes 491
494 Index
AFL (continued) modernization of, 266j
153, 157, 158, 159, 161, 397
306, 309-311, 313, 315, population control, 403
J
324, 325, 436 tariffs, and, 401
to immigrants,
hostility urban poor, 285
160 wages, 386
Labor's League for Polit- See also names of coun-l
ical Education, 324 tries; Third World
American Federation of La- Asian Drama: An Inquiry into
bor-Congress of Industrial the Poverty of Nations]
Organizations ( AFL-CIO ) (Myrdal), 300
322-327, 354, 355, 438- Asiatic mode of production,]
439 170
protectionist position of, Atlantic Monthly, 145
398 Atomic Energy Commission,!
American Federation of 426
Teachers, 441 Attlee, Clement, 6, 229, 246,^
American United Automobile 373
Workers, 400 Augustine, Saint, 16
Amin, Samir, 287 Australia, 168, 268, 269, 436
j
228 Austria
Anabaptists, 18, 24, 25, 32 bourgeoisie, 53
Anarchists, 80 Marxism, 243
Antt-DUhring (Engels), 81, 87 nationalizations, 241, 243 I
Anti-socialist socialism, 5, 23, socialism, 243, 248
52 Austria-Hungary, 76, 228
Bismarck, 5, 7, 66, 76, Austrian social democrats, 86;
78-83 Automation, 445
origins of, 77-83 Marx on, 119
Russia, 186, 187 Avineri, Shlomo, 30
Appeal to Reason, 307
Arab Communism, 296-298 Babeuf, Gracchus, 3, 25, 26-
Arab socialism, 296-298 27, 28
Arab Socialist Union, 296 Babouvists, 26-27, 28
Arabs, 6, 183 Bakdash, Khalid, 297
Arendt, Hannah, 215 Bakunin, Mikhail, 66, 73-74,
Argentina, 175-176, 404 75, 80, 83, 172, 285-286
See also Latin America; debate with Marx, 73, 75
Third World lumpenproletarian social-
Aristocratic utopianism, 16- ism and, 73
17 Ball, George W., 404-405
Aron, Raymond, 432 Balogh, Thomas, 257, 408
Ascetic communism, 13 Bank of England, 241, 259
Asia, 164, 165, 166, 167, 170, Baran, Paul, 277-278
263-264, 268, 269, 285 Bartering, 112
democracy, 411-412 Baruch, Bernard, 317
exploitation of, 379-380 Bauer, Otto, 243, 254
investment in, 386-387 Bebel, August, 82, 87, 89, 212
Index 495
Belcian Congo, 178, 182-184, Bolivia, 408
227 See also Latin America;
Belgian Workers' Party, 183 Third World
Belgium. 178, 227, 233, 404 Bolshevik Party, 207, 223,
colonialism, 178, 182-184 224
imports. 384 Bolsheviks, 187, 188, 193, 199,
Bell, Daniel, 47-48, 93, 308, 200, 207, 217, 222-224
437-442 Bonaparte, Jerome, 70
Belmont. August, 151 Boorstein, Edward, 290
Berger, Victor, 310 Born, Stephen, 55
Berle, A. A., 321, 364 Boudin, Louis, 82
Bernstein, Eduard, 81-82, 87, Boulding. Kenneth, 424-426,
173, 177-179, 231 427. 429
Bernstein, Irving, 312 Bourgeois democracy, 54-55,
Berry, George L., 316 56
Bethlehem Steel Corporation, Borgeoisie, 29-30, 52, 53, 228
366 Austria, 53
Bettelheim, Bruno, 444 China, 271, 275
Bettelheim. Charles. 224 Engels on, 79, 430
Better Fewer, But Better (Le- England, 52, 54, 179-180
nin), 201, 203 France, 54—55
Bevan, Aneurin, 300, 301. 303 Germany, 55, 56-57, 68,
Bismarck, Otto von, 86, 147, 78-79, 191
190, 208, 212 Italv, 53, 191
as an anti-socialist social- Marx on, 56-57, 430
ist, 5, 7. 66, 76, 78-83 Russia, 190-193, 206,
bureaucratic capitalism, 224-225
