Juhn Murphy Pierce PDF
Juhn Murphy Pierce PDF
Juhn Murphy Pierce PDF
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.
Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpress.
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Journal of Political Economy.
http://www.jstor.org
Wage Inequality and the Rise
in Returns to Skill
ChinhuiJuhn
Universityof Houston
KevinM. Murphy
Universityof Chicago
Brooks Pierce
TexasA&M University
I. Introduction
Between 1963 and 1989, the average weekly wage of working men
increased by about 20 percent. However, as we show in this paper,
This research was supported by grants from the National Science Foundation and
the Sloan Foundation.
[Journal of Political Economy, 1993, vol. 101, no. 3]
) 1993 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/93/0103-0001$01.50
410
WAGE INEQUALITY 411
these real wage gains were not spread equally across workers. Wages
for the least skilled, as measured by the tenth percentile of the wage
distribution, fell by about 5 percent, and wages for the most skilled,
as measured by the ninetieth percentile of the wage distribution, in-
creased by about 40 percent. Comparisons of 1989 with 1970 reveal
similar differences. While real wages for the median worker were 5
percent lower in 1989 than in 1970, wages for workers at the ninetieth
percentile were more than 15 percent higher in 1989 than in 1970.
This 15 percent increase in real wages contrasts even more sharply
with a 25 percent decline in real wages for workers at the tenth per-
centile of the wage distribution. Looking within education and experi-
ence categories reveals even more striking changes. Real wages for
tenth percentile high school graduates with 1-10 years of experience
are about 15 percent lower today than wages for the same group in
1963. In fact almost 40 percent of today's workers with 1-10 years
of experience earn less than workers at the corresponding percentile
in 1963.
The net result of this divergence in earnings between the most
skilled and the least skilled has been an enormous increase in wage
inequality. According to our calculations, the variance of log weekly
wages increased by about 72 percent from 1963 through 1989. These
findings are broadly consistent with the findings of others who have
recently looked at inequality (see, e.g., Bluestone and Harrison
[1988], Bluestone [1989], Levy [1989], or many of the studies cited
in Sawhill [1988]). While the basic facts support the general trends
identified in previous work, we feel that there are many unique com-
ponents of our analysis as well. First, much of the inequality literature
has focused on earnings or income as a measure of welfare rather
than on wages, which are more closely related to market prices for
human capital components. We believe that the emphasis on wages
as prices, instead of on incomes, allows us to make several important
contributions to this literature. In addition, we push our analysis in
a somewhat different direction and describe more clearly the timing
of the increase in overall inequality, decompose the increase in in-
equality into components accounted for by observable differences
across workers (e.g., age and education) and inequality within these
classifications, and finally evaluate some simple alternative explana-
tions. Each of these points adds significantly to our understanding of
the recent history of wage inequality.
Throughout the paper we interpret the dispersion in wages, after
controlling for observable skill determinants, as a distribution of un-
observable ability in the population in conjunction with a current
market value of this unobservable ability. In particular, we view the
trend toward increased inequality not in terms of increased disper-
412 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
survey. The data from the 1960 census refer to earnings and weeks
worked in 1959. As a result, our sample measures wages for 1959
and 1963-89. Throughout the paper we focus on log weekly wages
or log hourly wages for full-time workers (defined as those that usu-
ally work 35 hours or more per week). We deflate annual earnings
by the personal consumption expenditure deflator from the National
Income and Product Accounts and define the log average weekly
wage as the natural logarithm of deflated annual wage and salary
earnings divided by weeks worked and the log hourly wage as the
natural logarithm of deflated annual wage and salary earnings di-
vided by the product of weeks worked and usual weekly hours. We
present initial analyses for both weekly and hourly wages and focus
on weekly wages for the remainder of the results.
