The Institutional Nature of Price Bubbles - SSRN
The Institutional Nature of Price Bubbles - SSRN
The Institutional Nature of Price Bubbles - SSRN
Price bubbles remain a puzzle for economic theory, particularly given their
appearance in experimental markets with high efficiency and minimized
uncertainty and noise. We propose that bubbles are caused by the
institutionalization of social norms, when individuals observe and adopt the
behavior of others. Explanations of bounded rationality or individual bias
appear insufficient as we show experimentally that (1) participants pricing
skills are better ex-ante than ex-post and (2) that individual discrepancies
between intrinsic values and market prices become increasingly serially
correlated during trading. We also find no support for the Greater Fool
explanation. (94 words)
Markets sometimes develop price bubbles, i.e., they trade in high volumes at prices that
are considerably at variance from intrinsic values (Ronald R. King et al., 1993). Cases such as the
stock market crash of 1929 (Eugene N. White, 1990) demonstrate the enormous effect of
bubbles on individuals, firms, markets and even nations, and explain the interest they draw from
economists as well as the public (Charles MacKay, 1841; Charles P. Kindleberger, 1978). While
important in their consequences, the causes of bubbles are not well understood. Theoreticians
have suggested that bubbles may be rational (J. Bradford De Long et al., 1990; Peter M. Garber,
1990), intrinsic (Kenneth A. Froot and Maurice Obstfeld, 1991), and contagious (Richard Topol,
1991), but there is no widely accepted theory to explain their occurrence.
The existence of market bubbles seems at odds with common assumptions regarding the
efficiency of financial markets. Even more puzzling is the finding that bubbles occur not only in
*
Levine: Singapore Management University, 50 Stamford Road, Singapore 178899 (e-mail: [email protected]);
Zajac: Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan Road, Evanston, Illinois 60208 (e-mail: e-
[email protected]). Robert Kurzban has contributed greatly through conversations and advice. Martin
Dufwenberg and Tobias Lindqvist have shared their instrument and advice with us most collegially. We also
benefited from the comments of Martin Conyon, Massimiliano Landi, Niro Sivanathan, and participants at the
Institutional Theory Conference at the University of Alberta, 2006 and the meeting of the American Economic
Association, Chicago 2007. Oi Ying Lam, Sun Li, and Junjie Tong provided able research support.
C 2007 Some rights reserved. You are free to copy, distribute, display, and make derivative works, as long as you
attribute the work to the authors and use it only in a non-commercial manner. For details, see Creative Commons
attribution-noncommercial 2.5 license.
Word count (including in-text citations and excluding appendixes): 2988 Last saved: 20-Jun-07 12:23:00
I. Method
II. Results
In general, our results were similar to those obtained in prior work, i.e., we observed
bubbles in most of the experimental sessions (interestingly, we find this even though the Price
and Assessment Questionnaires could have affected behavior through psychological priming
effect). More significantly, we found that discrepancies between market prices and intrinsic
values were correlated among participants and became even more so over time. We found no indication
1 With the exception of the first session, which had eight participants.
that bubbles were caused by lack of knowledge. Quite the contrary; participants had a better
understanding of the theoretical pricing model ex ante, but somewhat astonishingly -- seem to
have partly abandoned that knowledge during trading. We also find no evidence of self-serving
bias.
(1)
The average pricing discrepancy can be decomposed as:
1 1 1
10 10 10
(2)
The first term on the right-hand side of equation (2) measures the dispersion between
prices in market transactions. It is the squared distance between a price in a specific transaction
and the average price for that period, averaged across transactions and periods. The less similar
are prices in the market, the higher this component would be. The second term on the right-
hand side measures the common component. It is the squared distance between the average
price in a period and the intrinsic value for that period, averaged over periods. If price
discrepancies are serially uncorrelated and uncorrelated with the discrepancies of other
participants, this component will be zero. The higher the common component, the higher is the
similarity between the pricing discrepancies in the market.
Table 3 reveals that the common component plays a major role in the discrepancies
between market price and intrinsic values. It accounts for most of the variance in all sessions but
one. Moreover, as Figure 2 shows, the common component tends to increase during trading,
showing that errors became more correlated as trading progressed.
The results suggest that price bubbles are not simply the result of individual cognitive
bias. We found that participants exhibited better understanding of intrinsic value pricing ex ante
than ex post. However, this understanding was apparently abandoned during trading, resulting in
worse fit to the fundamental model, higher price deviation, and higher amplitude ex post.
Because we have an indication of better knowledge ex ante, individual-level bounded rationality
alone cannot explain the deviations from the fundamental model. It is unlikely that time pressure
is responsible for the poorer performance during the trading session, because participants spent
much more time trading (20 minutes) than answering the Price Questionnaire (10 minutes).
