Solving The Present Crisis and Managing The Leverage Cycle: John Geanakoplos
Solving The Present Crisis and Managing The Leverage Cycle: John Geanakoplos
Solving The Present Crisis and Managing The Leverage Cycle: John Geanakoplos
John Geanakoplos is the James Tobin Professor of Economics at Yale On October 3, 2008, the author presented to Ben Bernanke and the Federal
University, an external professor at the Santa Fe Institute, and a partner in Reserve Board of Governors the substance of this paper’s proposal. The author
Ellington Capital Management, which trades primarily in mortgage securities. is grateful to Susan Koniak for very helpful and detailed comments and advice,
[email protected] as well as for allowing him to use material from their two New York Times
editorials. He is also appreciative of the very fine comments received from
Asani Sarkar and two referees, and is deeply indebted to Joseph Tracy for
editorial advice far beyond the call of duty, encompassing tone, style, and
content. Needless to say, neither he nor anyone else is responsible for, or even
necessarily in agreement with, the views expressed here. The views expressed
are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.
102 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
collateral can be used over and over to back loans backed by Natural Buyers Theory of Price
loans).
Practitioners, if not economists, have long recognized the
importance of collateral and leverage. For a Wall Street trader, Natural buyers
leverage is important for two reasons. The first is that if he is
leveraged λ times, then a 1 percent change in the value of the Marginal buyer
collateral means a λ percent change in the value of his capital.
(If the house in our example goes from $100 to $101, then after
selling the house at $101 and repaying the $80 loan, the investor Public
is left with $21 of cash on his $20 investment, a 5 percent return.)
Leverage thus makes returns riskier, either for better or for
worse. Second, a borrower knows that if there is no-recourse
collateral, so that he can walk away from his loan after giving up
the collateral without further penalty, then his downside is
limited. The most the borrower can lose on the house loan is his marginal buyer is the agent at the threshold on the cusp of
$20 of cash, even if the house falls in value all the way to $0 and selling or buying and it is his opinion that determines the price.
the lender loses $80. No-recourse collateral thus effectively gives The higher the leverage, the smaller the number of buyers at the
the borrower a put option (to “sell” the house for the loan top required to purchase all the available assets. As a result, the
amount). Recently, several commentators have linked leverage marginal buyer will be higher in the continuum and therefore
to the crisis, arguing that if banks were not so leveraged in their the price will be higher.
borrowing they would not have lost so much money when prices It is well known that a reduction in interest rates will
went down, and that if homeowners were not so leveraged, they increase the prices of assets such as houses. It is less
would not be so far underwater now and so tempted to exercise appreciated, but more obviously true, that a reduction in
their put option by walking away from their house. Of course, margins will raise asset prices. Conversely, if margins go up,
these two points are central to my own leverage cycle theory; I asset prices will fall. A potential homeowner who in 2006 could
discuss them in more detail later. But there is another, deeper buy a house by putting 3 percent cash down might find it
point to my theory that has so far not received as much attention, unaffordable to buy now that he has to put 30 percent cash
which I think is the real story of leverage. down, even if the Fed managed to reduce mortgage interest
The main implication of my leverage cycle theory is that rates by 1 percent or 2 percent. This has diminished the
when leverage goes up, asset prices go up, and when leverage demand for housing, and therefore housing prices. What
goes down, asset prices go down.4 For many assets, there is a applies to housing applies much more to the esoteric assets
class of natural buyers or optimists who are willing to pay much traded on Wall Street (such as mortgage-backed investments),
more for the asset than the rest of the public. They may be more where the margins (that is, leverage) can vary much more
risk-tolerant. Or they may simply be more optimistic. Or they radically. In 2006, the $2.5 trillion of so-called toxic mortgage
may like the collateral (for example, housing) more.5 If they securities could be bought by putting $150 billion down and
can get their hands on more money through borrowing, they borrowing the other $2.35 trillion.6 In early 2009, those same
will spend it on the assets and drive those asset prices up. If they securities might collectively have been worth half as much, yet
lose wealth, or lose the ability to borrow, they will be able to buy a buyer might have had to put nearly the whole amount down
less of the asset, and the asset will fall into more pessimistic in cash. In Section 3.1, I illustrate the connection between
hands and be valued less. leverage and asset prices over the current cycle.
Economists and the Federal Reserve ask themselves every
It is useful to think of the potential investors arrayed on a
vertical continuum, in descending order according to their day whether the economy is picking the right interest rates. But
willingness to buy, with the most enthusiastic buyers at the top one can also ask the question whether the economy is picking
(see exhibit). Whatever the price, those at the top of the the right equilibrium margins. At both ends of the leverage
continuum above a threshold will value the asset more and cycle, it does not. In ebullient times, the equilibrium collateral
become buyers, while those below will value it less and sell. The rate is too loose; that is, equilibrium leverage is too high. In bad
times, equilibrium leverage is too low. As a result, in ebullient
4
Leverage is like more money in making prices go up, but, unlike money, it times asset prices are too high, and in crisis times they plummet
affects only prices of goods that can serve as collateral; printing more money
too low. This is the leverage cycle.
tends to increase all prices, including those of food and other perishables.
5 6
Two additional sources of heterogeneity are that some investors are more This number is calculated by applying the bank regulatory capital
expert at hedging assets, and that some investors can more easily obtain the requirement (based on bond credit rating) to each security in 2006 at its
information (like loan-level data) and expertise needed to evaluate the assets. 2006 credit rating.
104 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
ago. In The Merchant of Venice, Shakespeare depicted 2.1 Investor Heterogeneity, Equilibrium
accurately how lending works: one has to negotiate not just an Leverage, Default, and Maturity
interest rate but the collateral level too. And it is clear which of
the two Shakespeare thought was the more important. Who Without heterogeneity among investors, there would be no
can remember the interest rate Shylock charged Antonio? But borrowers and lenders, and asset prices would not depend on
everybody remembers the “pound of flesh” that Shylock and the amount of leverage in the economy. It is interesting to
Antonio agreed on as collateral. The upshot of the play, observe that the kind of heterogeneity influences the amount of
moreover, is that the regulatory authority (the court) equilibrium leverage, and hence equilibrium asset prices, and
intervenes and decrees a new collateral level—very different equilibrium default.
from what Shylock and Antonio had freely contracted— When investors differ only in their optimism about future
“a pound of flesh, but not a drop of blood.” The Fed, too, could events in a one-dimensional manner, then the equilibrium
sometimes decree different collateral levels (before the fact, not leverage will consist of the maximum promise that does not
after, as in Shakespeare). permit default.8 For example, suppose an asset will be worth
The modern study of collateral seems to have begun with either 1 or .2 next period. Suppose further that risk-neutral
Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist investors differ only in the probability h that they assign to the
(1996, 1999), Holmstrom and Tirole (1997), Geanakoplos outcome being 1. The most optimistic investor h = 1 is sure that
(1997, 2003), and Geanakoplos and Zame (2009).7 Bernanke, the asset will be worth 1, and the most pessimistic investor h = 0
Gertler, and Gilchrist and Holmstrom and Tirole emphasize is sure the asset will be worth .2. At any asset price p, the
the asymmetric information between borrowers and lenders as investors with h big enough that h*1 + (1-h)*(.2) > p will want
the source of limits on borrowing. For example, Holmstrom to buy the asset, while the rest will want to sell the asset. The
and Tirole argue that the managers of a firm would not be able buyers with high h will want to borrow money in order to get
to borrow all the inputs necessary to build a project, because their hands on what they regard as cheap assets, while the
lenders would like to see them bear risk, by putting their own sellers with low h will not need the money and so will be willing
money down, to guarantee that they exert maximal effort. to lend. How much will the borrowers be able to promise using
Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and Geanakoplos (1997) study the the asset as collateral, assuming the promise is not contingent
case where the collateral is an asset such as a mortgage security, on the state? The answer is .2, precisely the maximum promise
where the buyer/borrower using the asset as collateral has no that does not lead to default in either state.9
role in managing the asset, and asymmetric information is Thus, when the heterogeneity stems entirely from one-
therefore not important. The key difference between Kiyotaki dimensional differences in opinion, equilibrium leverage
and Moore and Geanakoplos (1997) is that in Kiyotaki and entails no default. A consequence of this is that the loans will be
Moore, there is no uncertainty, and so the issue of leverage as a very short term. The longer the maturity of the loan, the more
ratio of loan to value does not play a central role; to the extent that can go wrong in the meantime, and therefore the smaller
it does vary, leverage in Kiyotaki and Moore goes in the wrong the loan amount can be if it avoids any chance of default.
direction, getting higher after bad news, and dampening the Investors who want to borrow large amounts of money will be
cycle. In Geanakoplos (1997, 2003), I introduce uncertainty driven to borrow very short term. The repo market displays
and solve for equilibrium leverage and equilibrium default these characteristics of short, one-day loans, on which there is
rates; I show how leverage could be determined by supply and almost never any default, even in the worst of crises.
demand, and how under some conditions, volatility (or more Much the same analysis holds when investors differ only in
precisely, the tail of the asset return distribution) pins down their risk aversion. For the most risk-averse investors, an asset
leverage. In Geanakoplos (2003), I introduce the leverage cycle that pays 1 or .2 will be regarded as too dangerous, while
in which changes in the volatility of news lead to changes in
leverage, which in turn lead to changes in asset prices. This line 8
See Geanakoplos (2003).
9
of research has been pursued by Gromb and Vayanos (2002), At first glance, it would seem that the most optimistic buyers might be willing
Fostel and Geanakoplos (2008), Brunnermeier and Pedersen to promise, say, .3 in both states, in order to get more money today to invest in
a sure winner of an asset. But since this promise will deliver .3 in the good state
(2009), and Adrian and Shin (forthcoming), among others. but only .2 in the bad state (assuming no-recourse collateral), the lenders will
not want to pay much for this debt: this risky debt is very much like the asset
they do not want to hold, and so they will pay very little more for it than the
7
Minsky (1986) was a modern pioneer in calling attention to the dangers of (.2,.2) promise, where (g,b) denotes a payoff of g if the good state occurs and b
leverage. But to the best of my knowledge, he did not provide a model or formal if the bad state occurs. Since the borrowers would have to give up .3 > .2 in the
theory. Tobin and Golub (1998) devote a few pages to leverage and the state they think is likely to occur, they will choose to use their scarce collateral
beginnings of a model. to back the (.2,.2) promise instead of the (.3,.3) promise.
The crisis stage of the leverage cycle always seems to unfold in 2.4 What Is So Bad about the Leverage Cycle?
the same way. First there is bad news. That news causes asset
prices to fall based on worse fundamentals. Those price The crisis stage is obviously bad for the economy. But the
declines create losses for the most optimistic buyers, precisely leverage that brings it on stimulates the economy in good
because they are typically the most leveraged. They are forced times. Why should we think the bad outweighs the good? After
to sell off assets to meet their margin restrictions, even when all, we are taught in conventional complete-markets economics
the margins stay the same. Those forced sales cause asset prices that the market decides best on these types of trade-offs. In
to fall further, which makes leveraged buyers lose more. Some Geanakoplos (2010), I discuss eight reasons why the leverage
of them go bankrupt. And then typically things shift: the loss cycle may nevertheless be bad for the economy. The first three
spiral seems to stabilize—a moment of calm in the hurricane’s are caused by the large debts and numerous bankruptcies that
eye. But that calm typically gives way when the bad news is the occur in big leverage cycles.
106 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
First, optimistic investors can impose an externality on the complete-markets price, because of the expectation by the
economy if they internalize only their private loss from a leveraged few that good times are coming, a huge wave of
bankruptcy in calculating how much leverage to take on. For overbuilding usually results. In the bad state, this overbuilding
example, managers of a firm calculate their own loss in profits needs to be dismantled at great cost and, more importantly, new
in the down states, but sometimes neglect to take into their building nearly stops. To make the point a bit more dramatically,
calculations the disruption to the lives of their workers when very high leverage means that the asset prices are set by a small
they are laid off in bankruptcy. If, in addition, the bankruptcy group of investors. If agent beliefs are heterogeneous, why
of one optimist makes it more likely in the short run that other should the prices be determined entirely by the highest outliers?
optimists (who are also ignoring externalities) will go In the current crisis, as I observed earlier, the $2.5 trillion of toxic
bankrupt, perhaps starting a chain of defaults, then the mortgage securities were purchased with about $150 billion in
externality can become so big that simply curtailing leverage cash and $2.35 trillion in loans. As of 2006, just two men, Warren
can make everybody better off. Buffet and Bill Gates, between them had almost enough money
Second, debt overhang destroys productivity, even before to purchase every single toxic mortgage security in the whole
bankruptcy, and even in cases when bankruptcy is ultimately country. Leverage allows the few to wield great influence on
avoided. Banks and homeowners and others who are prices and therefore on what is produced.12
underwater often forgo socially efficient and profitable Sixth, a large group of small businesspeople who cannot buy
activities. A homeowner who is underwater loses much of the insurance against downturns in the leverage cycle can easily sell
incentive to repair a house, even if the cost of the repairs is less loans to run their businesses or pay for their consumption in
than the gain in value to the house, since increases in the value good times at the height of the leverage cycle, but have a hard
of the house will not help him if he thinks he will likely be time at the bottom. Government policy may well have the goal of
foreclosed eventually anyway.10 protecting these people by smoothing out the leverage cycle.13
Third, seizing collateral often destroys a significant part of Seventh, the large fluctuations in asset prices over the
its value in the process. The average foreclosure of a subprime leverage cycle lead to massive redistributions of wealth and
loan leads to recovery of only 25 percent of the loan, after all changes in inequality. When leverage λ = 30, there can be wild
expenses and the destruction of the house are taken into swings in returns and losses. In the ebullient stage, the
account, as I discuss later. Auction sales of foreclosed houses optimists become rich as their bets pay off, while in the down
usually bring 30 percent less than comparable houses sold by states, they might go broke. Inequality becomes extreme in
their owners. both kinds of states.14
The next four reasons stem from the swings in asset prices The eighth problem with the leverage cycle is caused by the
that characterize leverage cycles. A key externality that inevitable government responses to the crisis stage. In an effort
borrowers and lenders in both the mortgage and repo markets to mitigate the crisis, the government often intervenes in
do not recognize is that if leverage were curtailed at the high inefficient ways. In the current crisis, the government is
end of the leverage cycle, prices would fall much less in the supporting the financial sector by holding the federal funds rate
crisis. Foreclosure losses would then be less, as would near zero. The government’s foreclosure prevention efforts
inefficiencies caused by agents being so far underwater. One have created financial subsidies for households that opt not to
might argue that foreclosure losses and underwater move, which can create inefficiencies in labor market
inefficiencies should be taken into account by a rational adjustment.15 Government bailouts, even if they were all for
borrower and lender and be internalized: it may be so the public good, cause resentment from those who are not
important to get the borrower the money, and the crisis might bailed out. The agents in the economy do not take into account
ex ante be so unlikely, that it is “second best” to go ahead with that by leveraging more and putting the economy at greater
the big leverage and bear the cost of the unlikely foreclosure.
11
But that overlooks the pecuniary externality: by going into See Tobin and Golub (1998).
12
foreclosure, a borrower lowers housing prices and makes it Standard economics does not really pay any attention to the case where
agents have different beliefs, and median beliefs are closer to the truth than
more likely that his neighbor will do the same. extreme outliers.
Fifth, asset prices can have a profound effect on economic 13
Here I rely on Tobin’s Q and the absence of insurance markets. The small
activity. As James Tobin argues with his concept of Q, when the businessmen cannot insure themselves against the crisis stage of the leverage
prices of old assets are high, new productive activity, which often cycle. In conventional complete-markets economics, they would be able to
buy insurance for any such event. Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis (1986)
involves issuing financial assets that are close substitutes for the offer a proof that when insurance markets are missing, there is almost always
old assets, is stimulated. When asset prices are low, new activity a government intervention in the existing markets that will make everyone
might grind to a halt.11 When asset prices are well above the better off.
14
This is a purely paternalistic reason for curtailing leverage.
10 15
See Myers (1977) and Gyourko and Saiz (2004). See Ferreira et al. (forthcoming).
Case-Shiller national
15 home price index (HPI) 120
3.1 Leverage and Prices (Right scale)
100
20
By now, it is obvious to everybody that asset prices soared from 2000 02 04 06 08 09
1999 (or at least after the disaster period that began September 11, Sources: First American CoreLogic LoanPerformance Data Base;
2001) to 2006, and then collapsed from 2007 to 2009. My thesis Ellington Capital Management.
is that this rise in prices was accompanied by drastic changes in Notes: The down payment axis has been reversed, because lower down
leverage, and was therefore just part of the 1999-2006 upswing payment requirements are correlated with higher home prices. For every
alt-A or subprime first-lien loan origination from 2000:1 to 2008:1, the
in the leverage cycle after the crisis stage in 1997-98 at the end down payment percentage was calculated as appraised value (or sale price,
of the last leverage cycle. I do not dispute that irrational if available) minus total mortgage debt, divided by appraised value. For
each quarter, the down payment percentages were ranked from highest
exuberance and then panic played a role in the evolution of to lowest, and the average of the bottom half is shown. This number is
prices over this period, but I suggest that they may not be as an indicator of the down payment required; clearly, many homeowners
important as leverage; certainly, it is harder to regulate animal put down more than they had to, which is why the top half is dropped
from the average. A 13 percent down payment in 2000:1 corresponds
spirits than it is leverage. to leverage of about 7.7, and a 2.7 percent down payment in 2006:2
Let us begin with the housing bubble, famously documented corresponds to leverage of about 37. Subprime/alt-A issuance ended
by Robert Shiller. In Chart 1, I display the Case-Shiller national in 2008:1.
108 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
Chart 2 Chart 3
Securities Leverage Cycle VIX Index
Margins Offered and AAA-Rated Securities Prices
110 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
Chart 6
ABX Index
ABX-HE:
AAA 06-1 AA 06-1 A 06-1 BBB 06-1 BBB- 06-1
AAA 06-2 AA 06-2 A 06-2 BBB 06-2 BBB- 06-2
AAA 07-1 AA 07-1 A 07-1 BBB 07-1 BBB- 07-1
Percent AAA 07-2 AA 07-2 A 07-2 BBB 07-2 BBB- 07-2
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
2006 07 08 09 10
My contention is that this sudden drop in prices, and the the peak of the securities market, the collapse in securities
further price declines later, were not simply the result of a drop prices preceded the significant fall in housing prices. Thus, in
in expected payoffs (that is, in fundamentals) by the same old my view the trigger for the downturn in bonds was the bad
buyers, but also the result of a change in the marginal buyer. A news about delinquencies and the concurrent creation of the
critical new downward force entered the market for mortgage standardized CDS market in subprime mortgage indexes,
securities. Standardized credit default swaps (CDS) on which then spilled over into the housing market.
mortgage bonds were created for the first time in late 2005, at The downward pressure on bond prices from credit default
the very height of the market. The volume of CDS expanded swaps and worrisome delinquency numbers meant that new
rapidly throughout 2006 and especially in 2007 (Chart 7).22 securitizations became more difficult to underwrite.
A CDS is an insurance contract for a bond. By buying the Securitizers of new loans looked for better loans to package in
insurance, the pessimists for the first time could leverage their order to continue to back bonds worth more than the loan
negative views about bond prices and the houses that backed amounts they had to give homeowners. They asked for loans
them. Instead of sitting out of the subprime securities market, with more collateral. As Chart 7 shows, from 2006:4 to 2007:4,
pessimists could actively push bond prices down. Their
purchase of insurance is tantamount to the creation of more
(“synthetic”) bonds; naturally, the increase in supply pushed Chart 7
the marginal buyer down and thus the price down. Volume of Credit Default Swaps
In January 2007, after the dramatic fall in BBB subprime Trillions of dollars
mortgage prices, housing prices were still only 1.8 percent off 70
their peak. Though the peak of the housing market preceded 60
21
The collapse of the ABX index in January 2007 is a powerful illustration of 50
the potency of market prices to convey information. This first market crash 40
should have been enough to alert our government to the looming foreclosure
disaster, but three years later we still have not taken decisive action to mitigate 30
foreclosures.
22
20
Chart 7 is derived from data provided in “ISDA Market Survey: Historical
Data,” available at www.isda.org/statistics/historical/html. Unfortunately, it 10
includes all CDS, not just CDS on mortgages. The data on mortgage CDS seem 0
difficult to find, since these CDS were traded bilaterally and not on an 2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09
exchange. It seems very likely to me that the mortgage CDS increased even
more dramatically from 2004-05 to 2006-07. Source: “ISDA Market Survey: Historical Data.”
112 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
there was a nontrivial chance of a much bigger loss on a single involved many financial institutions, it never involved such a
loan. Lenders, inherent pessimists, would not have considered large fraction of the general population. When housing prices
lending using a single subprime mortgage as collateral. But and securities prices fell, millions of homeowners as well as
now consider a pool of subprime mortgages from around the many of the most venerable financial institutions in America
country. If one believed that the loans were independent, so found themselves underwater, owing more money than the
that a housing price decline in Detroit did not imply a housing value of their assets.
price decline in California, then on a big enough pool of loans, Thus, the current cycle is really a double leverage cycle: not
the chance for more than 30 percent default might be only are the mortgage securities subject to the leverage cycle,
considered less than 1 in 10,000. Even a very pessimistic lender but their “fundamental” cash flows (namely, homeowner
who believed in a 4 percent expected loss per loan would be mortgage payments) are also subject to the leverage cycle.
willing to lend 70 percent of the value of the entire pool, These two cycles feed off each other. When margins are raised
provided that he got paid before anyone else. Thus, a buyer of on homeowners, it becomes more difficult to get a new
the pool of mortgages could imagine borrowing 70 percent of mortgage and home prices fall, jeopardizing mortgage
their collective value, when it would have been impossible to securities backed by houses. But more importantly, it becomes
borrow anything on the individual loans. more difficult for homeowners to refinance their old loans,
Securitization took this borrowing on pools one step further putting these loans and the securities they back in much more
by converting the loans into long-term loans. The underwriter jeopardy of defaulting. Similarly, when margins on securities
of the pool typically issued different bonds, whose payments are raised and their prices fall, then in order to sell the securities
depended on the homeowners’ payments on their loans. for higher prices, underwriters demand better underlying
Consider, for example, a bond structure with just two mortgages, that is, more money down from home buyers.
“tranches” of bonds. The senior tranche might pay interest
slightly above the riskless government rate on the best
70 percent of the loans. As long as losses on the pool are below
30 percent, the senior tranche holder continues to get paid his 4.3 Credit Default Swaps
interest and eventually his principal. The junior bondholder
receives what is left from the pool after the senior bondholder The current cycle has been more violent because of the
is paid. The whole securitized structure can be interpreted as if standardization/creation of the derivative credit default swap
the buyer of the junior piece actually bought the whole pool, market for mortgages in 2005, just at the top of the leverage
using a long-term loan from the buyer of the senior piece, cycle. One reason for the abruptness of the fall is that CDS
collateralized by the whole pool. Once one understands the allowed pessimists to leverage at just the worst time. Once CDS
juniors as effectively borrowing from the seniors, it becomes emerged, they were bound to put downward pressure on
clear how the rapid spread of securitization over the last thirty prices, because they allowed pessimists to express their views
years, but especially over the last ten years, dramatically for the first time and indeed leverage those views. Had the CDS
increased the leverage in the system. market for mortgages been around from the beginning, asset
Another factor that dramatically increased overall leverage prices might never have gotten so high. But their appearance at
in the system is the credit default swap, which I discuss shortly. the very top of the cycle guaranteed that there would be a fall.
Not only did CDS allow pessimists to leverage for the first
time, it also allowed them to leverage more than optimists.
When a bond trades near 100, but there is a perceptible chance
4.2 Housing and the Double Leverage Cycle of a big drop in price, then in a rational world the writer of
insurance is almost always going to be asked to put up much
Leverage on houses got to be much higher in this leverage cycle.
more collateral than the buyer of insurance, because his
In the recent leverage cycles, ending in 1994 and 1998,
potential liability is so high. A small group of pessimists can
homeowner leverage did not get remotely as high as it did in the
therefore have an outsized negative impact on prices by
recent cycle. In 2006, many homeowners were borrowing with
leveraging their CDS positions, since traders on the other side
basically no money down, or as little as 3 percent, as we saw in
will need far more capital to offset those positions.
Chart 1.25 New mortgages like option arms were invented,
A second reason why CDS made the fall much worse is that
which abetted this mad rush to loan homeowners all or nearly
in practice they allowed optimists to leverage even more than
all of the purchase price. Whereas previous cycles’ leverage
they had before. To the extent that CDS did not lower prices
25
See Haughwout, Peach, and Tracy (2008) for details on leverage used for before any bad news, it was because leveraged optimists
nonprime borrowers from 2001 to 2007. increased their leverage by taking the other side of the CDS, on
114 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
collateral at a third site that would not be compromised by the guarantees for entities that were considered too-big-to-fail.
bankruptcy of the lender. This raises questions about whether Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac grew bigger and bigger. The
there is enough collateral in the economy to back all the presumed government guarantee on their promises enabled
promises people want to make, which I discuss at length in them to leverage their assets to 30 or more, and still issue debt
Geanakoplos (1997) and Geanakoplos and Zame (2009). But just above Treasury rates. Without this implicit government
I believe there could be a government initiative to move as backing, they would never have been able to borrow so much
many bilateral contracts onto exchanges as possible; agents with such little capital.
trading with the exchange will be required to put up Many investment banks were allowed to write CDS without
collateral, and the netting through the exchange will collateralizing their implicit promises, as I observed before. It
economize on the collateral. As for any finance-related seems virtually inexplicable that Wall Street overlooked this
bilateral contracting so particular that it could not be moved counterparty risk; more likely, many counterparties assumed
to an exchange, the parties could either accept strict that these firms were implicitly backstopped by the Fed or the
disclosure requirements and limits on how much of this Treasury. And indeed, despite some doubts when Lehman
contracting they could engage in or accept doing without the collapsed, that expectation proved correct.28
instruments altogether.
116 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
As I explained above, all leverage cycles end with 1) bad 5.1 Step One—Addressing the Precipitating
news creating uncertainty and disagreement, 2) sharply Cause of the Crisis: “Scary Bad” News
increasing collateral rates, and 3) losses and bankruptcies
(Massive Uncertainty) about Housing
among the leveraged optimists. These three factors reinforce
and feed back on each other. In particular, what begins as
and the Assets Built on Housing
uncertainty about exogenous events creates uncertainty about
endogenous events, like how far prices will fall or who will go To foster recovery from the dramatic final stage of a leverage
cycle as large as the one we have just experienced, the
bankrupt, which leads to further tightening of collateral, and
thus further price declines and so on. In the aftermath of the government must address the cause of the uncertainty that
crisis, we always see depressed asset prices, reduced economic triggered the end stage. Without that, the efforts taken thus far
to bring margins down and recapitalize banks, even had they
activity, and a collection of agents that are not yet bankrupt but
hovering near insolvency. How long the aftermath persists been perfectly implemented, would not be enough to reverse
depends on the depth of the crisis and the quality of the the cycle and restore the economy to health. In this crisis, with
its roots in housing, that means doing something for housing
government’s response. Whether we find ourselves in a similar
crisis in the future depends on whether, understanding how prices and homeowners. This makes undeniable sense in this
leverage got us here, we adopt reforms that require supervisors crisis, not just because addressing the cause of the uncertainty
and disagreement (the scary bad news) is critical to reverse any
to monitor and regulate leverage in good times. First, I take up
what government actions could have been taken, and in what leverage cycle, but because the biggest social losses will
order, to address the final stage of the double leverage cycle that probably come from the displaced homeowners. And, of
course, the biggest reason for the tumbling mortgage security
the government was called on to address in 2007.
The thematic solution once the crisis has started is to reverse prices, and the resulting insolvency of the banking sector, is
the three symptoms of the crisis: contain the bad news, fear that housing prices will keep falling.
intervene to bring down margins, and carefully inject
“optimistic” equity back into the system. To be successful, any
government plan must respect all three remedial prongs, and Saving the Homeowners: Stemming the Tsunami
should be explainable and explained to the public in terms that of Foreclosures to Come
it can understand. Without public confidence, which can only
flow from public understanding, any federal government One of the saddest stories in this financial meltdown is that
millions of homeowners are being thrown out of their homes
(hereafter, “government”) plan undermines its own objectives
and limits its prospects for success. The government’s actions for defaulting on their mortgages. Throwing somebody out of
thus far have not addressed all three prongs adequately and his home is tragic for the homeowner, but also very expensive
for the lender. One of the shocking aspects of the foreclosure
policymakers have thus far largely failed to explain how their
various solutions are tied to the roots of the crisis we face. crisis is how low the recoveries have become on foreclosed
Unfortunately, the TARP, the government’s first properties, after expenses. (Interestingly, the mortgage bond
intervention plan to buy distressed assets, was not clearly index markets anticipated these bad recoveries.) Nobody gains
when the homeowners are thrown out and the banks and/or
thought through and neither it, the ostensible solution, nor
the problem that required a solution were clearly explained. investors collect pennies on the dollar for the money they
After its announcement, asset prices fell further. But even now, loaned. Yet, as we saw, 2 million homeowners have already
been evicted, another 2.5 million are seriously delinquent and
after the panic has subsided, we must ask who or what is the
government trying to save? Many in the public have come to almost surely will be evicted in the near future, and at least
believe it is merely trying to save banks, or some big banks, another 3 million will eventually default and be evicted if trends
continue. Without much bolder action than has thus far been
from failure because somehow their failure would signal a
catastrophe for the American brand, to be prevented at all taken by the government, the stream of evictions and bad
costs.30 The confusion about the government’s goals has recoveries for lenders will continue and accelerate, becoming a
torrent that will further depress housing prices and impede
created its own set of problems, which we can ill afford.
economic recovery.
Clarifying the government’s goals will be harder now, but it
Negative equity is a key driver of mortgage defaults. When
remains an indispensible step.
faced with an income shock, borrowers who are in positive
30
equity have the option to sell the house rather than default.
“Sixty-seven percent (67 percent) of adults believe Wall Street will benefit
more from the new bank bailout plan than the average U.S. taxpayer.” Borrowers who are underwater (in negative equity) may
Rasmussen Reports, February 2009/56. choose to default even in the absence of an income shock.
conclusion.31 The conclusion is an inescapable matter of Note: Circles indicate median combined-loan-to-value (CLTV) ratios
incentives. It may not be economically rational for a by product.
homeowner to continue to pay off a $160,000 loan when his
house is only worth $100,000.32 Mortgage loans have turned
out to be no-recourse—after seizing the house, the lender Foreclosures are horribly expensive for the lender. At the
almost never comes after the borrower for more payments. present time, subprime lenders collect about 25 cents per dollar
Besides the ability to live in the house, the only other thing the of loan when they foreclose. For example, if the loan is for
homeowner loses by defaulting is his credit rating, but $160,000 and the house has fallen in value to $100,000 and the
especially for a nonprime borrower with a low credit rating to homeowner defaults and is evicted, the lender can expect to get
begin with, how much can that be worth? Finally, a choice back $40,000. It takes eighteen months on average to evict a
today by a negative equity borrower to default may be moving homeowner, and during that time he does not pay his mortgage
up in time a necessity to default at some point in the future. In or his taxes, the house is often left empty and vandalized, a
this case, the borrower’s credit rating will likely be damaged realtor must be hired to sell the house, and so on. Of course, the
anyway. main reason the average recoveries are so low is that the
defaulters are the homeowners who are furthest underwater
(see Chart 8).
31
Haughwout, Peach, and Tracy (2008) stress the importance of negative In a rational world, many foreclosure losses would never
equity as a determinant of early defaults among nonprime borrowers. The happen. The lenders would renegotiate the loans by reducing
Congressional Oversight Panel cited negative equity as the single greatest
predictor of default in its report of March 6, 2009. It included the data I provide the principal so the homeowners could pay less and stay in their
here as evidence of this fact, data that I supplied to the Panel in advance of its homes, and the lenders would actually get more by avoiding the
report, as well as data from an array of government agencies, all of which losses from legal fees and bad home price sales. If the above
corroborated the Ellington Capital Management data presented here. That is
not to say that joblessness is not now having a significant effect on default rates.
loan were written down to $80,000, the homeowner would
It is. But even now, negative equity is the best predictor of default and many likely find a way to pay it, or else fix up the house and sell it for
Americans with jobs are defaulting, and will continue to default, not just the $100,000. Either way, the lender would get $80,000 instead of
unemployed. See generally the Congressional Oversight Panel’s Report of
$40,000. That would have the further benefit of keeping many
October 9, 2009, on the continuing foreclosure problem and the unimpressive
results from government foreclosure prevention efforts taken thus far. Finally, homes off the market and thereby aid in the stabilization of
to the extent that job loss has become (it was not at the start of this crisis) a home prices.
significant cause of defaults, strong effective measures to eliminate the scary The Home Affordable Modification Program pays servicers
bad news—that is, efforts to stabilize the housing market—will help the
economy recover faster and thus help the employment rate. to temporarily reduce interest payments and to extend the term
32
The implication of this statement is that the HAMP plan of reducing interest of the mortgage in order to reduce the monthly payments on
rates to lower mortgage payments to homeowners who are underwater is, at the mortgage, but does not incentivize servicers to cut princi-
least for those seriously underwater, an invitation or encouragement to act in a pal. Cutting monthly payments by half will temporarily reduce
manner that may make no or little economic sense, that is, stretching to make
mortgage payments, albeit lowered from their highs, on homes those people the homeowner’s payments by the same amount that cutting
will never own when many of them might be able to rent more cheaply. principal by half would. But under the government’s plan, the
118 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
cut is temporary, not permanent, and thus is likely to lead to The design of any modification program must recognize
many more defaults in the long run than cutting principal that the servicers have incentives that at times put them at odds
would as soon as the interest rate goes back up.33 In fact, since with bondholders and homeowners, so that they may actually
the homeowner will still be underwater, he will not in any prevent modifications that would help lenders and home-
meaningful sense own his house. He will be less likely to make owners but hurt servicers. In the case of many nonprime
repairs, he will not be able to give the house to his children, he borrowers, the loans have been pooled in a trust, and their
will not be able to sell it if he gets a job in another city.34 In principal has been tranched into many different bonds, each
short, there is every reason to think he will likely default even held by a different investor. The lenders are the bondholders,
before the interest rate goes back up. For loan modifications but they are numerous and dispersed and by contract have
where there is no principal reduction, the redefault rate is given up the legal right to renegotiate with homeowners,
above 50 percent within nine months.35 Indeed, because the delegating that right to an agent.37 That agent is the servicer,
government’s present plan allows servicers to increase who has a fiduciary responsibility to act in the interests of the
principal while cutting interest by adding fees and other costs bondholders in the trust.38 In “normal” times, this
to the old principal amount, the plan is likely to leave more arrangement worked tolerably enough. But in this crisis, with
homeowners underwater than there would be absent the plan so many mortgages in or near default, it has failed miserably for
and others more deeply underwater—that is, with even less at least four reasons, all traceable to a misalignment of interests
chance of ever owning their homes and thus less incentive to between servicers and those whose interests they are supposed
keep up with mortgage payments—than they would have
to protect, which has now ruptured with terrible effects.
without this government “rescue” plan.
First, modifying loans is a time-consuming and expensive
HAMP started off slowly and only recently is beginning to be
operation. The servicers who have the legal right to make
able to process a larger flow of mortgages. In the first six months
modifications do not get paid directly for improving the cash
of the plan, according to the Congressional Oversight Panel’s
flows to loans. It is generally cheaper for them to move into
October 2009 report, only 85,000 mortgages had been modified,
foreclosure. In particular, they have no incentive to set up the
and of those only 1,711 were “permanent” modifications (that is,
huge infrastructure and to hire and train the extra staff
permanent/temporary, since interest rate reductions under the
required to make sensible modifications on a grand scale.
plan are designed to end in a few years), and of those only 5
Second, modifying the loans has different effects on different
involved principal reductions.36 As of May 2010, HAMP had
bondholders. It has proved difficult to modify loans in a way that
started trial modifications on 1,244,184 loans, of which 429,696
pleases everyone. The servicers say they are terrified of lawsuits
had been canceled and 340,459 had been converted into
from the bondholders if their modifications help most
permanent modifications. Again, virtually none of the
bondholders but hurt others. For example, writing down
permanent modifications involved principal reduction. Of the
principal immediately may make more money for the trust as a
5.7 million loans that were delinquent sixty or more days in May,
whole, but it would immediately wipe out the BBB bonds and
only 1.7 million were eligible for HAMP modifications.
possibly other lower level bondholders. Letting the borrowers
33
Haughwout, Okah, and Tracy (2009) find in a sample of pre-HAMP
remain in their houses without paying during the foreclosure
subprime mortgage modifications that reducing principal is twice as effective process means that during all that time all the bondholders,
as cutting the interest rate in terms of reducing the post-modification redefault including the BBB, get their coupons paid in full from servicer
rate.
34
advances. The servicers then recoup their advances, at the expense
See Gyourko and Saiz (2004).
35 of the trust, when the house is finally sold.39 In reality, servicers
See “OCC/OTS Mortgage Metrics Report,” 2Q 2009.
36
To be clear, my criticism of HAMP is not based on the number of the time- 37
limited “permanent” modifications completed, but rather is centered on the It should be noted that this right was given up to avoid the collective action
near-exclusive concentration on interest reduction and, as I explain in the text problems inherent when the lenders are numerous and dispersed, and thus was
below, on leaving the servicers in charge of the modification decision. I could given to a third party (the servicer) to be exercised on the lender’s behalf, the
find no updated information in the report on how many, if any, of the trial or servicer acting as a fiduciary for the lenders. It was not given to the servicer to
permanent modifications involved principal reduction as opposed to interest be used to benefit the servicer’s interests at the expense of the principals (the
reduction, and I have no reason to assume that the percentage of modifications lenders), and using the discretion to modify or foreclose that way is self-dealing
with principal reductions has increased. It is also worth noting that in the on the part of servicers and a breach of their obligation to the lenders.
38
Congressional Oversight Panel’s Report of October 2009 (p. 127), the Panel See Alan Kronovet, “An Overview of Commercial Mortgage Backed
notes that the apparent rise in modifications due to the administration’s plan Securitization: The Devil Is in the Details,” 1 N.C. Banking Inst. 288, 311
might be overstated, as there was some evidence of a “substitution effect,” that (1997), explaining fiduciary duties of servicers. Section 1403 of the new
is, the number of “voluntary” modifications by servicers (or modifications housing bill that was signed into law on July 30, 2008 (HR 3221, the Housing
made outside of the administration’s plan) went down in the first six months and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, P.L. 110-289), lays out the fiduciary
of the plan, suggesting that the gross number of modifications attributable to responsibilities of servicers of pooled mortgages.
39
the plan itself might be exaggerated. The new report by the government does This requires that the servicers have access to capital to finance the coupon
not provide data from which one can assess any substitution effect. payments until the foreclosure process is concluded.
120 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
zero. The second-loan holder could still receive some cash, experts and community bankers in place as government
however. I would recommend distributing the same percentage trustees, not bankruptcy judges who are neither numerous
of the monthly payments to the second loan as it was getting enough to handle the number of defaulting homeowners who
before principal was reduced for a period of, say, two years. should justifiably qualify for principal reduction nor as
After that, the second loan would be completely extinguished knowledgeable as the personnel I would put in charge.47 If my
and all cash flows would flow to the first-loan holder. plan were indeed up and running, bankruptcy might be
For a vast number of homeowners now upside-down in something worth considering as a true last resort for those
their mortgages, that is, owing more than their home is already deeply in default. Finally, bankruptcy involves all kinds
presently worth, this process would likely result in a reduction of hidden costs, like lawyer fees and trustee expenses (on top of
of principal. Why? Because reducing principal rather than the costs associated with the experts required to advise the
cutting interest rates would be more effective at preventing bankruptcy judges) that are unnecessary and wasteful for the
defaults and would yield investors/lenders more money than vast majority of homeowners and lenders who should be able
foreclosing, as we have seen.46 to make a win-win deal without incurring those costs.48
If the government handled this correctly, most homeowners My original plan called for legislation to cut through the
who were unable to pay the original loan but were willing and able agency-problem mess in securitized pools of mortgages by
to pay a modestly lesser amount would get to stay in their homes, eliminating contract provisions in pooling arrangements that
the bondholders collectively would get more payments than they now enable servicers to act contrary to the interests of the
are currently expecting (though some tranches would be hurt), investors that the provisions were originally designed to
and the government would not have to invest any capital. protect. Thus, I envisioned that the government trustees would
This plan is not the same as “cramdown” in bankruptcy, only be empowered to modify securitized mortgages. This
which Congress has thus far rejected and which entails costs would leave unsolved the problem of whole loans that banks
and creates some perverse incentives that my plan avoids. are still refusing to modify sensibly, by writing down principal
Giving reductions in principal through bankruptcy (assuming for underwater homeowners.
the law were changed to allow that) would encourage I believe, however, that once a government program of
homeowners now current on their mortgages but underwater modifications for securitized loans proved its worth by
and thus likely to default sometime in the future to default resulting in more recovery for investors, banks would be likely
immediately to support their petition for bankruptcy relief. to adopt similar standards to modify whole loans. Nonetheless,
However, my plan, as originally conceived, does not build in a solid government plan to force sensible principal reductions
any incentives for the borrower to default in order to increase for securitized loans would, I believe, go a long way toward
the chance that the mortgage will be modified. Principal convincing the banks that no better deal from the government
reductions would be done first for homeowners who have not was forthcoming, particularly if the government clearly
defaulted yet, and only later for homeowners who have articulated that this was so, and would exert discipline on the
defaulted under some special hardship. It would give valuation of the whole loans and second loans on the banks’
underwater homeowners now holding on for the short term a balance sheets. Obliging the banks to mark to market would, of
continued incentive to keep paying until the government course, also push them to get the most value out of their loans
trustees could evaluate their loans and circumstances for a by writing down principal for underwater homes.
reduction in principal. Second, my plan differs from Finally, what if home prices vastly appreciate by the time the
bankruptcy in that it does not subject homeowners to the homeowner sells his home? To prevent unwarranted windfall
shame and devastating harm to future credit and thus to their profits to homeowners, the government plan could easily
economic circumstance that a bankruptcy proceeding entails. require the homeowner to share 50/50 with the lenders any
Third, my plan contemplates putting local housing market appreciation in home price up to the full amortized value of the
original mortgage, and the plan might even provide that, for
45
See Geanakoplos and Koniak (2008). Under this plan, the servicers would houses sold for more than the original loan price, lenders
still collect the servicing fees they do now. They would continue their duties of receive a greater percentage of the appreciation.
sending letters to homeowners, collecting the monthly payments and
47
distributing them to bondholders, evicting homeowners who did not pay, Indeed, it is highly doubtful that our bankruptcy courts could handle the job
selling their homes, and so on. The only change is that the mortgage loan Congress would be giving them if so-called cramdown legislation were
modification would be taken out of their hands and put into the hands of the adopted, at least not if it were adopted without first having a plan like the one
government trustees. This reassignment of a particular duty in the contract is I propose up and running to handle the vast majority of underwater
not a “takings” from the servicer, among other reasons because the servicers homeowners.
have failed to carry out their fiduciary obligations to the bondholders who 48
My plan envisions the government paying for the trustees (community
employ them to get the most possible value out of the loans. See Dana bankers) to decide on whether principal modification would bring in more for
(forthcoming). bondholders than foreclosure, but I estimate that government expenditure
46
See Haughwout et al. (2009) for evidence based on subprime modifications. should come to less than $5 billion.
122 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
because he gets to live in the whole house while paying for only 5.2 Step Two—A Fed Lending Facility
80 percent of it. If the home buyer needs a loan to get the house, to Help Restore Reasonable Leverage
the government equity piece reduces the down payment the
buyer must make, and the ongoing mortgage payments he The most easily implementable step and the second priority,
must make. And if we make the government’s equity piece after addressing the source of the uncertainty (the scary bad
the second loss piece, it leaves the lenders in a very, very safe news), in responding to the final stage of any leverage cycle
position, encouraging lending. In effect, it lowers the margin could be government action to decrease astronomical collateral
to the borrower, and raises the margin of safety to the lender. rates. Thus, in October 2008 I suggested that the most
Here is how it works.52 immediate step the Federal Reserve could take was to lend
Under the plan, the home buyer who wanted a loan to money using the so-called troubled assets (those that suddenly
purchase the house would be allowed to borrow at most became nearly impossible to use as collateral, as I explained
80 percent of the $80 of the house he bought, or $64. He would earlier) as no-recourse collateral. I suggested 50 percent
have to put up 20 percent x $80 = $16 of his own cash. The margins on average, a reasonable halfway level between the
homeowner would then have a big incentive to make his 5 percent margins required at the peak of the leverage bubble
payments. If he walks away from his debt, he can save $64, but and the 70-90 percent margin rate demanded in 2008. The
he has to give up living in a $100 house on which he had an $80 Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) and the Public-
ownership share. But if the borrower does default, and if the Private Investment Program (PPIP), announced in early 2009
lender has to foreclose, the lender would be able to collect his at what turned out to be the bottom of the price cycle, embody
debt out of the house sale proceeds ahead of the government the spirit of my recommendation. Indeed, the PPIP did lend on
equity piece. The government would collect next, and lastly the these bonds at exactly 50 percent margins. The turnaround of
buyer would get any leftover cash. If the house sold in
prime mortgage security prices (displayed in Chart 2) after
foreclosure (net of expenses) for $82, the lender would get his
these programs were announced seems to me to be some
$64, the government would get $18, and the homeowner
evidence for the wisdom of the intervention. But in terms of
nothing. The effective margin for the homeowner is thus
some important details, those programs did not go as I would
16 percent on the asset price of $100, but the margin of safety
have recommended. In any case, it now appears that having
for the lender is 36 percent. This should make the lender feel
achieved their purpose, they have been drastically attenuated.
very safe and encourage private lending on mortgages. The
Lending with smaller margins (haircuts) than the market is
homeowner’s down payment of 16 percent on the total home
willing to offer to borrowers who might not repay is a great
price is about half the down payment many nongovernment
departure from the traditional role of the Federal Reserve. The
lenders are demanding now. On top of that, the new buyer’s
orthodox view is that the Fed injects liquidity into the system
mortgage payments would be 20 percent lower than before,
by lending money to banks and others with impeccable
because he would be paying on a loan of $64 instead of $80.
reputations for repaying so as to reduce the riskless rate of
What about the costs of my plan? Last year, there were
interest on very short-term loans. The banks would then
5.5 million new home purchases, down from a high of 7 mil-
presumably turn around and relend that money to investors, at
lion. Even if the government had to buy the equity in the entire
a lower interest rate than would have obtained absent the Fed’s
7 million, at an average home price of $200,000, it would cost
intervention. However, the great bulk of lending in the
$280 billion. But the government would own equity, and be
investment world is not based on the reputation of the
protected by the homeowner’s down payment. Housing prices
borrower but based instead on the value of the collateral. The
would need to fall another 16 percent before the government
lesson of the leverage cycle is that when lenders demand too
lost equity value. As housing prices stabilized, the government
much collateral for their loans, liquidity dries up. The Fed
would gradually phase out the program, in all likelihood in a
cannot undo this by making riskless loans at a lower interest
year, at most two, after adoption. To lower the government’s
rate than the market, because in liquidity crises it is not the
overall equity investment, the program could be limited to
interest rate the banks charge that impedes investor borrowing
first-time home buyers.
but rather the amount of collateral they require. The Fed needs
to step around the banks and make risky loans directly to
investors with smaller haircuts than the market demands, if
it is to have the desired effect.
52
Equity sharing arrangements could also form with private investors. For a The mechanics of such a massive lending program require
discussion, see Caplin et al. (1997). some careful thought, but nothing compared with the
124 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
important to bear in mind not just for this crisis, but also in leverage on the new securities at astronomical 20:1 ratios. If
case there is another crisis in which prices do not rebound as instead the Fed would give much lower and safer 2 to 1 leverage
quickly after a leverage intervention. In my opinion, the two on the legacy assets, it would raise the legacy asset prices, and
programs did not encompass a wide enough set of assets or a thus even the new security prices, because it would remove the
wide enough set of borrowers, they took too long to get going, bargains investors are seeking in the legacy assets.55 The new
and in some cases TALF actually took leverage up almost to the assets would not need so much leverage, and the risk to the
crazy levels it had been before. Had TALF started earlier, and taxpayers would be reduced. This would also go a long way to
had it lent on more assets, it would not have been forced to give solving the bank lending problem. As I show again in
such high leverage on the narrow band of assets it did lend Geanakoplos (2010) (in a stylized example, to be sure), despite
against. lending on a much larger scale, by allowing leverage at 2 to 1 on
In the emergency stages of the leverage cycle, the Fed should a wide array of assets rather than at 20 to 1 on a narrow set of
have extended lending on more kinds of collateral. TALF assets, the Fed could actually reduce its expected defaults while
restricted leverage mostly to new securities, or to securities that increasing the prices of all the securities. A year later, it now
were still AAA-rated. As more and more mortgage securities appears that the Fed will not face significant losses on these
get downgraded below investment-grade status, they lose their TALF loans, and private leverage is also returning. But had
ability to be used as collateral even in the private sector. things gone worse, the Fed might have been stuck with some
Lending against the most toxic securities is actually necessary to dangerous loans.
maintain their value.54 In the crisis stage, the Fed needs to go around the banks and
The TALF program made government loans on new credit lend directly to more investors. In theory, the Fed could make
cards, auto loans, college loans, and other securitizations at 20 no-recourse loans only to a few banks, who would turn around
to 1 leverage. In my opinion, this repeats the error of the FHA and relend to everyone else. But the banks are nervous about
mortgage program, lending at the same inflated leverage that showing too much lending on their books, they ask for too
got us into trouble in the first place. The Fed has rightly much collateral, and now the Fed is giving them more
observed that propping up new security values is more profitable ways to make money than by lending; so the Fed
important than propping up legacy security values, because must reach out directly to more borrowers. Curiously, the PPIP
new securities represent new activities. When new prices go has been restricted to ten potential borrowers/investors,
down, new securities are not issued and the underlying activity making its scope and size in the end less than what was
for which the securities would be issued (students going to anticipated. Also, with only ten investors taking government
school, cars being purchased, new houses being built, money, the potential for conflicts of interest seems very high,
consumers buying with credit cards) stops. However, as I argue as I discuss later.
more formally in Geanakoplos (2010), in the depths of the The TALF and PPIP programs took too long to get up and
leverage cycle, the Fed could raise the price of new securities running. Hopefully, at the bottom of the next leverage cycle, or
further by leveraging them less, if it would also leverage the even earlier, similar programs could be implemented sooner.
legacy securities to modest levels. The reason is that potential I recommend that the Fed keep a standing, permanent lending
buyers of these new securities are tempted instead to put all facility up and running. In normal times, it would lend a little
their capital into the depressed legacy assets where they are bit across a wide range of assets, to be ready to spring into
nearly sure of a high return. This indeed is one of the main action if private collateral rates became too high. This facility
reasons banks stop lending to businesses or homeowners: they could be administered directly by the Fed, by people it hired, or
can get better returns by buying depressed legacy assets. Given it could be run through the repo desks of the Wall Street banks.
the depressed legacy security prices, the only way TALF could In the latter case, it would be wise to insist that the banks put
redirect this private money into new securities was by giving some of their capital at risk along with the Fed money. The
advantage of using repo desks is that they are already staffed
54
Again, such lending would be much less risky if the government had adopted with trained personnel, who have great expertise in making
a sensible plan to staunch foreclosures and stabilize housing prices, such as I margin calls. Duplicating that expertise would be expensive.56
have just outlined, because such a plan would reduce the toxicity of the The advantage of a permanent facility is that the Fed would be
securities at issue. And the quicker the government moves to do that, the less
risky such lending will become, not to mention the good it would do for the ready to quickly lend on a grand scale, on many securities, and
value of the toxic securities the government now owns through one program to many lenders, in the next crisis.
or another or now guarantees, representing continuing and enormous
55
government money still at considerable risk. This point is why I stress the Another reason why it actually could raise new security prices is that by
importance of understanding the nature of the crisis in crafting sensible leveraging the legacy securities at 2 to 1, it will free some investor equity to put
solutions and how failing to address one part of the problem, in our case the into the new securities.
56
failure to adequately address housing, limits the good that otherwise sensible I presented this proposal for a lending facility to the Liquidity Working
programs might make. Group at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in early 2009.
126 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
Forcing natural pessimists into purchases they fear, however and returns of these companies very public. These managers
much potential financial upside, may well undermine public would then be competing with each other on a world stage to
confidence in government, especially if the investments start to see how their investments performed. A more conventional
go bad. But even if taxpayers were on board, caution should be incentive device would be to say that a manager gets no fees
the watchword. The lending mentioned earlier (a much more until the return on the assets passes some hurdle. Only after the
direct approach to restoring leverage) would probably raise taxpayers make money would the managers earn any fees.
security prices, so the government purchases would not be at The PPIP embodies a number of the same principles I
rock-bottom prices. Private investors (naturally more agile and advocated. Under the PPIP plan, the government has set up
quicker than the government), knowing that the government accounts with professional money managers in which each
would be buying, would rush to buy first, reducing potential government equity dollar is invested side-by-side in the same
government profits. Of course, that, in some sense, would be securities with a dollar of investor capital. (This is in addition
what the government would want to happen because it would to the money loaned to the managers.)
mean that security prices would rise more quickly. But it might Should another crisis arise, the government must be aware
also result in taxpayers getting stuck with the worst assets, of the pitfalls of a large government buying program. The
causing public outrage and charges of foul play. government cannot appear to the public as enriching the
The biggest obstacle and the one that apparently stopped managers it entrusts with its money with fees that are too high.
Secretary Paulson’s original plan to buy the troubled assets is However, they must be given incentives to perform well.
the enormous challenge of deciding what to buy, and at what Otherwise, they might be tempted to spend taxpayer money
price. We must not forget that the downward swing in the buying portfolios sold by the failing companies of their cronies,
leverage cycle is always triggered by genuine bad news, which I in exchange for favors later on. Or they might pay less attention
call scary because it creates more uncertainty. Private investors to the government investments than to the investments of their
hold back for fear of “catching a falling knife”; the government fee-paying clients. Or they might buy for the government with
has far less expertise than these private investors. Since the an eye toward benefiting their private clients by raising prices
distressed mortgages are very heterogeneous, it is not at all clear of assets the clients hold, or in some other way. These conflicts
how the government acting alone could figure out what prices of interest become more acute to the extent that the number of
to pay. Indeed, since Secretary Paulson’s call for government managers is small and to the extent that they each have a huge
purchases of distressed securities, a large number of them
amount of government money to wield. For example, a big
(including most CDOs) have continued to lose value, with
enough buyer with government money could conceivably offer
some even going to zero. In retrospect, a program of
to rid a bank of toxic assets, at favorable prices, in exchange for
indiscriminate buying might have been a disaster. But how
favors like easier credit later on.
could the government decide what to buy, and at what prices?57
Another potential pitfall in government buying is the
The dangers of government buying look so profound that in
perverse incentives it might set up among sellers eager to get
October 2008, I recommended that if the government were to
their securities purchased. For example, it may be that the
buy at all, it would be better for the government to invest
banks were waiting for the government purchase not just of
through professional money managers, again piggy-backing on
securities, but shaky whole loans too, and that hope may have
the choices they make to invest their own capital.58 To help
contributed to their failure to modify whole loans in a rational
ensure that money managers had the right incentives, I also
manner.
recommended dividing the government money up among a
Thus, even with all the advice I have offered about how the
large number of private managers and making the investments
government should buy if it must, buying may still not be a
57
One suggestion that was made is by reverse auction. The government would wise policy, particularly not as a substitute for an adequate
divide the securities into different categories, and then buy from each category lending program, such as I described above.
those securities that the current asset holders are willing to sell for the lowest
price. But how would the government decide what the categories are and how
much to spend on each? And how would it be protected from sellers’ efforts to
unload the worst securities in each category? If the purchases were to be made
by an auction mechanism, I would have suggested a variation in which private
bidders were allowed to enter the auction, not just private sellers. I would have 6. Moral Hazard
recommended that the government commit to buying half the winners’
purchases, at their winning prices. That way, the government could ride on the It is often said that with every bailout comes a moral hazard
expertise of the private buyers. Still, even that solution could be gamed, that leads to a bigger problem the next time. The problem
particularly given that some private buyers might hold other positions—I am
thinking of CDS here—that made it worthwhile for them to overbid in a
would be that bailing people out in this crisis would lead to
manner that might not be easy to deter or discover. higher leverage in the next cycle. There really is only one
58 reliable antidote to that, and that is regulation of leverage.
See Geanakoplos (2008).
128 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
borrowing.) A very small tax might go a long way to discourage different securities. Setting an absolute leverage limit like 15,
excessive leverage, and might also change the maturity independent of the portfolio mix, might induce banks to shift
structure, inducing longer term loans, if it were designed their investments into securities with higher embedded
properly. Another advantage of the leverage tax is that revenues leverage. Fourth, a focus on securities leverage would lead to
from it could be used to finance the lending facility the Fed derivatives such as CDS becoming part of the leverage
would need to keep at the ready in anticipation of the downside numbers. As we saw, writing CDS insurance is like owning the
of future leverage cycles. underlying bond, so taking the ratio of the collateral required
Yet another way of controlling leverage is by mandating that on the CDS to the cash price of the bond gives a good measure
lenders can only tighten their security margins very slowly. of the CDS leverage. Fifth, it is harder to hide securities leverage
Knowing they cannot immediately adapt if conditions get more than investor leverage; for one thing, there is a counterparty to
dangerous, lenders will be led to keep tighter margins in good, each security transaction reporting the same number that can
safe times. be used by regulators as a check on reported numbers. Finally,
Leverage constraints have been proposed at the investor a leverage supervisor managing securities leverage numbers
level for selected financial firms. Congress is considering a hard might be less vulnerable to political pressure because his
cap on bank leverage of 15. There are six potential advantages, mandate would be more technical.
however, to limiting leverage at the securities level instead of at
the investor level. The first is that many people can leverage;
limiting leverage at banks or at a few other financial institutions
might just induce leveraged purchases to move somewhere 8. Conclusion
else. Second, the leverage of an investor is often a meaningless
number, at least as an indicator of credit tightness, since just The leverage cycle brought us to the edge of a cliff. We have
when things are getting bad, and margins on securities are moved back from the precipice, but unless we understand the
tightening and the whole economy is being forced to features of the leverage cycle and design our responses to
deleverage, many firms will appear to be more leveraged address the specific problems that characterize the end stage
because their equity will be disappearing. (It has become of an outsized leverage cycle, we are left hoping for a miracle
fashionable nowadays to say that leverage regulation should be to restore our financial prosperity. Marking time and waiting
countercyclical, by which people mean that investor leverage for the miracle of things getting better appear to be part of the
should be allowed to go up in bad times and down in good current government policy, at least as it relates to housing and
times. Enforcing a hard cap on investor leverage would foreclosures. That miracle, if it comes, will be nothing more
paradoxically exacerbate the leverage cycle by forcing firms to than the start of another cycle, maybe one even worse than
sell at the bottom of the cycle, even if they had long-term loans the one we have just experienced. My recommendations for
that did not require rolling over.) Third, different securities solving the present crisis and managing the leverage cycle
include different amounts of “embedded leverage.” Thus, it in its ebullient stage might prevent such an outcome.
makes sense to mandate different leverage numbers for
Adrian, T., and H. Shin. Forthcoming. “Liquidity and Leverage.” Ferreira, F., J. Gyourko, and J. Tracy. Forthcoming. “Housing Busts
Journal of Financial Intermediation. and Household Mobility.” Journal of Urban Economics.
Aragon, D., A. Caplin, S. Chopra, J. V. Leahy, Y. LeCun, M. Scoffier, and Foote, C. L., K. S. Gerardi, L. Goette, and P. S. Willen. 2009. “Reducing
J. Tracy. 2010. “Reassessing FHA Risk.” NBER Working Paper Foreclosures.” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Public Policy
no. 15802, March. Discussion Papers, no. 09-02.
Backman, A., and G. O’Connor. 1995. “Rating Cash Flow Transactions Fostel, A., and J. Geanakoplos. 2008. “Leverage Cycles and the Anxious
Backed by Corporate Debt: 1995 Update.” Moody’s. Economy.” American Economic Review 98, no. 4 (September):
1211-44.
Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1996. “The Financial
Accelerator and the Flight to Quality.” Review of Economics and Geanakoplos, J. 1997. “Promises, Promises.” In W. B. Arthur,
Statistics 78, no. 1 (February): 1-15. S. Durlauf, and D. Lane, eds., The Economy as an Evolving
Complex System, vol. 2, 285-320. Reading, Mass.: Addison-
———. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Wesley.
Cycle Framework.” In J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds.,
Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1C, 1341-93. Elsevier. ———. 2003. “Liquidity, Default, and Crashes: Endogenous
Contracts in General Equilibrium.” In M. Dewatripont, L. P.
Brunnermeier, M. K., and L. H. Pedersen. 2009. “Market Liquidity and Hansen, and S. J. Turnovsky, eds., Advances in Economics and
Funding Liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies 22, no. 6 Econometrics: Theory and Applications, vol. 2, 170-205.
(June): 2201-38. Econometric Society Monographs: Eighth World Congress.
Cambridge University Press.
Caballero, R. 2010. “The ‘Other’ Imbalance and the Financial Crisis.”
VOX, January 14. ———. 2008. “Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage
Cycle.” Remarks delivered at the Board of Governors of the Federal
Caballero, R., E. Farhi, and P.-O. Gourinchas. 2008. “An Equilibrium Reserve System, Washington, D.C., October 3.
Model of ‘Global Imbalances’ and Low Interest Rates.” American
Economic Review 98, no. 1 (March): 358-93. ———. 2010. “The Leverage Cycle.” In D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and
M. Woodford, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2009,
Caplin, A., S. Chan, C. Freeman, and J. Tracy. 1997. Housing vol. 24, 1-65. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Partnerships: A New Approach to a Market at a
Crossroads. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Geanakoplos, J., and S. Koniak. 2008. “Mortgage Justice Is Blind.”
Editorial. New York Times, October 30.
Caplin, A., C. Freeman, and J. Tracy. 1997. “Collateral Damage:
Refinancing Constraints and Regional Recessions.” Journal ———. 2009. “Principal Matters.” Editorial. New York Times,
of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, no. 4, part 1 (November): March 5.
496-516.
Geanakoplos, J., and F. Kubler. 2005. “Leverage, Incomplete Markets,
Dana, D. Forthcoming. “The Foreclosure Crisis and the Anti- and Pareto Improving Regulation.” Unpublished paper.
Fragmentation Principle in State Property Law.” University of
Chicago Law Review. Geanakoplos, J., and H. Polemarchakis. 1986. “Existence, Regularity,
and Constrained Suboptimality of Competitive Allocations when
Farhi, E., and J. Tirole. 2009. “Collective Moral Hazard, Maturity the Asset Market Is Incomplete.” In W. P. Heller, R. M. Starr, and
Mismatch, and Systemic Bailouts.” NBER Working Paper D. A. Starrett, eds., Social Choice and Public Decision
no. 15138, July. Making: Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, 65-96.
Cambridge University Press.
130 Solving the Present Crisis and Managing the Leverage Cycle
References (Continued)
Geanakoplos, J., and W. Zame. 2009. “Collateralized Security Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. “Credit Cycles.” Journal of
Markets.” Unpublished paper. Political Economy 105, no. 2 (April): 211-48.
Gromb, D., and D. Vayanos. 2002. “Equilibrium and Welfare in Minsky, H. P. 1986. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy.
Markets with Financially Constrained Arbitrageurs.” Journal New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
of Financial Economics 66, nos. 2-3 (November-December):
361-407. Myers, S. C. 1977. “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing.” Journal
of Financial Economics 5, no. 2 (November): 147-75.
Gyourko, J., and A. Saiz. 2004. “Reinvestment in the Housing Stock:
The Role of Construction Costs and the Supply Side.” Journal Peristiani, S., P. Bennett, G. Monsen, R. Peach, and J. Raiff. 1997.
of Urban Economics 55, no. 2 (March): 238-56. “Effects of Household Creditworthiness on Mortgage
Refinancing.” Journal of Fixed Income 7, no. 3
Haughwout, A., E. Okah, and J. Tracy. 2009. “Second Chances: (December): 7-21.
Subprime Mortgage Modification and Re-Default.” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 417, December. Shiller, R. 2008. The Subprime Solution: How Today’s Global
Financial Crisis Happened and What to Do About It.
Haughwout, A., R. Peach, and J. Tracy. 2008. “Juvenile Delinquent Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Mortgages: Bad Credit or Bad Economy?” Journal of Urban
Economics 64, no. 2 (September): 246-57. Tobin, J., and S. S. Golub. 1998. Money, Credit, and Capital.
New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole. 1997. “Financial Intermediation,
Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 112, no. 3 (August): 663-91.
The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York provides no warranty, express or implied, as to the
accuracy, timeliness, completeness, merchantability, or fitness for any particular purpose of any information contained in
documents produced and provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in any form or manner whatsoever.