For purposes of analysis we selected a sample that we felt would
be representative of workers with a reasonably strong labor force
attachment. Our sample inclusion criteria were that the workers be
aged 18-65, work full time, not be self-employed or working without
pay, not live in group quarters, work at least 14 weeks, have a positive
number of years of potential labor market experience, not work part
of a year because of retirement or school, and earn a minimum of
$67 per week in 1982 dollars (equal to one-half of the 1982 real
minimum based on a 40-hour week). We imputed weekly earnings
for workers top-coded at the census maximum as 1.33 times the top-
coded value. For the most part, the qualitative results in the paper
are not sensitive to the exclusion and imputation procedures we used.
The one major exception is the exclusion of workers earning less
than half of the real 1982 minimum wage. When these workers are
included, wage inequality actually declines somewhat more over the
1963-69 period. For example, when these workers are included, the
log weekly wage differential between the ninetieth and tenth percen-
tiles falls by three points from 1963 to 1969, whereas in our reported
results it actually rises slightly. This distinction, however, does arise
for other time periods. The question of whether one believes that
wage differentials fell or remained stable over the late 1960s turns
on the credibility one lends to these relatively extreme observations.
In previous versions of this paper we noted that because of changes
in the survey structure between the 1975 and 1976 surveys (wage
data for 1974 and 1975), measured inequality dropped significantly.
We have subsequently been able to overcome most of this problem
by improving our predictions of weeks and hours worked last year,
deleting all individuals with imputed wage and salary information,
and excluding self-employed workers on the basis of the existence of
any significant self-employment income (i.e., those with nega-
tive self-employment income or more than $100 [1982] of self-
WAGE INEQUALITY 415
140.00 -
g130.00-
3U
.00
M 1200
V
0)
D 110.00
'-4
100.00
140.00
130.00 -
o 120.00-
cc
v110.00
100.00
10.0 I f I I I I l I Ii I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
65 70 75 80 85
YEAR
FIG.2.-Indexed real hourly wages by percentile, 1963-89
WAGE INEQUALITY 417
0.40
0
0I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
to
X
W
0.20
.' 0.10-
Co
D 0.00
-0.10
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
PERCENTILE
FIG. 3.-Log real wage changes by percentile, 1964-88
00
to~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~b
I~~
U, ~~~ , 0 0 0
W
'4~~~~~~~~~-
ww , , '4
w
0 w 0 '
a o In o f o o~~~~~n
o - o In l~~~~~~~~~~~~~
I
Ia a in 0 0 i0 0 0I
0
0 0 0 00 0 V
1 a, V
TABLE 1
INEQUALITY MEASURES FOR LOG WAGES OF MEN, 1959-88
NOTE.-Standard errors are in parentheses. Data for 1964-88 are 3-year averages of surrounding years from
1964-90 March Current Population Surveys. Data for 1959 are taken from the 1960 Public Use Micro Census
Tapes.
0.30 -
,?0.20 -
a 0.10
0.00
-0.10
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
PERCENTILE
FIG. 5.-Estimated wage change by percentile, 1964-88
that workers at the tenth percentile have lost about 7 percent in real
terms, whereas workers at the ninetieth percentile have gained almost
25 percent. Among the older group, workers at the tenth percentile
gain about 3 percent (about the same as the median worker in the
younger group) and workers at the ninetieth percentile gain about
39 percent. On the basis of these calculations, it seems that the in-
crease in inequality is about the same for both experience groups (in
fact it is also quite similar for those with 11-20 years of experience
and only slightly smaller for those with more than 30 years of expe-
rience).
One message from figure 5 that will continue throughout the paper
is that the increase in wage inequality shows up both between and
within groups. As a result, while we can say that older workers have
gained relative to younger workers as a whole, it is still true that the
highest-paid among the youngest workers (say the ninetieth percen-
tile) have gained relative to the lowest-paid (or even the twenty-fifth
percentile) older worker.
One of the most striking things about figure 5 is that for the lowest
40 percent of younger workers, real wages are lower in 1988 than
for the corresponding group in 1964! Hence for two-fifths of all
younger workers there has been no increase in economic opportunity
as measured by weekly wage rates in about two and one-half decades.