Surveying the perception of the participants about their own pricing skills and those of
the others rules out the possibility of widespread self-serving bias. Taken together with prior
findings that documented bubbles even when speculation was not possible (Vivian Lei, Charles
N. Noussair and Charles R. Plott, 2001), these findings suggest little validity in the Greater Fool
explanation.
In contrast, a decomposition of price discrepancy shows how substantial the common
component is in such discrepancies and highlights the increasing similarity in discrepancy as
trading progressed. When this analysis is taken together with the evidence about better individual
pricing skills ex ante and the absence of self-serving bias, it seems to indicate that bubbles
originate from institutionalization of social norms about pricing.
As Douglas C. North suggested: We form mental models to explain and interpret the
environment[which] may be continually redefined with new experiences, including contacts with
others ideas (emphasis added, 1994:362-63). While prior work has acknowledged that people
observe and adopt others behavior, few have theorized or documented institutionalization in
highly efficient markets, as we do here (cf. Christopher Avery and Peter Zemsky, 1998). Further,
these results show that direct communication is not be necessary for institutionalization to
appear; the mere posting of bid and asks can be sufficient to spread beliefs and sway markets
away from intrinsic value. Hence, if institutionalization appears so rapidly and profoundly in
markets designed for high efficiency, it seems reasonable to presume an even greater
institutionalization in real-world markets, financial or others, with their inherent uncertainty,
lower efficiency, and direct communication between market participants.
The findings reported here allow us to rule out explanations that turn on individual
biases and focus on institutional processes instead. A potentially fruitful path would be to
investigate how social interaction leads to the spread and formation of shared beliefs in markets,
and whether small initial differences can lead to dramatically different outcomes, as was recently
shown in markets for cultural products (Matthew J. Salganik, Peter Sheridan Dodds and Duncan
J. Watts, 2006).
Avery, Christopher and Zemsky, Peter. "Multidimensional Uncertainty and Herd Behavior in
Financial Markets." American Economic Review, 1998, 88(4), pp. 724.
Babcock, Linda and Loewenstein, George. "Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of
Self-Serving Biases." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1997, 11(1), pp. 109-26.
Bates, Robert H.; Grief, Avner; Levi, Margaret; Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent and Weingast,
Barry W. "Introduction," R. H. Bates, A. Grief, M. Levi, J.-L. Rosenthal and B. W. Weingast,
Analytic Narratives. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1998,
Camerer, Colin F. "Bubbles and Fads in Asset Prices." Journal of Economic Surveys, 1989, 3(1), pp.
3-41.
Cronbach, Lee J. "Coefficient Alpha and the Internal Structure of Tests." Psychometrika, 1951,
16, pp. 297-333.
Cyert, Richard and March, James. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice Hall, 1963.
De Long, J. Bradford; Shleifer, Andrei; Summers, Lawrence H. and Waldmann, Robert J.
"Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets." Journal of Political Economy, 1990, 98(4), pp. 703-38.
Dreman, David. "One More for the Road?," Forbes. New York, 1993, 363.
Dufwenberg, Martin; Lindqvist, Tobias and Moore, Evan. "Bubbles and Experience: An
Experiment." American Economic Review, 2005, 95(5), pp. 1731-37.
Fischbacher, Urs. "Z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-Made Economic Experiments."
Experimental Economics, Forthcoming.
Froot, Kenneth A. and Obstfeld, Maurice. "Intrinsic Bubbles: The Case of Stock Prices."
American Economic Review, 1991, 81(5), pp. 1189-214.
Garber, Peter M. "Famous First Bubbles." The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1990, 4(2), pp. 35-
54.
Haessel, Walter. "Measuring Goodness of Fit in Linear and Nonlinear Models." Southern
Economic Journal, 1978, 44(3), pp. 648-52.
Holt, Charles A. "Industrial Organization: A Survey of Laboratory Research," J. H. Kagel and
A. E. Roth, Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University
Press, 1995, 349-443.
Hommes, Cars; Sonnemans, Joep; Tuinstra, Jan and Velden, Henk van de. "Coordination
of Expectations in Asset Pricing Experiments." Review of Financial Studies, 2005, 18(3), pp. 955-80.
Keynes, John Maynard. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan,
1936.
Kindleberger, Charles P. Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises New York:
Basic Books, 1978.
King, Ronald R.; Smith, Vernon L.; Williams, Arlington W. and van Boening, Mark V.
"The Robustness of Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Stock Markets," R. H. Day and P.
Chen, Nonlinear Dynamics and Evolutionary Economics. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press,
1993,
Lei, Vivian; Noussair, Charles N. and Plott, Charles R. "Nonspeculative Bubbles in
Experimental Asset Markets: Lack of Common Knowledge of Rationality Vs. Actual
Irrationality." Econometrica, 2001, 69(4), pp. 831.
Lux, Thomas. "Herd Behaviour, Bubbles and Crashes." The Economic Journal, 1995, 105(431),
pp. 881-96.
MacKay, Charles. Memoirs of Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds. London R.
Bentley, 1841.
MacKenzie, Donald and Millo, Yuval. "Constructing a Market, Performing Theory: The
Historical Sociology of a Financial Derivatives Exchange." American Journal of Sociology, 2003,
109(1), pp. 107-45.
North, Douglass C. "Economic Performance through Time." American Economic Review, 1994,
84(3), pp. 359-68.
Podolny, Joel. Status Signals: A Sociological Study of Market Competition. Princeton, New Jersey:
Princeton University Press, 2005.
Porter, David P. and Smith, Vernon L. "Stock Market Bubbles in the Laboratory." Journal of
Behavioral Finance, 2003, 4(1), pp. 7-20.
Salganik, Matthew J.; Dodds, Peter Sheridan and Watts, Duncan J. "Experimental Study of
Inequality and Unpredictability in an Artificial Cultural Market." Science, 2006, 311(10 February
2006), pp. 854-56.
Shleifer, Andrei and Summers, Lawrence H. "The Noise Trader Approach to Finance." The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1990, 4(2), pp. 19-33.
Simon, Herbert A. "A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
1955, LXIX, pp. 99-118.
Smith, Vernon L. "An Experimental Study of Competitive Market Behavior." Journal of Political
Economy, 1962, 70(2), pp. 111-37.
Smith, Vernon L.; Suchanek, Gerry L. and Williams, Arlington W. "Bubbles, Crashes, and
Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets." Econometrica, 1988, 56(5), pp.
1119-51.
Svenson, Ola. "Are We All Less Risky and More Skillful Than Our Fellow Drivers?" Acta
Psychologica, 1981, 47, pp. 143-48.
The Economist. "Of Manias, Panics and Crashes," 2003, 64.
Topol, Richard. "Bubbles and Volatility of Stock Prices: Effect of Mimetic Contagion." The
Economic Journal, 1991, 101(407), pp. 786-800.
van Boening, Mark V.; Williams, Arlington W. and LaMaster, Shawn. "Price Bubbles and
Crashes in Experimental Call Markets." Economics Letters, 1993, 41, pp. 179-85.
Westphal, James D. and Zajac, Edward J. "Decoupling Policy from Practice: The Case of
Stock Repurchase Programs." Administrative Science Quarterly, 2001, 46(2), pp. 202-28.
White, Eugene N. "The Stock Market Boom and Crash of 1929 Revisited." The Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 1990, 4(2), pp. 67-83.
Zajac, Edward J. and Westphal, James D. "The Social Construction of Market Value:
Institutionalization and Learning Perspectives on Stock Market Reactions." American Sociological
Review, 2004, 69(3), pp. 433-57.
Zucker, Lynne G. "The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence." American Sociological
Review, 1977, 42(5), pp. 726-43.
Appendix 1a: Participant Instructions
This is an experiment in economic decision making. The instructions are simple. If you follow
the instructions carefully and make good decisions, you will earn a considerable amount of
money. It will be paid to you in cash at the end of the experiment.
In this experiment, you will assume the role of a stock trader. During each period of the
experiment, you will be able to buy shares from the other participants or sell to them shares that
you own. You also might earn dividends on shares that you own. You will decide at which prices
you are willing to buy and sell, and how many shares to hold.
You will not know the identities of the other participants or how much money they earn or lose
during the experiment. Similarly, they will not know who you are or how much money you earn
or lose. Please do not speak with any other participants during this experiment.
The experiment will last for approximately an hour, including time for instructions and practice.
The Market
Six participants will trade in the experiment. Selected randomly at the beginning of the
experiment, half will receive 6 shares and 200 cents. The other half will receive 2 shares and 600
cents.
The experiment has 10 periods. In each period, you may buy or sell shares. The shares have a
lifespan of 10 periods, and your inventory of shares carries over from one trading period to the
next. Each period lasts for 120 seconds.
At the end of each trading period, each share may or may not pay a dividend. The dividend will
be randomly decided as 0 or 20 cents, with 50 percent chance for either outcome. That is, the
chance of receiving nothing is equal to the chance of receiving 20 cents. Thus, the average
dividend per period is 10 cents.
Your profits in the market will be equal to the total of the dividends that you receive on the
shares in your inventory at the end of each market period plus the cash you have at the end of
the experiment. Section 3 describes how to calculate your earning.
10 1 10 10 100
10 2 9 10 90
10 3 8 10 80
10 4 7 10 70
10 5 6 10 60
10 6 5 10 50
10 7 4 10 40
10 8 3 10 30
10 9 2 10 20
10 10 1 10 10
Bottom
Make an Offer to Sell (in cents): Enter the amount that you demand for selling a single share.
Click the button to publish the offer. It will immediately appear in the Offers to Sell column and
will be visible to the other participants. The offer is not visible until you publish it by pressing
the button.
Buy: To buy a share, click on one of the offers in the Offers to Sell column, and click the Buy
button. Unless someone else was quicker in responding, you will receive one share and the cost
will be deducted from your cash.
Sell: To sell a share, click on one of the requests in the Requests to Buy column, and click the
Sell button. Unless someone else was quicker in responding, you will receive the amount
specified in the request and one share will be deducted from your holdings.
Make a Request to Buy (in cents): Enter the amount that you are willing to pay for a single
share. Click the button to publish the request. It will immediately appear in the Requests to Buy
column and will be visible to the other participants. The request is not visible until you publish it
by pressing the button.
Center
Offers to Sell Shows the available offers in descending price order, so that the lowest price is at
the bottom.
Transaction price column Shows all of the prices at which a share has been bought or sold in
the current period.
Requests to Buy Shows the available requests in ascending order, so that the highest price is at
the bottom.
Earnings Report
The earnings report appears at the end of each period. After seeing your earnings, press the
Next button to go to the next period. The next period will begin after all of the participants
press the Next button.
Appendix 1b: Price Questionnaire
Please write your participant number
Please take about 10 minutes to fill in this questionnaire. You may use the instruction sheet to
assist you.
1. In the 4th period, someone wants to sell you his stock. Write the maximum price you will
be willing to pay for it
2. In the 8th period, someone wants to sell you her stock. Write the maximum price you will
be willing to pay for it.
3. In the 1st period, write the minimum price you will be willing to sell a single stock for.
4. In the 3rd period, write the minimum price you will be willing to sell a single stock for.
5. In the 6th period, you are offered a single stock. Write the maximum price you will be
willing to pay for it.
6. In the 7th period, write the minimum price you will be willing to sell a single stock for.
7. In the 2nd period, you are offered a single stock. Write the maximum price you will be
willing to pay for it.
8. In the 5th period, someone offers to buy your stock. Write the minimum price you will be
willing to sell the stock for.
9. In the 9th period, someone offers to buy your stock. Write the minimum price you will be
willing to sell the stock for.
10. In the 10th period, write the maximum price you will be willing to buy a stock.
Appendix 1c: Self Assessment Questionnaire
Please write your participant number Please take about 5 minutes to fill in this questionnaire
b. Year of Birth:
c. Race:
d. Nationality:
If you have academic education or currently a university student, please answer the following:
c. What was (is) your academic major (if undecided, write undecided):
d. Have you taken any classes in Finance or Economics? Please write their full titles below:
Session
1a 2a 3a 4a 5a 6a 7a 8a 9a 10a
Haessel R2
Declared (D) 0.927 0.903 0.859 0.916 0.888 0.906 0.969 0.004 0.927 0.758
Trading (T) 0.552 0.962 0.691 0.698 0.069 0.747 0.896 0.000 0.810 0.525
T>D No Yes No No No No No No No No
Normalized Absolute Price Deviation
Declared (D) 0.356 0.279 0.779 0.675 0.454 0.392 0.288 0.793 0.452 0.456
Trading (T) 0.594 0.176 0.567 0.757 1.342 0.394 0.167 1.289 0.203 1.856
T>D Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes No Yes
Normalized Average Price Deviation
Declared (D) 0.016 0.036 0.083 0.067 0.044 0.041 0.083 0.113 0.057 0.052
Trading (T) 0.142 0.040 0.120 0.131 0.162 0.092 0.034 0.204 0.039 0.295
T>D Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No Yes
Price Amplitude
Declared (D) 0.119 0.123 0.317 0.367 0.195 0.133 0.142 0.602 0.200 0.398
Trading (T) 0.678 0.149 0.560 0.443 0.786 0.479 0.186 0.785 0.395 1.329
T>D Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Table 1: Measures of Goodness of Fit, Price Deviation, and Price Amplitude for Average
Declared versus Trading Prices
Construct No. of Mean Standard Cronbachs
Items Deviation Alpha
Participants self-assessment 3 2.90 1.04 0.79
Participants assessment of the other participants 6 3.00 0.79 0.69
Participants assessment of the other 3 2.95 0.77 0.83
participants perception of him/her
1 1 1
10 10 10
Table 3: Decomposition of the average individual pricing discrepancy into dispersion and
common components
Figure 1: Illustration of declared, intrinsic, and actual prices over trading periods
Legend (left to right): average trading price; average present value (intrinsic value); maximum present value possible
(intrinsic value); average declared value in Pricing Questionnaire.
Figure 2: Illustration of common component in price discrepancy over trading periods