82 Brabant, 19
welfare programs, 80 Brahmins, 13
Black, Hugo. 313 Brandt, Willy, 249, 254-255
Blacks, 183-184 coffee,394-395
education, 444 exports, 394-395
unrest of, 432. 435 urban poor, 286
Blanc, Louis. 43, 80. 322. 371 See also Latin America;
Blanqui, Auguste, 3, 43-45, Third World
59, 60, 73, 75, 83. 198 British India. 384
Engels on, 44-45 British Miners' Union, 243
on proletarians, 43—44 British Steel Corporation, 246
on suffrage. 44 Brooks, Thomas, 151-152
Blanquists, 43, 58, 61, 69, 70, Brophy, John, 316
197, 209 Brothers and Sisters of the
Bloch. Ernst, 15, 18 Free Spirit, 20
Blue-collar labor, 432-433, Browder, Earl, 319
435 Brown, George, 258
Blum, Leon, 229, 238-239, Brzezinski, Zbigniew, 8, 209,
258, 440 411
Boer Republic, 176 Buddha, 13
Boer War, 176 Bukharin, Nikolai, 82, 207,
Bohemia, 20, 21 223-224
496 Index
Buonarrotti, Filippo Michele, inefficiency and assimila-
25, 27-28 tive power of, 90
Bureaucratic capitalism, 79- intellectual life and, 37
82 as an irrelevance for man-
Bureaucratic collectivism, 7, 9, kind, 379
188, 205, 209-216, 220- labor under, 98
225, 277, 377 length of working day
Burke, Edmund, 188 and, 71
Lenin on, 164, 184-185,
206
Canada, 168, 269
Capital
Marx on, 7, 53-54, 91-
129, 163-166, 167-169,
centralization of, 105
174,185,190-191,206,
constant, 113-114
208,211,235,344,381-
export of, 383, 386, 387
382, 428
finance, 383
law of motion of, 116-
organic composition of,
129
121
nationalizations and, 240-
ownership of, 114
248
production of, 110-112
neo-, 47, 335-356, 439,
surplus, 383, 388
451
as a symbol of value,
overestimation of, 53
108-109
planning under, 344—348
technical composition of,
reform of, 7-8
121
rise of, 23
two meanings of, 110
Russia, 189-190, 205-
as unproductive, 109-112
207
Capitalism, 1-4, 12, 18, 131-
socialist, 227-261
161
structural changes in, 85
atomization, 37, 39
as a transitory system,
automation and, 445
106
bureaucratic, 79-82
U.S., 305, 313, 321, 333-
change after World War
376
II, 384
utopianism and, 19
China, 271
waste of, 31
commodities and, 106-
the welfare state and,
116
331-376
early, characteristics of,
the world market and,
333
332, 377-419
emergence of, 22, 23
as the basis of produc-
Engels on, 7, 53-54, 85,
tion, 380
91-129, 154, 164-165,
Engels on, 379-380,
174, 179-181, 190- 381-382
191 ?n< ^-236,254, intracapitalist invest-
344, 381-382 ment, 384-386
England, 246-248 major development
France, 30-31, 239, 245 after World War n,
Germany, 234-236 384
imperialism and, 382-383 Marx on, 380
Index 497
Capitalism (continued) landlords,275
neo-colonial invest- ownership, 416
ment, 387 peasants.273-281, 415,
in perpetuating eco- 416, 434
nomic backwardness, surplus and, 278
389-395 People's Liberation Army,
in perpetuating pover- 282
389-395
ty, poverty, 280, 377
planning, 406-411 the proletariat, 272
restructuring of, 396- Red Guards, 282
406 strikes, 282
World War and, 228
I totalitarianism, 279, 283,
Carpenters* Union, 135 415
Carr, E. H., 55-56, 165, 173, Utopias, 14
193, 199, 206, 231 welfare state, 14
Castro, Fidel, 176, 288-293 Chinese Revolution, 270-272
Chad, 412 compared to Russian
See also Africa; Third Revolution, 272-273
World Christian democrats, 254, 255
Challenge of World Poverty, Christian Federation of Labor,
The (Myrdal), 300, 302 440
Charter of Algiers, 402 Christianity, 13-14
Chartism, 49, 52, 58, 69, 71 En^k on. 1 5
Chauvey, Daniel (pseudonym), revolutionary creed, 15
294-295 See also Protestantism;
Chernyshevsky, Nikolai Gav- Roman Catholic Church
rilovich, 203 CUy of God (Saint Augustine),
Chiang Kai-shek, 271, 272, 16
390, 414 Civil War in France (Marx),
Chicago Federation of Labor, 197
152 Claflin, Tennessee, 140
Chile, 6, 408 Class Struggles in France
See also Latin America; (Marx), 58
Third World Clayton Act, 151
China, 4, 6, 14, 169. 172, 203, Cleaver, Eldridge, 286
225,263,270-272,299,384, Co-determination principle,
388 245
bourgeoisie, 271, 275 Coffee, 394-395
capitalism, 271 Cole, G. D. H., 43, 51, 52-
collectivization, 277-278, 53, 233-234, 240
377 Collectivization
Communism, 218, 271- China, 277-278, 377
284, 415 Cuba, 377
Cultural Revolution, 281- Egypt, 377
283, 289 future of, 2-3
Great Leap, 12, 280, 281, Russia, 7, 9, 188, 205,
295 209-216,220-225,277,
Japanese invasion (1937), 377
271 U.S., 436-437
498 Index
Colonialism, 163-186, 227, Italy. 61, 214. 315
380 Marx on, 41, 49, 50, 52,
Belgium, 178, 182-184 211, 452
cost of, 180-181 Peru, 296
Engels on, 174, 179-181 Russia, 187-190, 200,
England, 167, 168, 180, 205-225, 274, 279, 415
301 socialism corrupted by,
France, 266, 286-287 187-188
Germany, 180 Sudan, 296, 297-298
Lenin on, 164, 179, 180- Syria, 296, 297
181, 184-185 Third World, 219, 272-
Marx on, 167, 168, 174, 284, 291-298, 414-419
179, 180, 301 totalitarianism and, 82,
U.S., 180, 390 195,205,210-216,332,
Colorado Labor War, 144 379
Commodities U.S., 308, 310, 314, 317-
capitalism and, 106-116 320
cost of, 454 Communist International, 274,
demand for, 125-127 318, 319
Engels on, 106-116 Communist League, 55, 58,
as an exchange value, 61, 67
106-107, 112-113 Communist Manifesto, The
free, 454-^55 (Marx and Engels), 43, 48,
labor as,116 49, 51, 52, 53, 54, 55-56,
Marx on, 106-116, 125- 62, 68, 69, 72, 84, 169-170,
127 185, 220, 227, 229,230,256
production of, 106-116 on the bourgeoisie, 430
supply of, 125-127 on capitalism, 53-54, 164
as a use value, 106-107, on centralized state credit,
112-113 78
Commons, John R., 155 four types of society in,
Communism, 2, 4, 5, 8, 9, 20- 169-170
22, 422 Lassalle and, 78-79
aim of, 46—47 on wages, 78
Arab, 296-298 Communist Party (China),
ascetic, 13 271-272, 284
China, 218, 271-284,415 Communist Party (Germany),
compared to fascism, 214 231-233
Cuba, 291-293 Communist Party (Italy), 61,
Egypt, 296, 297 214
Engels on, 49, 50-51,452 Communist Party (Russia), 217
England, 52, 58 Communist Party (U.S.), 317-
France, 47, 52, 335 320
freedom movement Communitarian socialism, 136
under, 219-221 Conference for Progressive
Germany, 52, 55, 230- Political Action, 143, 152-
234 153, 311
Iraq, 296 Congregationalists, 25
Index 499
Congress of Industrial Organi- See also Latin America;
zations (CIO), 314, 316, Third World
320, 324-325, 436 Cultural Revolution, 281-283,
Political Action Commit- 289
tee, 324 Czechoslovakia, 8, 204, 219-
Congress of the Socialist In- 220, 284
ternational, 89, 399
Connally, John, 325
Dahrendorf, Ralf, 108, 245
Conquest, Robert, 209
Daley, Richard, 325
Constant capital, 113-114
Darwin, Charles, 87
Constantine, Emperor, 15
Das Kapital (Marx and Engels),
Consumers' cooperatives, 77
47, 48, 49, 72, 74, 85, 91-
Consumption
129, 166, 270
abstinence from, 114
alienation idea in, 48
attitudes under socialism,
basic paradox of, 93
425-^26, 428, 454-456
on capitalism, 91-129,
depressions and, 119-120
165, 190
disparity between pro-
on commodities, 106-116
duction and, 119-120,
contemporary critics of,
124
4-5
Cooperatives
consumers', 77
on global abundance,
producers', 77, 80
423^24
simplifications in, 103
Council of Economic Advi-
on socialized man, 91-
sors, 338-339, 365
129
Credit, centralized state, 78
structure of,102-104
Credit associations, 77
on wealth, 91, 93, 129
Credit Mobilier, 5
on the world market, 380
Critique of the Gotha Program
David, 178
(Marx), 92, 211
Critique of Political Economy De Castro, Josue, 264
(Marx), 102
De Gaulle, Charles, 241
Cromwell, Oliver, 24, 273
De Leon, Daniel, 149
Crosland, Anthony, 249, 250-
De Man, Henri, 239-240
Deat, Marcel, 240
251, 257, 424, 438
<7< Debray, Regis, 299
Cuk'i. fs
265, 288-293,
Debs, Eugene Victor, 131, 152,
295, 299, 415
307-311, 320
agriculture,290-291
12,
Debsian socialism, 143, 150,
377
collectivization,
307-311, 314
Communism, 291-293
Debsian Socialist Party, 150
housing, 292
Decline of Socialism in Amer*
militarization of work,
ica The (Weinstein), 310
f
291
Deist, Heinrich, 253, 254
poverty, 377
Russia compared to, 292- Democracy
293 anti-democratic bureau-
socialism, 288-290 cracies and, 90
sugar harvest (1970), 12 bourgeois, 54-55, 56
unemployment, 290-291 as the essence of social-
500 Index
516 Index
Russia (continued) Schapper, 61
Marxism, 56, 67-68, 195- Scheidemann, Philipp, 231,
197, 273-274 232, 233
Mensheviks, 198 Schiller, Karl, 255
New Economic Policy, Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr,
201 315-316, 321
peasants, 67-68, 171-173, Schonfield, Andrew, 259, 3
189-190, 192-193, Schorr, Alvin, 337
200-201,207-210,217, Schulze-Delitzsch, Heim
231, 280-281 77
personal privileges in, Schumpeter, Joseph, 141—
212-213, 218-219 227
poverty, 377 Schwartz, Benjamin, 272
the proletariat, 191-192, Schweitzer, Johann Baptist
196, 197, 209 von, 79, 81
purges, 209, 216 Science, 1-2, 35-37
the rising at Kronstadt, as an element in the la-
Communism. (
2 >6, 297 Theses <>n Feuerbach (Marx),
See also Asia; Third 45-46
World Third World, 5, 7, 8, 22, 25,
34, 41. 129, 163-187, 204,
225, 263-304, 332
Taborites. 21
agriculture, 12, 290-91,
Taft-Hartley Law, 324
393-395, 400-403,
Taft, Phillip. 133, 152, 153
415-417, 447-448
Taft. Robert A., 338
collectivization, 277-278,
Taiwan, 398.
377
Gross National Product,
Communism, 219, 272-
386
284, 291-298, 414-419
investment in, 385
democracy, 411-418
nationalizations. 413-414
economic levels, 264
U.S. aid to. 390
exports, 385
See also Asia; Third foreign aid, 390-393, 406,
World 410, 413
Tariffs. 85, 397, 401 housing, 292
Kennedy on, 391 investments in, 384-395,
Third World and, 397, 403-408
401 Marxism, 398
U.S., 391, 395, 401 modernization of, 397
520 Index
Third World (continued) on peasants, 273
nationalizations, 296, on students, 444-443
393-394, 413-414 Trotskyists, 207,
210-211
peasants, 270, 272-281, Truman, Harry 407S, 338,
296, 415-416, 434 Tucker, Robert C. 72
planning, 406-411 Tugwell, Rexford G., 321
population control, 403, Tunisia, 287
427-428 See also Third World
poverty, 280, 377, 389- Turkey, 384
395, 418 Twentieth Party Congress
research needs, 402-^03 278
socialism, 269-270, 288- Tyler, Wat, 20
290, 298-299, 418-419
lumpen proletarian, Unemployment
285-288 automation, 445
preconditions for, 377- Cuba, 290-291
378 U.S., 152, 155, 321, 354
surplus, 96, 277-278, 412 355
tariffsand, 397, 401 Unions, 69-73
technology, 424-425 England, 32-33, 69-7C
urban poor, 270, 284-288 243, 400
wealth, 412-413 France, 440
Thomas, Norman, 308, 313- gradualism movement, 83
314, 320 revolution and, 65-66
Tinbergen, Jan, 399 U.S., 8, 135, 139-14C
Titmus, Richard, 257, 259 141, 143, 145-159,
Totalitarian utopianism, 12 305-329, 398-399,
Totalitarianism, 4, 41, 47, 49, 432-441
61 world industrializatioi
China, 279, 283, 415 and, 397-400
of Communism, 82, 195, See also Labor; names
205, 210-216, 332, 379 unions
Marx as the father of, 56 United Automobile Worker
Russia, 195, 205, 210- 323, 325
219, 222-225 United Mine Workers, 399
Stalin, 209-216 United Nations, 406, 409
surplus extraction, 96 Committee for Develop
Touraine, Alain, 440 ment Planning, 410
Toward a Democratic Left United Nations' Conferenc
(Harrington), 354, 383, 390, on Trade and Development
406 (UNCTAD), 267
Towards the Understanding of United States of America, 69,
Karl Marx (Hook), 58 82, 131-161, 168, 182, 196,
Trades Union Congress, 149, 197, 259, 268, 269, 277,
400 306-307, 312-321, 365
Trotsky, Leon, 57, 61, 191, affluence, 131-132, 154,
193-194, 201, 204, 207, 350, 435, 445, 449
222, 223, 276, 452-453 agriculture, 96, 339-340,
on Germany, 230 342, 360
Index 521
U.S.A. (continued) land pollution, 350
air pollution,350-352 liberalism, 248, 256, 310
automobiles, 350-352 lunar program, 427
capitalism, 305, 313, 321, Marxism, 140-141, 146-
333-376 151, 308
the Civil War, 137 migration in, 312
collectivism, 436—437 National Guard, 145
colonialism, 180, 390 nationalizations, 367
communal living in, 429 neo-capitalism, 335-356,
Communism, 308, 310— 439, 451
314, 317-320 New Deal, 317, 319, 320,
Conference on Progres- 321, 371, 398
sive Political Action, ownership, 363-371, 376
311 in perpetuating economic
Democratic Party, 151, backwardness, 389-
311-313, 325-328 395
democratization of power in perpetuating poverty,
in, 431 389-395
education, 340-342, 355- poverty, 325, 336-342,
356,360-361,435,441, 433, 438
443_446, 449 the proletariat, 432-^440
exports, 387 racism, 325, 337, 341,
of jobs. 398 406, 432
foreign aid, 390-393, 406, railroads, 340
410, 413 recession of 1970-1971,
free-land movement, 446
137-139 Republican Party, 343
gold discovered in Cali- sectarianism, 140, 147-
fornia. 60 150, 308
Green Corn Rebellion, sharecropping system, 96
309 social democracy in, 133,
healthcare, 355, 361,449, 135-138, 143-144, 157,
455 160-161, 178,228-229,
housing. 335-339, 342, 305-329
345-346, 353, 358-359 Engels on, 136, 306
immigrants, 147-148, Marx on, 135-137, 306
155-161, 308-309, rise of, 65-67
312-313 social mobility, 341
AFL's hostility to, 160 Social Security, 323, 325
imperialism, 390-395 socialism, 131-161, 305-
imports, 385, 389, 394- 321,326-327,328,333,
395, 401 344-348
income in, 373-374 attitude toward, 131-
inflation, 433 132
investments, 387, 390- standard of living in, 154-
391, 392-393, 403-407 158, 159, 428, 453
Jews, 310 strikes, 141, 144-145,
lack of feudalism in, 133, 147, 152, 309,315,432
136 suffrage, 155
522 Index
U.S.A. (continued) U.S., 285
tariffs,391, 395, 401 Urban Problems Commission,
taxes, 146, 336, 339-340, 339
350, 372-376 Use value, 106-107, 113
technology, 159-160 Usury, 112
trade policies, 390-395 Utopia (More), 24
transportation, 340, 350- Utopianism, 11-40, 43, 163,
352, 358-359 447
unemployment, 152, 155, aristocratic, 16-17
321, 354, 355 beginning 11 of,
unions, 8, 135, 139-140, capitalism and, 19
141, 143, 145-159, China, 14
305-329, 398-399, England, 23-26, 32
432-441 France, 23, 26-31
urban poor, 285 Greece, 11, 14, 15-16,
utopianism, 132-142, 17-18
145, 305, 308 Jews, 11-15
Vietnam War, 266, 328, 16th-19th century, 23-33
338, 388, 445 12
totalitarian,
violence in, 144-145, 12th-16th century, 18-23
337-339, 451 U.S., 132-142, 145, 305,
voluntarism, 150-151, 308
306, 322, 324
wage-price freeze, 438 Valdes, Gabriel, 392
wages, 155-156, 160,437, Value
438^*39 capital as a symbol of,
water pollution, 350 108-109
wealth, 372-373, 438 commodity exchange,
welfare state, 332-376 106-107, 112-113
welfare system, 339 gold as a symbol of, 108-
working day, 450-451 110
World War I, 309 labor as an increment in,
World War H, 318, 321 114
youth discontent, 432, 443 labor theory of, 98-99,
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statis- 100, 105
tics, 433 land as a symbol of, 108-
U.S. Department of Labor, 109
433, 439 of natural resources, 92
U.S. Internal Revenue Service, silver as a symbo! of,
373 108-110
U.S. Develop-
International surplus, 113
ment Institute, 409 absolute, 117
U.S. Post Office, 369, 371 relative, 117, 124
University of Michigan Re- use, 106-107, 113
search Center, 437 Van Kol, 178-179
Urban Land Institute, 350 Vandervelde, fimile, 183, 184,
Urban poor, 270, 284-288 185
Third World, 270, 284- Varga, Yevgeny Samoylovich,
288 190, 195,211-212,218,388
Index 523
Mr./Mrs./Miss-
(please print)
Add ress
City ,
State Zip
Do you know someone who enjoys books? Just give us their
names and addresses and we'll send them a FREE CATALOG
tool
Mr./Mrs./Mlss-
Address
City State Zip_
Mr./Mrs./Miss_
Address
City State Zip
FC—3/73
Mi i iiiiiwn
AMER CA'S FOREMOST SOCIALIST, SORVEYS,
CHRONICLES AND EXPLAINS THE MOVEMENT!
From pre- 19th-century visions of Utopia to the humane and
realistic construction of a program for man's future.
Iffl
"Mr. Harrington has produced a climactic work... He has.,
made our politics seem viable once more, and our collective
future like something worth living for."
—Christopher Lehmann-Haupt, The New York Time
"A most powerful, sophisticated and comprehensive treatment
... A persuasive contemporary restatement of some old truths."
—Saturday Reviet
"Everyone owes himself a week with Socialism. It is informed
and well written and invites interest as well as belief/'
—John Kenneth Galbraiii
1
i I