Figure 6 breaks things down still further by looking at real wage
422 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
0.30 -
0.20 -
a)
C"
c 0.10
a)
3
0.00
0 _
-J
-0.10
-0.20
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
PERCENTILE
FIG. 6.-Estimated wage change by percentile, 1964-88
changes for high school and college graduates for workers with 1-10
years of experience. As with the experience contrasts shown in figure
5, the between-group differential moved in the direction of greater
inequality, with college graduates gaining on high school graduates
at all percentile levels. The gains for college graduates relative to high
school graduates are very similar at all percentiles above the twenti-
eth, with college graduates gaining about 20 percent relative to high
school graduates.
The increases in inequality within a group are equally striking.
High school graduates at the ninetieth percentile gained about 9 per-
cent in real terms from 1964 to 1988, whereas high school graduates
at the tenth percentile lost about 15 percent in real terms. The data
in figure 6 imply that the bottom 40 percent of high school graduates
with 1-10 years of experience earn 10- 17 percent less than the corre-
sponding workers in 1964. In fact only the top 30 percent of young
high school graduates have gained in real terms since 1964. The
relative wage changes for college graduates show a similar increase
in inequality, with the ninetieth percentile college graduates gaining
about 25 percent and the tenth percentile college graduates losing
slightly less than 5 percent. As in the experience calculation described
above, this large increase in within-group inequality implies that while
college graduates gained on high school graduates as a whole, the
WAGE INEQUALITY 423
best high school graduates (say the ninetieth percentile) gained sig-
nificantly on the low-end college graduates (say the tenth percentile).
The basic message of figures 5 and 6 is that wage inequality has
increased significantly within groups defined by experience and edu-
cation. Table 2 takes this analysis one step further by looking at the
distribution of regression residuals from a regression of log weekly
wages on a very flexible specification of education and experience
effects.' Looking at regression residuals allows us to look within very
narrowly defined education and experience categories. A striking fea-
ture of the table is the similarity of the inequality measures for 1959
and 1970. Apparently there was very little change in within-group
inequality over the 11 years from 1959 to 1970. In contrast, the pe-
riod from 1970 to 1988 is characterized by an enormous increase in
inequality, with workers at the ninetieth percentile of the residual
distribution gaining about 26 percent relative to workers at the tenth
percentile.
To understand the magnitude of the changes we describe, consider
the following frame of reference. In 1964 the standard deviation of
log weekly wages was .45, from table 1. In 1988 the standard devia-
tion based on regression residuals was approximately .49, from table
2. This means that wage inequality as measured by standard devia-
tions rose by an amount greater than the predictive power of the
observables in our wage equation. The magnitude of the inequality
increase is greater than the wage variation explainable by experience
and education combined.2
As stated in the Introduction, we view this increase in within-group
wage inequality as a trend toward higher skill prices. However, the
argument could be made that it is the result of increased dispersion
in unobserved ability within recent entry cohorts due to, say, increas-
ingly unequal educational opportunities. To evaluate this potential
objection, table 3 documents wage inequality growth over time within
synthetic cohort groups. Panel A gives the ninetieth-tenth percentile
differential for log weekly wages of various 6-year entry cohorts. One
follows a cohort over time by moving horizontally across columns
within the same row. One follows the same experience group over
time by moving upward along a diagonal (those who enter in 1959-64
have the same experience level in 1964 as entrants in 1965-70 do in
1970). Within cohorts, inequality changes over time are attributable
1 We estimated a wage equation with education dummies for less than high school,
high school, some college, and college graduates and with linear terms in education
within these groups. The regressions also include a quartic in experience fully inter-
acted with the education variables and regional dummies.
2 Typically, education and experience observables can explain about a quarter to a
third of the observed log weekly wage variation in a cross-sectional regression.
424 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
TABLE 2
INEQUALITY MEASURES BASED ON REGRESSION RESIDUALS FOR MEN, 1959-88
NOTE.-Data for 1964-88 are 3-year averages of surrounding years from 1964-90 March Current Population
Surveys. Data for 1959 are taken from the 1960 Public Use Micro Census Tapes.
TABLE 3
1983-88 1.38
1977-82 1.27 1.38
1971-76 1.13 1.24 1.38
1965-70 1.08 1.12 1.29 1.42
1959-64 1.13 1.01 1.13 1.30 1.40
1953-58 1.02 1.07 1.16 1.32 1.43
1947-52 1.02 1.11 1.15 1.30
1941-46 1.02 1.07 1.16
1935-40 1.06 1.09
1929-34 1.09
Average Changes within Cohorts and Experience Levels
1983-88 1.09
1977-82 1.06 1.16
1971-76 .96 1.09 1.18
1965-70 .86 .96 1.12 1.23
1959-64 .92 .86 .98 1.12 1.21
1953-58 .88 .91 .99 1.15 1.26
1947-52 .89 .94 .99 1.14
1941-46 .94 .94 1.05
1935-40 .95 .98
1929-34 .99
Average Changes within Cohorts and Experience Levels
Of course, it is possible that cohort and age effects are equal and
have such a magnitude as to appear to be time effects. This follows
from the usual identification problem arising when one tries to sepa-
rate cohort, age, and time effects. While we cannot calculate growth
in inequality over time separately from inequality growth across co-
horts and ages, we can identify the change in inequality growth over
time. We can difference inequality measures within a cohort (elimi-
nating the cohort effect) and compare this difference across adjacent
426 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
cohorts (eliminating the age effect and leaving only a change in in-
equality growth over time). From table 3 we can see that this is identi-
cal to comparing the average changes within cohorts over time. Since
the aver-age change within a cohort from 1964 to 1970 is much
smaller than the changes across later 6-year periods, we know that
the data indicate an accelerating increase in inequality with time that
cannot be explained by any combinations of cohort and age effects.
Given these data, we interpret increasing inequality over time as
arising mainly from increasing skill prices, and not from changes in
the distributions of unobservable skill quantities. In the following
section we present a framework that attempts to quantify the contri-
bution of changing observable quantities, observable prices, and
prices of unobservables to the overall increase in inequality.
Cqc~~~~~~~~~~~~C
=~~~~~~~~~~~
.1
* S~~~~~~
q 0 .4
a 0a 0 0 0 a 0 0aa 0 0 0
I I I I I I I I
rT;iuojo.ina o.ki DBa, CI0 a; uoa;;lqj;.Juo3 TvluWmdu;TO *Bmg bol 0;-O* D; ua;~nqj;.iuaj
bC
4V-
I.
0~~~~~~~~
.4
* ~ ~ ~ ~ ~4~~~
.4
0 ~~0
.4 .4 .4
0
0
.4
#a
.4
0
cm
.
0
"a
0
0
I
a0
0
00
q
00
"a
00 0
Pd
.4
U
.
4 0~ I
In this case we predict wages for each worker in year t given his
observable characteristics and the wage equation estimated for year t
and again assign him a residual based on the cumulative distribution
for all years. Finally, if we allow observable prices and quantities and
the distribution of residuals to change through time, we obtain
TABLE 4
OBSERVABLE AND UNOBSERVABLE COMPONENTS OF CHANGES IN INEQUALITY
Unobserved
Total Observed Observed Prices and
Change Quantities Prices Quantities
Differential (1) (2) (3) (4)
A. 1964-88
NOTE.-The years refer to the middle point of the 3-year interval. Col. I gives the change in the indicated
statistics over the years shown. Components in cols. 2-4 are calculated on the basis of the full distribution accounting
scheme outlined in the text.
170 -
160 -
150-
U
m. 140-
H
130-
V
D 1
1204
V
110
100
65 70 75 80 85
YEAR
FIG. 8.-Skill price indexes for men, 1963-89 (1963/64 = 100)
TABLE 5
INDUSTRY AND OCCUPATION DISTRIBUTION BY PERCENTILES, 1959-89
PERCENTILES
Industry:
Agriculture/mining 1.20 2.33 2.63
Construction 13.34 8.66 8.93
Manufacturing:
Low-tech 9.03 2.75 1.87
Basic 11.85 17.26 10.18
High-tech 6.54 15.52 17.77
Commercial transportation
and utilities 5.66 10.84 9.49
Wholesale 4.86 5.55 6.75
Retail 21.66 9.60 5.96
Professional services, finance,
insurance, and real estate 9.91 8.58 21.90
Education and welfare 5.26 6.13 5.16
Public administration 2.56 10.02 7.75
Other service 8.14 2.75 1.62
Occupation:
Professional/technical 5.19 15.27 31.11
Managers 5.09 12.71 38.64
Sales 4.99 5.29 8.88
Clerical 6.44 8.71 2.17
Craft 20.14 27.20 12.50
Operatives 20.37 14.18 2.36
Transportation operatives 8.94 6.69 2.35
Laborer 12.76 4.74 .69
Farm private household .57 .09 .00
Service 15.52 5.13 1.30
434 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
3 Given the rapid rise in skill premia over the period, these "measured" demand
shifts must understate the "true" changes in demand that would have occurred with
fixed skill prices.
00
o 0
* 0
a 0
la
so 1~~~~~~~~~~~~~~m~C
di~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~nI
-0~~~~~~~~~~
W4 I IR W!~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~"4 b
"4
0 0 0
.4 .4 "
0 0
0 "
0
-0 CZ-
b0
z
-.M
00
TABLE 6
EFFECTS OF INDUSTRIAL COMPOSITION ON WAGE INEQUALITY, 1967-89
WITHIN-INDUSTRY BETWEEN-INDUSTRY
roughly 100 percent). Given that wage premia have increased in spite
of this enormous growth in supply, it seems clear that there must
have been significant growth in the demand for education. One view
for the fall in education returns over the 1970s and the subsequent
rapid rise in the 1980s (suggested by Murphy and Welch [1989]) is
that supply grew faster than demand over the 1970s and then slower
than demand during the 1980s. Similarly, perhaps much of the in-
crease in the returns to experience can be attributed to the arrival of
the baby boom cohorts and the associated youthening of the labor
force. However, as Katz and Murphy (1992) point out, this does not
seem to be a sufficient explanation for the rapid rise in experience
returns in the 1980s as the baby boom cohorts moved up in the age
distribution.
A complete explanation of the economic phenomena behind the
data we have described would appear to require at least two addi-
tional components. First, it seems clear from the data that the demand
for skill has risen. Further research must identify the sources of this
demand shift; likely but untested candidates are biased rates of tech-
nological progress and changes in the world economy. Also, an accu-
rate description of the determinants of the timing in observable skill
prices requires explicit consideration of supply and demand forces
for the skill in question. Continued success in understanding the
forces bringing about greater wage inequality hinges on the progress
of future work in these areas.
3~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1
001~~~~~~~~~
h 0
s r ra rw o o o o o. o.o.Ii
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 00
C
u/>m1 A14u" SD01 40 *uUTJUA on ;uuOdUo3 *3UUIJBoA
C"
bio
CZ
CZ
I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
CZ
I~~~~~~~~~~ c
ri~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~r
what from the mid-1960s through about 1968 and has increased sig-
nificantly since. Business cycle swings are also clearly important, as
evidenced by the large increases in inequality during the recessions
of 1971, 1975, and 1982. Overall from 1968 through 1989 the vari-
ance of log earnings increased by about 80 percent (from .25 to .45).
The remaining panels of the figure decompose this increase into the
weeks worked variance, the weekly wage variance, and the covariance
of weekly wages and weeks worked. Since annual earnings are simply
the product of weeks worked and the weekly wage, we can write the
log of annual earnings as
y =+ w, (11)
where y is the log of annual earnings, 1 is the log of weeks worked,
and w is the log weekly wage. Using this notation we can write the
variance of log annual earnings, r2, as
cr2 = as-2 + (3-2 + 2cwx(12)
where a 2 is the variance of log weekly wages, ar is the variance of
log weeks worked, and au1 is the covariance of log earnings and log
weeks. The variance of weekly wages is shown in panel B of figure
10 and follows a pattern quite similar to the ninetieth-tenth percentile
log wage differential shown in figure 7. The variance of weekly wages
is very steady from 1963 through 1968 and then increases relatively
smoothly from 1968 until 1986. In contrast, the variance of log weeks
(panel C) shows a distinct cyclic pattern, with sharp rises in 1970-71,
1975, and 1982. This cyclic pattern results from the fact that reduc-
tions in annual hours are very unevenly distributed across workers
(i.e., relatively few workers work many fewer weeks).
The covariance term in panel D reflects the growing positive associ-
ation between wages and time worked. As two of us have found in
our other work (Juhn, Murphy, and Topel 1991; Juhn 1992), this
strengthening of the cross-sectional labor supply relationship occurs
mostly prior to 1975, after which the relationship is relatively stable.
Over the period as a whole, the increase in the weekly wage variance
accounts for about .14 of the overall .18 increase in the annual earn-
ings variance. The remainder is attributable to the increased variance
of weeks worked and a small rise in the covariance of weekly wages
and weeks worked.
We stress the need to distinguish between the earnings and wage
inequality concepts. For example, because of the highly cyclic pattern
of weeks worked, the variance of log annual earnings is actually lower
in 1989 than in 1982, whereas the variance of weekly wages is actually
about 20 percent higher in 1989 than in 1982. As measured by the
variance of log annual earnings, inequality is lower now than in 1982,
WAGE INEQUALITY 441
but as measured by weekly wages, it is significantly higher. This strik-
ing example serves as a warning to keep in mind which inequality
concept is of interest for a particular problem.
VII. Conclusion
In this paper we have identified the enormous increase in wage in-
equality among male workers over the past two decades. The trend
toward greater wage inequality is attributable primarily to increases
in the premia on both unobserved and observed (such as education)
dimensions of skill, with the majority of the increase over the period
due to the unobserved component. We also show that the timing of
the increased premium on the unobserved components of skill differs
from the timing of changes in the skill premia on education and labor
market experience. In particular, returns to unobservable skills have
shown a steady increase since 1970.
Our basic rationale for this increase is the rapid growth in demand
for skilled workers. While it seems clear that skill premia have risen
and hence that the demand for skill has risen as well, the exact source
of this demand increase is as yet unknown; likely candidates are bi-
ased rates of technological progress and changes in the world econ-
omy. We feel that further progress in comprehending the increases
in wage inequality documented here will require a greater under-
standing of these fundamental underlying forces.
References
Bluestone, Barry. "The Changing Nature of Employment and Earnings in
the U.S. Economy: 1963-1987." Paper prepared for the Conference on
Job Creation in America, Univ. North Carolina, Chapel Hill, April 1989.
Bluestone, Barry, and Harrison, Bennett. "The Growth of Low-Wage Em-
ployment: 1963-86." A.E.R. Papers and Proc. 78 (May 1988): 124-28.
Borjas, George J. "Assimilation, Changes in Cohort Quality, and the Earnings
of Immigrants."J. Labor Econ. 3 (October 1985): 463-89.
Chiswick, Barry R. "Is the New Immigration Less Skilled than the Old?"
J. Labor Econ. 4 (April 1986): 168-92.
Juhn, Chinhui. "Decline of Male Labor Market Participation: The Role of
Declining Market Opportunities." QJ.E. 107 (February 1992): 79-121.
Juhn, Chinhui; Murphy, Kevin M.; and Pierce, Brooks. "Accounting for the
Slowdown in Black-White Wage Convergence." In Workersand Their Wages:
Changing Patterns in the United States, edited by Marvin H. Kosters. Washing-
ton: American Enterprise Inst. Press, 1991.
Juhn, Chinhui; Murphy, Kevin M.; and Topel, Robert H. "Why Has the
Natural Rate of Unemployment Increased over Time?" Brookings Papers
Econ. Activity, no. 2 (1991), pp. 75-142.
Katz, Lawrence, and Murphy, Kevin M. "Changes in the Wage Structure
442 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY