Reforming The Public Expenditure Management System (MTEF)
Reforming The Public Expenditure Management System (MTEF)
Reforming The Public Expenditure Management System (MTEF)
35107
Management System:
Medium-Term Expenditure Framework,
Performance Management, and Fiscal Transparency
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Conference Program
CHAPTER 18. Information Flow for Successful MTEF Operation and its
Implication for the Korea Government .............................................. 279
1. Introduction .......................................................................................... 279
2. MTEF, FMIS, and other public expenditure reforms ..................... 280
3. New information needs for MTEF operation .................................. 282
4. Inadequacy of current FMIS to support MTEF ............................... 286
5. Implementation strategy for improving FMIS and MTEF ............. 290
References ................................................................................................. 298
Table 4-1. The objectives and their matching policy tools of MTEF................ 45
Table 4-2. Comparison of single year budgeting and MTEF............................ 45
Table 4-3. Annual procedure of MTEF ................................................................ 48
Table 4-4. Time coverage of MTEF....................................................................... 50
Table 4-5. Fixed vs. flexible MTEF ....................................................................... 54
Table 12-9. Areas of assessment and evaluation tasks for general secondary
schools of Seoul metropolitan office of education ...................... 179
Table 12-10. Accountability-Strengthening Program ...................................... 185
Table 13-1. Performance information definitions and sample indicators .... 189
Table 13-2. Possible composition of a national oversight steering committee ... 191
Table 13-3. The responsibilities of the national oversight offices .................. 199
Table 13-4. Decisions at the ministerial and agency levels ............................. 200
Table 13-5. Criteria for selecting issues for program evaluations ................. 215
Table 13-6. Suggested elements in a states strategic planning process........ 221
Honorable Minister,
Distinguished participants from the World Bank and other organizations,
Ladies and gentlemen,
On behalf of the Korea Development Institute, it is my pleasure to welcome you all
to the Joint Conference of the World Bank and KDI on Reforming the Public
Expenditure Management System. I would like to give a special welcome to Minister
Byungil Kim of the Ministry of Planning and Budget who sponsored this Conference.
I want to start by thanking the organizers from the World Bank, Ministry of
Planning and Budget, and KDI for their dedicated efforts. I am pleased to see so many
leading experts from the international community who came here to share knowledge
and experience.
Ladies and gentlemen,
KDI was established in 1971 as the first government-funded research institute in
social science. At the time of its inception, KDI focused on policy issues related to the
Five-Year Economic Development Plans, which served as a basis for economic
management in those days. As Korea made a democratic transition in the 1980s, social
issues such as welfare and balanced regional growth came to the fore, and were
accorded a greater weight in KDIs research agenda. This change was consistent with
its mission as a policy-oriented research institution devoted to the development in
the broad sense of the term. In fact, KDI is distinguished from other government-
funded research institutions for its extensive coverage of research areas and its
comprehensive approach.
An important area of research throughout this period has been fiscal policy. Fiscal
policy addresses both macroeconomic and microeconomic issues. It is an important
determinant of the macroeconomic stability of a nation in the long and the short term; a
prudent management of government liabilities is critical for the long-term price
stability and economic growth, and a flexible management of budget balances is
essential to dampen the short-term cyclical fluctuations.
From a microeconomic perspective, fiscal policy is concerned about reallocating
national resources across different sectors. Government policies are implemented in
most part through expenditures on education, defense, infrastructure investment,
income security, health, environmental protection, and others. These sectoral policies
are collated against each other and prioritized in the annual budget process. In this
way, fiscal policy works as a disciplining mechanism to impose an overall resource
constraint on sectoral demands and maximize the efficiency of public expenditure.
Ladies and gentlemen,
The recent economic crisis that hit the Korean economy at the end of 1997 left an
unmistakable mark in every policy area, including the fiscal policy. The budget balance
deteriorated substantially, and government liabilities doubled in a matter of two years.
However, the rapid recovery in 1999 and 2000 contributed to the regained tranquility in
xii Welcoming Remarks
public finance, with the balance showing surpluses and the debt-to-GDP ratio
stabilizing at around 20 percent in the following years.
But challenges still remain. Revenue growth is expected to slow down as the
potential growth rate of the Korean economy declines. At the same time, pressures for
increased spending are building up to prepare the Korean economy for the intensifying
global competition, support the financial-sector restructuring, and finance the
expanding welfare programs. In addition, public demand for a transparent
management of taxmoney is increasing.
Faced with these challenges, we found that a thorough reexamination of the public
expenditure management system was called for. We need a system that enables us to
implement fiscal policy in a strategic way to fulfill all of its promises; contributing to
the long- and short-term macroeconomic stability and maximizing the allocative and
operational efficiency of public expenditure.
Three issues were selected for our study; (1) medium-term expenditure framework,
(2) performance management, and (3) fiscal transparency. Each of them represents a
significant departure from the past mode of expenditure management. They are
complementary to and interdependent on each other.
The Ministry of Planning and Budget has already made some progress in
introducing elements of the needed reforms in these areas. Our study builds on these
efforts and aims to provide directions for further improvement. It began early last year
and has been carried out in collaboration with the World Bank, with the financial
support from the Ministry of Planning and Budget.
This Conference was organized to present our major findings and gather a broad
range of inputs from many sources. It will provide a forum for debating policy options
for reforming the public expenditure management system. I hope at the end of the
Conference, we can have a better understanding on this matter. Any contribution
toward providing new thoughts and insights will prove to be both important and
meaningful, and will be incorporated into our final report to the Ministry of Planning
and Budget. The report will be published next month in Korean.
Ladies and gentlemen,
Now with my welcoming remarks complete, let me turn the floor over to Minister
Byungil Kim of the Ministry of Planning and Budget.
I wish you all an informative and productive conference.
Thank you.
Keynote Speech
Byung-il Kim
(Minister of Planning and Budget)
1. Introduction
Dr. Choong-Soo Kim, President of KDI,
Mr. Bill Dorotinsky, Lead Public Sector Specialist of the World Bank, and
distinguished guests from around the world!
It is my great honor to have this opportunity to be the keynote speaker at today's
joint conference of the World Bank and KDI, and talk about fiscal reform in Korea.
I would like to begin by extending my compliments to the staff of the World Bank
and KDI for their devoted research on Reforming the Public Expenditure Management
System, initiated by the Korean Government last year.
In addition, it is my pleasure to welcome the participants from various countries
and international organizations such as the World Bank and IMF, who have travelled a
long way to be here today.
Thank you for your participation.
One of the recent global trends is that the role of public finance as a policy tool is
becoming increasingly important, as the scope of government intervention in the
economy becomes smaller.
In addition, budget deficits and national debt can have direct effects on the
national economy under the open economic system, and are important factors in
deciding national credit ratings. Therefore, in reality, the influence of public finance on
national economy is significant.
Under such circumstances, Korea's fiscal management environment is changing
rapidly.
Internally, economic and social structures are changing and the demand of the
citizens is becoming more diverse.
Externally, the security situation in the Korean Peninsula is changing, and the
world economy is shifting into bloc economies such as FTAs, constantly giving rise to
new demands for public expenditure.
In the short-term, there are demands for building a Northeast Asian Economic
Hub, and R&D for the development of new growth-driving forces. Moreover, the need
for additional spending in the agricultural sector restructuring is rising, to meet
international standards including the opening of the agricultural market.
In the long-term, public expenditure in the areas of public pension, health
insurance, and welfare for the aged population is expected to increase substantially due
to rapid population ageing.
xiv Keynote Speech
On the other hand, the revenue situation is expected to become more difficult, as
the Korean economy gradually turns into a stable low-growth economy.
In response to such changes in the fiscal management environment, it is time to
make substantial changes in the public expenditure management system to enhance the
productivity of public finance.
The Korean government is implementing 3 fiscal reform tasks since the inauguration of the
Participatory Government, to enhance the efficiency of public spending while maintaining fiscal
soundness.
Firstly, in contrast to previous medium-term fiscal plans that were formulated
irregularly, a National Fiscal Management Plan was formulated last year, to be revised
and updated every year, allowing the efficient allocation of national resources from a
mid to long-term perspective.
The Plan sets aggregate objectives of national fiscal management based on a 5-year
macroeconomic outlook and projected public expenditure requirements, and presents
sectoral resource allocation priorities and spending size by budgetary programs.
Furthermore, a Top-down budgeting system will be introduced this year.
Accordingly, expenditure ceilings will be set using the total budget size and sectoral
and ministerial resource allocation sizes presented in the National Fiscal Management
Plan.
After an agreement on sectoral and ministerial ceilings has been reached, each line
ministry will autonomously formulate their respective budgets within the expenditure
ceilings. The budget will be finalized after a final consultation with the Ministry of
Planning and Budget.
In response to such changes in the fiscal management system, a Performance
Management System is being introduced at the same time, to ensure accountability
against expanded autonomy of the line ministries.
Last year, performance goals and indicators have been developed for some of the
budgetary programs in 22 line ministries. Beginning this year, the system will be
gradually expanded to encompass more ministries and programs, with its full
introduction scheduled for the year 2008.
Turning to the issue of the coverage of public finance and fiscal transparency,
Korea's coverage of public finance has been rather limited compared to
international standards. This gave rise to the problem of making it difficult to perform
international comparisons in fiscal size and balance, expenditure by areas, and national
debt.
The Korean government has formulated a plan to revise the coverage of public
finance, and will begin implementing the plan this year. As a result, it will be possible
to assess and analyze budgetary activities in accordance to international standards.
In this process, detailed reviews of international standards and country cases will
be of great help.
I would like to take this opportunity to request the valuable advice and
information from the international experts here at the conference.
Keynote Speech xv
3. Conclusion
This international conference will offer an opportunity to discuss a variety of
policy recommendations and proposals. I trust that these will provide momentum for
reforming the public expenditure management system in Korea, and serve as references
for fiscal reform in other countries as well.
Distinguished guests from around the world!
Thank you again for your participation.
Although your stay in Seoul will only be a week long, I hope you will take time to
enjoy the beautiful atmosphere of spring in Korea.
May your stay in the Land of the Morning Calm leave you with pleasant and
unforgettable memories of the Korean culture.
Thank you.
Conference Program
16:00 17:00 Topic 3: Successful Installation of MTEF to the Korean Fiscal System
Presenter: Seok-kyun Hur (Associate Fellow, Korea Development Institute)
Discussants: YoungJoo Lee (Deputy Director, Ministry of Finance and Economy,
Republic of Korea),
Dang Huu Phap (Deputy Director, Ministry of Finance, Vietnam)
15:15 17:00 Panel Discussion: Lessons from International Experiences on Performance Management
Moderator: SungIl Lim (Senior Fellow, Korea Research Institute for Local Administration)
Discussants: Joel Turkewitz (Senior Public Sector Specialist, World Bank)
Youngsun Koh (Fellow, Korea Development Institute)
Ohbong Kwon (Director, Ministry of Planning and Budget, Republic of Korea)
Saravuth Sok (Deputy Director, Ministry of Finance and Economy, ambodia)
Sanya Praseuth (Deputy Director General, Ministry of Finance, Lao PDR)
10:20 11:20 Topic 2: Information Flow under the Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Presenter: Junghun Cho (Public Sector Specialist, World Bank)
Discussants: Seok-kyun Hur (Associate Fellow, Korea Development Institute)
Geum-Nam Kim (Senior Deputy Director, Ministry of Finance and
Economy, Republic of Korea)
11:20 11:30 Break
Batsukh Batmunkh
Vice Director
Mongolian Development Institute
Government Building-3
Baga Toiruu-44
Ulaanbaatar-20a, Mongolia
Phone: (976) 11-322311
Fax: (976) 11-324518
Email: [email protected]
Munkyu Bang
Director
Industrial Public Finance Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5045
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7980
Email: [email protected]
Yangkyoon Byeon
Vice Minister
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5100
Fax: (82) 2-3496-5104
Email: [email protected]
Junghun Cho
Consultant
Public Sector Group
The World Bank
Phone: (1) 202-458-0661
Fax: (1) 202-522-7132
Email: [email protected]
xxiv List of Participants
Bill Dorotinsky
Lead Public Sector Specialist
Public Sector Group
The World Bank
Phone: (1) 202-473-7189
Fax: (1) 202-614-1065
Email: [email protected]
Niklas Frank
Deputy Secretary
Committee on Finance
Swedish Parliament
100 12 Stockholm, Sweden
Phone: (46) 8-786-5935
Fax: (46) 8-786-6171
Email: [email protected]
Allan Gustafsson
President
Mapsec
Kungsbron 1, D4, Stockholm
Sweden
Phone: (46) 708-24 24 34
Fax: (46) 8-506 362 01
Email: [email protected]
Harry P Hatry
Research Associate
Office of Public Affairs
The Urban Institute
2100 M Street, NW
Washington, DC 20037
USA
Phone: (1) 202-261-5709
Email: [email protected]
Ratanak Hav
Deputy Director
Department of Economic Integration and ASEAN
List of Participants xxv
Dongho Hong
Director
Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5028
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7625
Email: [email protected]
Seok-kyun Hur
Associate Fellow
Division of Public Finance and Social Development
Korea Development Institute
Phone: (82) 2-958-4239
Fax: (82) 2-958-4090
Email: [email protected]
Jambaa Jargalsaihan
Director-General
Economic Policy and Planning Department
Ministry of Finance and Economy
210646 Ulaanbaatar
Mongolia
Phone: (976) 11-991-18345
Fax: (976) 11-32-02-07
Email: [email protected]
Kioh Jeong
Professor
Korea National University of Education
Phone: (82) 43-230-3420
Fax: (82) 43-233-6366
Email: [email protected]
Hongsang Jung
Director
Public Funds Management & Research Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
xxvi List of Participants
Byungil Kim
Minister
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5000
Fax: (82) 2-3496-5010
Email: [email protected]
Choongsoo Kim
President
Korea Development Institute
Phone: (82) 2-958-4001
Fax: (82) 2-960-2952
Email: [email protected]
Geum-Nam Kim
Senior Deputy Director
Government Finance Information & Management Division
Treasury Bureau
Ministry of Finance and Economy
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-503-9131
Fax: (82) 2-3679-6107
Email: [email protected]
Youngsun Koh
Fellow
Division of Public Finance and Social Development
Korea Development Institute
Phone: (82) 2-958-4096
Fax: (82) 2-958-4090
Email: [email protected]
List of Participants xxvii
Ohbong Kwon
Director
Fiscal Analysis Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5047
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7653
Email: [email protected]
Changho Lee
Director General, Ministry of Planning and Budget
The Embassy of Korea in the U.S.A.
Phone: (1) 202-939-5638
Email: [email protected] / [email protected]
Jang-ro Lee
Senior Deputy Director
Fiscal Analysis Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3480-7657
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7653
Email: [email protected]
Ju Ho Lee
Professor
KDI School of Public Policy and Management
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3299-1016
Fax: (82) 2-968-5072
Email: [email protected]
Younghee Lee
Fellow
Local Tax Division
Korea Research Institute for Local Administratioin
Staff
Presidential Committee on Government Innovation and Decentralization
xxviii List of Participants
YoungJoo Lee
Deputy Director
Treasury Division
Ministry of Finance and Economy
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-2110-2560
Fax: (82) 2-503-9282
Email: [email protected]
SungIl Lim
Senior Fellow
Division of Local Finance
Korea Research Institute for Local Administration
Phone: (82) 2-3488-7321
Fax: (82) 2-3488-7306
Email: [email protected]
Astrid Lbke
Deputy Head of Division
Division A 4
Directorate-General of Budget
Federal Ministry of Finance
Wilhelmstrasse 97, D-10117 Berlin
Germany
Phone: (49) 1888-682-1341
Fax: (49) 1888-682-3690
Email: [email protected]
Ho-seung Moon
Director
Corporate Policy and Research Division
The Board of Audit and Inspection
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-2011-2420
Fax: (82) 2-2011-2848
Email: [email protected]
Richard Murray
Executive Director, Fiscal and Corporate
The Treasury, Australia
Langton Crescent, Parkes ACT 2600,
Australia
List of Participants xxix
Mulia P Nasution
Head of State Financial Accounting Agency
Ministry of Finance
Jl. Lapangan Banteng Timur 2-4
Jakarta Pusat 10710
Indonesia
Phone: (62) 21-345-0959
Fax: (62) 21-345-0959
Email: [email protected] / [email protected]
Dongseok Oak
Professor
Incheon University
phone: (82) 32-770-8538
Email: [email protected]
Jin Park
Professor
KDI School of Public Policy and Management
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3299-1027
Fax: (82) 2-3299-1240
Email: [email protected]
Ki-Baeg Park
Research Fellow
Research Division 1
Korea Institute of Public Finance
Phone: (82) 2-2186-2227
Fax: (82) 2-2186-1065
Email: [email protected]
xxx List of Participants
No Wook Park
Research Fellow
Center for Fiscal Analysis
Korea Institute of Public Finance
Phone: (82) 2-2186-2267
Fax: (82) 2-2186-2320
Email: [email protected]
Soomin Park
Director
National Resource Allocation Improvement Team
Ministry of Planning and Budget
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5035
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7651
Email: [email protected]
Sanya Praseuth
Deputy Director General
Accounting Department
Ministry of Finance
Lanexang Avenue, P.O.Box 46
Vientiane, Lao PDR
Phone: (856) 21-252462
Fax: (856) 21-217451
Email: [email protected]
Saravuth Sok
Deputy Director
Economic and Financial Policy Planning and Monitoring Unit
Ministry of Economy and Finance
St. 92, Wat Phnom, Phnom Penh
Cambodia]
Phone/Fax: (855) 23-430-745
Email: [email protected]
Eonseog Song
Director
Construction & Transportation Budget Division
Ministry of Planning and Budget
List of Participants xxxi
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3496-5146
Fax: (82) 2-3480-7675
Email: [email protected]
Michael L. O. Stevens
Consultant
Africa Region
The World Bank
Phone: (1) 202-473-7493
Email: [email protected]
Ui-hwan Tcha
Director General for Policy Analysis and Evaluation
The Office for Policy Analysis and Evaluation
The Office for Government Policy Coordination
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3703-3915
Fax: (82) 2-734-8795
Email: [email protected]
Ha Duy Tung
Senior Officer
International Cooperation Department
Ministry of Finance
8 Phan Huy Chu, Hanoi
Vietnam
Phone: (84) 4-933-0106
Fax: (84) 4-933-2351
Email: [email protected] / [email protected]
Joel A. Turkewitz
Senior Public Sector Specialist
WBIPR
The World Bank
Phone: (1) 202-458-2365
Email: [email protected]
Cheonsik Woo
Fellow
Division of Knowledge Economy
Korea Development Institute
Phone: (82) 2-958-4139
Fax: (82) 2-962-7810
Email: [email protected]
xxxii List of Participants
Bum-ki Woo
Director
Fiscal and Tax Team
Presidential Committee on Government Innovation and Decentralization
Phone: (82) 2-3703-3217
Email: [email protected]
Ilho Yoo
Professor
KDI School of Public Policy and Management
Republic of Korea
Phone: (82) 2-3299-1058
Email: [email protected]
Heesuk Yun
Associate Fellow
Korea Development Institute
Public Investment Management Center
Phone: (82) 2-958-4689
Fax: (82) 2-962-9143
Email: [email protected]
Part I
by
Bill Dorotinsky, The World Bank
1. Overview
(1) Estimating total available resources for the public sector over a multi-year
period, usually within a multi-year macroeconomic and fiscal policy
framework.
(2) Estimating the actual cost of current government policy and programs by
sector, again in a multi-year context.
(3) Reconciling the information in steps 1 and 2 to align policies with available
resources, and using this information as a basis for improved policy and
funding choices, and ultimately improved outcomes.
This simplified framework provides the general thrust of the MTEF concept, but is
necessary to break the process into greater detail to explore the dynamics of the
process. Actual decision-making processes and institutions will vary by country, but
for ease of exposition, an MTEF process can be divided into five general operational
stages:
In general terms, Stages 1 and 2 are about developing macroeconomic estimates for
the economy, and shaping public fiscal policy within the multi-year framework. Stage 3
is about sectoral (e.g. health, education, welfare, etc.) policy development. Stages 4 and
5 are about reconciling competing claims on public resources with available resources.
Macroeconomic Estimates
Revenue Estimates
Fiscal Policy
Expenditure Estimates
(current services)
2 For a longer discourse on the adverse effects of overly optimistic forecasts, see Dorotinsky (1999).
3 Current practice in Poland, Canada, and U.S..
4 Also current practice in Poland.
5 For example, the United States Government does not have a macroeconomic forecasting office for budget
development. Rather it purchases six leading blue-chip and academic forecasts which form the basis of
forecasts. Economists from the Office of Management and Budget, Council of Economic Advisors, and
Department of the Treasury gather to evaluate the forecasts with respect to the most recent Government data
and expected trends, and collectively agree on the most likely evolution of key variables. The variables are then
fed into a mini-model to produce all those variables needed for producing the budget.
6 Canada, for example, had systematically over-estimated economic growth and public revenues during the
1980s, contributing to their annual deficits. To compensate, Canada averages several non-governmental
forecasts, then adds 50-100 basis points to interest rates to assure a conservative forecasts, and runs these
through a small model to produce the forecast variables for budget formulation.
7 Finland prepares economic forecasts four times each year: in February for the Government decisions on
aggregate spending limits; in May as a mid-year update; in August for the budget discussions; and a smaller
exercise in November to confirm the estimates used in budget development.
8 Many countries have independent Central Banks that produce their own forecasts for monetary policy,
but these are rarely used in budget formulation. In the U.S., the Federal Reserve and Executive branch forecasts
are informally shared at a technical level to try to assure some consistency in the basis of policy formulation by
both institutions. Also, the Congressional Budget Office also produces its own independent set of economic
estimates for Congress, which can serve as the basis of Congress budget development.
9 Coordination, at least informally, of Central Bank estimates and expected monetary policy with
Government economic estimates and fiscal policy, is important to assure a sound basis for both monetary and
fiscal policy. Doing so informally, at a technical level, can preserve the independence of the Central Bank and
still assure Government fiscal policy is fully informed and sound. Developing a budget expecting moderate
monetary policy can be easily undermined where the central bank adopts a tight monetary stance, driving up
4 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
unexpected events. If unspent at year end, these funds automatically pay off outstanding debt. Sweden
similarly uses unspent reserves for debt reduction, but rather than conservatively adjusting the macroeconomic
estimates Sweden reduces its public expenditure target below its estimated affordable expenditure estimates to
build a margin of safety. These reforms provide a systematic bias towards conservative expenditures and a
prudent use of unspent funds for debt reduction.
11 Sweden has two formal supplemental budgets, one in the spring accompanying the spring fiscal policy
update and one in the fall accompanying the budget proposals for the following year. In the U.S., supplemental
requests can be transmitted at any time, but are discouraged unless large and of high importance.
Chapter 1. Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework 5
External aid flows must also be included to provide the comprehensive revenue
picture. These deserve some special treatment in the estimates for several reasons:
counterpart funds must be identified and available from domestic resources; the aid
flows themselves may be highly unpredictable, and it is important to assure that
spending does not occur in advance of receipt of aid funds that may not materialize; in
selected cases, domestic expenditure must occur before the aid flows are released as
reimbursements, and these must be identified as well; the future cost for operating and
maintenance of infrastructure financed by foreign aid must be factored into the budget,
and this is more difficult if the budget does not even contain all aid revenues; ideally,
aid inflows would match government sectoral priorities rather than driving them; for
foreign loans, debt service costs must be factored into the multi-year plan.
Also important is identification of tax expenditures special exemptions from general
taxation for special interests, industries, regions, etc. These are revenues foregone, and
future estimates should assume current laws or policies remain in place, and model the
multi-year trends in tax expenditures for appropriate factors such as economic growth. Tax
expenditures should be explicitly identified for each type of tax revenue, allowing policy
officials to assess the benefit of this tool.
With conservative economic estimates in hand, the Ministry of Finance can prepare
broad expenditure estimates based on current policy, and explore expenditure
sensitivity to changes in economic estimates. The objective of this exercise is to explore,
at a relatively aggregate level of spending, the trends in spending and gauge
affordability over several years. The multi-year aspect allows the Ministry of Finance
an early warning indicator if some programs are likely to grow beyond affordable
limits, as well as to explore general policy options (e.g. pay policy) and their impact on
spending trends (as well as explore policy changes that might liberate resources in
current and future years for new initiatives). It is important to explicitly note that this
covers ALL public spending trends consolidated central government in GFS
terminology. If only budgetary central government is included, the picture is only
partial, and does not allow exploration of all sources of spending, identification of
over-all trends that may require Government attention, and will lead to suboptimal
policy decisions.12
These initial estimates are often termed baseline estimates, and while different
countries use different bases for calculating them, the general concept is to forecast
future spending assuming continuation of the current spending levels or laws that is,
assuming no changes in policy or spending trends, what do the out-years look like?13,14
12 While more attention in projections and sensitivity analysis will be paid to consolidated central government,
especially extrabudgetary and social funds, trends in subnational government revenues, spending, and deficits
also need to be reviewed. Excess subnational spending can directly threaten the central budget, and monitoring
trends early for possible Government intervention is important for long-term fiscal health.
13 The U.S. develops baseline estimates on current law: for mandatory spending (spending that occurs
through statute, rather than annual budget bills), the forecast assumes no change to laws, and uses economic
estimates and demographic trends to extrapolate spending to the budget year plus nine additional years. For
discretionary spending (spending that occurs only through the annual budget), the most recent enacted budget
is extrapolated out nine years using basic economic assumptions supplied by the budget office, typically the
consumer price index for wage and non-wage expenditures.
14 Australia uses the concept of current policy, focusing more on the policy commitments of the current
6 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
A useful exercise would be to prepare two broad baseline estimates: one assuming
current funding levels of discretionary spending and current laws for mandatory spending as
a current policy baseline; and one assuming current normatives and other laws with implicit
commitments were fully funded (which may require spending ministry assistance, and
which may in fact also represent the current annual requests from spending agencies). The
exercise would be instructed to identify the policy gap or difference between current levels
of public spending and those required to fulfill policy commitments as contained in
normative laws (and gauge the realism of normative sector policies).
With conservative revenue estimates in hand, the Ministry of Finance can prepare a
fiscal policy paper for presentation to Cabinet. This document draws together the results of
the modeling and forecasting exercises into an understandable report of trends and policy
implications for senior government officials and the public. The paper explores
implications of monetary and fiscal policy for economic growth, as well as trends in fiscal
policy, deficits and debt projections under current trends, and broad options for changing
policies. It serves as a useful vehicle if clear in presentation and readily assessable to
non-economists for educating senior policy officials of basic economic issues, and
linkages between government policies and outcomes (economic, fiscal, etc.). The paper
should include recommendations of MoF on a path for sustainable or improved economic
growth, including aggregate revenue and expenditure paths (including deficits and debt
policy).
The fiscal policy paper would be presented to Cabinet for discussion, with the
objective of obtaining some Cabinet decision on over-all government revenue,
expenditure, and deficit policy or framework. The focus of the decisions should be on
the policies for revenues and expenditures, the path over the budget and subsequent
years, to attain government objectives. The discussion should generally not turn on the
economic forecasts themselves, especially if these represent best estimates.
Countries follow different practices in releasing the fiscal policy and expenditure
estimates to the Parliament and public. Finland releases this information to the public
and parliament for informational purposes, while Sweden actually submits for passage
by parliament the fiscal policy, expenditure envelope, and allocations to sectors. In
Sweden, this was done to bind Parliament to the expenditure totals and sector ceilings,
and prevent unproductive amendments that added to expenditure rather than
encouraged efficient choices within sectors. In other countries, such as the U.S., the
fiscal policy, expenditure targets, and sector funding levels are not released until the
formal budget is proposed.
government over several years. Termed forward estimates, Australias multi-year forecast separately identifies
revenue policies, including tax expenditures, as well as general spending. For a good example of a comprehensive
multi-year document, see Australias 2002-2003 Budget Paper No. 1 at http://www.budget.gov.au/2002-03/bp1/html/.
Chapter 1. Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework 7
Fiscal
Fiscal Envelope
Envelope
SectoralResource
Sectoral ResourceCeilings
Ceilings
Setting Ministry
Ministry Resource
Resource Ceilings
Ceilings
Strategic Policy
Priorities Under
Resource Limits
(downsizing, or
expansions)
15 In Finland and The Netherlands, the allocation stage is easier during budget preparation as many of the
policy priorities have been set in government coalition agreements. Absent coalition governments, it is not clear
these pre-specification of policy priorities would continue.
8 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
16 For a more thorough treatment of cabinet dynamics, see Manning, Barma, Blondel, Pilichowski, and
Wright (1999).
Chapter 1. Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework 9
The broad functional steps in the Brazilian budget formulation process are:
Develop indicative sectoral limits based on analysis of current operating costs, programs,
and activities. The ceilings include several subsets of estimates:
Within the available resource estimates, subsets a, b, and c are treated as priorities in the
annual budget process. Subsets d, e, and f are treated as residual: if resources are available
to allocate, they first go to new or expanded activities, then to continuation of projects, and
finally to new or expanded projects.
Note that items d through f are only the marginal cost of the activity or project. The
personnel costs and associated overhead costs (running costs) are separately funded in a
and c.
This process assures the basic obligations of the state debt service, mandatory social
benefits, personnel (which are fixed in Brazil) and fixed administrative costs, as well as
transfer payments, receive funding first.
Having received sector or ministry indicative ceilings, each line Ministry must
develop its budget proposal. The expectation is that each Ministry would take the
resource ceiling as given, and allocate spending among its activities and programs to
attain its objectives.
This is particularly important to assure harmonization of normative laws and
sectoral and ministry strategic plans and attendant objectives, organization and
staffing, with the resources available. These decisions include both capital and current
10 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Program priorities
relative to objectives
Sector programs Assess modalities for
objective
Evaluate Production
Function
Under ceiling
Sector Budget Request
Above ceiling
Again, multi-year
objectives and means of achieving the objectives will be different under different
resource constraints.
A second example, more narrow, also illustrates the point. During the 1980s, the
U.S. Consumer Product Safety Commission, an agency charged with regulating
consumer products to assure their safety, trained staff in offices across the U.S. by
sending specialists from Washington, D.C. to provide the training. As the budget
became tighter, the agency changed its means of delivering training. Instead of sending
trainers from Washington and incurring travel and lodging expenses, the agency made
training videos in Washington, and mailed these to its offices. Evidence suggested this
means of training was as effective as the live trainers. However, the agency used this as
an example of the terrible effects of the budget restrictions. The Budget Office used this
same case to illustrate the point that such evaluation of activities and improvements in
efficiency are exactly what an agency should be doing. Different levels of funding
influence choice of means of production.
Ministries may have begun to develop their budgets prior to receiving the call
circular, and such early budget development can assure that ministry budgets are
carefully developed. Ministries may have undertaken their own strategic planning
exercise, or undertaken a special review of the effectiveness or continued usefulness of
policies, programs and projects. These reviews and plans should be undertaken, either
as part of the annual budget cycle, or prior to it and then fed into the resource
allocation decisions in the budget process.
An important issue is the extent to which the spending ministries have the policy
and program analysis skills to undertake the reviews of activities and laws, assess their
effectiveness and cost, and develop options for the responsible Minister. These are
skills that have heretofore not been in great demand, and may require training to
further develop.
At the end of the stage, the ministries will submit their budget requests to the
Ministry of Finance. The format of the requests will vary by country, but something
more than tables of numbers with a cover memorandum is appropriate. Text
explaining the policies contained in the proposals, changes in policy from prior years,
significant reallocation decisions, new objectives, all should be included. As countries
move towards performance budgeting, the budget requests should include the output
or outcome targets associated with the resource levels and allocations contained in the
request. Moreover, simple identification within the request of on-going activities and
programs from new programs assists in evaluating the proposals.
Vetting
Sector Ceilings assumptions
policies,
Technical estimate
Assessment Challengin
Sector Requests and modalities
Reconciliation productio
functio
Evaluate
performanc
Assuming the sector ceilings and Sector requests match, the Ministry of Finances
role becomes one of providing critical analysis of the agency requests, and conducting
a process that leads the Ministries feel they had a fair hearing for their requests.
Ministries should be questioned in detail about their requests, especially the
assumptions and data underlying their requests. It is also useful to conduct budget
Chapter 1. Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework 13
hearings, where the Ministries have an opportunity to meet with government officials
to make the best possible case for their budget request. These hearings can be time
consuming, but are important to give the Ministries a further stake in the budget
process. The less Ministries feel they have had a fair chance to make their case, the less
likely they are to accept the results of the process or to support the approved budget
during budget execution.18
Generally, the Ministry of Finance needs to vet the spending requests, probing
whether recurrent spending is needed and ministries have adequately reviewed
existing programs, and whether new programs are well-developed. How the MoF
interacts with spending ministries can influence outcomes. The MoF should seek to
engage in a dialogue with ministries to assess whether they have in fact considered the
questions of mix of inputs, whether there are benchmarks for assessing staffing
patterns, whether there are alternate means or modes of achieving the objectives, and
should use these issues to develop a budget. It is the dialogue that is important the
questions and answers. These issues must regularly be raised, or they will go
unaddressed: thus, current staffing and production patterns will remain fixed, and only
the increment for new programs or activities will be considered. For example, the MoF
may provide additional funds to spending ministries for official pay raises but may
provide no funds for promotions. Assuming there is a salary cap per ministry, this
puts a slight but palpable pressure on spending ministries to economize on salaries and
the wage bill, examining where savings can be achieved within the wage bill, to
provide some level of promotions. It also forces economical decisions on the number of
promotions, which may differ from the normal practice of automatic promotions
based on seniority and tenure (perhaps substituting performance evaluations and merit
as the basis of promotions).
Ministry of Finances performance assessment should include reviews of capital
spending and progress in capital projects, as well as assessments of whether external
and internal audit findings have been addressed by each ministry. The assessment can
cover many aspects of performance, and the results should be fed into the MoF
recommendations on funding. In the U.S., policy papers with funding options are
prepared for each program by the budget office, and these papers are used by senior
policy officials in the administration to make budget decisions. These papers integrate
findings on agency performance along many aspects in arriving at a funding decision.
If the sector requests and ceilings are not the same, differentiation between
recurrent and new spending as suggested above allows the Ministry of Finance to
quickly assess if recurrent spending is over target, and respond appropriately to the
source of the problem.
In some countries, review of budget requests, especially recurrent spending, is
given higher priority and more formal attention. The U.K.s former Public Expenditure
Surveys served as an annual functional review of ministry programs. In the early
1990s to facilitate its fiscal retrenchment, Canada instituted program reviews under the
auspices of a cabinet committee to review spending proposals in detail.
In addition to Ministry of Finances vetting of requests, this stage serves as a forum
for the various new funding proposals to compete for resources. If the Government sets
18 The Swedish Ministry of Finance does second-guess spending ministry budget submissions, especially
on social transfer programs, mainly through seeking additional technical details on the estimates. The MoF does
not directly challenge the requests. The Ministry budget requests are used to develop the Ministry of Finances
recommendation to cabinet, but does not directly respond to each Ministry on their request. The MoF is
prepared to detail its views at the two-day cabinet retreat where MoF allocations are below Ministry requests.
14 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
aside some resources during the sector ceiling stage for new funding proposals, these
funds would be used to fund the best of the new spending initiatives. (If no reserve
was established, and instead government allocated all available funding to the sectors,
giving some priority to some sectors over others, then competition between proposals
may have occurred within the sector.)
As noted earlier, this stage may proceed with varying degrees of cooperation or
conflict between MoF and spending ministries. In Australia, the process is a
professional dialogue where both parties to the discussion bring their unique skills and
perspective to the table to improve the projects and proposals. Ministries themselves
revise the requests based on discussions with MoF, and may reconsider the means
being proposed to attain an objective.
At the end of the day, the MoF must make some recommendations, and forward
these on to Cabinet for final approval.
Policy official
Policy dialogue
assessment Modify baselines
and
reconciliation Finalize decisions
Revised
Requests, Budget Proposal
Unresolved
Issues
This final stage will take markedly different forms depending on the structure of
the budget process. In the U.S., after decisions have been taken, results are passed back
to each Ministry, which has an opportunity to appeal the results to the budget office. If
issues are not resolved at that level, they may appeal upward, eventually to the
President. Not many issues reach this stage. After appeals are resolved, then ministries
must revise their budget request to be in alignment with the Presidents policy. This
process of appeals is intended to assure some due process to Ministries in funding
decisions, but makes for a contentious process.
Chapter 1. Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework 15
In Australia, MoF discussions with line ministries are less contentious, and more in
the nature of a management consultant (MoF) advising a client (line ministry). Line
Ministries take on board the MoF suggestions they agree with, and revise their budget
requests to come into alignment with MoF.
Line ministries of course are busy revising their requests, preparing their own
justification material, and even drafting legislation that may be required to support the
policies contained in the budget.
A primary role for the MoF in this stage is resolving any loose-ends in the decision
process, finalizing or refining numbers and policies to assure consistency. MoF efforts
move into production of documents and tables and graphs, getting everything ready
for final review and approval by Government and transmission to Parliament.
A further MoF role in many countries is preparation of communications strategy
and material to clearly explain decisions, elaborate the rationale for choices taken, and
explaining the directions for budget policy. An effective communication strategy, well
executed, is a critical factor in the success of the budget proposals and sustainability of
reforms. Careful attention to preparing policy officials to answer questions and defend
the proposals, as well as to the positive messages that need to be communicated to the
public, would increase the likely success and acceptance of any budget proposal.
16 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
References
by
Soomin Park, Ministry of Planning and Budget
Efficiency
Stiff portfolio in macro & micro levels
Top-down Budgeting
Bottom-up Oriented
( Strategic Resource Allocation based on Macro
Budgeting
Meeting
Y+5
Yearly 5 years
Player Coordinator
F is c a l z Long-term Perspective
S o und ne s s z Symphony of Sustainability & Economic Stabilizing
Our roadmap
Gradual introduction
Maintaining strong fiscal discipline
Surpassing global standards
CHAPTER 3
Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea
by
Dong Yeon Kim, The World Bank
1. Introduction
Budget reforms usually reflect specific political, social, and economic problems
and issues. The rationale to undertake fiscal reform is invariably one of tackling
problem areas and addressing identified weaknesses. Even traditional line-item
budgeting, for example, was itself an evolutionary reform in response to serious
concern about the lack of adequate spending control and substantial corruption. So too
were performance budgeting, program budgeting, and zero-based budgeting.
Medium-term expenditure framework (MTEF), along with top-down budgeting,
has drawn particular attention from many OECD and developing countries over the
last decade or so.19 MTEF, by integrating long-term perspectives into budgeting, is a
practical tool to control fiscal risk and facilitates effective allocation of resources
through strengthened strategic decision-making in resource allocation. For example,
Sweden adopted MTEF to contain and reduce fiscal deficit. Since the introduction of
MTEF, fiscal balance has improved from a deficit of 10.8% of GDP in 1994 to a surplus
of 4.8% in 2001. 20 On the other hand, U.K. intended to increase public investment,
which continued to decrease. Through MTEF, public investment has increased from 20
UK billion pounds in 1997 to 31 billion pounds in 2003.21 Recognizing its value, the
World Bank has advocated MTEF as part of fiscal reform to improve fiscal discipline,
strengthen effective resource allocation, and improve policy efficiency and
effectiveness. To this end, the World Bank has promoted operations to introduce MTEF
into client countries.22
Korea has initiated a series of fiscal reforms since the East Asian financial crisis
that occurred in late 1997. The new Administration, since its inauguration in 2003, has
been striving to further plans for reform, central to which is MTEF along with top-
down budgeting. The primary objective of MTEF is to integrate national policy priority
into budgeting and set up a new strategic decision-making mechanism. The reforms to
introduce these new initiatives are due to be implemented in 2004 with the aim of full
application for the 2005 budget. This change will be a turning point in Korean public
expenditure management (PEM), because it is not limited to bringing about changes to
the budgeting process, but seeks to set up a strategic decision-making mechanism
19 More than 20 OECD countries surveyed prepare multi-year expenditure estimates and 7 OECD countries surveyed
21 The number is expressed in nominal term. See Liz Passman (2003), p.4.
22 The World Bank has provided assistance, financial and/or technical, to at least 45 client countries as of
2003 to implement MTEF to help strengthen countries public expenditure management system.
24 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
which, through a top-down and more discretionary approach, will alter managerial
behavior and organizational culture in the government.
This paper deals with Koreas MTEF and top-down budgeting reform plan by
analyzing key issues which may affect successful implementation of reform. More
specifically, the paper identifies why MTEF is considered necessary and what new
budget process it will involve. Then, this paper addresses key challenges which Korea
may confront and provides suggestions for implementation strategy to mitigate risks
for successful reform. While this paper deals mostly with Koreas PEM system and
addresses issues pertaining to Korea, it will be useful for other countries to draw some
policy implications and lessons.
Pension Scheme (GEPS), Private School Teachers Pension Scheme (TPS), and Military Personnel Pension
Scheme (MPPS).
27 Koh (2003) , p.13.
26 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
percent of GDP in 2002.28 This will inevitably make it harder to maintain fiscal balance
for quite a long time.
Thirdly, of no small concern is the current division of the Korean peninsular and
financial burden this situation continues to place on expenditure demands. This unique
issue, whose outcome remains very ambiguous, requires sufficient planning in terms of
public finance. The future of Korea, including possible unification with North Korea, is
unclear but suffice to say all contingencies warrant due consideration. Reducing the
negative effects of unification under any circumstances, will depend heavily on
preparation and organization prior to such an eventuality.29
Moreover, the revenue side poses as high a risk to the fiscal balance as the
expenditure side. Further aggravating the potential danger of threats is the outlook of
Koreas economy growth rate, which is expected to slow markedly in the coming years.
Reduced economic growth rates necessarily imply declining rates of revenue, which
will test Koreas fiscal discipline.
Korea is in the process of preparing public expenditure reform plans with the
following characteristics representing the main directions.
Long-term Perspective: Under the new system, the MPB will prepare a Long-term
Financial Management Plan, which makes a long term more than 10 years
projection of the overall fiscal balance and sectoral allocation. For this projection, the
MPB will factor in various macroeconomic and social variables including sustainable
debt level and tax burden, national policy agenda, and sectoral expenditure demand.
This Plan will serve as a baseline to determine fiscal balance and sectoral allocation for
31 This plan is in the process of being prepared so this section is not necessarily representative of the official
the upcoming three years and be reviewed and updated on a rolling basis to reflect any
unexpected changes.
Top-down Budgeting: Fiscal targeting, of which sustainable fiscal balance over the
economic cycle is a core aspect, will be driven by the Long-term Financial Management
Plan and macro-economic forecasting. Based on fiscal targeting and revenue estimates,
the decision is to be made for the budget aggregate for three years. Following this, and
with consideration to policy objectives and priorities, sectoral and ministerial
expenditure limits, for three years, will be finalized.
Strategic Decision Making Mechanism: As part of the new strategic decision-making
mechanism, cabinet-level meetings will be held to discuss long-term plans, macro-
economics, budget aggregate, and sectoral limits. The main purpose of the cabinet
meeting is to establish a forum wherein consensus-building on national policy
priorities and expenditures will be made at the early stage of budget formulation. The
additional objective is to obtain strong commitment from the cabinet, and enhance
transparency through open and direct discussions. To support this meeting, the MPB
should prepare a draft fiscal target, fiscal aggregate, and sectoral ceilings. During the
preparation process, the MPB should interact closely with the President, who will
preside over the cabinet meeting, on proposals in order to foster greater coordination
and obtain critical support.
Decentralization: Currently, the MPB is heavily involved in preparing
appropriations for individual projects in the budget process, which leaves very little
room for line ministries to maneuver. In contrast, the new system will make line
ministries play a much more substantial role. Within the boundary of the sectoral
ceiling and policy priorities set by the cabinet meeting, line ministries will have more
autonomy to prepare their own budget proposals. The MPB will focus its efforts on
reviewing budget proposals to ensure that sectoral ceilings have been respected and
that proposed requests sufficiently reflect policy priorities. Increased line ministries
discretion over their budget preparation can significantly contribute to enhancing the
accountability of line ministries, because line ministries will be held accountable for
what they can control rather than for what they can not. A proper system of checks and
balances including performance management should be in place to align managerial
discretion with accountability.
Under the above direction, Koreas budgeting process will undergo fundamental
change. The changes, incorporating the introduction of MTEF, will lead to new
processes and stages outlined below:
32 One possible classification scheme considered by the MPB is to sort all budget projects as A, B, or C,
where A is projects related to national strategic objectives and sector objectives, and mandatory expenditures
such as debt payment and debt interest; B is core projects in each sector; and C is projects that are classified into
neither A nor B.
33 The role of the National Assembly and legislative procedures are integral to the budgeting system and
important for reform. However, legislative issues are beyond the scope of this paper.
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 29
developed alike, is that too much attention is given to the technical aspect of MTEF and
little consideration on how to change the institutional framework, decision-making
process, and organizational culture of public sector. International experience clearly
suggests that basic principles of MTEF must be carefully adjusted to fit into country
context.
In this regard, it will be necessary to analyze key issues Korea may face down the
road of reform and suggest how Korea can prepare itself to address these challenges.
Special attention should be paid to country context in the areas of macro-economic
forecasting, strategic decision-making, setting the level of line ministries discretion,
designing incentive systems, and reforming budgetary basics such as budget structure,
scope and improving information system.
34 By way of background of Koreas institutional changes, economic forecasting and budgeting has seen
several important changes. These changes have occurred at the institutional level directly impacting the
decision-making mechanism and coordination functions. In 1994 the EPB was merged with the Ministry of
Finance to form the Ministry of Finance and Economy (MoFE). This was soon fractured leading to the
establishment of the Planning and Budget Commission (PBC) and the Office of National Budget (ONB) as
separate bodies from the MoFE. Shortly thereafter, the PBC and ONB themselves were merged to create the
MPB, leaving the MoFE and MPB as two independent ministries.
30 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
analysis and avoid pressure from outside political circles. In developing this formula, a
conservative method would be preferable to contribute to fiscal soundness.35
It is recommended to establish a unit/department within MPB responsible for
macro-economic forecasting and assessment of social/political factors that affect fiscal
policy. This new organization could comprise of one or two divisions. Having such an
organization within the ministry could allow the MPB staff to appropriately deal with
macro-issues, undergo training to enhance their capacity, and to coordinate greater
links with outside experts. The MPB may make both judgemental and predictive errors,
but will perform better over time as they build up experience.
Lastly, to cover macro-economic uncertainty, the concept of budget margin
should be created in the annual budget. The budget margin acts as a kind of buffer and
mainly aims to absorb fluctuations in the expenditure level due to changes in the cycle
and other macro-economic uncertainties.36, 37 It can be utilized in cases of forecasting
deviations and new presidential policy initiatives. The size of the budget margin may
depend on accuracy of information. The budget margin should be no larger or smaller
than what is considered enough to fulfil its role of accommodating uncertainty. It is
perceived from international experience that, over time, macro-economic forecasting
tends to become more accurate allowing the size of the budget margin to decrease.38
How should decisions about total budget aggregate and sectoral ceilings be made and by
whom?
35 For example, the Canadian Department of Finance systematically revises the private sector forecasts dow
nwards as a further measure of prudence. This takes the form of the government adding 50-100 basis points (0.
5-1.0 percentage points) to the average private sector economic forecasts for interest rates and then feeding this
through its entire econometric model, thus producing lower forecast economic activity. This provides a buffer i
n order to maintain the governments fiscal objectives (OECD, 1999, p.9).
36 Swedish Ministry of Finance (2002), p.13.
are projected for 2002-2004 as 0.04, 0.05 and 0.07 percent, respectively (Swedish Ministry of Finance, 2002, p.13).
39 However , it should be noted that MTEF consists of top-down resource allocation and bottom-up
approach for cost estimation. In this sense, the bottom-up element should not be overlooked.
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 31
commitment at the highest level. The MPB should play a key role by preparing its
proposal on fiscal policy, total budget aggregate, and sectoral ceiling for the cabinet
meeting. Furthermore, it is important that the MPB works in close consultation with
the President in preparing the proposal. From this, mutual benefit can be achieved as
the President can input his policy priority into the budget and the MPB can gain
political support.
A concern may arise over the possibility of disagreement at the Cabinet meeting,
particularly over sectoral ceilings. This concern arises because Korea has been weak in
forming consensus through consultation and negotiation processes. Added to this, lack
of negotiation experience is the growing voice from numerous interest groups as Korea
becomes a more democratized society. While valid demands should be heard and
brought to the table for discussing national agenda, many not-in-my-back-yard type
protests are becoming ubiquitous as well. This situation calls for special attention to be
paid to the design and implementation of MTEF, since the cabinet meeting is likely to
experience difficulty reaching agreement.
Given this situation, it may be advisable that the cabinet meetings adopt a two-
stage approach. The first stage would be to decide the budget aggregate, and the
second stage would determine the sectoral allocation. If these two were placed on the
table together, it would be very difficult to reach an agreement. Thus, division of these
two in decision-making becomes important as the decision on the total budget
aggregate turns the discussions on sectoral ceilings into a zero-sum game. Against all
these efforts, if cabinet meeting fails to reach an agreement, it should be understood
that the President will make the final decision, with the MPBs objective and
professional support.
A centralized budgeting process has been with Korea for a long time, with the
MPBs deep involvement in almost all facets of the budgeting process. Entrenched in
this all-under-my-control mechanism, the MPB may be reluctant to relinquish its
influence over appropriations. Meanwhile, concern over line ministries lack of
capacity and experience in areas such as prioritizing within a sector may also lead to
hesitation for greater discretion to line ministries.
Such barriers, however, can only be overcome by making steps to directly address
these issues. A new incentive system must be introduced so that MTEF can be
perceived by the MPB as being beneficial to them and that their influence over
appropriation will be upgraded to more professional and legitimate influence.
Ultimately, discretion to prepare a budget request within sectoral and ministerial
ceilings should be granted to line ministries. This may afford line ministries greater
ownership over their respective budget proposals and make them more likely to the
identify policy priorities within their sectors as well as grant managerial flexibility
resulting in greater efficiency. Through these experiences, line ministries can also build
up necessary in-house capacity to manage increased discretion over their policy and
budget more effectively and responsibly.
On the other hand, Budget proposals prepared by line ministries should be subject
to the MPBs review. This review should mainly act as a checkpoint to ensure that line
ministries proposals are in line with the national policy priority agreed on at the
Cabinet meeting and stay within the sectoral ceiling. Also the MPB should provide
guidelines, including criteria for common expenses, and perform monitoring and
32 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
How can the new incentive system overcome resistance to implementation, and what
should be the new role of the MPB and line ministries under this new system?
It is possible that both the MPB and line ministries will resist reforms for many
reasons. The MPB may be concerned with potential loss of influence and power
through the proposal to diminish its role in allocating resources. On the other hand,
line ministries may be skeptical about receiving more discretion in their own budget
preparation. Both the MPB and line ministries may also perceive the changes as merely
additional work without any real benefit.
Two main considerations should be given to deal with resistance to the new
system. First, some resistance may arise from a lack of knowledge regarding the real
nature and characteristics of the proposed new system; how annual budgeting process
changes under MTEF, what will be the new roles of MPB and line ministries, what
kinds of benefits can be expected from MTEF. Secondly, uncertainty over individual
incentives under the new system, if not handled appropriately, may lead to resistance.
MPB and line ministries staff may not be sure how the changes will affect their
personal interest.
For the MPB, the existing system places a large work burden on the staff and much
time is devoted to micro-level decision on individual activities.41 However, under the new
system, focus will shift to higher level decision-making, analyses of macro-economics and
national policy priorities, and preparation of draft proposals for the cabinet meetings.
Furthermore, the MPB could have the privilege to interact closely with the President. From
all these, the MPB will not lose its current standing as a prestigious ministry. On the
contrary, its influence and power may be strengthened. The MPBs influence will remain
high through monitoring and coordination over line ministries budget proposals during
the budget review stage and through performance evaluations of major projects.
On the other hand, line ministries have an opportunity to enhance their level of
influence, providing an incentive to gain greater discretion in decision making. Line
ministries, firstly, will be granted discretion in planning and prioritization within their
The number of projects per budget examiner in the MPB has jumped from 81 in 1994 to 150 in 2003; and t
41
he portion of budget allocated per budget examiner increased from 1.0 trillion won in 1994 to 4.6 trillion won in
2003 (MPB, 2003, p.8).
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 33
sectors and secondly, they will have flexibility in implementing policy and executing
budget. There will be a learning curve when introducing these changes which will
further allow line ministries to build up capacity to deal with their new role. The
timeline for granting discretion may need to be done gradually to plan a path for
granting discretion over to line ministries.
Besides, gaining greater discretion over budgetary decisions can also increase the
legitimacy of holding line ministries accountable for the performance of their output.
Under the new system, unlike the current situation where line ministries are sometimes
held accountable even though they dont have any control over resources and decision-
makings, line ministries should be accountable for the decisions they make and their
performance only.
42 According to the MPBs plan, a certain number of projects, amounting to 30 percent of the total
The first step to enhance accountability is to emphasize that ministers should hold
ultimate responsibility for programs operated under their discretion.43 Presently, the
Korean government has little ex post evaluation, although it has introduced some ex
ante evaluation systems, including the preliminary feasibility study. To move further
along this path, the MPB should embrace the role of watchdog by performing more
comprehensive monitoring and evaluation of projects. Setting up policy objectives for
the cabinet meeting and discussing projects objectives with line ministries during the
budget review stage will be a sound basis for this process. To further contribute to this
mechanism, budgeting and accounting systems should be linked and information
exchange between the MPB, the MoFE, line ministries, and the Board of Audit and
Inspection integrated.
Another lesson from international experiences with MTEF is that success of fiscal
reform largely depends upon budgetary basics such as budget structure, scope,
classification, accounting, information, evaluating, and auditing. Unless these basics
are firmly set up, introducing MTEF may not generate anticipated benefits due to a
weak public expenditure management environment.
Unfortunately, many weaknesses exist in the Korean PEM system. First, the budget
structure is too complicated; a fragmented assortment comprising one General
Account, 22 Special Accounts, and 45 Funds. Second, its expenditure classification is far
too subdivided; consisting of more that 2,200 appropriation accounts (Se-Hang) and
more than 6,000 sub-accounts (Se-se-Hang). Each of them is subject to negotiation
between the MPB and line ministries. Third, the coverage of the budget is limited;
excluding some important fiscal activities of the government, like the National Health
Insurance and quasi-government activities. 44 Current coverage of the budget is not
consistent with Government Finance Statistics (GFS), an international standard for
public expenditure statistics issued by the IMF.45
The fragmented budget structure, complex classification, and limited budget
coverage cause several problems. First, it is difficult to control public financial
resources, which impedes allocative efficiency. Second, the inherent opaqueness of the
system leads to transparency and accountability issues. Third, these budgetary basics
problems also contribute to managerial inflexibility and make results orientation more
difficult to attain. These problems, all together, make it technically prohibitive to
allocate resources within sectoral limits down at the level of sub-accounts, and this
would hold even if the Korean government introduces a new system incorporating
sectoral ceilings.
Much effort to realign the budget structure, classification, and coverage are needed.
The Korean government should make all the special accounts and funds subject to the
same level of scrutiny as budgetary expenditure. And, extra-budgetary funds should be
discouraged unless very strong justification exists. The budget subdivisions, currently
classified by line items with its heavy emphasis on input control, should be more
43 A serious problem is that the tenure of ministers has been notoriously short with the average term of a
minister being less than one year, during 1993-2002 (Maeil Economic Newspaper, March 10, 2003).
44 For more details, see Koh (2003), pp.29-31.
45 It is however important to note that GFS is for statistical purposes rather than budgetary management
purposes. IMF acknowledges that countries are not obliged to prepare an annual budget completely in line with
GFS. Rather, it requires a country to ex-post prepare and rearrange expenditure according to GFS.
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 35
46 An integrated information system becomes a more vital issues under Koreas divided organizational stru
cture where treasury management and budget execution reporting is under the MoFE and budget formulation
and execution is under the MPB. The current two stand-alone information systems in the two ministries need to
be seamlessly linked to each other.
47 This is not to say that the MPB should handle macroeconomic conditions for all purposes. Rather, the
MoFE should be in charge of monitoring and setting macroeconomic conditions for general purpose and the
MPBs concern should be limited to those related to budget formulation.
36 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
strong roles in Koreas public sector.48 Among the reasons to explain this predominance
of career technocrats are historical and social respects for government officials. This has
attracted many well-educated and highly trained people to join the public sector and
become career technocrats. This also means that technocrats relatively distance
themselves from political pressures. At the same time, the executive body and
technocrats need to draw together to present a broad and united front of political
support for its reforms as demands of various interests increasingly enter into the
decision-making process.
Past experience of linking planning closely with budget during the EPB period and
strong sense of ownership for the reform within the government and technocrats
creates a favorable environment for MTEF to be successful. But that is not to say that
the path of this reform will be easy. Challenges and obstacles lie ahead making the
successful implementation of the new system no guarantee. In order to overcome these
obstacles, the key issues outlined in the previous chapter need to be carefully
addressed and detailed plans prepared. Besides these key questions, below are some
observations and suggestions regarding Koreas path for implementing MTEF and top-
down approach.
Pre-conditions
There are several important pre-conditions for successful implementation of MTEF
in Korea. Among these are strong political support, the MPBs willingness and
commitment to the new system, compliance of line ministries, capacity building for the
MPB and line ministries, and development of a legal framework for the new system.
Some have been met but not all. Although not all the pre-conditions are in place, the
Korean government, rather than delay reform, should focus on putting them in place in
parallel with proceeding with reforms. Most OECD countries also had, and still have,
some shortcomings in their expenditure management. Instead of waiting till everything
becomes impeccable, they used MTEF as an instrument to alter the status quo and
improve along with strengthening policy linkage with budget. Considering its highly
skilled civil service, Korea may opt to introduce MTEF while simultaneously striving to
improve these pre-conditions.
48 It is indicative to point out that most political appointees in economic policy-related ministries, particular
ly the MPB and MoFE, have been actually been awarded to career technocrats over the last four decades.
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 37
incomplete. It will not only create a favorable environment for MTEF to be introduced,
but also will create a synergy effect for building a more effective and transparent public
sector.
Performance-orientation
Improvement of PEM requires serious focus on results achievement or
performance from government expenditures. Accordingly, MTEF and performance
management represent two sides of the same coin. Even if MTEF is successfully
introduced, it may be vulnerable unless performance-oriented management is
implemented correspondingly.
International experience shows that nurturing a performance-oriented
environment is of central importance before new tools and techniques for performance
management or PBB can be fully introduced. In the case of Korea, performance
orientation in the public sector is considerably under-developed. In the current system,
life-long tenure, seniority-based promotion and salaries are the norm. There is little
managerial flexibility, to the extent that even ministers cannot make changes in the
organizational structure, nor do they have the discretion to hire career officials. Thus, it
is at least equally important for Korea to make efforts to realign the public sector
environment, especially the civil service system, to fit into performance-oriented
management while efforts to introduce performance management system needs to
continue.
A suggestion to exemplify the advantages of such a culture would be to select one
or two government ministries/agencies and designate them as regulation-free
organizations. All regulations would be removed, allowing ministers/CEOs full
discretion over personnel, organizational structure, management, etc. 50 At the same
time, the chosen agencies would have clear assignments and a vision to achieve the
objectives. In such an organization, performance would be a key driver for the minister
and senior officials because they would be judged on what was achieved rather than how
things were done. This should also lead to positive spill-over effects. Through this pilot
project a performance-oriented culture could spread out in the public sector.
Koreas PEM is currently in transition, having already begun some reforms to
move forward, but still many more issues remain to be addressed. Many challenges lie
ahead that must be confronted, but there is also cause for optimism. The Korean
government is dedicated to reform, initiatives have been derived and pushed from the
inside, and there are positive dynamics for change. A budget system is a
communication system, conveying symbols and signals about behavior, priorities,
intentions, commitment, and price. The new PEM system, thus, is much more than
simply fiscal reform; its about creating new value and changing behavior, making
public sector more performance-oriented, accountable, and transparent.
50 This idea is borrowed from Special Economic Zones, which are designated areas dispensed of regulations
in order to boost investment and create a free and competitive business environment for economic activities.
Chapter 3. Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea 39
References
Allen, Richard and Tommasi, Daniel, Managing Public Expenditure: A Reference Book for Transition
Economies, OECD, 2001.
Anipa, Seth, Felix Kaluma, and Elizabeth Muggeridge, DFID Seminar on Best Practice in Public
Expenditure Management: Case Study of MTEF in Malawi and Ghana, Consulting Africa
Limited, 1999.
Blondal, Jon, Budgeting in Sweden, OECD, 2001.
Byeon, Yang-Kyun, Introducing A Top-down Resource Allocation System and Its Expected
Effects, in his Three Essays on the Sustainability of Government Finance and Improving
Efficiency in Resource Allocation in Korea, Ph.D. Dissertation, Sogang University, 2002, (in
Korean).
Dorotinsky, Bill, Developing a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF) for Columbia.
Dorotinsky, Bill, Key Roles in Executive Branch Budget Formulation: Integrating the Elected Executive
into the Budget Process, 1999.
Funke, Michael and Holger Strulik, Growth and Convergence in a Two-Region Model: The
Hypothetical Case of Korean Unification, IMF Working Paper, 2002.
Jun, Taek-Seung and Ki-Paik Park, Review of Pilot Studies on Performance-based Budgeting, Korea
Institute of Public Finance, 2002 (in Korean).
Koh, Youngsun, Public Expenditure Management in Korea, Korea Development Institute, 2003.
Maeil Economic Newspaper, March 10, 2003 (in Korean).
Ministry of Finance and Economy, Consolidated Fiscal Balance of Korea, each year (in Korean).
MPB (Ministry of Planning and Budget), National Resource Allocation Improvement Plan (Draft),
2003 (in Korean).
_____, How Korea Reformed the Public Sector (1998-2002), 2003 (in Korean).
Muggeridge, Elizabeth, Mozambique; Assistance with Development of a Medium-term
Expenditure Framework, Draft Report, World Bank, 1997.
National Statistics Office, Future Population Estimates, 2001 (in Korean).
OECD, Budgeting in Canada, PUMA/SBO(99)5/FINAL, 1999.
Passman, Liz, Presentation on Public Expenditure Planning and Control, UK Treasury, November
2003, p.4.
Potter, Barry and Jack Diamond, Guidelines for Public Expenditure Management, International
Monetary Fund, 1999.
Schick, Allan, Why Most Developing Countries Should Not Try New Zealands Reforms, The
World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 13, No. 1, February 1998, pp. 123-31.
Swedish Ministry of Finance, The Swedish Medium-term Budget Framework, 2002.
_____, Budget Statement 2003.
United Nations, The Sex and Age Distribution of World Population, each year.
Wilks, Stuart, Reform of the National Budget Process in Sweden, International Journal of Public
Sector Management, Vol. 8, No. 2, 1995, pp.33-43.
World Bank, Public Expenditure Management Handbook, 1999.
CHAPTER 4
Successful Installation of MTEF to the Korean Fiscal System
by
Seok-Kyun Hur, Korea Development Institute
1. Introduction
The budget process in Korea begins in March when the Ministry of Planning and
Budget (MPB) transmits the Guide to Budget Compilation to the ministries. After
negotiations between concerned parties, the budget draft is approved by the President
and then presented to the National Assembly by October 2nd. The latter is supposed to
approve the budget no later than December 2nd , well ahead of the new fiscal year that
starts on January 1st of next year.
The current budgeting process in Korea is characterized by a lack of medium-term
strategic perspectives on financial management. Macroeconomic forecasts contained in
the Guide to Budget Compilation cover the next budget year only and no mention is
made of the out-years. A medium-term fiscal plan was published in 1999, which
included projections of fiscal aggregates and outlined priorities among the 12 broad
spending categories between 1999 and 2002. It was subsequently revised in 2001.
However, the plan remained largely indicative and, in practice, there was little formal
connection between the plan and the annual budgeting process.
Another characteristic of the Korean budgeting process is the excessive reliance on
the bottom-up approach. The Guide to Budget Compilation contains a very rough
ceiling on the aggregate spending level (for example, one-digit increase in total). It does
not provide a sectoral or ministerial allocation of the budget. As a result, budget
requests for the next year across all line ministries tend to be unrealistically large, often
implying a 20-30 percent growth from the current years budget. The MPB then enters
into a laborious period of negotiation with line ministries. The process becomes more
painful because of the extremely segmented appropriation accounts there are over
2,200 accounts (Se-Hang) and the MPB often negotiates with line ministries on sub-
accounts (Se-Se-Hang) which total more than 6,000.
The current approach has certain merits. The budget authorities have large
discretion over the total size of the annual budget and have used the power to contain
and adjust expenditure growth to changing revenue conditions. To some degree, such
myopia is inevitable in Korea where the socio-economic environment changes quite
rapidly and unexpectedly. In addition, by emphasizing input control and regularity of
budget execution, we find few cases of abuse or misuse of tax money.
On the other hand, the weaknesses of the current approach should not be
overlooked. Without a long-term view on the appropriate level of tax burden, it can
induce an ever-increasing expenditure to accommodate rising demands from various
sectors. It also fosters gradualism in budgeting and can hinder a strategic
reprioritization of spending, exactly when the strengthened control on aggregate
expenditure generates greater necessity for such reprioritization. Line ministries have
42 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
little information on the availability of resources in the future and their planning
function is severely limited. Limited planning function in turn reduces the effectiveness
and efficiency of overall public spending.
Recognizing these shortcomings, the MPB is moving toward a medium-term
expenditure framework (MTEF) and a top-down approach in budgeting. In 2003, it
specified the aggregate level of the general account for fiscal year 2004, which takes up
the largest part of central government spending. It also asked line ministries to provide
out-year projections of major program expenditures for fiscal years 2004 and 2005
together with the budget requests for fiscal year 2003. In addition, the MPB designated
a few organizations for a pilot study on top-down budgeting.
These are desirable developments, but we still have a long way to go before seeing
the successful installation of an MTEF in Korea. The MPB did not set medium-term
expenditure targets and did not provide line ministries with a sectoral allocation of the
budget and medium-term forecasts on economic variables necessary to project out-year
spending. Nor were there concrete guidelines on expenditure projections. For example,
dividing the projection into three parts for existing policies, for savings options, and
for new policy initiatives would be useful in identifying line ministries spending
priorities, but it was not attempted.
One big challenge is the extreme compartmentalization and fragmentation of the
budget, which is comprised of one general account, 22 special accounts, and 45 public
funds. These accounts and funds are intricately inter-related with each other through
complicated flow of grants and loans. Even when a sectoral allocation of the budget is
set up, it will be technically very difficult to allocate the sectoral budget to accounts
and funds.
Key questions in setting up an MTEF and introducing a top-down budgeting
process include the following: How can we produce unbiased and credible medium-
term macroeconomic forecasts? How can we overcome shortcomings of a
compartmentalized budget structure, and establish an aggregate fiscal discipline? What
are the guiding principles in setting up a medium-term aggregate expenditure level
and allocating it across sectors and/or ministries? How can we minimize resistance
and objections from line ministries to pre-determined sectoral allocation of spending?
What are the technical details needed in out-year projections of spending? How much
autonomy should be reserved for line ministries in top-down budgeting? What will be
the redefined roles of the budget authorities?
The present study aims to answer these questions and produce operational plans
to introduce an MTEF and top-down budgeting. It will first discuss general issues in
budgeting, overview MTEF as recommended by international organizations and as
practiced in foreign countries, and compare it with the current budgeting process in
Korea. It will then propose an appropriate system for Korea.
The contents of the paper are construed as follows: Section 2 discusses
motivational aspects of introducing MTEF and explores the requisites for successful
installation of MTEF in Korea while comparing the current single year budgeting
system with MTEF. Section 3 explores common pillars of MTEF system and provides
suggestions for successful installation of MTEF in Korea. Finally, section 4 concludes.
Chapter 4. Successful Installation of MTEF to the Korean Fiscal System 43
51 The idea of MTEF was devised originally in countries (e.g. Sweden and UK) suffering from heavy
government debt. However, due to the heterogeneity of the situation each country is faced with, the
implementation of MTEF in practice varies from a country to another.
52 Even though a result differs by the time spans of data, the current year-by-year system is shown to be
pro-cyclical. We suspect that the combination of the year-by-year system and the strong emphasis on fiscal
consolidation causes the pro-cyclical feature.
44 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Boom Expenditure
Surplus
Revenue
Deficit
Depression
Table 4-1 describes the objectives of MTEF and matches them with relevant policy
components in MTEF. In addition we provide analogies of MTEF to a consumers
intertemporal maximization program under uncertainty. Despite fundamental
differences between the two, there are enough existing similarities to deepen our
understanding about the MTEF.
Suppose a consumer with certain duration of life lives in a world full of
uncertainties. Then, evidently his/her economic decisions should concern the
following three dimensions: time, states, and sectors. To rephrase, he/she has to choose
(1) how much to consume today instead of consuming tomorrow, (2) how many apples
to consume instead of pears today, and (3) how much more to consume tomorrow in
case of an event in comparison with the case of another event. Interestingly, each
combination of an objective and a policy tool is analogous to each dimension of the
consumers decisions.
Likewise, MTEF defines the functions of fiscal activities in a multi-dimensional
space: First, MTEF is a mechanism through which subsidiaries of a government are
encouraged to compete with others by demonstrating cost efficiency and social need
for public goods or services they produce. Second, MTEF provides insurance not only
to subsidiary organizations but also to the aggregate economy. Budget allocation in
consideration of long-term fiscal sustainability will induce precautionary fiscal savings
for a rainy day. Third, budget planning based on the longer term prospect contributes
to improvement in growth potentials through rational allocation of public resources.
Chapter 4. Successful Installation of MTEF to the Korean Fiscal System 45
Table 4-1. The objectives and their matching policy tools of MTEF
LINK BETWEEN POLICY, Very weak because policy choices are Policy-making tightly disciplined by resource
PLANNING, AND BUDGETING made independent of resource realities. realities. Thus a much stronger link exists
(Reflecting the governments Thus policy is not sustainable and between policy-making, planning, and
capacity and willingness to spending patterns may not reflect the budgeting. Spending reflects the stated
prioritize expenditure programs) priorities articulated by government. priorities of Government.
PERFORMNCE AND SERVICE Incentives for results in terms of Emphasis is on the delivery of agreed outputs
DELIVERY outputs and outcomes are generally low and outcomes with available resources.
(Relating to operational because emphasis is on input control. Incentives are structured to increase the
performance of all resources Little attention to the predictability of demand for evidence of good performance
human as well as financial) budget funding. (accountability for sector managers for
results).
Consequently, service delivery should
improve.
AUTONOMY OF CREDIT Generally low, because lack of Generally high because of greater discipline
MANAGERS discipline within the traditional budget in setting and enforcing hard budget
framework is translated into detailed constraints plus accountability mechanisms
input controls that makes it possible for managers to be
given more authority to determine how
agreed outputs and outcomes should be
achieved.
46 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
In contrast with the current single year budgeting system, the potential advantages
of adopting MTEF are highlighted in Table 4-2. In an ideal situation, in which there is
no information asymmetry, single year budgeting may produce the same level of
outcome as MTEF. However, reality is that information asymmetry combined with
various socio-economic uncertainties persists within a government as well as between
the government (as a whole) and the public. Furthermore, generational inequity cannot
be restrained due to dynamic inefficiency under the current single year budgeting.
Unlike other countries, which have already adopted MTEF, Korea does not have
an apparent fiscal problem at the present. The annual budget is more or less
maintained in balance and the ratio of government debt to GDP is smaller than in other
OECD countries. Inefficiency arising in the process of allocating fiscal resources exists
but is not big enough to attract the publics attention. In such a situation, it would be
very difficult to address the need for introducing MTEF not only to the public but also
to public officials. However, anticipating increasing social welfare spending following
the rapidly aging demographic structure, we have to be reminded that MTEF serves as
a precautionary measure. By taking precautionary measures before symptoms arise,
unnecessary turmoil in the economy could be avoided.
53 In a principal-agent context, the objective of the line ministry would be assumed to maximize the size of
term because it provides data on a prospective basis, for the budget year t and for
following years t+1 and t+2.
MTEF is a rolling process repeated every year and aims at reducing the imbalance
between what is affordable and what are demanded by line ministries. MTEF does this
by bringing together policy-making, planning, and budgeting early in the budgeting
cycle, with adjustments taking place through policy changes. It involves building
domestic macro-economic and sector modeling capacity. Also, even if the whole of the
Governments budgeting system is not working well, each sector is better off managing
itself with a medium-term perspective.
A well implemented MTEF should: (i) link the Governments priorities with a
budget within a sustainable spending envelope; (ii) highlight the tradeoffs between the
competing objectives of the Government; (iii) link budgets with the policy choices
made; and (iv) improve outcomes by increasing transparency, accountability, and the
predictability of funding.
In detail, seven major requirements must be considered for MTEF implementation:
projections. Policy transparency means being open to the public about what
Government intentions are in a particular policy area, which outcomes are to
be achieved, and the costs of achieving these outcomes. Also, transparency
means reporting actual performance with quality of outputs and results
achieved.
would be critical in order to succeed in introducing MTEF once and for all. The lack of
political support is of concern because budgeting is still seen as a technical exercise
mainly driven by the Ministry of Planning and Budget (MPB). Another reason is that
politicians seem unaware of the benefits of the new process, and still rely to a large
extent on the old, incremental methods to obtain funding. Finally, the incentive for
good budget preparation remains limited, because much is lost in the implementation,
which is still driven by cash rationing.
Implicit in the above are two further gains: (i) to improve the linkage between
annual budgeting and medium-term considerations, such as investment plans,
borrowing capacity, changing spending policies, and priorities, and (ii) to provide
relevant information to political decision-makers on cost implications of expenditure
policies.
MTEF should cover the entire consolidated budget in GFS. It means that all the
resources under the discretion of the government need to be reviewed and prioritized
for spending. This comprehensive budget coverage is particularly important
considering that MTEF tries to improve resource allocation in line with the
governments priority.
50 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Usually, the time horizon of MTEF ranges from 3 to 4 years. The longer the
horizon, the less responsive the annual budgeting is to changes in the socio-economic
environments. In contrast, a shorter time horizon is not consistent with the basic
motive of MTEF, the provision of insurance to line ministries. Accordingly, an optimal
time horizon should be determined which lies in-between. In addition, the Korean
economy is exposed to various risk factors, internal and external, as evidenced in the
past. Therefore, it is recommended that MTEF of Korea cover a three-year time horizon.
deficit/GDP. Since the integration of fiscal deficit over time is equal to government
deficit, these two ratios encompass the same amount of information mathematically.
According to the IMF, government debt is defined as follows:
The above definition of government debt does not include de facto government
liabilities such as contingent ones. A true indicator of government debt should be the
sum of the above IMF definition and the following:
Under the assumption that the annual budget is prepared through MTEF process,
the previous years MTEF plan (t) does not necessarily bind the annual budget or the
MTEF of this year (t+1).54 Expenditure perspectives of two or three years included in
MTEF should be seen as guidance. Since situations almost always occur unexpectedly,
it would be optimal to adjust the original plan following the track of events. For
54 In our prior knowledge, Brazil is the only country, which strictly keeps the ceilings set by MTEF for the
example, in the event of a natural disaster such as a typhoon, there would be a huge
amount of unexpected public expenditures.
On the other hand, if a change in the ceiling is permitted frequently and flexibly,
the time consistency or credibility of MTEF would be affected bringing about a similar
outcome to that of the year-by-year approach.
Figure 4-3 describes the multi-year process of MTEF. C represents the MTEF
ceilings determined for the periods (t, t+1,t+2) at t-1 whereas A and B are the MTEF
ceilngs determined for the periods (t+1, t+2,t+3) at t. A and B differ by the state of an
economy from period t to t+1. Realization of different paths makes A and B deviate
from the original plan C. In order to maintain balance between flexibility and
consistency, we have to determine an acceptable degree of variation, which sets a
boundary separated by space between A and C or B and C.
A
B
In practice, there are several ways to maintaining balance between flexibility and
consistency: (1) to allow adjustments among the sectoral ceilings while maintaining the
global ceiling, (2) to assign different margins of adjustment between the global ceiling
and the sectoral ceilings or among the sectoral ceilings, and (3) to decompose the
budget items into mandatory spending and discretionary spending and allow different
margins of adjustment to them. Each of the above alterations has pros and cons in
comparison with others. Hence, it is in the hands of political decision-makers to choose
one of them.
One of most important modules in MTEF is the provision of diverse channels for
information flow, the usefulness of which depends on its precision. Accordingly, a
Chapter 4. Successful Installation of MTEF to the Korean Fiscal System 55
logical tool for justifying a certain program, such as performance evaluation, would be
essential in MTEF. However, heterogeneity (or diversity) of public programs and
unaccountability of their hidden or intangible effects makes inter-program
performance comparison impossible.
MTEF itself is a fiscal program and is an object of performance. The two biggest
objectives of MTEF are (1) to maintain fiscal sustainability and (2) to enhance the
allocative efficiency among various sectors. However, due to the difficulty of finding a
right performance measure for inter-program comparison, in practice, performance
evaluation for MTEF is limited in checking fiscal sustainability. MTEF is not a legal
code to keep, once put into practice. Rather, MTEF is an apparatus to be evolved
reflecting past track records. The provision of performance measures for MTEF will
complete the evolutionary cycle of MTEF.
4. Concluding Remarks
The budgeting process is a collective action game. Various agents participate in the
process in the name of social welfare with hidden heterogeneous incentives. From the
standpoint of a principal, who devolves his/her decision right to the agents, optimal
mechanisms designed to coordinate interactions and conflicts among the agents would
be very critical. However, at the implementation stage informational asymmetry may
work against achieving social optimum.
The purpose of our research is to introduce a Medium-Term Expenditure
Framework and evaluate the pros and cons following its adoption to Koreas current
budgeting process. MTEF is not a perfect solution guaranteeing the efficiency of the
public sector. However, compared with the current system, MTEF is advantageous in
the following sense:
(1) MTEF is less reliant on discretionary factors and is rather rule-based. Rule-
based allocation of public resources ensures system predictability to
participants. Accordingly, the participants can pursue fiscal programs in a
more consistent way.
(2) MTEF system encourages efficiency-based competition among the conflicting
agents leading to a pseudo-market allocation. In contrast, allocation under the
current system does not provide a formal channel, through which the agents
can compete against others.
For the successful installation of MTEF in Korea, there are several points to
ponder. A substantial portion of this paper is devoted to the examination of various
issues, especially procedural ones. References to foreign country cases makes us realize
that at the stage of implementation MTEF should adapt the socio-economic
environments of an economy it is applied to. Accordingly, different schemes can be
adopted from country to country depending on the country-specific factors. Though
seemingly heterogeneous, diverse types of MTEF are designed to attain a common
goal, the provision of information channels and mechanism for early resolution of
uncertainty within a government, which is a necessary condition for Pareto efficiency
in Welfare Economics. Therefore, in designing an optimal MTEF for Korea, we have to
always ask ourselves whether a certain feature or a procedure under consideration will
contribute to reaching a pseudo market allocation of the annual budget.
56 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
References
by
Allan Gustafsson, Sweden
1. Background
Sweden is a constitutional monarchy and the King is the Head of State. His duties
are, however, mainly of a representative and ceremonial nature. The Constitution,
based on the principles of popular sovereignty, representative democracy, and
parliamentarism, thus begins by stating that all public power in Sweden proceeds
from the people.
Sweden has a unicameral parliament, the Riksdag, with 349 seats. Elections are by
proportional representation. The electoral system is designed to ensure a distribution
of seats between the parties in proportion to the votes cast for them nationally. A party
must gain at least 4 percent of the national vote to qualify for representation. Elections
are held every four years. The Riksdag, upon a proposal by the speaker of the Riksdag,
appoints a Prime Minister who is given the task of forming a government. The Prime
Minister chooses his/her ministers and together they make up the Swedish
Government. The Government is accountable to the Riksdag.
The Swedish Constitution consists of four separate documents. Of those, the
Instrument of Government (Regeringsformen), together with the Riksdag Act
(Riksdagsordningen), which occupies a position midway between constitutional and
regular statute law, set the overall framework for the budget and the budget process.
The structure of the budget and the budget work is regulated by a Budget Act which is
a regular statute law.
1.2. Reforms
The present structure and the procedures for preparing and deciding on the
budget are the result of a series of reforms initiated and implemented in a very short
time in the middle of the 1990s. The impetus to the reform came from the very deep
crises affecting the national economy and the government finances at the beginning of
the 1990s.
When analyzing the crises, it was found that one of the contributing factors to the
crises was a very lax budget process. One of its consequences was a seemingly
unstoppable growth in the relative size of the public sector and thus the tax burden.
Furthermore the Swedish public finances had become extremely sensitive to the swings
of the business cycle because of the dominant role of transfers to households in
government expenditure. As long as these swings were moderate, the opposing effects
on government revenue and expenditure served as automatic stabilizers. External
shocks of the magnitude experienced in the early 1990s, however, took the economy
58 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
out of bounds. The central government deficit exploded and reached 12 percent of
GNP in 1993. The gross financial debt peaked at 77 percent of GNP in 1996.
In order to reduce the swings in the budget balance but also and perhaps more
importantly to create a semi-automatic mechanism for containing the growth and
eventually reducing the size of the central government, the traditional incremental
bottom-up approach to budgeting was replaced by a very strict top-down process.
Subsequent to the reforms of the mid-1990s, public financial management now has
a three-year perspective within a top-down framework. This three-year perspective
and the top-down approach apply to budget preparation as well as to the decision-
making process in the Riksdag.
Execution of the budget is fully decentralized to the agencies responsible for
executing the some 500 appropriations. Appropriations for the administration of the
agencies are given as block appropriations, i.e. the agencies are completely free to
decide on the input-mix required to achieve the objectives established for its
operations. Objectives, targets and general reporting requirements are stated in the
yearly letter of appropriation (see further below) .
For many agencies, central financing from the Treasury is supplemented by or, in
some cases, completely made up of revenue accruing directly to them in the form of
fees and sales revenue. To give additional financial flexibility, the agencies have the
right, up to a limit, to carry over unused appropriations to the following year. They can
also, within limits, borrow against next years appropriation. Investment is financed by
internal loans issued by the Swedish National Debt Office. Payments are made directly
by the agencies and the accounts are kept according to generally accepted accounting
practice i.e. the type of accounting used private enterprises. The main instrument
against overspending is agency self-discipline. The accounts of every agency are
audited by the Swedish National Audit Office (Riksrevisionen). The audited accounts
are presented in a yearly report together with a review of activities of the past year put
in relation to the objectives and targets set in the letter of appropriation.
Budget formulation involves, in one way or another: the Riksdag, the Office of the
Prime-Minister, the Ministry of Finance, the line ministries55 and the agencies.
2.2. Macro-forecasting
55 The Office of the Prime Minister and the Ministries together make up the Government Offices.
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 59
through the Budget Department. The Financial Markets Department within the
Ministry of Finance provides input on financial variables, notably interest rates.
Besides providing input to the forecasting work of the DEA, NIER produces its
own independent macro-economic forecasts. Macro-economic forecasts are also
produced by the major banks and other private sector institutions. The existence of
multiple forecasters serves as a check on the forecasts made by the DEA.
Short-term macro-forecasts are based on a set of partial simulation models but
outcomes of those are adjusted on the basis of judgment backed up by a set of quick
indicators. Medium-term models rely more heavily on models. DEA uses a stripped-
down version of a partial equilibrium model developed by the NIER. Work is on-going
at the NIER to develop a more sophisticated scenario-type model.
The process at DEA generates forecasts for a number of variables that are
subsequently used as inputs in the forecasting of government expenditure, for
example: nominal GNP, nominal GNI, household consumption, CPI, interest rates and
employment.
DEA produces four to six complete forecasts during a year. Two of those are
published those on which the Spring Finance Bill and the Budget Bill are based.
The ambition is to produce as accurate forecasts as possible. The political level at
the Ministry of Finance has largely refrained from trying to influence the forecasts
knowing well that any manipulation would jeopardize its credibility. The existence of
alternative forecasts those of the NIER and private sector institutions also serve as a
check on the official ones. Contrary to what is done in some other countries, for
example Canada, there is no systematic conservative bias introduced into the forecasts.
The need for a buffer to absorb external shocks is instead met by an explicit budget
margin on the expenditure side of the budget.
As a starting point for every budget round, a baseline is estimated. The base-line,
termed consequence assessment, is an estimate of what would be the outlay for every
single appropriation and, thus, for the aggregate budget. The baseline presumes no
change in policy and no change in activity volumes except for those that follow from
decisions made in earlier budget rounds. The baseline thus only takes into
consideration changes in factors that are beyond the immediate control of government,
such as changes in prices, wages, exchange rates, and interest rates. To increase
accuracy and fairness, a number of more focused price indices not just CPI are used.
For the appropriations for normal administrative costs of agencies, three indices are
used: for wages, for rents and for other operational costs. From the thus reflated initial
baseline estimate is then deducted a variable percentage to reflect presumed efficiency
gains. The efficiency factor, which is based on national accounts statistics, concretely a
moving average for the preceding ten years, has in recent years hovered around 1.5
percent.
For appropriations like defense and infrastructural investment other types of
specialized indices are used.
The models used to produce the baseline estimates vary a great deal in complexity.
Some are quite simple doing nothing more than reflating last years appropriation
adjusted for presumed efficiency gains. Other models, in particular those referring to
some of the entitlement programs, are more complex. Some simulations use a sample
of individual household data as its basis; others more aggregate data. All models are
partial but estimated feed-back effects are incorporated into successive forecasting
rounds.
At present, the responsibility for the different models is largely decentralized to
line ministries and sometimes to the responsible agencies. At the beginning of the
exercise, Ministry of Finance, however, makes available a set of parameters
assumptions regarding the evolution of the different price indices, GDP growth rates,
unemployment etc. to the forecasting institutions. Sometime in the future, the models
will be incorporated into the government-wide budgeting and reporting system that is
in the process of being developed.
3. Allocation: level 2
3.1. Global expenditure ceiling
Global expenditure ceilings are set for three years on a rolling basis. That is, every
year a global ceiling for year t+3 is established. Beginning 2002, the Governments firm
proposal is presented in the Budget Bill and voted on by the Riksdag in the fall.56
56 During the first years after the introduction of the new budget process, it was presented in the Spring
Finance Bill and voted on separately. The rationale for presenting and voting on the global expenditure ceiling
separately in the spring was to put focus on the longer-term fiscal issues. However, it, in practice, led to two
budget processes leaving very little time for follow-up of government programs and the proposal and the
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 61
The Riksdags decision on the expenditure ceilings are, strictly speaking, not
legally binding but in practice they have held firm.57 The over-all ceiling has become
almost sacrosanct, while its break-down into expenditure ceilings is more indicative
and finds its final form only for the up-coming year.
The process in which the global expenditure ceiling for year t+3 is set is not
entirely straight-forward, being partly technical, partly political. The starting point is a
forecast of central government revenue based on the existing tax structure and existing
tax rates plus any already decided on changes in the latter. From this revenue estimate
is deducted the business-cycle adjusted surplus target and the target budget margin in
order to arrive at the global expenditure ceiling. The present surplus target is an
average of 2 percent of GDP over the business cycle and the target budget margin for
year t+3 is 1.5 percent of total expenditure. If year t+3 is forecasted to be a boom year,
the surplus target should in principle be adjusted upwards and vice versa. In
mathematical notation:
Underlying this approach to the expenditure ceiling coming in from the revenue
side is, or at least was, a concern about the tax burden in general and the marginal
effects in particular. The concrete effect was, as the Swedish economy recovered from
the crises of the early-mid nineties, a dramatic lowering of the proportion taken up by
general government in the economy: from 70 percent to 55 percent measured on the
expenditure side. In the last three years, this downward trend has, however, leveled off
at about 55 percent.
The revenue projections are, however, not end of story. Expenditure is also
forecasted making in effect Tt+3 in the formula above to some extent endogenous.
Should the projections of growth in the economy, and thus of revenue, point to a
surplus beyond the desired surplus target and the target budget margin, the
Government can decide to lower taxes and/or increase expenditure. If the opposite
would obtain, expenditure will have to be curtailed and/or taxes increased.
The budget department prepares a number of scenarios which are presented to the
Minister of Finance and the Prime Minister who in the end make a political choice as to
the exact level of the expenditure ceiling.
One technical aspect of the expenditure ceilings is worth pointing out; they are
expressed in nominal terms. A nominal ceiling on government expenditure adds
credibility to the inflation ceiling established by the central bank. It is particularly
important in a country, like Sweden, where the public sector occupies such a large
share of the national economy.
The total expenditure ceiling for year t+2 may, in principle, be altered but the
Government has so far chosen to confirm the one established the year before, save for
any adjustments for technical reasons.
discussion on the global expenditure ceilings have now been shifted to the fall.
57 Contrary to the Latin tradition, budgets in Sweden do not have the status of laws.
62 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
The ceiling for t+2 becomes the starting point for the process of preparing the
detailed budget the subsequent year. During the first years after the budget reform, the
Government prepared and Parliament decided on indicative expenditure ceilings in the
spring. This is no longer the case. Nevertheless, the Government, in its March retreat,
decides internally on the expenditure area allocations and those allocations serve as
guidelines for the preparation of the detailed budget proposal, i.e. the proposed
allocation to the approximately 500 appropriations.
The starting point for the allocations between the expenditure areas is the baseline
calculations or consequence assessments described above. The line ministries also
present budget requests on the basis of requests prepared by the agencies under their
jurisdiction. In these requests the ministries may argue for higher allocations to
particular areas and they are not, at least not in practice, constrained by the
expenditure area ceilings decided on by Parliament in the previous fall. What ensues is
a rather intensive negotiations process involving the line ministry and the Budget
Department within the Ministry of Finance and to the extent necessary the Minister of
Finance and even the Prime Minister. However, once the expenditure ceilings are set
by the Cabinet in March, they, in principle, have to be respected when making the final
allocation to individual appropriations presented in the Budget Bill. Some adjustment
may have to be made for technical reasons or because some fundamental assumption,
for example, on employment/unemployment, has to be revised.
The budgeting process is thus fundamentally incremental, albeit within the
confines of the global and the expenditure area ceilings. There is definitely no zero-
based budgeting taking place and there is no systematic attempt at estimating the
return on government spending in different areas. Nor is there really any systematic
use of information on results and of all other types of information that agencies are
required to feed back to the Government Offices and to Parliament.
Attempts at basing the budget process on and around a more streamlined
programmatic structure for the budget, allowing a systematic feed-back and analysis of
outputs and outcomes, have, at least for the time being, got bogged down; a new
programmatic structure has been introduced and should, in principle, be used for
reporting, but budgeting and the allocation of resources is still made in the old
structure severely limiting the usefulness of the reform.58
58 The duplication of structures will undoubtedly prove untenable and in time a replacement of one for the
other or some type of merger of the two will necessarily have to be engineered. As a trial balloon an accrual-
based shadow budget for 2004 will be presented for information purposes. The shadow budget will be broken
down by policy areas rather than by expenditure areas.
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 63
Budget Department has a tendency to get involved in rather low-level issues, issues
that presumably, given the existence of expenditure areas ceilings, could be handled
within the respective line ministries. However, well established procedures for
handling differences of position do exist; outstanding issues are raised to successively
hierarchically higher levels if need be to the Prime Minister until they are resolved.
The top-down approach to budgeting has not completely closed the window for
intra-governmental negotiations. Although line ministries, in principle, ought to
respect the ceilings established by the Riksdag, they often do use their budget proposal
as a vehicle for demands for additional funding. These proposals can, however, not be
wildly out of line or they would not be taken seriously. The ceilings thus act as a
restraint but not as an absolute constraint on the agency and line ministry proposals.
One could also argue that, for want of a more systematic and structured way of
assessing the effectiveness of government spending, in particular of larger
programmatic aggregates, agencies and line ministries should have at least one formal
channel for arguing their case.
The proposed allocation between expenditure areas and within expenditure areas
is finally established in the Budget Bill. The final inter-expenditure area allocations
correspond very closely to those decided on in the March retreat by the Cabinet. The
difference between the two has, in recent years, been less than one percent and almost
solely in entitlement programs where changes in the macro environment and/or in
other external factors have necessitated a review of the forecasts. In principle these
changes normally increases should be absorbed by a reallocation within or between
expenditure areas. In practice they have, in most cases, led to a reduction of the budget
margin.
The differences between the provisional inter-expenditure allocations presented
for t+2 in the Budget Bill one year earlier and the eventual final allocations have tended
to be considerably bigger. In the two most recent Budget Bills, the importance of the
expenditure area breakdowns for t+2 and for t+3 have been downplayed by only
requesting the Riksdag to approve the forecasted consequence assessments rather
than to set firm ceilings. In next years budget round, the allocations for t+2 may again
be given a more definite status while those for t+3 are likely to continue to be only
indicative and based on the presumption of no substantive changes.
consequences. Generously interpreted that could mean that the Budget Department
ought to get involved in just about every single decision on the budget. On the other
hand, with the top-down decision-making mechanism in place, any effects on
aggregate spending are already effectively blocked. The departments involvement in
the details is really more a question of old habits taking a while do die. The present
culture at the Department was also very much set during the days of the financial
crises when the Departments singly most important task was to scour the budget for
potential expenditure reductions.
The Department is still largely staffed with relatively young professionals for
whom a couple years at the Budget Department traditionally have served as a catapult
to good careers in other parts of the public sector.59 The increased responsibility for the
allocation of resources between expenditure areas has not yet led to any noticeable
changes in staff composition or any systematic up-grading of staff skills, although it
ought to have.
In the line ministries, the units responsible for the coordination of budget work
have come to play a more important role. It is difficult to say whether there has been
any systematic up-grading of staff skills.
59 There are signs that that may now be changing with a general tightening of the public sector job market.
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 65
i.e. the right to borrow against next years appropriation, d) an estimate of fee revenue
that will be under the control of the agency, e) a ceiling on borrowing for investment in
fixed assets, f) a ceiling on credit to meet short-term cash-flow needs, and g) any
explicitly authorized, special, longer-term or multi-year commitments.
In parallel with the preparation of the letters of appropriation by the Government,
the Riksdag compiles the final central government budget and hands it over to the
Government a few days before Christmas.
5. Execution
Once the budget is enacted and the letters of appropriation issued, the execution of
the budget is fully delegated to the agencies. For the framework appropriations
financing the administrative expenses of agencies, one twelfth of the yearly
appropriation is transferred monthly to interest-bearing accounts within the
government group account held in one of the commercial banks. 60 Payments are
executed by the agencies themselves without the intervention of any central
government treasury. Should the need for liquidity exceed what is available, it is met
by a credit facility attached to the bank accounts.61
The strict annuality of traditional budgetary principles is, thus, done away with
and all control of execution is ex post. Within the more flexible framework created by
block appropriations, carry-overs, appropriation credits, loan and credit facilities, the
agencies are expected to, and in fact generally do, behave responsibly.
The accounting is decentralized to the agencies and the accounting is done
according to generally accepted accounting principles, i.e. the principles that are used
in the private sector world wide. The general accounts are complete, i.e. they, besides
the central funding, include all other revenue such as sales income and fees, all
expenses, and assets and liabilities. The follow-up against the appropriations
sometimes called the budgetary accounting is integrated into the general accounts.62
Information from the budgetary accounts is transferred monthly to the central
government financial management information system. Complete, accrual-based
accounts for all individual agencies are prepared twice a year and consolidated into
aggregate accounts for the entire central government. This is done by the National
Financial Management Authority.
All agencies are subject to financial audits every year and performance audits are
carried out as necessary. With the creation of the new Swedish National Audit Office
under the Riksdag, the consolidated accounts will also be audited. Another mechanism
to stimulate good and responsible financial management is a yearly rating of the
agencies done by the National Financial Management Authority.
60 In the near future, the Government will tender for payments and group account services from several
banks. The Swedish National Debt Office is responsible for the oversight of government payments and is
responsible for the over-night clearing of the group-account(s).
61 As regards transfer payments, they are also channeled through sub-accounts of the government group
account but are replenished on the day of payment from the general government account controlled by the
National Debt Office.
62 This integration is, however, not entirely straightforward and transparent because the budgetary
accounts follow different principles than those of the general accounts. Efforts to fully integrate budget follow-
up into the general accounts by defining the appropriations in terms that are fully compatible with those of
accrual accounting have got bogged down.
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 67
Although the new process has transformed the dynamics of preparing and
deciding on the budget, it takes a while for bad old habits to die completely. And what
Swedish politics traditionally has been made of is promising the electorate additional
social benefits under the name of reforms. However, with the ceiling effectively set
three years earlier, the one seemingly remaining opportunity for politicians wanting to
squeeze in yet one more reform has been to eat away at the budget margin. For that
they have had to bet on being no unexpected cost increases in other areas.
Unfortunately this has invariably proven to be an overly optimistic assumption and the
price to be paid has been painful decisions and maneuverings at year-end to squeeze
under the ceiling and a concomitant loss of credibility.
The top-down budgeting process, together with the increased focus on results, has
created an opportunity for pondering, in a more thorough and systematic way, the
overall composition of the budget. This opportunity has not really been seized.
It must, of course, be acknowledged that it is impossible to scientifically calculate
and in any definitive way decide what would be the optimal sector allocation of
government resources. There are too many imponderables, potential synergies and
external effects for that ever to be conceivable.
It could still be argued that a lot more could be done in the way of analyzing the
effectiveness and efficiency of programs even at a more aggregate level and seeing
to it that the outcomes of those analytical endeavors are fed into the political process.
For that to happen, the roles of the different actors in the budget process would need to
be reviewed in order to achieve a clearer division of labor and responsibilities. One
obstacle has previously also been the limited IT support for the budget process. That is
now changing with the building up of an internet-based FMIS that will soon service all
ministries and agencies. However, better IT support is a necessary but not a sufficient
condition for a division of responsibilities better in keeping with the new top-down
68 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
approach. A cultural revolution and new capabilities will be needed at all levels within
the Cabinet Office.
The new multi-year top-down budget process has extended the budget horizon
beyond the immediately coming year. It has not, however, automatically led to a
systematic factoring in of the longer-term beyond the three-year horizon of the
expenditure ceilings. For Sweden, as for many other European countries, the fiscal
perspective for the period beyond 2008 is quite problematic because of the aging
population. Sweden does have a target for the budget balance that is higher than that
of most other countries within the European Union. Still it is probably not ambitious
enough to build the buffers that will be needed if the next generation is not to bear the
entire burden of the aging population. The problem is a specific and acute one for
Sweden, but a generic one for all MTEF type efforts; in incorporating the medium-term
into the budget process, one must not loose sight of the long-term!
The challenge is to create a framework for political decision-making that, just as
the new top-down budgeting process in Sweden, conditions the outcome in favor of
long-term collective rationality at the expense of short-term vested interests and vote
maximization.
Global, hard budget constraints are essential to fiscal discipline; but it makes a
difference how they are defined. There are several different dimensions to this issue.
For example, what should be the accounting basis for the constraints? In Sweden,
the accounting basis for the volume constraint (to use a generic term for the
expenditure ceiling) is the budgetary accounts, and they are expenditure-based. An
alternative would be to base the volume constraint on the general accounts which are
accrual-based. One important difference between the two sets of accounts is the
treatment of investment. In the budgetary accounts, the full outlay for investments is
included while in the accrual-based accounts only depreciation appears. The treatment
of investment in the expenditure-based budgetary accounts means that, in relation to
the global constraint, outlays for investments compete, krona for krona, with recurrent
expenditure. One effect is that, in a tight fiscal situation, reductions in the budget are
likely to focus on investment, simply because the government has more discretionary
power over it.
A second important issue as regards the global volume ceiling is what should be
included: total expenditure/cost for the entire general government or only central
government? If the constraint should cover only central government, should it
constrain total expenditure/cost or only that financed by central funds?63
Furthermore, should all types of expenditure/cost be included, or should some be
excluded because the government has very little control over it in the short term? In the
case of Sweden, interest payments on the central government debt are excluded. They
63 A technical question in that respect is whether it is possible, in situations where central funds are pooled
with other types of revenue, to attribute an expenditure/cost to a particular source of finance at least in a
credible way. And if one can not credibly follow it in the accounts, should one design a constraint that
presumes just that?
Chapter 5. MTEF in Sweden 69
were with good reason excluded during the turbulent years of the 1990s when interest
rates were very volatile and even the slightest suspicion that the Swedish Government
would default on its loans for example because of putting interest payments under
the ceiling would have pushed interest rates even higher. In a more stable situation,
like today, the choice is not quite as obvious. Interest payments are largely exogenous
in the short term but in the medium- and long-term the Government can certainly
influence them through its debt policy. Including interest payments under the ceiling
would increase the incentives to reduce debt for the benefit of future generations.
And then there are the funds outside the budget, like the pension fund. In Sweden
they are included because payments in nature are very similar to regular government
expenditure; they can be influenced by political decisions. In a funded system the
Government would have no such right and it would be incorrect to include it.
As regards the budget balance, it is defined in national accounts terms. Having the
two global constraints defined in different terms complicates matters technically and
pedagogically. An alternative, given the existence of accrual-based accounts in the
areas for which the balance is calculated, would be to define it in straight accrual
accounting terms. The balance thus calculated could then for comparative purposes
cf. the Maastricht criteria be translated into NR terms.
Sweden has, for good or bad, made a set of choices for how to define the aggregate
ceilings. For any other country, the definitions would have to be based on an
assessment what the ceilings should and could achieve and what the technical options
for defining the ceilings are.
CHAPTER 6
The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions
by
Niklas Frank, Sweden
1. Background
In Sweden the Parliament is highly involved in the budget process. From a formal
point of view the Parliament can change anything it wants in the budget. All the
standing committees in Parliament, there are 16 all together, are involved in the
process, and the responsibility for expenditure is divided between the various
committees. The budget is split in to 27 expenditure areas designed to reflect different
areas of political interest, and the responsibility for the expenditure areas are divided
between the committees according to their specialities. One committee may be
responsible for one or more expenditure area but no expenditure area may be split
between committees.
When the Government submits a bill to the Parliament, each Member of
Parliament has the unrestricted right during 15 days to submit counter proposals, so-
called motions. The motions are then distributed to the same committee that has been
assigned the bill. Based on the bill and the motions, the committee then produces a
report to the Chamber. This report contains the formal proposal on which the
Parliament votes, as well as written argumentation about all the proposals. The
committees must respond to every bill and every motion, none of them may be put
aside. This applies also in the budget process. The Parliament subsequently has to
process the Governments budget documents as well as all the counter proposals that
have been made by individual members.
0
80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02
-1
-2
72 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
The Swedish budget process was radically reformed in the middle of the 1990s,
from a bottom-up to a top-down process. The starting point of the reforms was the
deep economic recession that hit the country in the beginning of 1990s. The
environment in which the budget reforms took place was an environment of crisis.
In 1993 which was the worst year of the recession unemployment rose to 8 percent,
a historically record high level. Growth in GDP was negative by 1.8 percent and the
situation for the public finances was very serious.
The Central Government borrowing requirement amounted in 1993 to almost 17
percent of GDP and the overall deficit in the public sector was almost 12 percent of
GDP. The deterioration of the public finances was great and very rapid. In the late
1980s Sweden had one of the largest surpluses in the OECD and only a few years later
one of the largest deficits. By 1993 the national debt amounted to 76 percent of GDP,
and was rising rapidly. Between 1988 and 1993 the public sector expenditure rose from
55 to 68 percent of GDP.
6
Sweden European Union
4
0
80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
At the same time there were serious problems in the financial sector as well. The
Government had to spend about 4 percent of GDP to save banks from going bankrupt.
In November 1992 the fixed exchange rate was abandoned for a freely floating rate,
after the Central Bank had unsuccessfully tried to defend the fixed exchange rate by
raising the short-term interest rate to 500 percent. The value of the currency quickly
dropped by about 25 percent.
To stabilize the public finances and lay foundations for an economic recovery,
broad and radical measures were taken both reductions in public expenditure and
increases in taxes. There was also a broad political understanding that besides dealing
with the immediate crises in the public finances, there was a need to find ways of
preventing a similar situation from reoccurring in the future. In order to improve the
long-run stability of the public finances and prevent a repetition of the dramatic
deterioration during the early 1990s, the institutional arrangements around the budget
were fundamentally changed.
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 73
The new budget process, which was in place in 1997, was stronger than the old
process in virtually all respects. Changes were made in how the Government prepares
the budget and in the way the Parliament considers and approves the budget as well as
in the control and steering mechanisms on the implementation of the budget by the
various Government agencies. The principles and rules for the budget were given a
stronger legal status in the form of a budget law that was approved by the Parliament.
According to a comparative study about the strength of the budget processes in a
number of European countries, the Swedish process went from being one of the
weakest in Europe to being one of the strongest after the budget reform.
The reformed budget process enabled the Parliament to take a more general and co-
ordinated approach to the budget, focusing less on details and more on aggregates. The
level of Central Government expenditure is determined three years ahead by setting an
expenditure ceiling, and decisions on the budget are taken in two stages, the so-called
framework model. The decision-making approach is top-down, starting with the whole
and ending with the details. A surplus target for the whole public finances is being used.
In this presentation, I will focus on two elements of the new budget process, the two
elements I regard as being the most important. First there is the use of two budgetary
targets the Central Government expenditure ceiling and the surplus target for the total
public sector, and second there is the two-stage decision process in the Parliament.
2. Two budgetary targets, the expenditure ceiling and the surplus target
A central element of the reformed budget process is the usage of quantitative
budgetary targets. The Government has set up two such targets. There is a target
stating that the expenditure of the Central Government budget must not exceed the
expenditure ceiling that Parliament has decided upon. There is also a target for the
financial balance in the total public sector, stating that as an average over a business
cycle, there should be a surplus of two percent of GDP.
The two targets are different in their construction and use, and they should be
regarded as complementary parts of an integrated budget system.
Expenditure area 1
+ ...........
+ ...........
+ Expenditure area 27
= Sum of expenditure areas
- Interest on National Debt
+ Public pension system expenditure
= Expenditure capped by ceiling
+ Budget margin (residual)
= Global Expenditure Ceiling
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 75
The expenditure ceiling is stated in nominal terms, which means that the level set
for each year of the three-year budget cycle is neither adjusted for inflation, nor
indexed in any other way. The calculation of the ceiling is based on a macro-economic
forecast that is presented in great detail in the budget documents. The inflation target
of the central bank is to keep inflation at 2 percent (+/- 1 percentage point), and the
macro-economic forecast for the budget is done in accordance with this target,
assuming that the central bank meets its target.
The Parliaments decision on the expenditure ceiling is a so-called guideline
decision, which means that it is not legally binding, and the Parliament is also able to
review an earlier decision on an expenditure area. This could happen if there was a
change of Government, in which case the incoming Government has the opportunity of
submitting a proposal that differs from expenditure levels determined earlier. The
expenditure ceiling should be regarded as a very strong budgetary commitment on the
part of the sitting Government to implement a policy where aggregate Central
Government expenditure (excluding interest on national debt) is kept within levels
previously determined.
The surplus target is defined to include the three sectors that make up the entire
public sector, the Central Government, the Local Governments and the Public Pension
system. The target is specified in accordance with the European accounting system
(European System of Accounts, ESA95) and numbers are comparable to the other EU-
countries. This is also the system used when evaluating the European stability pact to
make sure that no country has a public sector deficit that exceeds 3 percent of GDP at
any time.
The target stipulates that as an average over the business cycle, the over all public
sector should show a surplus of two percent of GDP. For an individual year the surplus
might, and should, deviate from the two percent depending on the current
macroeconomic situation. Twice every year, the Government reports to the Parliament
about the financial balance and presents three-year forecasts for the economy and the
public sector financial balance.
The surplus target and the expenditure ceiling should be regarded as
complementary targets. When the expenditure ceiling is set, it must be set in such a
way that the surplus target is met, provided the estimated revenues. If revenues exceed
the forecast those extra funds may not be used to increase expenditure more than is
permitted by the expenditure ceiling. If revenues fall below the estimates then revenue
either will have to be raised or expenditure cut in order to maintain the surplus target.
Together the two targets provide a strong framework for the budget formulation.
The budget process in the Parliament begins when the Government submits its
Spring Fiscal Policy Bill. The bill, which must be submitted no later than April 15,
contains an assessment of the current economic situation with perspectives for the next
three years and proposals for the orientation of the economic policy and the budget
policy.
In the Spring Bill there are no formal proposals from the Government involving
precise numbers. The bill contains detailed medium-term forecasts for the macro
economy, the Central Government expenditure and revenue, and the overall public
finances. In the bill the Government presents the expenditure for the coming three
years on expenditure area level, divided in to the 27 different areas. At this stage the
Government presents a calculation of the year t+3 to the Parliament for the first time.
Calculations of revenue are also presented in a relatively high level of detail.
The Spring Bill is thus used to give Parliament a rather detailed picture of the
economy as well as the budgetary situation. There must however be neither tax
proposals, nor proposals concerning the expenditure at this stage. The detailed
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 77
presentation of the budget gives the Parliament information about what the
Government intends to propose later in the Budget Bill, due in September.
As with all Government bills, the members of Parliament have 15 days to write
their counter proposals, their motions. In the case of the Spring Bill, the opposition
parties, currently four, present their alternative views on the economic situation and
their alternative suggestions regarding guidelines for the economic policy and the
budget policy. In this process the special committees in Parliament may submit their
opinions about the Government bill, as well as about the oppositions proposals, to the
Committee on Finance.
The Spring Bill, the proposals from the opposition and the opinions from other
committees, are all submitted to the Committee on Finance, which writes a report to
the Chamber where the political alternatives are presented. In the middle of June a
formal decision is taken about the guidelines for the economic policy and the budget
policy.
3.2.1. Overview
The Government submits its Budget Bill for the following year by September 20 at
the latest, a few days after the opening of the parliamentary session. During election
years the submission period may be extended, but no later than November 15. The
Budget Bill covers all expenditure and revenue, since no further proposals with
budgetary consequences may be submitted before the beginning of the fiscal year. The
gross principle is applied in that all revenue and expenditure are accounted for
separately.
All intended changes for the coming year in revenues and expenditure must be
presented to the Parliament in the Budget Bill. The estimates of expenditure as well as
revenue must include all the proposed changes. There must be no last minute changes
of taxes or expenditure after the presentation of the Budget Bill.
The expenditure is presented with its 27 expenditure areas and 500 appropriations,
and the revenue is presented with its 150 items. The opposition parties present their
alternative proposals to those of the Government. Usually the opposition parties
provide an overall presentation of their budget alternatives in special motions on
economic policy. In this context they present their proposals for the expenditure ceiling
and for the allocation of expenditure between the expenditure areas. In their motions
on economic policy the parties also present an overview of the changes in taxes and
charges they wish to implement, and how proposals for different reforms should be
financed.
A more detailed specification of the various parties budgetary proposals is set out
in special tax and appropriations motions, where the parties usually present their
proposals in the form of one motion per expenditure area.
In the first decision the Parliament also determines changes in the taxes and
charges for the next fiscal year. This enables the level of Central Government revenue
for the following year to be estimated. For obvious reasons, it is not possible to
determine limits for revenue in the same way as for expenditure. This is why the
Parliament does not make a decision on revenue limits. Revenues are determined by
how the tax base changes, which itself is related to changes in the economy, and the
rules applicable to taxes and charges. These rules apply until they are changed or
removed and are not considered by the Parliament each year when determining the
budget. The budget proposal can, however, contain proposals for changes in the
regulatory framework covering e.g. tax changes. The Parliament approves an estimate
of the Central Government revenues during the coming fiscal year, and at the same
time decides which changes in taxes and charges are to be implemented. Since the
levels of revenue and expenditure are thus determined, the level of borrowing
requirements can also be stated.
The Committee on Finance handles proposals on the frames for all the expenditure
areas. The other committees may submit their views to the Committee on Finance on
the expenditure areas for which they are responsible. The committees are free to
propose changes in the level of the different expenditure areas and/or recommend a
reallocation of funds between expenditure areas. In the same way, they can make
proposals that affect the level of Central Government revenue.
The Committee on Finance then examines these proposals and uses them as a basis
for submitting an overall proposal that will be considered by the Chamber around
November 20. The debate in the Chamber concludes with the Parliament making one
single decision determining several important elements simultaneously. The main
elements of the decision are:
The fact that all these points are decided by Parliament in one single decision, is
not a mere technicality, but is of crucial importance to the top-down character of the
budget process. The Committee on Finance decides the distribution of expenditure
between the expenditure areas, in a single decision. Thus any Parliamentary changes in
the Governments suggested distribution can only be done by the Committee on
Finance in this first stage of the decision process. This single decision system has at
least two important implications for the budget process.
Firstly, it sets a restriction on what the special committees can do in the second
stage of the process. The special committees are responsible for the distribution of
expenditure appropriations within their respective expenditure areas, but they have to
keep expenditure inside the expenditure area frame set in the first stage. A special
committee can therefore not expand the expenditure in its own area even if there is a
majority in that committee to do so. The room for maneuver in the special committees
is therefore highly restricted.
Secondly, it forces the opposition parties to present complete budget alternatives
instead of only picking the pieces they prefer to discuss. To present a feasible
alternative to the Governments budget proposal, the opposition has to present an
alternative decision including all its tax changes and its distribution of expenditure
between the 27 expenditure areas. All expenditure limits and tax changes are treated as
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 79
a single package, and alternatives are considered against each other as single
packages. The Parliament then takes a position on the entire package. This means
that even if the opposition parties agree on an issue, they cannot form a majority on
this issue alone and use this to reject a part of the Government proposal. To defeat the
Government in the parliamentary vote, the opposition must agree on an entire budget
package.
This budget decision is probably the single most important decision that the
Parliament takes during the year. If the opposition would actually win this vote there
would be a Government crisis. Without support for its budget policy the Government
might have to resign, or there would most likely be at least a vote of no confidence.
With this package decision, six weeks before the start of the year t+1, the
Parliament sets the expenditure limits and concludes its revenue deliberations and
determines the tax regulations that will be in force in the coming year. Still remaining
is the more detailed allocation of Central Government expenditure. This is dealt with
during the second stage of the budget process.
been done, the Government issues budget letters to its agencies with instructions for
how the appropriations are to be used.
When all the reports have been dealt with, the Parliament compiles the now
finalized Central Government budget for the coming year and hands it over to the
Government a few days before Christmas.
The two-stage decision model has given the Committee on Finance the overall
responsibility for the budget in the Parliament. The Committee on Finance has been
given the power to restrict the other committees possibilities of spending resources in
their own areas. Giving this power to the Committee on Finance has been an important
element in creating a top-down structure of the process. The overall expenditure ceiling
and the distribution between expenditure areas are decided first, setting the limits for
the appropriations in the different expenditure areas. Provided that the expenditure
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 81
area frames are not exceeded, the special committees however still have great freedom
to redistribute the expenditure within their respective expenditure areas.
Transparency has improved in several ways. The budget has been made complete
and extra-budgetary funds abolished. Revenue and expenditure are accounted for
separately and net budgeting is not permitted. The need for the opposition to present
complete budget proposals has made the political alternatives more open and
comparable. It is no longer possible for an opposition party to present for instance large
increases in benefits without declaring how it will be financed.
One criticism from the Parliament has been that the budget process takes all year.
Producing a complete budget alternative is a great deal of work for the opposition
parties, particularly for a small party with limited resources. This aspect led to a
change in the system in 2002. Before then the formal proposal on the overall
expenditure ceiling was a part of the Spring Bill. The Spring Bill then contained
guidelines for the economic policy and for the budget policy as well as an expenditure
ceiling for the year t+3. In 2002 this was changed so that the ceiling for t+3 is proposed
in the Budget Bill in September. This was a controversial change decided by a united
opposition against the will of the Government, who argued that the change would
weaken the budget process.
When the system was launched, there was a guideline about the size of the budget
margin saying that the margin should be approximately 1.5, 2.0 and 2.5 percent of the
total expenditure for the years t+1 to t+3. As uncertainty about the numbers grew over
time, so would the budget margin. In practice, however, this margin has not been
upheld. Instead there has been a tendency to use the margin for new expenditure,
leaving little or no room to accommodate increased expenditure due to changing
underlying variables. Several times the Government has had to take short-term
measures in the end of the year to avoid the expenditure ceiling being exceeded. This
has had a tendency to shift focus back again from the medium term to the short term,
at least in the end of the fiscal year.
This problem has been discussed extensively as the Government has been
criticized for its handling of the budget margin. The Government has been requested
by the Parliament to present new guidelines about the size and use of the budget
margin in the Spring Bill in April this year.
The lack of margin to the ceiling at the end of the year has led to short-term
measures to avoid exceeding the ceiling. At times such measures have been dubious
82 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
from the perspective of the budget law. The Government has for instance decided to
delay expenditure from December to January and there are examples where net
budgeting has been applied even though the budget law prohibits it. These short-term
measures are obviously closely related to the problem of having a too small budget
margin.
6. Concluding remarks
Both the Government and the Parliament have made evaluations of the budget
process, and both have concluded that the reformation has been very successful. The
two evaluations have pointed out the problems mentioned above, but put in
perspective of all the changes that were made, these problems must be considered
limited. There can be no doubt that the new process is far stricter than the old, since it
was strengthened in practically every respect and transformed from one of the weakest
to one of the strongest in Europe.
60
50
30
80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02
How important is the budget process to the outcome of the budget policy? Would
the budgetary situation look different if the budget reform had never taken place?
Concerning this, a few observations can be made. The far-reaching decisions that were
taken in the middle of the 1990s to strengthen the public finances were all taken before
the reformation of the budget process. In the rather critical situation of 1993 there was a
great need to strengthen the budget and no time to wait. When the political will was
strong enough, drastic measures could be taken even without a strong budget process.
After the immediate crises, during the years in the late 1990s the economy was
performing relatively well. Between 1998 to 2000, the economy grew faster than the
European average. Tax revenues were exceeding the forecasts and there was a
substantial surplus in the total public sector. At the same time the expenditure ceiling
was set so that expenditure were reduced as a share of GDP. Between 1997 and 2000
the expenditure ceiling was reduced from 38 to 34 percent of GDP. Since then the
ceiling has been stable.
Chapter 6. The Swedish Budget Process: Expenditure Targets and Top-down Decisions 83
39,0
38,0
37,0
36,0
35,0
34,0
33,0
32,0
31,0
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
I believe there is a rather strong case for the claim that the reformation of the
budget process has contributed to the stable development of the public finances since
the middle of the 1990s. A lot of political prestige has been invested in the new system,
both by the Government and the opposition, and the potential political risks of ruining
or undermining the system are considerable. During this period there has been a Social
Democratic minority Government that has negotiated the budget with either one or
two other parties, and the respect for the expenditure ceiling has been a cornerstone all
through those negotiations. As mentioned above, the budget margins have become
very small at times, but measures have been taken to stop the ceiling from being
exceeded. It is not a very brave guess that without the ceiling, the negotiations would
have generated significantly higher expenditures.
It should be added though, that the real test for the system is yet to come. During
the boom years of the late 1990s the surplus target for the public sector could be upheld
with relative ease thanks to the high levels of tax revenue. There was even room to
fulfil the surplus target and cut taxes at the same time. The last few years, however,
have shown a less favorable macroeconomic development. This has led to weaker
growth in tax revenues and increases in expenditure mostly related to health insurance
and unemployment. For the first time since the new budget system was put in place,
there is now simultaneous pressure on both budgetary targets, and the macroeconomic
situation is not helping to ease the pressure.
It is crucial to keep in mind, even though it may seem self-evident, that in the long
run no budget process is stronger than the political will to maintain it. There is a
delicate balance between a system strict enough to have substantial influence on the
budget policy, and loose enough to provide the necessary room for political maneuver.
CHAPTER 7
Medium-term Financial Planning in the Federal Republic of Germany
by
Astrid Lbke, Germany
1. Introduction
This paper provides an overview of the federal government's medium-term
financial planning in the Federal Republic of Germany.
Section 2 describes the historical development of medium-term financial planning
since the 1969 budget reform as well as the need for and the objectives of such financial
planning. The basic features of the content and of the planning period are outlined.
Section 3 shows in detail which parties offer advice and help shape the medium-term
financial planning and sketches the planning procedure. Section 4 takes as a specific
example the current budget preparation procedure to demonstrate how financial
planning can be realized in the same cycle.
The 1969 budget reform set up a mandatory, standardized framework for the
budget law of the central and regional governments. For one thing, the budget
provisions in the Basic Law of the Federal Republic of Germany (Sections 109 to 115)
were revised. For another, the Law on Budget Principles was passed. The Law on
Budget Principles contains the common principles which the federal government and
the Lnder must follow in managing their budgets. The Law on Budget Principles
provides the substructure upon which is built both the Federal Budget Code of the
German federal government, and the Land budget codes of all the federal States
(Lnder) of the Federal Republic of Germany.
The principal innovations introduced by the budget reform in conjunction with the
Law to Promote Economic Stability and Growth (StWG), which had already entered
into force in 1967, were the following:
z In their budget management, the Federation and the Lnder are enjoined to
take account of the requirements of macroeconomic equilibrium (stable prices,
a high level of employment, and external balance accompanied by steady and
adequate economic growth) (Article 109 (2) GG).
z Revenue from borrowing may not exceed the total expenditure for investment
provided for in the budget estimates (Article 115 GG). Exceptions to this rule
are permissible only to remedy a serious and sustained disturbance of
macroeconomic equilibrium.
z The Federation and the Lnder each base their respective budget management
on a financial plan covering a five-year period (Section 50 of the Law on
Budget Principles - HGrG).
86 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Since this reform, adopting an approach geared to the medium term has become a
matter of course in all sectors of budget and fiscal policy. As employed by the FMF, the
financial plan has become a useful tool for fending off excessive demands on the
budget. The obligation to draw up a financial plan each year reinforces awareness
within the federal government of the need for fiscal discipline and responsible budget
policy and helps to ensure a balanced fiscal policy. In this way any need for fiscal
policy action can be identified at an early stage.
Though financial planning is a valuable instrument, it cannot guarantee the
implementation of a sound fiscal policy.
"Financial planning" is taken to mean the actual process of planning, whilst the
"financial plan" is the outcome of this process.
Financial planning is detailed: Financial planning comprises the detailed planning by
budget title of all individual revenue and expenditure positions included in the budget
in the planning period, that is, not just aggregate figures for total revenue and
expenditure. Currently these comprise about 1,100 revenue titles and about 5,300
expenditure titles, grouped in chapters and departmental budgets.
Financial planning is comprehensive: It includes expenditure which can already
definitely be earmarked, and provision for risks which loom in the medium-term
planning period. Sound financial planning includes reserves as well.
Chapter 7. Medium-term Financial Planning in the Federal Republic of Germany 87
them. Later in the budget preparation procedure they will have to negotiate their
estimates at working level with the departments for which they are responsible.
3.2. Procedure
At the start of the calendar year, which is also the start of the budget preparation
year, the financial plan is updated based on the actual figures of the fiscal year which
has just ended. As the new budget is prepared, the individual revenue and expenditure
titles must be re-evaluated. At the same time, during this process account is also taken
of the risks and of any changes in the law. In this way it is then possible to roll the
individual titles forward for another three years and to evaluate them on this basis.
Once a first compilation has been made, the financial plan is first analyzed
internally by the Federal Ministry of Finance in order to identify any need for action in
areas in which particularly strong increases or undesirably high expenditures are
expected. This information may be input into the development of the policy guidelines
of the federal government.
At issue in the budget negotiations between the Federal Ministry of Finance and
the departments are the budget estimates for the coming fiscal year and also
simultaneously the financial plan. Thus the planned figures for next fiscal years are
debated within the government between the Federal Ministry of Finance and the other
federal ministries. The results of this process of consultation result in a further
adjustment of the financial plan.
It is essential for expenditure and revenue to be brought into line with the
aggregate productive capacity of the national economy. To this end, planning must be
based on a medium-term projection of key macroeconomic data, which can enable a
forecast to be made in particular of tax revenue and expenditure for the labor market.
In the German system of financial planning, a forecast of aggregate economic
development is made for the first two years of the planning period, taking account of
Chapter 7. Medium-term Financial Planning in the Federal Republic of Germany 89
All Lnder and communes in the Federal Republic of Germany are obliged to draw
up a financial plan.
In a country consisting of a federation of states, the fiscal policies pursued by the
different levels of government must be co-ordinated in the interest of achieving the
envisaged development of the economy as a whole. To this end, the financial planning
data of all levels must be combined in an aggregate public-sector budget. This means
that the budgets and financial plans of public authorities must be comparable and must
in particular employ a standardized system of budget classification.
As a member of the European monetary union, the Federal Republic of Germany
must fulfil certain criteria concerning the general government deficit (no more than 3
percent of gross domestic product) and the total amount of public-sector indebtedness
(no more than 60 percent of gross domestic product).
Since in Germany the Lnder and the federal government are autonomous and
independent of each other in their fiscal administration (Article 109 Basic Law), they
need to reach mutual agreement on their spending policies if the "Maastricht criteria"
are to be fulfilled. For this reason the Law on Budget Principles had added to it the new
Section 51 a, which sets up the so-called "national stability pact."
This development has lent increased importance to the Financial Planning Council,
as this has become the body in which the budgetary developments of the federal
government and of the Lnder are discussed and in which recommendations for the
observance of fiscal discipline are drawn up. Spending policies are discussed twice a
year in the meetings of the Financial Planning Council, and if possible agreement
is reached.
The comparability of the data is based on the arrangement of the budget system, a
standard which is equally binding for the federal government and the Lnder; it
formed part of the 1969 budget reform and is laid out in the Law on Budget Principles.
4.1. Introduction
The Federal Ministry of Finance (FMF) is responsible for the budget preparation
procedure. The procedure begins one year before the passage of the budget law with a
circular to all government departments to submit their bids/estimates to the FMF.
In accordance with the arrangement of the budget system, as set forth in the
Federal Budget Code (BHO), the budget is subdivided into departmental budgets,
90 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
chapters and titles. The departmental budgets contain the funds appropriated for the
ministries. They are subdivided into chapters for the ministry, general appropriations,
subordinate authorities, etc. Each chapter is subdivided into titles, which are the
smallest subdivisions in the budget.
At present the federal budget comprises approximately 1,100 revenue titles and
5,300 expenditure titles, grouped together in chapters and departmental budgets. These
titles are subject to ex-ante control in medium-term financial planning and in the
budget preparation procedure. After the close of the fiscal year, they are audited by the
Federal Court of Audit (FCA) to see if they were managed effectively.
4.2. Schedule
The budget preparation procedure may be seen from the following diagram:
2003 C ir c u la r t o t h e d e p a r tm e n t s f o r t h e p r e p a r a t io n o f t h e
D ecem ber b u d g e t ( 2 0 0 5 ) a n d t h e fi n a n c ia l p la n ( 2 0 0 4 - 2 0 0 8 )
2004
P r e p a r a tio n o f th e e s tim a t e s o f t h e b u d g e t a n d t h e
Janu ary
f in a n c ia l p la n
F e b ru a ry
M a rc h
D e p a r t m e n ta l b id s s e n t t o F M F ;
S t a r t o f n e g o t i a t io n s F M F / d e p a r t m e n t s a t t e c h n ic a l le v e l
A p r il
M e d i u m - t e r m p r o je c t io n o f e c o n o m ic d e v e lo p m e n t a n d
M ay m e d iu m - t e r m ta x r e v e n u e e s t im a t e ;
F in a n c ia l P la n n in g C o u n c il
June S t a r t o f b u d g e t n e g o tia ti o n s a t m in is t e r ia l l e v e l
C a b in e t r e s o lu ti o n o n d r a f t b u d g e t a n d f in a n c i a l p l a n
J u ly
D ra ft b u d g e t s e n t to B u n d e s ta g (B T ) a n d B u n d e s r a t (B R )
August
f o r d e lib e r a t io n a n d f in a n c i a l p l a n f o r in f o r m a t i o n
S e p te m b e r 1 s t r e a d in g in t h e B T
1 s t r e a d in g in t h e B R
S t a r t o f d is c u s s io n s in B T c o m m it t e e s
O c to b e r
S h o r t - t e r m p r o je c t io n o f e c o n o m ic d e v e lo p m e n t a n d
s h o r t - t e r m t a x r e v e n u e e s t im a te ;
N ovem ber F in a l d is c u s s i o n i n B T b u d g e t c o m m it te e ;
F in a n c ia l P la n n in g C o u n c il
2 n d a n d 3 rd r e a d i n g i n t h e B T
2 n d d e b a te in th e B R
D ecem ber P r o m u lg a t io n o f th e b u d g e t s t a t u t e
2005 S t a r t o f b u d g e t e x e c u tio n
2006 R e n d e rin g o f a c c o u n ts
Chapter 7. Medium-term Financial Planning in the Federal Republic of Germany 91
After the circular on the preparation of the budget has seen sent to the
departments, the preparations for the medium-term financial planning begin in the
FMF. This includes a stocktaking of the finished titles of the fiscal year which has just
come to an end and the forecast of future expenditure based on the individual titles.
The tax estimate of the previous autumn as well as discussions of the Financial
Planning Council form the first foundation for the macroeconomic benchmark data.
The bids/estimates of government departments are submitted to the FMF in the
spring and are checked against the principles of need, conformity with regulations, and
economy.
These principles also guide the negotiations which follow at working level with
the departments on the draft budget and the financial plan. The divisions assigned to
examine the titles ("twinned" divisions) are independent of the departments and are
subordinated through the Budget Directorate-General to the executive level of the FMF
(Finance Minister and State Secretaries).
Any issues that cannot be settled at this level are the subject of further negotiations
at directorate or ministerial level. This process is aimed not only at bringing together
the positions of the FMF and of the departments. At the same time, the macroeconomic
benchmark data must be reconciled with the detailed, title by title planning in the draft
budget and with the financial plan. This is an iterative process in which each and every
individual title is negotiated between the FMF and the department concerned and
rolled forward for the financial planning period, so that within the administration
medium-term planning data is available for all the expenditure and revenue titles. The
law the Federal Budget Code requires that a realistic estimate be made for every
budget title, so the key data of the starting position may have to be corrected. In this
process, more recent data is provided by the macroeconomic projection in April and
the latest tax estimate in May.
After having been adopted by the cabinet (June), the draft budget is submitted to
the Bundestag and the Bundesrat for consultation. In addition to the draft budget, the
federal government's financial plan (scope and nature of expected revenue and
expenditure over a five-year period; Section 9 StWG) is also presented. However, the
Bundestag and the Bundesrat merely take notice of the financial plan.
At this point in the budget preparation procedure, the medium-term financial
planning has been completed. The parliamentary procedure concerns only the draft
budget for the coming fiscal year.
After the first parliamentary reading in the Bundestag, the draft budget is referred
to the Budget Committee of the Bundestag, which takes charge of the subsequent
deliberations.
The Budget Committee scrutinizes all the estimates and, where necessary, submits
proposals for amendment. The decisions of the Budget Committee are prepared by a
number of committee members. The rapporteurs/co-rapporteurs of the Budget
Committee discuss the draft budget with representatives of the supreme federal
authorities concerned and of the FMF and the Federal Court of Audit (FCA). Proposals
submitted by the rapporteurs form the basis of deliberations in the Budget Committee
and are adopted in most instances. A detailed debate is generally held in the Budget
Committee if the rapporteurs and co-rapporteurs are unable to reach agreement on
specific points or if an issue is of such fundamental significance as to require to be dealt
with by the Budget Committee itself.
92 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
The comments of the specialized committees and of the Bundesrat are taken up in
the deliberations of the Budget Committee. Issues that cannot be finally disposed of
when the departmental budgets are considered by the Budget Committee are shelved
until the so-called "settlement" session. This is usually held in November, and marks
the conclusion of the Budget Committee's deliberations on the draft budget. The FMF
submits documentation for decisions to be taken in the settlement sessions combining
all the deferred issues and other matters on which it considers a decision necessary (the
so-called settlement items).
This is followed by the second and third readings of the budget law in parliament,
during which minor amendments are made, and the final debate in the Bundesrat.
5. Conclusion
Medium-term financial planning in the Federal Republic of Germany has proved
to be an effective instrument in the quest for a stable fiscal policy.
It is based essentially on the fact that each of the approximately 6,400 revenue and
expenditure titles are re-evaluated at the start of the budget preparation procedure and
planned for the next four years, taking into account the expected risks. At the same
time the Federal Ministry of Finance evaluates the overall economic situation of the
country on the basis of the macroeconomic data. In this way the German federal
government gains an exact picture which is determined by the macroeconomic climate
and which also takes detailed account of future revenue and expenditure.
On the one hand the analysis of these data makes it possible to identify any fiscal
policy action which needs to be taken by the government. On the other hand from the
negotiation of the financial plan with the departments in the budget preparation
procedure there emerges a target specification on the expenditure ceilings for the
coming years. The financial plan forms the basis for the budget preparation and
facilitates the budget negotiations in the following years.
CHAPTER 8
Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case
by
Bill Dorotinsky, The World Bank
1. Introduction
In the United States, medium-term aspects of budgeting are an integral part of the
annual budget process, and as such are somewhat difficult to disentangle from the
annual budget process. This paper will outline the major rules and process in multi-
year budgeting, covering both the executive and legislative budget processes.
After presenting the necessary institutional background for understanding the U.S.
public sector, the evolution of budgeting, and key actors, the paper turns to multi-year
macrofiscal forecasting in the annual budget process. The paper then turns to sectoral
allocation of resources, including conflict resolution mechanisms. The paper then
briefly addresses the question of policy content and ownership of the executive budget,
the role of the legislature, and in-year spending ceilings. The paper concludes with a
summary assessment of multi-year budgeting in the U.S. and some lessons learned.
2. Background
2.1. Governmental structure and public finance roles.
z The legislature (Congress) has the ultimate authority over spending, granted
to it under the Constitution.64 Providing authority to spend is exclusively a
legislative power. The executive branch may not spend more than the amount
appropriated, and it may use available funds only for the purposes approved
by Congress. In theory, the Congress could develop a budget without any
presidential input, although this has not been the case in modern history. It is
also important to point out early that while the President does propose one
comprehensive budget, the Congress enacts the budget through 13 separate
appropriations bills or votes, roughly corresponding to function.
z The President and executive branch have important roles in the budget
process in that (i) they propose the budget first, thus setting the agenda; (ii)
they have the detailed spending information needed to prepare good budgets;
and, (iii) the President has Constitutional power to approve or veto legislation
(including the 13 appropriations bills).
64 No money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.
94 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
The relationship between the executive and legislative branches over budgeting
and control of public finances has developed gradually over the 200 years of the
countrys history, with the balance of influence over spending shifting between the two
branches. Until 1921, spending agencies submitted budget requests directly to the
Congress. While Congress had preeminent authority in spending decisions, it was very
dependent on the budget estimates and requests submitted by spending agencies. As
the complexity of the public finances expanded, this uncoordinated approach placed
too high a burden on Congress to prepare a coherent fiscal position, and also provided
too little formal room for Presidential policy in advancing a coherent executive fiscal
position.
The Budget and Accounting Act of 1921 established the executive budget process,
requiring the President to prepare and submit a comprehensive federal budget to
Congress annually. The Act also created the Bureau of the Budget (renamed the Office
of Management and Budget (OMB) in 1974) to support the President in carrying out
coordinating the executive branch budget. OMB assists the President in overseeing the
preparation of the Federal budget and also supervises budget execution
/implementation. OMB evaluates the effectiveness of agency programs, policies, and
procedures, assesses competing funding demands among agencies, and sets funding
priorities. OMB ensures that agency reports, rules, testimony, and proposed legislation
are consistent with the President's budget and with Administration policies. In
addition, OMB oversees and coordinates the Administration's procurement, financial
management, information, and regulatory policies. And, not a small task, OMB is in
charge of general management oversight and reforms in the public sector.
Along with OMB, the Council of Economic Advisors and the Treasury Department
assist the President by providing economic projections and revenue estimates.
With the passage of the Budget and Accounting Act, influence over budgeting
shifted to the executive branch. This tendency generally continued until the early 1970s,
when Congress began to reassert its role. By the mid-1960s, the size and complexity of
the Federal budget had grown significantly. Some programs from the Depression
(Social Security) and War on Poverty (such as Medicaid and Medicare) were large and
growing, and were entitlement programs not governed by the annual budget. To
manage these programs required more than an annual focus in the budget.
In 1970, Congress passed the Legislative Reorganization Act, requiring more
budgetary information from the President, including that the budget cover the budget
year and four additional years.
In 1974, Congress passed the Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control
Act. The Act further reinforced the congressional budget role establishing important
tools for managing its handling of the budget. The House and Senate Budget
Committees were created to coordinate congressional consideration of the budget, and
the Congressional Budget Office was established as a source of nonpartisan analysis
and information, including providing an alternate economic forecast for the Congress.
The law also established a specific timetable for action on the budget and a concurrent
budget resolution on budget aggregates (a legislative device that does not require
Presidential approval, but guides legislative action on the budget).
CBO's role is to provide the Congress with objective, nonpartisan analyses on
economic and budget decisions, and with information and estimates for the budget
process. CBO prepares analyses and estimates relating to the budget and the economy,
and presents options and alternatives for the Congress, but does not make policy
Chapter 8. Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case 95
recommendations. CBO helps the Congress formulate a budget plan, stay within that
plan, and assess the impact of federal programs.
Congress also has the Congressional Research Service, which provides research on
specific topics for Members of Congress, as well as the General Accounting Office
the Supreme Audit Institution or external audit body that provides evaluations of
programs in addition to audit reports.
To understand the U.S. budget process generally, including multi-year budgeting,
it is important to understand both the executive and legislative budget processes.
Formal econometric models are not used in preparing economic forecasts of key
economic variables for use in the President's Budget. Professional economists in OMB,
Treasury, and the Council of Economic Advisors (the 'troika') focus on trends in six key
variables:
Some attention is also paid to projected income distributions, which will effect tax
revenue projections (profits versus wages). Policy discussion focuses more on the
wedge between the GDP price index and CPI than on each measure itself. The CPI
generally out-paces the annual rate of GDP growth. The rule of thumb: the wider the
gap between the two measures, the worse for the Federal Budget.
In debating the appropriate level of key economic variables for use in the
President's Budget, participants do receive other forecasts as benchmark levels (several
academic private sector estimates, as well as estimates by international organizations).
The existence of these alternate estimates is thought by some to place constraints
on the extent to which political officials might manipulate economic estimates beyond
reason in order to support their political agenda via the budget. Regardless, alternate
estimates do provide substantive grist for the debate.
The process of forecasting is really an incremental one. Analysts begin with the
most recent official forecast, and then proceed to review the key variables in light of
trends in the economy. The current forecast is modified where a consensus is reached
among OMB, Treasury, and CEA on necessary changes.
Generally, only first-order effects on the economy are considered. Professional
economists in the executive branch are loath to attempt second-order estimation (e.g.
the effect on tax revenues of a change in tax laws which change behavior).
Forecasts are updated every six months. Executive branch economists constantly
monitor key statistical releases on economic activity, and are always thinking of the
implications of the news for the official forecast.
96 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Once staff of the troika have finished their review and developed opinions on
necessary revisions, senior policy officials meet to discuss the forecast. Eventually, the
Chairman of the CEA, the Director of OMB, and the Secretary of Treasury must agree
on the final numbers before they can be used to develop the Budget.
Policy consensus must be reached for economic forecasts. The key policy officials
involved in fiscal policy must reach some consensus on broad policy directions as they
consider the economic forecasts. (In the 1980s, this policy review often resulted in more
optimistic estimates, which led to the appellation 'rosy scenario' forecasting based on
economic theory dubbed 'voodoo economics.')
Generally, the key policy officials will include the troika, as well as senior
administration officials (possibly the President, Vice-President, Chief of Staff, and other
White House political staff). These arrangements have varied by Administration. Under
President G. H. W. Bush, domestic and economic policy were the domain of two very
influential officials, the Chief of Staff John Sununu and the Director of OMB Richard
Darman.
Under President Clinton, a formal advisory body called the National Economic
Council (NEC) was established in 1993 to provide advice to the President and build
consensus among key policy officials. The Council was composed of the President,
Vice-President, seven domestic Cabinet Secretaries, the Secretary of State, Director of
OMB, Chair of the Council of Economic Advisors, National Security Advisor, Assistant
to the President for Domestic Policy, and Secretary of Defense.
The important point to bear in mind is that there were vehicles for achieving policy
consensus within Government. As of 1993, these have become more formalized in the
NEC. This would be roughly analogous to Cabinet consensus in Parliamentary systems.
Once approved, CEA staff use a private sector econometric model (dubbed the
'black box') to produce somewhat greater detail for the forecast, especially
consumption, investment, and export components of the national accounts. Also,
greater detail in terms of income distribution is sought for use by Treasury in
forecasting revenues. While based on an econometric model, the black box really is an
accounting device or reverse model, where key variables are entered, and consistent
details are generated. The black box assures that basic national accounting identities are
observed to produce a generally consistent set of supporting detail for the approved
policy variables. This black box output detail is then given to OMB and Treasury for
production of further detail.
The U.S. Treasury is responsible for tax-based revenue forecasts, while OMB
generally estimates user fees and similar non-tax revenues. Treasury has formula based
on historical tax collection records of estimated revenues given the basic national
account and income distribution data.
OMB has simple formulae based on recent historical trends and simple regression
models which provide greater detail on inflation, a wider array of interest rate
estimates, etc. (e.g. Medical inflation is, on average, 2 percent greater than the CPI
estimates). These more detailed estimates are then provided to the executive branch
agencies for use in estimating future year or budget year costs. Agencies use estimates
of inflation and possible pay increases in calculating their budget requests (policy) and
current services estimates.
Chapter 8. Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case 97
The set of variables which the Federal Executive Branch has determined are
necessary for producing the budget are listed in Box 8-1.
Revenue-related estimates
10. GDP (quarterly and annually)
11. GDP Price Index (quarterly and annually)
12. Civilian unemployment (quarterly and annually)
13. Corporate profits
14. Goods imports
15. Personal income, broken into wage and non-wage income (interest income, dividend
income, rental income, proprietors' income) (quarterly and annually)
16. Civilian labor force (quarterly and annually)
17. Treasury bill rates (91, 182, and 364-day rates (quarterly and annual)
18. Treasury notes and bonds (2, 3, 5, 7, 10, and 30-year rates) (quarterly and annually)
19. Prime rate (quarterly and annual)
20. LIBOR (quarterly and annual)
21. AAA state and local bond rate (quarterly and annual)
22. Mortgage rate (quarterly and annual)
23. Energy prices (imported and domestic oil, coal, natural gas, and a hybrid gas and oil
index) (quarterly and annual)
24. Housing starts, mortgage originations (existing and new homes), average single-family home
Many of the routine budget tasks, such as applying a pay inflator to base year pay
and projecting into future years, are automated in the OMB budget database system.
The appropriate economic estimate is fed into the OMB computer, and the relevant
accounts are directly updated.
In early budget discussions at the macro level, OMB uses the most recent approved
budget information (congressionally-approved budget), adjusted for information on
implementation of the current budget, to make projections of spending trends. Several
concepts unique to the U.S. budget system need to be understood; baselines,
discretionary spending, and mandatory spending.
98 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Baselines provide the President and Congress with a framework for making and
enforcing budgetary decisions, serving as a benchmark. OMB and CBO baselines
project federal spending, revenue, and budget surplus or deficit amounts that would
occur if existing budget policies were left unchanged. The rules for calculating the
baseline are set in law.
Discretionary spending applies to programs whose funding must be provided
annually in the budget. Mandatory spending encompasses entitlements to individuals
and other programs whose spending is controlled via separate legislation, and not
subject to the annual budget.
Mandatory spending and receipts are generally assumed to continue at the level
prescribed by existing law. Discretionary spending is assumed to continue at the level
of the current year's spending level, adjusted to reflect certain assumptions. The
projections for mandatory spending, receipts, and discretionary spending are based
upon economic assumptions (e.g., economic growth, inflation, and unemployment) and
technical assumptions (e.g., demographic and workload changes).
There is no formal or informal discussion between executive branch staff and staff
at the Federal Reserve on economic forecasts. However, Washington, D.C. based
economic professionals do have a general idea of what others in their field are thinking.
The Federal Reserve has their own model, and do not share their forecasts. The
Federal Reserve MPS model does, however, have some close similarity to the private
sector economic model the executive branch uses for obtaining more detailed estimates.
However, since the President's Budget is released publicly, including the basic
economic assumptions underlying the budget, the Federal Reserve has the basic
information on Executive Branch economic thinking to use in their own forecasts and
decision-making.
Once the President's Budget economic forecasts are released with the President's
Budget, the Congressional Budget Office makes their own set of estimates. CBO is
thought to follow a similar consensus and incremental approach to forecasting.
However, CBO does invite private and academic forecasters to present their views of
the economy. Also, CBO, being a single agency, has a somewhat easier time in arriving
at consensus estimates, versus the executive branch with three separate agencies
involved. CBO does subscribe to some private sector forecasting services, though which
ones, and how these private forecasts are used in developing the official CBO forecast,
is not known.
OMB and CBO do have some different assumptions and conclusions on income
distribution and some key variables. Particularly with regards to income distribution,
OMB has tended to estimate greater GDP growth and greater corporate profits
which are highly taxed and hence greater Federal tax revenues, than CBO has
projected.
Because of lingering suspicion over OMB economic estimates after President
Clinton's inauguration, the President declared that CBO economic assumptions would
be used instead of OMB's. While only lasting for a short while, the President's decision
did serve to remove different economic estimates as a source of budget debate, and also
chastened the troika to produce more pragmatic estimates.
Publication of the economic estimates in the Presidents Budget also allows close
scrutiny of the soundness of the estimates.
Chapter 8. Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case 99
As noted above, within the executive branch, the Treasury has general
responsibility for tax policy, including estimating the effect on revenues of changes in
tax policy.
Most of the laws establishing the federal government's revenue sources are
permanent and continue year after year without any additional legislative action.
Revenue legislation may be considered in the congressional budget process when
President proposes changes in taxes.
3.7. Debt
Within the executive branch, the Treasury also has responsibility for debt policy,
Because of the size of the economy, debt policy has generally not been a major focal
point in budget debates, except for the 1990s under President Reagan, and again now
with the rapid increase in deficits. Most of the focus has been on taxes (revenues) and
spending, with deficits and debt a residual. (Note that for smaller or less open
economies with more limited access to capital markets, debt policy is a far greater
issue.)
Perhaps the more immediate administrative issue for the Treasury in debt policy is
Congressional limits on debt. The gross federal debt consists of the debt held by the
public plus the debt held by government accounts. Almost all of the gross federal debt
is subject to a public debt limit. The Treasury can borrow funds only up to statutory
debt limit. Most gross federal debt is held by the public, though a significant amount
(roughly 30 percent) is held by government accounts (primarily trust funds such as
Social Security, whose surpluses must be invested in special federal government
securities by law).
Congress occasionally will enact increases to the debt limit. Within the
congressional budget process, the annual congressional budget resolution specifies the
appropriate level of the public debt for each fiscal year covered by the resolution. In
order to actually change the public debt limit, however, legislation must be passed by
both Houses of Congress and signed by the President. The House of Representatives
Ways and Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee are the responsible
committees of Congress for debt limit issues.
In addition to the annual budget process, debt limits are another means for
Congress to control the executive branch, and force the executive to discuss debt issues
directly.
A Mid-session Review is also required by the law to be sent to Congress by July 15
of each year. The Mid-session updates the economic estimates and Presidents Budget
proposal.
4. Strategic Allocation
4.1. Sectoral ceilings
In the U.S., sectors are termed functional classification. The President's budget
classifies federal budgetary activities into functional and subfunctional categories that
represent the major purposes of the federal government. Each budgetary activity of the
federal government, including budget authority, outlays, tax expenditures, and credit
authority, is classified into a subfunction based on the primary purpose it serves
100 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
without regard to the agency or other unit responsible for it. There are currently 21
functional and 77 subfunctional categories. Figure 8-1 presents the current functional
and subfunctional classification.
The functional categories provide a broad statement of budget priorities and
facilitate the analysis of trends in related. They are not used for setting ceilings.
Indicative ceilings for the annual budget process in the U.S. are set according to the
ministry (department) classification set for the budget year, and four subsequent years.
Generally, OMB begins with the second year of the prior budgets multi-year forecast,
and makes adjustments for total spending trends and limits, economic or legislative
changes, and also to reflect known policy preferences. A new policy reserve has
sometimes been set at this stage, representing a pool of unallocated resources that will
be used to fund new initiatives (whether arising from the President or from ministries).
In some cases these are provided to the President for information, and in other
instances not, depending on the degree of interest of the President in budget issues and
the degree of delegation to staff and the Director of OMB.65
The ministry ceilings are indicative. OMB requests that agencies stay within the
ceiling, but there are no formal sanctions for not doing so. Because the ceilings are not
Presidentially-approved or sanctioned, they have few teeth. Even if there were, it is
highly unlikely a cabinet member would be reprimanded or dismissed for not meeting
the ceiling. However, there are more informal pressures for compliance that operate
more at a career staff level. In advising the Director of OMB and President, OMB staff
do make note of whether the ministry complied, and by how much they were off
ceiling. Further, even if the ministry does not specify where they would reduce to meet
the ceiling, OMB staff will recommend where reductions should take place. So, it is in
the interest of ministries to themselves identify low priorities.
Further, implicitly, there is always some question in ministry budget staff minds as
to whether OMB scrutinizes their budget more closely if ceilings are ignored. (For small
agencies, over which OMB has more direct influence, there is greater likelihood of
compliance with the ceilings.) Regardless, ministry requests are generally within 5-10
percent of ceilings.
After receiving ministry requests, OMB prepares policy papers for the Presidents
decision. There is a well established process for decision-making, with only the most
significant issues ever making it to the Presidents desk. Many will be made by the
OMB director, and for smaller issues, by political appointees within the OMB.
After decisions are taken, the decisions are passed-back to the ministries, usually
around Thanksgiving (November). Ministries are given a tight deadline for reviewing
and formally registering any appeal to the passback levels. This process of passback
and appeals can be very contentious between OMB and ministries.
The process of resolving appeals involves direct meetings between OMB staff and
ministry budget staff and focused debate. Efforts are made to resolve as many issues as
possible at a staff level, before raising the issues to a political level. Eventually, some
issues may need to be resolved by the Director of OMB and affected cabinet secretary.
Generally, few issues require appeal all the way to the President. Some Presidents
(Ford, Carter, and Clinton) have taken a direct role in deciding appeals. Others (Nixon,
Reagan, George H.W. Bush and George W. Bush.) have delegated appeal decisions to
presidential aides or the OMB Director.
65 While the formal Presidents Budget document includes the budget year and four additional year, down
to the program level, over the last decade or so the Senate has included language in the budget resolution
requiring ten-year estimates. The executive has generally complied with this request, submitting these estimates
at a more aggregate level.
102 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
Throughout this process, it is the better prepared, better argued, and better
documented case that tends to win out. For OMB and agency staff, the premium tends
to be on data and analysis. For highly political issues, of course the political officials
will take the decision and weigh many factors. Even the best analysis will not win out
against politics. But for the majority of issues OMB would deal with during this time,
data, documentation, and analysis are the key factors.
Out-year estimates can sometimes also be used in resolving disputes with agencies,
at least for discretionary spending. There have been instances where an agency agreed
to a lower increase in its proposed budget in exchange for increases in its budget for the
budget year +1 or beyond. Of course, the subsequent years ceiling will be revisited in
light of changing circumstances during the next budget cycle, and the agreed increase
may not in fact happen.
With this in mind, OMB puts a premium on hiring the best staff, and having access
to as much data as possible. It is not uncommon for, OMB staff outnumbered by
budget staff in ministries armed with agencies own data, to provide critical
information or data at a key moment in negotiation that wins out when the agency
may not have itself reviewed its own data.
Once agreements are reached and appeals resolved, the ministries are responsible
for preparing the budget documentation and justification. In addition to the formal
Presidents Budget, each agency will prepare a separate budget justification for
transmittal to Congress, as well as congressional testimony for their executives. OMB
reviews and approves all these documents before they are sent to Congress, to assure
they are all in alignment with Presidential/administration decisions and policies.
Agencies do have direct relationships with Congressional committees and staff,
and have been known to provide information informally which sometimes undermines
the budget. However, OMB staff closely monitor these discussions, and do report back
to the Director of OMB on ministry behavior. Egregious breaches might solicit a call
from the OMB Director to a Minister, but these are not common.
Final budget allocations (passback and appeals) are set relative to the ceilings. This
has been especially true with the enactment of legally binding ceilings on discretionary
and mandatory spending through the Budget Enforcement Act (BEA). While the BEA
addresses aggregate spending levels, these are translated into ministry ceilings, and the
sum of ceilings must of course match the legal limits.
The actual ministry budget allocation, while taken relative to the ceiling, is really
determined by the accumulation of individual decisions on programs and policies. The
policy papers prepared for decision (referred to above) incorporate extensive analysis
by OMB staff of agency budget requests, as well as other research or findings (e.g. audit
findings) regarding programs and policies. The analysis results in OMB staff
recommendations for specific changes in funding, programs, policies, employment, etc.
It also reflects the findings of OMB staff from budget hearings held with each agency
(at which each agency can make their case for their request). As each decision is taken,
its effect relative to the ceilings is monitored to assure the totals are not exceeded.
While only some appeals will be addressed directly by the President, in the end it
is the Presidents Budget that is transmitted to Congress, under his signature. The
President is ultimately responsible for its content. The Cabinet does not formally
approve the budget.
Chapter 8. Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case 103
4.4. Roles
The U.S. does not have a formal MTEF. The budget process has evolved,
particularly after 1974, to incorporate medium-term projections in the process, as well
as ministry strategic plans. Generally, the relationship between OMB and ministries has
not changed dramatically due to the introduction of medium-term forecasts. Other
factors influence relations more. For example, during periods of deficits, Presidents
with a policy of spending reduction, and OMB Directors with high influence over
domestic policy, OMB tends to be stronger relative to the ministries, and during these
times OMB may be less collegial in relations with ministries. At other times, OMB
influence may be less, and relations with Ministries become far more collegial.
That said, there was some movement under President Clinton towards a more
collegial approach by OMB. Early in the Clinton Administration, a survey was
conducted of spending ministries as to what they thought of OMB, and barriers to
agency efficiency. Not surprisingly, the results were rather negative, with ministries
feeling OMB was too much into rule-mongering and second-guessing, and too high-
handed. The results were at first surprising to OMB staff, and certainly not accepted.
After a series of brown-bag discussions between staff and the OMB Director, some
acceptance of the results seemed to sink in, with staff understanding that to really be
effective, the ministries needed to be partners and understand the overall constraints.
No subsequent surveys have been taken, so it is not clear if the ministries would report
differently now than a decade ago.
6. Legislature
As noted in the introduction, the Congress has the authority to change the
executive budget proposal completely, including total revenue, total expenditure,
deficit, debt, and allocations to ministries. This authority is in practice counterbalanced
by the executive authority to veto the budget bills.
Over time the congressional budget process has been improved to give Congress
greater ability to manage its own affairs. General examples of these from the early
1970s were mentioned in the introduction. This section will go into the congressional
budget process in more detail.
The Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act of 1974 established the
basic structure for the congressional budget process, creating the House and Senate
Budget Committees and CBO. The Congress budget process starts in February with the
submission of the Presidents budget, after which the House and Senate Budget
Committees begin developing their budget resolutions.
The annual budget resolution establishes total spending and revenue for five or
more years, allocates spending by functional classification, and includes CBO
baseline estimates of revenues. The spending amounts are then allocated to the
House and Senate Appropriations Committees for discretionary spending, to the
authorizing committees for mandatory spending, and to the House Ways and
Means Committee for revenue targets. The Appropriations Committee of each
house subdivides the discretionary allocation among its 13 subcommittees (broadly,
the major functions). The committee allocations are one means of enforcing the
aggregate spending levels in the budget resolution by holding committees
accountable for meeting their targets.
After extensive hearings, each of the subcommittees reports one of the 13 regular
appropriations bills to its respective full appropriations committee, which in turn
reports the bills to their Chamber. A cost estimate of each bill is prepared and
compared to the amount allocated or subdivided to the relevant subcommittee. The
Congressional Budget Act prohibits bills from exceeding the budget resolution
committee allocations. However, to be enforced, a Member of either Chamber must
raise a point of order when the bill is being considered on the floor of the respective
Chamber.
For mandatory spending, revenues, and debt limits, the process of reconciliation
(also established under the Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act) is
used to enforce the budget resolution allocations. Congress includes reconciliation
instructions in the budget resolution directing the authorizing committees to
recommend changes in law to achieve the direct spending, revenue, and debt limit
targets in the budget resolution. The Budgets Committees of each Chamber then
compile the various proposed legislative language from the authorizing committees
into a reconciliation bill. Unlike the process for discretionary spending, there are no
points of order for a reconciliation bill that does not meet the budget resolution
mandatory spending targets. Amendments on the floor of each Chamber may seek to
bring the reconciliation bill closer to the budget resolution targets, but that is entirely at
the discretion of a Member, and subject of course to a successful vote for the
amendment. For revenues, a point of order may be raised for amendments that would
reduce revenues below the budget resolution.
The Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act does prohibit either
Chamber from considering amendments to a reconciliation bill that would increase the
deficit. The law also provides a congressional budget process timetable; the budget
Chapter 8. Medium-term Perspectives in Budgeting: The U.S. Case 105
resolution should be adopted by April 15, and the reconciliation bill by June 15. (These
are frequently not met.)
The Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 also required that any measure reducing
revenues below the budget resolution or increasing mandatory spending be offset with
equivalent revenue increases or mandatory spending reductions (commonly referred to
as the pay-as-you-go rule). This is also enforced by a sequestration process, whereby
any violation will trigger an offsetting sequestration of nonexempt mandatory
spending programs.
7. In-year Effect
Generally, OMB has been responsible for costing new legislation. As a practical
matter, not all legislation is costed. Only executive branch proposals, and legislation in
Congress likely to be passed by Committee and proceed to the floor.
During the budget process, scorekeeping (measuring the budgetary effects of
pending and enacted legislation against the baseline) is used to compare proposed
budget policy changes to existing law and to enforce spending and revenue levels
agreed upon in the budget resolution and other budget legislation, such as the
discretionary spending caps and pay-as-you-go rules.
During the fiscal year, scorekeeping is also used for new legislation. As OMB must
clear all legislation before transmittal to Congress, no uncosted or unfunded legislation
is transmitted from the executive. All proposals must fit within the ceilings.
(1) In considering policy and programs, thinking beyond one year to the outyear
effects of proposals and existing spending is common throughout the system.
Over a quarter century of requirements for multi-year estimates, and
progressively greater attention to these estimates, have made multi-year
thinking a normal part of public finance.
(2) The baseline estimates serve as a useful reference point for considering changes
in policy and programs over several years, and better inform decision-makers.
This has likely led to different choices in programs, and in reallocation from
lower to higher priority programs, early in the budget process but it is not
possible to systematically measure this effect.
(3) Beyond the information effect noted above, including use of indicative ceilings
in the budget process, the multi-year estimates had limited bite. Not until the
large deficits of the 1980s and general political and public consensus that
106 Part I. Medium-Term Expenditure Framework
deficits were bad did multi-year estimates and ceilings gain real teeth. And
further, not until the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings and Budget Enforcement Act
legislated ceilings and pay-go requirements did the real effect of ceilings and
estimates come to be felt.
(4) Some means of bringing consensus on multi-year policy is critical. It is this
consensus that shapes behavior and changes direction the most. For the U.S.,
consensus within the executive branch is achieved through the NEC. Within the
legislative branch, it is achieved via the negotiations that take place in the
Budget Committees in crafting the budget resolution (frequently including
negotiation with the executive branch). And finally, the Budget Enforcement
Act represented the executive-legislative consensus necessary in the U.S.
political system to really begin to reign in deficit spending.
(5) Despite the presence of multi-year estimates for a quarter century, this has not
prevented growth in spending. It has influenced choices, and might even have
contributed to a shift towards more mandatory spending programs not directly
under annual budget control. For the U.S., information on future impact has not
been enough to effectively limit spending growth. This might be part of the
curse of riches, where deficits and postponement of decisive choices on fiscal
matters can be financed given the easy access to international capital markets
enjoyed by the U.S. The impact of multi-year information might be greater for
countries with less easy access to capital markets. For the U.S., hard, legally
binding fiscal targets were required to make a difference.
(6) The Gramm-Rudman hard targets proved too demanding, and the targets could
not be reached through the political process. The BEA proved more successful,
by limiting discretionary spending and requiring off-sets for deficit-increasing
changes to entitlement programs. These procedural rules changed the
incentives in the budget system to limit spending growth, and this proved more
successful than hard deficit reduction targets.
(7) With the short-lived budget surpluses in the late 1990s and early 2000s, the
consensus on budget discipline broke down, and the BEA lost emphasis. The
multi-year estimates are firmly entrenched and still prepared, and at least
provide the political officials with clear information on the direction they are
heading. The availability of this information does likely serve as some break on
excess, but again the teeth are lacking. However, as the outyear picture
worsens with continuous provision of multi-year estimates, the pressure to
contain spending will likely reassert itself a self-correcting mechanism, albeit
with lags in effect. Even in the absence of hard legal constraints, multi-year
information is of value.
While the deficits are large, and there is increasing suggestions of the imprudence
of current policy, some of the expansionary fiscal policy is intended to boost economic
growth. The policy is intended as counter-cyclical just as large surpluses were
incurred during years of strong growth and used to pay down the debt, so now deficits
are incurred. One can debate whether it is really needed, or needed in the size and form
in which it is incurred (tax cuts). It does not mean the underlying budget system is
entirely broken. Where a policy decision is taken to operate an expansionary fiscal
policy, it does not mean the underlying process is dysfunctional. It would be if the
expansionary policy were taken absent information on likely outcome, but that is not
the case.
Part II
Performance Management
CHAPTER 9
An Overall Framework for Considering Performance Management
by
Joel Turkewitz, The World Bank
1. Overview
Moving This paper provides a brief overview of major issues in the design of
performance-enhancing reforms in the public sector. As this paper is written as an
input into a dialogue between the Government of Korea and the World Bank on
improving public expenditure management, specific particular attention has been
given to experience and learning in achieving greater performance orientation through
alterations in the allocation and spending of public financial resources. The first section
of the paper reviews some current thinking about the fundamentals of improving
performance in the public sector. The second section presents a discussion of different
approaches to generating enhanced performance orientation in the budget process, and
the final section examines the evidence to date on the impact of performance-oriented
reforms and the implications of that evidence on the design of performance
management programs.
66 For a discussion of the idea of performance in the public sector, see Schick (2003).
110 Part II. Performance Management
The drive to improve public sector performance has given a new look to the public
sector as it entered the 21st Century. Processes and organizations have been remade
through innovations like program budgeting, medium-term expenditure frameworks,
accrual accounting, and performance auditing. Privatization and decentralization have
reshaped the state, while contracting-out and performance contracting has modified
public sector employment. Enhanced monitoring and evaluation, program reviews,
and increased civil society participation in setting policy and reviewing results have
changed how managers and politicians are held accountable for results.
Decades of reform efforts have achieved mixed results. Initial expectations in
countries like the United States and Sweden that improved performance could be
rapidly achieved through changes in the budget process have failed to materialize,
while experiences in such places as New Zealand, South Africa and many smaller
public sector organizations has been much more positive. The inability to state
definitively whether performance management works is not a data problem but instead
reflects the fact that reforms vary greatly in their objectives, the traditions and histories
of the countries undertaking reform, and the variations in the reforms that have been
tried. Some countries that have undertaken performance-oriented reforms have
succeeded in improving their overall public finance performance, reallocating
resources across sectors, and improving efficiency within programs. In other countries,
reforms appear to have done little more than reshuffle arrangements within the public
sector with no discernable impact on public finance or service delivery.
Reforms that have succeeded in creating well-performing public sector have
benefited from inputs that can neither be planned nor designed such as good timing,
effective leadership, and governmental stability. Successful reforms have drawn upon a
generally accepted group of ideas regarding the organization and operation of high-
performance public sector environments. As stated by Allen Schick (1999), those ideas
include:
z Performance improves when managers are told what is expected of them, and
results are measured against these expectations.
z Performance improves when managers are held accountable for their use of
resources and the results that they produce.
67 See Schick (1999) for a discussion of strategies for reform, and the associated case studies for analysis of
specific reform efforts. Efforts to increase managerial autonomy may have a hard time co-existing with efforts
to enhance program oversight, especially when those efforts are introduced simultaneously.
68 See Schick (2003) for a discussion of the fallacy of performance as measurement.
112 Part II. Performance Management
An alternative term performance-informed budgeting has been suggested recently in the United States.
70
72 Kristensen (2002). For a useful discussion of performance budgeting, see Diamond (2003).
73 Incrementalism refers to the tendency for budgets to be determined by slight modifications in allocations
based upon a determination of what is needed this year to do what was done last year.
74 Joyce (2003), p.15.
Chapter 9. An Overall Framework for Considering Performance Management 113
75 The following discussion draws heavily on Robinson (2004a) and Robinson (2004b).
76 For a discussion and analysis of the reforms, see Schick (1996) and Robinson (2002).
114 Part II. Performance Management
Performance approaches that link ex post evaluations with future allocations seek
to increase the pressure on managers to perform. The Bush administrations Presidents
Management Agenda (PMA) and the complementary Program Assessment Rating Tool
(PART) in the United States are leading examples of a strategy dedicated to
incorporating past results into future allocations. The PMA requires the OMB to assess
the management of agencies, with a focus on the degree to which the agencys senior
management utilizes performance information in their strategic and day-to-day
decision-making. The PART program requires the Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) to determine whether a program is well functioning, with over 50 percent of the
PART score determined by an analysis of results and accountability. Both PMA and
PART are integrated into the budget process by the OMB, as well as through the
unusual step of making PART scores public and using a traffic light scale (green for go,
yellow for caution, and red for halt) for its PMA evaluation in order to ensure
maximum accessibility of agency rating to politicians and their constituencies.77
The current U.S. approach is fundamentally similar to a series of reforms
undertaken by the Government of Canada. An extensive program review was initiated
in 1994 on the heels of efforts to rationalize programs that was begun in the 1980s.
While the initial efforts focused on building up evaluative capacity in the Comptroller
Generals Office, the later, more successful efforts have required explicit reallocation of
resources within fixed budgets and have been combined with other reforms designed
to enhance managerial attention to service delivery and citizen needs. Detailed
program evaluations have also been a feature of the Australian governments approach
to improving performance, especially in the period from 1987 to 1997, but have been
abandoned in the period since 1997.78 The challenge faced by all efforts to conduct
systematic program evaluations is the sheer time and cost required to perform rigorous
evaluations. In many cases, program evaluations appear to have been forced to
compromise on quality, and have led to enormous conflicts within public
administration with relatively minor gains.
As with performance reforms in general, there does not appear to be a compelling
case for promoting one performance budgeting reform over the other. The case studies
that accompany this report will provide greater detail as to the mechanics of each of
these strategies information that will be essential for Korean policy-makers in their
determination of a suitable approach for the country. Instead of looking at their
differences, I want to turn now to a brief consideration of two features that are common
to all performance budgeting efforts the restructuring of budgets around programs
and the selection of performance indicators. It is the authors belief that the former, the
creation of programs, has generally received insufficient attention while the latter has
received too much focus.
If one were to read through recent discussions of performance budgeting, it would
be easy to get the impression that the core of the effort was defining the right set of
indicators and ensuring their rigorous monitoring. It might come as a surprise that
such efforts would likely be useless if the operative budget retained its traditional line-
item structure. In a traditional line-item model, it is hard if not impossible to determine
the policy objectives that are driving spending or to identify the amount of money
77 The Bush Administration has combined these enhanced agency and program reviews with a significant
increase in the use of monetary performance bonuses to reward mangers for high performance. The
effectiveness of such performance rewards in generating effective and efficient public sectors has been
challenged.
78 For a discussion of the role of evaluation in the Australian reforms, see Mackay (2004).
Chapter 9. An Overall Framework for Considering Performance Management 115
z Programs must consider all related activities (including regulatory ones) and
projects, which together assist in achieving their objectives. This means that capital
and recurrent spending should be considered together in judging program
performance relative to its objectives.
of system to supply relevant and timely data on finances and outputs. The integration
of financial management with budgeting is an enormous task, frequently requiring new
cost coding as well as new accounting practices, such as accrual accounting.
Establishing a program structure to budgets is, therefore, improperly understood
as a procedural step on the way to introducing performance measures. When it is
properly done, establishing a program structure requires changes within agencies, as
well as the creation of a completely new relationship between budgeting and financial
management. The importance of the changes that can be introduced in the
programming exercise have already been mentioned in the discussion of overall
performance reform the process of organizational and institutional restructuring
precedes the capacity to utilize data to improve performance.
Against this backdrop, the selection of performance indicators can appear to be a
relatively minor component of reform. This is incorrect since it is clear that selecting
inappropriate indicators or establishing unreasonable targets for performance can
destroy the momentum of reform. Indeed, establishing useful indicators and utilizing
data in the budgetary process is critical to achieving the objectives defined in the
programming process.79
Struggles to define useful indicators have been reported almost universally among
the countries in the vanguard of reform. This reflects the complexity of the task as well
as the unfamiliarity of most public sector managers in thinking in monitoring terms.
Undoubtedly, problems will be encountered by nations or agencies embarking on their
own performance budgeting effort, especially in the tricky area of identifying realistic
outcomes and ascribing causality in areas effected by multiple programs. At the macro-
level, monitoring of performance is likely to be a frighteningly inexact undertaking.
Countries are fortunate in that they now have the ability to examine a growing
glossary of indicators defined in the course of previous reforms as they develop
measures that are suitable for them. Experience also suggests that the development of
indicators is a continuous process, as measures evolve over time due to dialogues
between managers and policy-makers and the modification of programs.
79 As Diamond (2003) writes, experience suggests that the benefits of a budget program format will soon
be lost unless departments (and most central agencies) continue the momentum and purpose of reform by
moving to develop standards of service delivery and search for ways by which these standards can be
continuously improved and services delivered more effectively.
Chapter 9. An Overall Framework for Considering Performance Management 117
accompany this piece, along with other studies referenced in this paper, suggest some
of the successes along with the challenges of demonstrating impact.
One of the problems in coming to empirically based conclusions on effective
program design is a result of the restricted nature of existing analysis. As one
commentator has recently noted, Regrettably, the empirical literature on government-
wide performance budgeting is disappointingly limited in scope and methodology,
and does not provide for strong conclusions about the efficacy of these systems. 80
The absence of a robust empirical literature may be due in part to the complexities of
reform but also may be related to somewhat mistaken preconceptions as to where
performance management and performance budgeting would have greatest impact.81
Early efforts at performance management and performance budgeting were
invigorated by an interest in centralized management of economies and social
programs. The early attempts at government-wide performance programming,
borrowed from the U.S. Defense Department, envisioned the ability to distribute
budgetary resources across the government in order to maximize societal welfare. Since
that time, the performance movement has evolved greatly but has retained a
overwhelming interest in improving the allocative efficiency across sectors through
centralized processes involving a limited number of organizations. In the U.S., this has
meant that attention has focused on the creation and approval of federal budgets, with
a specific concentration on those processes involving the OMB.
The initial and continuing focus on centralized allocative processes has perhaps
decreased appreciation of the other processes that determine how public money is
allocated and spent. For example, agencies provisionally allocate money through
their budget submissions, and managers further reallocate money once budgets have
been determined in the operation of their programs. Money also gets reallocated
within the execution process through delays in payment or via payment to third
parties.82
It may well be that performance budgeting and performance management is most
likely to have impact at levels that have been obscured by our preconceptions. There is
significant evidence to suggest that managers in a large variety of programs within the
United States have made use of performance information to direct resources to greater
effectiveness and inefficiency. This has included defining inter-agency allocation
processes that are influenced by performance as well as mid-year reallocations based
on interim program results.83
Ultimately, improvements in public sector performance come about through some
combination of better calibrated allocative processes distributing resources to better
designed programs that are managed in an environment that demands performance. In
this brief review, we have suggested some of the choices to be made in program design,
and some of the factors associated with changing managerial cultures and improving
decision-making. I conclude this brief piece with a quote from Allen Schick, At the
budget process, as well as an examination of how performance information can be utilized across the entire
budgeting process.
83 See Joyce (2003). For a discussion of how outcome information is being used at the federal level in the
References
Diamond, Jack, From Program to Performance Budgeting: The Challenge for Emerging Market
Economies, IMF Working Paper 2003, WP/03/169.
Hatry, Harry, et al., How Federal Programs Use Outcome Information: Opportunities for
Federal Managers, Managing for Performance and Results Series, IBM Center for the
Business of Government, May 2003.
Joyce, Philip, Linking Performance and Budgeting: Opportunities in the Federal Budget
Process, Managing for Performance and Results Series, IBM Center for the Business of
Government, 2003.
Kristensen, K., Overview of Results Focused Management and Budgeting in OECD Member
Countries, OECD, Paris, 2002.
Mackay, Keith, Two Generations of Performance Evaluation and Management Systems in
Australia, draft paper, 2004 (on file with the author).
Robinson, Marc, Does Performance Budgeting Work? An Analytical Review of the Empirical
Literature, draft IMF paper, 2004a (on file with the author).
______, Performance Budgeting: Lessons from a Comparative Overview, manuscript, 2004b
(on file with the author).
______, Output-Purchase Funding and Budgeting Systems in the Public Sector, Public
Budgeting and Finance, 22 (4), 2002.
Schick, Allen, The Performing State: Reflection on an Idea Whose Time has Come but Whose
Implementation has Not, GOV/PUMA/SBO(2003) 17, June 2003.
______, Opportunity, Strategy, and Tactics in Reforming Public Management, paper presented
at the OECD Symposium Government of the Future: Getting from Here to There, PUMA,
SGF(99)4, September 1999
______, The Spirit of Reform: Managing the New Zealand State Sector in a Time of Change, a
report prepared for the State Services Commission and the Treasury, Wellington, 1996.
Wildavsky, A., Planning-Programming-Budgeting: Rescuing Policy Analysis From PPBS,
Washington, D.C., 1969.
CHAPTER 10
Introducing Performance Management
by
Youngsun Koh, Korea Development Institute
As the last step indicates, there are various tools to assess performance. The first is
performance monitoring. In performance monitoring, performance indicators are
defined and then measured on a regular basis. The measured performance is in turn
compared to the targets that were chosen at the start of the period. In Korea, examples
can be found in the Performance Budget Pilot Project that was carried out in 1999-2002
and the Performance Management System that was introduced in 2003.
Performance monitoring can produce information on outputs and outcomes in a
frequent and timely manner at relatively low costs. Based on this information, the
organization in charge of the program can modify its business plans and service
delivery system. On the other hand, monitoring by itself can rarely explain the
causality between inputs and outputs/outcomes. It only describes the measured
performance of a program, and says nothing about the extent to which the program
contributed to the observed performance. In addition, performance monitoring does
not question the relevance and appropriateness of the chosen performance indicators,
122 Part II. Performance Management
and takes as given the objectives and design of the program. Moreover, it is often
difficult to measure with only a limited number of indicators the performance of a
program that has diverse stakeholders and multiple objectives. In some cases, it is even
impossible to define performance indicators. Despite these limitations, however,
performance monitoring plays an important role in the overall performance
management process by providing the basic information on program performance.
A second tool for performance assessment is program evaluation. According to the
OECD (1999), performance evaluation can be defined as a systematic and analytical
assessment addressing important aspects of a program and its value and seeking
reliability and usability of results. Program evaluation addresses the question of why
and how the program produced certain outputs and outcomes. It purports to analyze
scientifically the impact of a program on the expected and unexpected results, describe
objectively the factors that contributed to the success or failure of the program, and
provide information that can be used to redesign the program and for other purposes.
Program evaluation can also question the relevance and appropriateness of the chosen
performance indicators and reassess the objectives and design of the program. On the
other hand, program evaluation usually requires large amounts of money and time,
and cannot be performed on all programs.
Of course, there are other tools for performance assessment than these two. Audits
have traditionally been the most important instrument to ascertain the regularity and
integrity of public sector operations. More recently, performance audits have been
employed by the supreme audit institutions of many countries to analyze the efficiency
of government programs. In addition, many countries have also been utilizing
performance appraisal of individual government employees to attribute the outputs
and outcomes of an organization to those of individuals, and to reflect the information
on their promotion and salary determination.
Monitoring Evaluation
Among these tools, performance monitoring and program evaluation are deemed
the most important, and accordingly they take a central stage in performance
Chapter 10. Introducing Performance Management in Korea 123
management. Some, such as Rist (2003), even equate performance management with
performance monitoring and evaluation (PM&E). Table 10-1 contrasts the main
characteristics of monitoring and evaluation.
Kang and others (2003) tried to estimate the impact of pollution abatement
investment in the following way. First, they calculated EBOD, which is defined as the
difference between the actual BOD and the assumed level of BOD when no investment
has been made since 1990:
where
Because they did not have data on w1, w2, and w3, Kang and others (2003) assumed
various levels for these weights. In the next step, they estimated the following equation
with the standard regression method:
EBODt = + Rt-1 + Pt + ut ,
where
Rt-1 = accumulated investment after depreciation up until year t-1 (100 million
won), and
Pt = annual precipitation (100mm).
The estimated value of ranges between 2 and 2.5, and indicates that the pollution
abatement investment has not been very cost-effective. According to Table 10-2, each
investment of 100 million won (around 83 thousand USD) reduces pollution by 0.00002
ppm. In this case, it costs 500 billion won (around 420 million USD) to reduce pollution
by 0.1 ppm.
Weights
R2 DW
w1 w2 w3 (x 0.00001) (x 0.01)
0.4 0.1 0.5 -1.02 2.14 (3.47) 6.16 (1.67) 0.64 1.80
0.4 0.2 0.4 -1.05 2.28 (2.75) 7.50 (1.37) 0.53 1.56
0.3 0.2 0.5 -0.84 2.19 (2.67) 6.71 (1.24) 0.51 1.59
0.3 0.4 0.3 -0.90 2.47 (1.93) 8.20 (0.97) 0.36 1.33
0.2 0.3 0.4 -0.87 2.33 (2.22) 7.46 (1.08) 0.43 1.43
0.2 0.4 0.4 -0.07 2.38 (1.86) 7.41 (0.88) 0.34 1.35
0.1 0.4 0.5 -0.49 2.28 (1.78) 6.61 (0.78) 0.31 1.36
0.1 0.5 0.4 -0.52 2.43 (1.60) 7.36 (0.74) 0.27 1.29
Note: In parentheses are t-statistics.
Source: Kang and others (2003).
Such a lack of adequate data can be observed in other areas as well, and poses a
serious threat to the successful introduction of a performance management framework
in Korea.
z improving decision-making;
z assisting in resource allocation; and
z enhancing accountability.
measurement. Basic research programs, for example, aim to accumulate and diffuse
scientific knowledge, which in itself is not quantifiable. Even when quantification is
possible, it may be difficult to establish the causality between the intervention and final
outcomes. The educational achievement of middle school students, for example, can
depend on the current education as much as on the previous ones they received in
kindergartens and elementary schools.
Second, program costs should also be measured precisely. To this end, overhead
costs from support services should all be allocated to programs. In addition, economic,
rather than historic, costs should be the basis for cost comparison, and this requires the
introduction of accrual accounting in budgeting. For example, annual depreciation of
buildings and facilities should be added to program costs. While many countries
currently employ accrual accounting for their financial statements, only a handful of
them, including the U.K, New Zealand, and Australia, have introduced accrual
accounting in budgeting. This indicates the degree of difficulty involved in the task.
Third, even if it is possible to measure both performance and costs precisely, it will
be difficult to link them directly when their relationship is not stable. And even if their
relationship is stable, past stability does not guarantee the same stability in the future.
For example, a large expansion of a certain program can result in substantial changes in
average and marginal costs. When this is expected, the government cannot rely on past
data to budget for expansion.
The experiment by the U.S government shows that these concerns are real. The
GPRA required the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to report on the
feasibility and advisability of including a performance budget as part of the Presidents
budget (GAO, 2002). In 2001, OMB reported the results of five performance budgeting
pilots that explored agencies capabilities of more formally assessing the effects of
different funding levels on performance goals. Overall, OMB concluded that the pilots
raised key challenges regarding performance budgeting at the federal level including,
for example, the following:
including decisions about future allocations. One should also remember that perfect
information is not essential. Decisions are always made on the basis of imperfect
information. Making available at least some information on performance may be able
to add some greater degree of confidence to the decision-making process. At the least,
it can be used to raise questions that should be considered or explored through other
means.
At the same time, efforts should be made to minimize the resistance by various
stakeholders to performance management. A better understanding of their incentives
and interests would help in this regard. Further, a realistic expectation on what
performance management can bring about will also help. Success is guaranteed only by
a prudent and gradual approach; a firm belief in the value of performance-orientation,
but with a clear recognition of the gap between hope and reality.
Citizens
The Performance Management System (PMS), which started in the spring of 2003, is
led by the Ministry of Planning and Budget (MPB). PMS corresponds to performance
monitoring and does not include program evaluation as its component. PMS requires
line ministries to set up performance goals and indicators, prepare annual performance
plans and performance reports, and submit them to the MPB at the start of the annual
budget cycle. The MPB is in charge of making the system in place by examining the
132 Part II. Performance Management
status of PMS in line ministries, coordinating the implementation, and feeding back the
results to resource allocation.
PMS covers only part of ministries activities, as those activities not involving large
sums of expenditure (such as pure policy-making) are excluded from performance
monitoring. Also, activities for which the benefits of performance monitoring are
expected to be small (such as wages and salaries, basic program expenditures,85 and
general administrative expenses) are excluded as well.
For now, PMS applies to 22 leading ministries but will be eventually extended to
all ministries in the central government. The leading ministries were asked to list the
programs (PMS programs) that will be subject to PMS, pick 30 percent of them for
2004, set up strategic and performance goals for these programs, and develop
indicators. In 2004, they begin to measure these indicators, and set up goals for the rest
of their PMS programs. Non-leading ministries will start developing their indicators in
2004.
85 In Korea, programs with small and recurrent costs are designated as basic programs after negotiation
between line ministries and the MPB. Others are designated as major programs.
Chapter 10. Introducing Performance Management in Korea 133
Source: MPB.
The pilots on performance budgeting that were carried out in 1999-2002 covered
all expenditures of line ministries. When significant difficulty was encountered in
developing performance indicators, the MPB decided to change the design of the
system and cover only those programs for which clear performance targets can be
established. But the current design can result in the exclusion of important activities
and programs from performance management. In particular, programs whose
expenditure consists mainly of wages and salaries or recurrent running costs will be
excluded regardless of their importance, as well as the grant programs for local
governments. If these programs take a large part in carrying out the mission of the
ministry, performance management will lose its substantial meaning.
Of course, there exist cases where performance indicators are difficult to build. But
indicators are only a part of the whole exercise. A more important aspect of
performance management lies in clarifying the mission of the ministry and classifying
its activities in terms of strategic and performance goals. In this process, managers and
staff are reminded of the ultimate objectives that they want to achieve, and a cultural
change toward a results-orientation emerges within the organization.
Chapter 10. Introducing Performance Management in Korea 135
Self-assessments by the
z The central government ministries and local governments
central government ministries
assess their own operations.
and local governments
GOAS is led by the Office for Government Policy Coordination (OGPC) within the
Office of the Prime Minister. The OGPC performs organizational assessments and
oversees other assessments with the help of the Committee for Policy Assessment
(CPA). The latter is an advisory committee serving the prime minister86 and has private
sector experts as its members.
Below we will explain the organizational assessment, self-assessment, and
assessment of specific programs in greater detail.
The most important one of these is the assessment of major policies. It is carried
out over the core programs of the ministries and/or those programs that embody the
major policy agenda of the government. When selecting the programs to be subjected
to the assessment, the OGPC selects them at the level of bureaus. Once selected, they
become part of the self-assessment programs. That is, ministries should first provide
their own assessment of the programs selected by the OGPC. The OGPC then reviews
these self-assessments and provide their own views with the help of the CPA. The
results are reported to the prime minister in a ministerial meeting twice a year.
The criteria for assessment as suggested by the OGPC are presented in Table 10-8.
86 The prime minister in Korea is appointed by the president just like the ministers and does not have a
2.3.3. Self-assessment
Self-assessment is carried out over the central government ministries and local
governments. Self-assessment of the central government ministries is implemented in
much the same way as the organizational assessment, except that ministries themselves
select the programs to be subjected to the assessment. Each ministry also has a
Committee for Self-assessment in place, which provides assistance in making self-
assessment. The criteria for self-assessment are the same as those for the organizational
assessment (Table 10-8).
Policy
implemen- z Are the changes in policy environment adequately
Appropriateness
tation accounted for during the implementation process?
of the
z Are adequate efforts being made for public relations?
implementation
z Is a cooperation network in place with other ministries
process
that have related roles?
Achievement of
z Have the objectives been achieved?
Perfor- the objectives
mance Effectiveness of
z Does the policy have real impacts on the public?
the policy
Source: OGPC (2003).
Line ministries can also initiate evaluations. In this case, they need to submit their
evaluation plans by mid-March to the OGPC and report the evaluation results to the
prime minister.
and reporting is a precondition for good performance management. When it is not well
established in line ministries, and when they do not feel the need for such a system, it
is difficult to instill a performance-orientation in them.
Moreover, when the primary use of performance management as envisaged by the
budget authorities lies in linking performance and budgeting, line ministries will take
it as another source of external interference in ministerial affairs and resist its
introduction.
Third, the diverse system of performance management as explained in the
previous section poses another obstacle to transitioning toward a new framework.
PMS, GOAS, MBO, and performance audits are likely to overlap each other and be a
source of turf-wars between the sponsoring agencies. To avoid this possibility, the MPB
openly announced that it will differentiate PMS from other forms of performance
management by focusing on the programs with large expenditures and measurable
performances.
But the current fragmented efforts by various central agencies are only second-best
to a consolidated drive toward a comprehensive and coherent framework for
performance management. Such fragmentation can increase confusion in line
ministries, overburden them with paperwork, and generate skepticism. It should
therefore be minimized in coming years.
In the U.S, federal agencies should prepare strategic plans, performance plans, and
performance reports under GPRA (Table 10-9). In Korea, line ministries are expected to
prepare performance plans and reports under PMS. More detailed requirements like
those in GPRA would help enriching the plans and reports. The MPB can also compare
Chapter 10. Introducing Performance Management in Korea 141
them across different ministries and propose best practices. It can also rate their quality
and publish the result on a web-site. Of course, line ministries should be given the
freedom to determine the document formats and encouraged to experiment with
different modes of presentation as long as they satisfy basic requirements.
A second step to build a system of planning and budget is introducing a medium-
term expenditure framework. The reason for the weak planning capacity in many line
ministries can be traced back to the uncertainty surrounding the amount of available
resources in coming years. It is very difficult and often meaningless to plan for the
future when uncertainty is large. I believe this explains why most ministries currently
live from hand to mouth, without a serious effort to prepare a realistic long-term plan
and design their annual operations within this plan. A medium-term expenditure
framework will certainly be of much help in this regard.
Third, when reviewing the budget requests from line ministries, the MPB should
pay attention not only to the outputs and outcomes of individual programs but also to
their design and implementation process. This point is illustrated in the Program
Assessment Rating Tool (PART) as employed in the U.S federal government. The PART
purports to provide a consistent approach to rating programs. It consists of
approximately 30 questions, which are divided into four sections (OMB, 2003). The first
three sections address program purpose, strategic planning, and management,
respectively. The fourth hones in on results and asks whether performance can be
demonstrated. Thus a substantial part of the PART questions deal with the issues of
program design and implementation under the premise that a good performance
cannot follow from a poor design and/or implementation.
Data obtained through monitoring is rarely sufficient to get at outcomes, and used
alone, is not capable of identifying attribution or causality (e.g. to what extent can one
say that a program activity is directly responsible or not for the given results?).
Monitoring information often can best be used to direct management attention and to
raise questions that should be explored in greater depth through evaluation.
Evaluation has the potential to identify what actually has happened as a result of a
program or initiative, whether planned or not, including unintended outcomes and
effects that often may be more significant than the stated objectives. In particular,
evaluation has the potential to identify why and how outcomes have come about. This
is essential information in order to be able to attribute effects to program activities. It is
also critical information in order to make decisions about future policies and programs,
to assist in program improvement, and to be able to generalize what has happened
from a single setting to elsewhere.
In a country like Korea which has little experience in evaluation, a formal strategy
to introduce the evaluation practice seems desirable. The Australian Ministry of
Finance, for example, imposed the following four requirements on line ministries
(Mackay, 2003):
This strategy had significant influence in spreading the evaluation practice among
line ministries in subsequent years. The MPB should consider adopting a similar
strategy. In addition, attention should be paid to the accumulation of data, which is
essential for good evaluation. As illustrated at the beginning of this paper, almost all
sectors are in dire need of basic data. In particular, an income panel data set, none of
which exists at the present, would provide a valuable basis to assess the various
welfare programs that have been expanding rapidly in recent years.
burden on line ministries. It should therefore proceed to the extent that it is feasible
and meaningful.
Figure 10-4 illustrates how the Immigration and Naturalization Service (INS) of the
U.S government realigned its programs and accounts to link them to performance
goals. In the new account structure, the support and administration account is
temporary, capturing the overhead and support costs that could not be easily spread in
2003 (the first years of restructuring). INS spread these costs in the 2004 budget.
Existing Program Structure New Program Structure New Account Structure Performance Objectives
Border Patrol
International Affairs
Enforcement
Objective: Secure the ports
of entry, land border, and
Intelligence coasts of the U.S. against
Immigration Enforcement
Interior Enforcement unlawful entry.
Account
Investigations Objective: Facilitate lawful
travel and commerce across
the borders in the U.S.
Detention &
Detention & Removals
Removals
Objective: Deliver services
to the public in a
Adjudication &
professional and courteous
Naturalization
Immigration Services manner and ensure that
Immigration Services
Account correct immigration benefit
International Affairs decisions are made in a
Benefits timely and consistent
fashion.
Information and
Records Management
Information Resource
Management
Data and Objective: Strengthen
Communications human resource
recruitment and retention
Support and
Construction and efforts and provide for a
Administration
Engineering workforce that is skilled,
diverse, and committed to
excellence.
Training Infrastructure and
Administrative Support
Legal Proceedings
Management and
Administration
information on costs has limited value. The accrual accounting would reveal the true
economic costs of the programs.
Here again a pragmatic approach is needed, focusing our efforts on those areas
that make significant differences in costing. For example, the U.S government has
introduced accrual accounting in federal credit programs direct loans and loan
guarantees in 1990. Currently, efforts are being made to extend it to three additional
areas; government employees pension programs, the removal of hazardous materials,
and capital assets. According to OMB (2002),
z Pensions and retiree health benefits are earned as Federal employees work; they
are paid much later, after the employees retire. The legislation transmitted [to the
congress] would require program and other employer accounts to pay the
employer share of the accruing costs of these benefits to retiree benefit accounts.
These accounts would pay the benefits when they come due.
z Similarly, programs that generate hazardous substances would be required to pay
the accruing cost to clean up contaminated assets at the end their useful life. These
payments would go to funds responsible for the cleanup.
z In contrast, capital assets are bought before they are used. In this case, an agency
Capital Acquisition Fund (CAF) would be created. Following good budget
practice, the CAF would request budget authority (BA) up front to acquire assets
that are included in the budget, and outlays would be recorded when payment is
made. However, this BA would be in the form of borrowing from Treasury
authority. The CAF would then borrow for the period of the assets useful life;
collect annual capital user charges in proportion to asset use, and make the
mortgage payments to Treasury.
References
GAO (General Accounting Office), Managing for Results: The Statutory Framework for
Performance-based Management and Accountability, GAO/GGD/AIMD-98-52, January
1998.
________, Managing for Results: Agency Progress in Linking Performance Plans with Budgets
and Financial Statements, GAO-02-236, January 2002.
Kang, Man-ok, Byung-kook Lee, and Im-ho Lee, Environmental Budgets in Korea, Research
Monograph, Korea Environment Institute, 2003 (in Korean).
Mackay, Keith, The Two Generations of Performance Evaluation and Management System in
Australia, in Performance Evaluation System and Guidelines with Application to Large-Scale
Construction, R&D, and Job Training Investments, World Bank and Korea Development
Institute Conference Proceedings, Korea Development Institute, July 2003, pp.45-60.
MPB (Ministry of Planning and Budget), Guidance on the Performance Management System, 2003 (in
Korean).
OECD, Improving Evaluation Practices: Best Practice Guidelines for Evaluation and
Background Paper, PUMA/PAC(99)1, January 1999.
OGPC (Office for Government Policy Coordination), Government Operations Assessment: E-
Community, 2000. 5 (in Korean).
________, Guidance on the Government Operations Assessment, 2003. 1 (in Korean).
OMB (Office of Management and Budget), Analytical Perspectives: Budget of the United States
GovernmentFiscal Year 2003, U.S. Government Printing Office: Washington, 2002.
________, Performance and Management Assessments: Budget of the United States GovernmentFiscal
Year 2004, U.S. Government Printing Office: Washington, 2003.
Perrin, Burt, Implementing the Vision: Addressing Challenges to Results-focused Management
and Budgeting, OECD, 2002.
Politt, Christopher, Integrating Financial Management and Performance Management, OECD
Journal on Budgeting, Vol. 1, No. 2, 2002, pp.7-37.
Rist, Ray C., Designing and Building a Performance-Based Monitoring and Evaluation System:
Structures and Strategies, in Performance Evaluation System and Guidelines with Application
to Large-scale Construction, R&D, and Job Training Investments, World Bank and Korea
Development Institute Conference Proceedings, Korea Development Institute, July 2003,
pp.31-43.
Schick, Allan, The Performing State: Reflection on an Idea Whose Time Has Come But Whose
Implementation Has Not, GOV/PUMA/SBO(2003)17, OECD, May 2, 2003.
CHAPTER 11
Performance Management in the Health Sector
by
Heesuk Yun, Korea Development Institute
believe that prevention may be a better alternative to a cure. As a society enters into a
more developed stage, more preventive programs and technologies emerge to improve
the nations health. Immunizations to prevent disease, mammography screening to
detect breast cancer, and campaigns promoting smoking cessation are such. However,
since the potential efficacy of preventive care is hard to prove with certainty, the need
for rigorous evaluation will increase in the near future in Korea.
Against this background, this paper attempts to summarize the essential elements
and special characteristics of performance evaluation in the health field in relation to a
general evaluation framework. Also, emphasizing the need to build an infrastructure
for evaluating health interventions, the paper introduces the U.S. experience of
devising indicators for measuring health performance. In doing so, standards for
effective evaluation of health interventions will be briefly reviewed, and implications
for establishing a performance evaluation in the health field in Korea will be extracted.
This evaluates the performance of the health care system. A health care system has
a structure defined by laws and regulations, and has as its components personnel,
facilities, organization, and financing. The characteristics of the population that the
system serves and the physical, social, and economic environment where they live are
also included in the structure components. The structure of the system influences the
process or delivery of health services, which in turn produces outcomes. The system
performance evaluation typically examines the influence of the structure and structure
components on the outcomes. For example, if whether the patents payment method to
primary care physicians has any influence on patients utilization of health services.
Chapter 11. Performance Management in the Health Sector 149
This examines the efficiency and effectiveness of specific health services provided
to patients in the system. Evaluation is focused on the measurement of benefits, health
outcomes, or a specific health service associated with particular medical technology
compared to the costs of producing them. Technologies that produce large benefits at
low costs have greater worth than technologies that offer few benefits at high costs.
Performance evaluation in every field follows general steps. First, questions calling
for the evaluations, which are often too general and vague, need to be transformed into
questions which are precise enough to be measured and evaluated. This is followed by
evaluation designing, analysis with credible evidence and presenting conclusions, and
lastly, sharing lessons and ensuring use.
Keeping in mind this commonality, however, particularity of evaluation in the
health field should also be emphasized, which brings special features in each step of
the evaluation process.
Since the beginning of modern medicine, rigorous scientific inquiry has been the
most important factor that characterizes the adoption of new procedures and practices
in the health field. This in turn characterizes performance evaluation in the area of
health in a way that all causal links, explicit or implicit, in the intervention logic should
be certified with scientific rigor.
Intervention logic is a hypothesis on the sequence of events for bringing about
change by synthesizing the main program elements into a picture of how the program
is supposed to work. As a conceptual link from a programs inputs, or resources
devoted to it, to its output, and to the achievement of results and outcome, intervention
logic summarizes the program's overall mechanism of change by linking processes to
eventual effects (CDC, 1999). Elements in a logic generally include inputs (e.g., trained
staff), activities (e.g., identification of cases), outputs (e.g., persons completing
treatment), and results ranging from immediate (e.g., curing affected persons) to
intermediate (e.g., reduction in tuberculosis rate) to long-term effects (e.g.,
improvement of population health status).
A main purpose of evaluation is to assess effects, and intervention logic, an
explanation of what the public action is supposed to achieve and how it is supposed to
achieve it, is the basis of the assessment. Since there are usually causal assumptions
hidden beneath the surface relating to how the program is supposed to generate its
supposed effects, and the state of the external environment such as other policy
interventions and other external factors, the logic needs to be investigated carefully. In
other words, the main job of the evaluator is to examine the relationship between
activities of interest and observed consequences. This can be accomplished by
identifying and critically assessing these hidden assumptions concerning conditions for
the intervention to be effective. In the health field, intervention logic often involves
scientific theory in laboratory diagnosis of disease or pharmaceutical knowledge,
which makes it more complicated to identify the hidden assumptions and to
investigate their uncertainties. Inevitably, scientific specialty is heavily involved.
A noticeable example is the growing interest in preventive care. While advocates
of preventive care assert that diagnosing and treating illness at an early stage can save
a significant amount of money and successfully restore the patient to good health, the
efficacy of preventive care is difficult to prove. It requires conceptualization of those
specific conditions and socioeconomic characteristics of patients for whom preventive
care might have some impact. For example, little is known about the circumstances
under which various screening programs, such as Pap smears to detect cervical cancer,
are effective.
152 Part II. Performance Management
Reduction in
Lead Poisoning
of Children
Identification of
Housing Repair
Hazardous
Housing
Figure 11-3 shows an example of a smoking cessation program to reduce low birth
weight among low-income, pregnant women. Sheehan (1998) examined the association
between stress, addictive behaviors, and low birth weight among 5,295 low-income,
inner-city women in Hartford, Connecticut. The arrows in Figure 11-3 indicate direct
and indirect relationships between various factors and low birth weight. Addictive
behaviors such as smoking and alcohol consumption have direct effect on low birth
weight in the causal relationships. If a pregnant woman smokes or drinks alcohol more,
the childs birth weight would be lowered. The standardized regression coefficients
indicate the size of the change in low birth weight produced by a standardized change
in various factors. Economic stress has direct effects on family stress and social
support, and family stress and social support, in turn, have direct effects on addictive
behavior. Hence, the three stress variables have indirect effects on low birth weight
through their direct effects on smoking and drinking behavior.
-.13 No Social
Support
.55
.41
.75 .90
.35 Economic
Stress
Addictive .28 Low Birth
Behavior Weight
.89
.30
Family .32
.35
Stress
Medical
.19
Risks
Source: Sheehan, Stress on Low Birth Weight, reproduced from Grembowski (2001).
154 Part II. Performance Management
This causal relationship has some implications about the programs expected
outcome. First, the program alone is likely to reduce but will not eliminate the low
birth weight problem. In the cause and effect structure, 90 percent of the variation in
low birth weight is not explained by the variables in the structure. Also, the figure
indicates that both medical risks and addictive behavior have direct effects on low birth
weight. Thus, because the unexplained variance is large and other risk factors exist
beyond the programs control, the program will at most reduce the low birth weight
problem.
The size of reduction can also be projected. It is suggested that the programs
indirect effect on low birth weight will be smaller than 0.28. If the program reduces
smoking by 0.25, then the programs indirect effect on low birth weight would be 0.25
0.28 = 0.07.
Second, the causal relationship in the figure also suggests that the programs
performance would be increased if the program was modified. As shown, because
stress has a direct effect on addiction and indirect effects on low birth weight, the
program would perform better if it also includes a part for stress reduction.
This is an example showing that scientific and statistical reasoning offers an
understanding of how the program is supposed to work, and how efficient the
program will be in achieving its objectives. Evaluation research in the health field is
normally based on theory from laboratory experiments, economic as reasoning and
statistical projection, and it should be constantly adjusted with scientific rigor
whenever new information about the evaluation logic is added to the information set
or the contextual situation is changed.
In most cases, health programs lie in complicated contexts including historical and
geographical settings, political, social, and economic conditions, and influences of
related or competing organizations. The most important are the socio-economic
conditions. The evaluator should consider the needs of the target population and the
particular problems which the program is designed to address. It is difficult to identify
what effects are genuinely caused by a program and to separate these effects from
other influences on the socio-economic problems. Hence, the evaluator needs to
understand these intertwined factors in order to design a context-sensitive evaluation,
to interpret findings accurately, and to assess the generalizability of the findings.
It should also be noted that because health programs are often created to reduce
health disparities across socio-economic groups, evaluators also must consider political
aspects among various income groups and politicians, and interest groups surrounding
a health care program (Shortell, 1978). Since politics is about how we attach values to
policy issues, politics and values are inseparable from the evaluation of health
programs in nature. Consequently, evaluations are always conducted in a political
context where a variety of interest groups compete in their own interests.
Chapter 11. Performance Management in the Health Sector 155
When we say that certain effects were produced or caused by an intervention, this
means that if the intervention had not taken place or had taken place in a different
degree, those effects would not have occurred, or would not have occurred in the same
degree. Simply put, evaluations are carried out to determine what would have
happened without the intervention. This is called the counterfactual situation
(European Commission, 1997), and ideally, deriving the counterfactual situation with
certainty is desired.
Evaluation would be easy when comparing two groups that are identical in every
respect except that one group is exposed to the intervention while the other group is
not. In the real world, however, this is not the case since we can never find two groups
that are identical in every respect except for being exposed to a program. The non-
equivalence of the two groups means that the counterfactual situation has to be
estimated rather than derived, and this emphasizes the importance of evaluation
designs scientific accuracy and data credibility.
The methods for evaluation design are drawn from social, behavioral, statistical
and health sciences. Design types include experimental, quasi-experimental, and
observational designs, and according to the specific evaluation case, the best fitting
design should be selected to provide the appropriate information to address the case
specific questions (Fink, 1993). Experimental designs use random assignment to
compare the effect of an intervention with otherwise equivalent groups. Quasi-
experimental methods compare nonequivalent groups (e.g., health program
participants with those on a waiting list) or use multiple waves of data to set up a
comparison. Observational methods use comparisons within a group to explain unique
features of its members (CDC, 1999). The choice of design has implications for what
will count as evidence, how that evidence will be gathered, and what kind of claims
can be made. In particular, health problems are usually entangled with other living
conditions or other health problems where the origin of the cause is hard to trace.
Hence, special attention must be given when selecting a design. At the same time, data
availability has enormous importance in performing evaluation in all types of design.
Though it is true that more rigorous methodological tools and designs focusing on
the impact or outcome of evaluations are essential parts to ensuring the quality of
healthcare evaluation research, what is more pressing is the need to understand
specific program components and the process by which they are implemented since
every health program has its special features due to scientific hypotheses or the
contextual particularity in which it lies. The interdependency of the health program
with other political and environmental factors stated above should also be considered
carefully.
For this reason, the observed golden rule is that there is no single evaluation
methodology which is universally applicable for the entire health field. Instead, the
choice of method should be determined by the particular evaluation problems at hand.
Actually, arbitrary choice of method at the beginning without careful examination of
the case often results in a poor evaluation. The evaluation methodology should be
carefully chosen after examining the targeted health evaluation case, and more
importantly, should be customized and modified to reflect the particularity of the case.
156 Part II. Performance Management
Also, if a program's activities are aligned with those of other programs operating
in the same setting, or with change of social, economic conditions, certain effects cannot
be attributed solely to one program or another. In this case, the goal of the evaluation is
to gather credible evidence that describes each program's contribution in the combined
change effort.
Although it was previously emphasized that each evaluation uses a different and
customized methodology for the targeted program, it should also be highlighted that
there exists a strong need for a recommended general framework for health field
evaluation that is both a synthesis of existing evaluation practices and a standard for
further improvement.
The existence of a standardized framework supports a practical approach to
evaluation that is based on steps and standards applicable in public health settings.
Because the framework is purposefully general, it provides a guide for designing and
conducting specific evaluation projects across many different areas of public health
intervention. In addition, the framework can be used as a template to create or enhance
program-specific evaluation guidelines that further operationalize the steps and
standards in ways that are appropriate for each program (CDC, 1999).
By integrating the principles of the general framework into all program operations,
it is possible to stimulate innovation toward the improvement of outcomes and better
detection of program effects. Consequently, detecting these effects in a more efficient
and timely manner will enhance the evaluators ability to translate findings into
practice. Furthermore, guided by the steps and standards in the framework, a basic
approach to program planning will also evolve, and integrated information systems
will support a more systematic measurement. Also, lessons learned from evaluations
can be used more effectively to guide changes in public health strategies.
It should be noted that the standard framework should be considered as a
practical, non-prescriptive tool for individual evaluation work; in that it only acts as a
guide for public health professionals in their use of program evaluation. However,
designed to summarize and organize essential elements of program evaluation, the
framework comprises steps in program evaluation practices and standards for effective
program evaluation. Adhering to the steps and standards of this framework will allow
a better understanding of each program's context and will improve the way program
evaluations are conceived and conducted.
It is also worth noting that the general framework can encourage evaluation
research to be integrated with routine program operations. Because performance
evaluation is in nature a case-specific analysis, it is not easy to practice it consistently
across program areas, or sufficiently integrate it into the day-to-day management of
most public health interventions. Hence, there needs to be a standard framework that
offers operating principles for guiding public health activities.
These principles of evaluation work as guidelines to improve how public health
activities are planned and managed. It would be possible to ensure that new and
existing programs follow these principles by requiring each program to conduct
routine, practical evaluations that provide information for management and improve
Chapter 11. Performance Management in the Health Sector 157
program effectiveness. In that way, public health professionals will recognize that the
basic steps of the evaluations framework are parts of their routine work. In day-to-day
public health practice, program goals are defined; core questions are stated; data are
collected, analyzed, and interpreted; judgments are formed; and lessons are shared.
Evaluation is about revealing the value of a program. This involves making value
judgements on the degree to which a programs performance has been good or bad, so
predetermined and transparent indicators are needed to ensure that value judgements
do not become arbitrary. For this purpose, a prerequisite for evaluation research is to
set up a system of criteria by which to measure the observed effects of a program and
the benchmarks on the proper function or success of a program. However, setting the
system of indicators may be difficult for a number of reasons. For one, objectives can
sometimes be expressed in very vague terms, and a single program may have multiple
objectives, either in terms of results of outcomes, some of which may carry relatively
more weight, or even be incompatible with others. Also, objectives may also evolve
over time, as the programs environment evolves. Furthermore, indicators should
ideally allow evaluators to compare the performance with other policy instruments in
the same field of action because even if a program falls short of achieving its objectives,
its performance may not necessarily be unsatisfactory.
In the health field, where intervention logic is grounded on scientific knowledge
and all the political, social, and economic interests, indicators should function as the
guiding rules that pertain to the evaluation's focus and questions. The role of indicators
should translate general concepts regarding the health program, its context, and its
expected effects into specific measures that can be interpreted, while providing a basis
for collecting evidence that is valid and reliable for the evaluation's intended uses. For
this reason, setting up a system of indicators in the area of health is more complicated
than in other fields, because indicators need to present even the puzzling aspects of the
laboratory hypothesis in a meaningful form for monitoring.
Indicators include measures of the program's capacity to deliver services, the
participation rate, levels of client satisfaction, the efficiency of resource use, and the
amount of intervention exposure. Also included are outcome measures such as changes
in participant behavior, community norms, policies or practices, health status, quality
of life, and the settings or environment around the program. Furthermore, multiple
indicators are needed for tracking the implementation and effects of a program.
Developing multiple indicators should be based on intervention logic, and in this
sense, intervention logic can be used as a template to define indicators leading from
program activities to expected effects. For each step of the model, qualitative and
quantitative indicators could be developed to suit the concept in question, linking
assumption, the information available, and the planned usage of data. Relating
indicators to intervention logic also allows detection of small changes in performance
faster than when relying on a single outcome as the only performance measure. In
addition, lines of responsibility and accountability are clarified in this approach as the
measures are aligned with each step of the program strategy. Consequently, combining
intervention logic and indicators results in a set of measures that detect the
consequences of intermediate effects on health outcomes of the program.
Even during evaluation, indicators might be modified or new indicators can be
adopted. According to changes in the environment or context, indicators need to
adjust. It should also be noted that measuring performance by tracking indicators is
158 Part II. Performance Management
only part of an evaluation and must not be the only basis for judging whether an
intervention is a success or failure. Serious problems can result from using performance
indicators as a substitute for the entire evaluation process and reaching final
conclusions. For example, an indicator such as a rising rate of disease might be
assumed to reflect a failing program when, in reality, the indicator is influenced by
changing conditions that are beyond the program's control.
Although health outcome measures are widely used and have intuitive appeal,
they are insufficient by themselves for monitoring the efforts of a given program to
reduce complex public health problems. Many measures of health outcomes are
affected by various factors that are not under the health interventions control,
Chapter 11. Performance Management in the Health Sector 159
(1) Indicators should be aimed at a specific objective and be result oriented. They must
clearly specify a desired public health result, including identifying the population
affected and the time frame involved. Process and capacity measures should clearly
specify the health outcome, or long-term objective, to which they are thought to be
related.
(2) Indicators should be meaningful and understandable. They must be seen as important
to both the general public and policy makers at all levels of government and should
be stated in non-technical terms.
(3) Data should be adequate to support the indicator. Adequate data on the populations
of interest must be available for the use of indicators and have the following
characteristics:
Data to track any objective must meet reasonable statistical standards for accuracy
and completeness;
Data to track any objective must be available in a timely fashion, at appropriate
periodicity, and at reasonable cost; and
Data applied to a specific indicator must be collected using similar methods and with
a common definition throughout the population of interest. Comparisons of an
indicator across regions are valid only if the definition and collection methodology are
consistent across regions.
(4) Indicators should be valid, reliable, and responsive. Indicators should as much as
possible, capture the essence of what they purport to measure, be reproducible
(reliable), and be able to detect movement toward a desired objective (responsive).
Prevention of chronic disease is the primary goal of many health programs, but
chronic disease incidence and mortality data are not useful because the expected time
period between most prevention activities and the effect of those activities on disease
incidence or mortality tends to exceed several years, which also exceeds the time that
health departments are generally willing to wait to assess the interventions
effectiveness. Therefore, potential chronic disease measures are focused on risk
reduction and screening, and process measures.
Chapter 11. Performance Management in the Health Sector 161
Individual Percentage of women who gave birth in the past year and reported
pregnant woman smoking tobacco during pregnancy
Individual Percentage of employed adults whose workplace has an official policy
working adult that bans smoking
Nutrition
Content Percentage of persons aged 18 and older who eat five or more servings of
fruits and vegetables per day
Content Percentage of persons aged 14-17 (grades 9-12) who eat five or more
servings of fruits and vegetables per day
Total calories Percentage of persons aged 18 and older who are 20 percent or more
above optimal body mass index
Exercise
Individual adult Percentage of persons aged 18 and older who do not engage in physical
activity or exercise
Individual youth Percentage of persons aged 14-17 (grades 9-12) who do not engage in
physical activity or exercise
Screenings and
Tests
Hypertension Percentage of persons aged 18 and older who had their blood pressure
checked within past 2 years
Cholesterol Percentage of women aged 45 and older and men aged 35 and older who
had their cholesterol checked within past 5 years
Breast Cancer Percentage of women aged 50 and older who received a mammogram
within past 2 years
Colon Cancer Percentage of adults aged 50 and older who had a fecal occult blood test
within past 12 months or flexible sigmoidoscopy within past 5 years
Cervical Cancer Percentage of women aged 18 and older who received a Pap smear within
past 3 years
Diabetes
HbA1C Percentage of persons with diabetes who had HbA1C checked within past
12 months
Foot exam Percentage of persons with diabetes who had a health professional
examine their feet at least once within past 12 months
Eye exam Percentage of persons with diabetes who received a dilated eye exam
within past 12 months
162 Part II. Performance Management
HIV infection, tuberculosis, and many of the STDs resemble noninfectious chronic
disease. The interval between the acquisition of infection and the development of
serious consequences may be years long. Monitoring the long-term consequences of
these infections does not provide a useful short-term indication of the performance of
prevention efforts, so measuring in this public health area is more complex than in
others. Three general strategies for preventing these diseases are: reducing the risk of
exposure, reducing the probability that an exposed person becomes infected, and
reducing the duration of the infectious state among persons who became infected.
164 Part II. Performance Management
Although there is little agreement on linkages between specific process and mental
health outcomes, there is some agreement on the dimension that are important in
evaluating mental health services; quality assurance, access to services and utilization
of services, consumer satisfaction with services, and psychological and social outcomes.
The vaccine preventable diseases are well understood. Cases are easily identified,
and health outcomes are well defined. A strong, causal relationship exists between
immunization and disease prevention. Clearly defined process (vaccination rate) and
outcome (disease incidence rate) measures are preferred, and they should be
responsive to effective interventions within a short period of time.
Process Measure Percentage of parents with children under 18 who believe that
the benefits of immunization outweight the risks
Process Measure Percentage of parents with children under 18 who report
receiving immunization reminders from their immunization
providers
8. Summary
As stated in the beginning, performance evaluation in the health field is an
increasingly important area of study for future government officials, health
professionals, and service providers. The essence of evaluation is to isolate causes of
particular events or outcomes. If a particular intervention appears to be associated with
a beneficial effect, one must find out whether the effects can really be attributable to the
intervention or whether they might be the result of some other factors. With this
commonality, what distinguishes evaluation of public health action from other fields is
the use of rigorous scientific methods involving laboratory frontier knowledge and
contextual complexity requiring socio-economic and political awareness.
In order to set up an evaluation system in the field, building infrastructure is
required more than anything. The framework for evaluating public health intervention
needs to be devised, indicators need to be collected and assessed for future use. Also, to
utilize indicators, appropriate data for each indicator should be gathered and
organized. Furthermore, since indicators are designed to detect changes in a limited
time period, following up data collection should be made within a reasonable time.
Although it will take a tremendous amount of resources to accomplish these
prerequisite tasks, now is the time for Korea to tackle them in order to remain
accountable and to manage surging healthcare costs.
168 Part II. Performance Management
References
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Framework for Program Evaluation in Public Health,
1999.
Drummond, Michael F., Bernie J. OBrien, Greg L. Stoddart, and George W. Torrance, Methods for
the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes, Oxford University Press, 1997.
European Commission, Evaluating EU Expenditure Programmes: A Guide, 1997.
Fink Arlene, Evaluation Fundamentals: Guiding Health Programs, Research, and Policy, SAGE
Publications, 1993.
Grembowski, David, The Practice of health Program Evaluation, SAGE Publications, 2002.
Ministry of Health and Welfare, Yearbook of Health and Welfare Statistics, 2003.
National Research Council, Assessment of Performance Measures for Public Health, Substance Abuse,
and Mental Health, (eds.) Edward B. Perrin and Jeffrey J. Koshel, 1997.
Shortell, Stephen M. and William C. Richardson, Health Program Evaluation, The C. V. Mosby
Company, 1978.
Suchman, Edward A., Evaluative Research: Principles and Practice in Public Service and Social Action
Programs, Russel Sage Foundation, 1967.
CHAPTER 12
Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm
Reform in Korea
by
Ju Ho Lee, KDI School of Public Policy and Management
1. Introduction
Foreign institutions have affirmatively evaluated the performance of primary and
secondary education in Korea. Such is the case when these assessments are based on
outstanding math and science scores achieved during international competitions.
However, underlying these superficial results are factors that significantly influence
parents and students such as school satisfaction and teacher evaluations, which ranks
in the bottom tier among OECD countries.
This paper sheds light on student performance, which rests on the current college-
admission system, not the performance-management system. In short, the overall
increase in test scores can be attributed to the severe competition characterized by
students will to enter better universities, rather than the notion that a performance-
driven system in schools are increasing the quality of students.
Under the college-admission system, performance-management system is not
operating effectively. Schools are protesting the sole reliance of college admission-
based studies, emphasizing the need for character development. At the same time,
teachers and administrators at the Ministry of Education and Human Resource
Development are actively dissuading the implementation of scholastic-based
performance-management system. However, the absence of such system leads to a
vicious cycle, where students continue to seek private tutors through the inadequacy of
schools, rooted by skyrocketing demands for college preparation.
As the struggle to provide performance-management system for primary and
secondary schools emerge, surveys such as the National-Standard of Education
Achievement, City and Provincial Office of Education Evaluation (henceforth office
evaluation), and the Primary and Secondary School Evaluation (henceforth school
evaluation) are beginning to broach. Hence, this paper will assess the efforts of the
current performance-management system in primary and secondary schools and
propose a new scheme to improve the current performance-management system in
South Korea.
The structure of this paper is as follows. In section 2, a general overview of the
performance in schools and the relationship between the results of such performance
and the characteristics of performance-management system will be discussed. In
section 3, a general overview of the performance-management system in schools will be
examined and assessed. Finally, section 4 will propose reforms to improve the
performance-management system for primary and secondary schools in South Korea.
170 Part II. Performance Management
2. Performance in education
Korean scholastic attainment based on international assessment test is clearly high
among OECD countries as depicted in Table 12-1. For each category, Korea scored first
for science, second for math, and sixth for reading. However, when taking their
distribution into consideration, students below level 1 (1%) and students at level 5 (6%)
are quite low, meaning a large chunk of the students are positioned between levels 3
and 4 (39% and 31%, respectively). Although the size of students below level 1 is ideal,
the size of students at level 5 only resembles the 20th ranking country among the 27
countries surveyed in this test. Hence, although Koreas small proportion of low-
performance students is ideal, the incapability to educate outstanding students poses a
serious problem.
Scientific literacy 1 2 14 4 12 20 10 5 23 30
Math literacy 2 1 19 8 10 20 15 6 26 30
Reading literacy 6 8 15 7 14 21 9 2 20 30
At level 2 19% 18% 21% 20% 22% 22% 20% 18% 26% 30%
At level 3 39% 33% 27% 27% 31% 27% 30% 28% 31% 19%
At level 4 31% 29% 21% 24% 24% 19% 26% 28% 19% 6%
In the results from PISA 2000, student engagement shows us very interesting
point.
In Table 12-2, student engagement is illustrated by asking students whether they
strongly agree, agree, disagree or strongly disagree to the following statements about
their school: I feel like an outsider (or left out of things), I make friends easily, I feel like
I belong, I feel awkward and out of place, other students seem to like me, and I feel
lonely. Forty-one percent of Korean students reported to demonstrate a low sense of
belonging, the lowest out of the 27 OECD participating countries. This is a striking
result, which challenges the academic achievement demonstrated in Table 12-1.
Furthermore, low participation, which measures how many times in the past week
students say they missed school, skipped classes, and arrived late, shows that only 8
percent of students feel that they have low participation. Perhaps pressures from
parents to attend classes and competition from colleges that require class participation
have contributed to this ironical result.
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 171
Low sense of Belonging1) 41% 38% 25% 17% 30% 23% 18% 21% 23% 22%
Low participation2) 8% 4% 20% 15% 15% 13% 24% 26% 22% 21%
Note: 1) Percent of students in each OECD country who have a low sense of belonging.
2) Percent of students in each OECD country with low participation at school.
Source: OECD, Student Engagement at School, PISA 2000.
However, why is it the case that high scholastic achievement and low sense of
belonging coexist in South Korea? One plausible explanation would be the prevalence
of privately funded private tutors and remedial classes outside school. The data from
Table 12-3 shows that Korea and Japan have remarkably high participation of
educational courses outside school. Interestingly, the inclusion of private tutors
reduced Japans participation to 17.3 percent while maintained the Korean numbers to
rank first at 57.5 percent.
The low assessment of Korean teachers as shown in Table 12-4, adds to the
possibility that high scholastic achievement scores received by students should be
attributed to private tutors rather than their schools. In table 12-4, students were asked
to indicate the frequency with which teachers in the language of assessment show an
interest in every student's learning, give students an opportunity to express opinions,
help students with their work, and continue to teach until students understand. Values
above the OECD average, set to 0, indicate higher than average student perceptions
that teachers are supportive, while negative values indicate below-average student
perceptions of teachers' supportiveness. Korean students report the lowest support
(-0.67) from their teacher.
Average ranking 2 1 8 13 N. A 20 21 18 24 3
Participation1) 63.6% 70.7% 24.7% 20.1% N. A. 10.4% 7.8% 14.4% 5.6% 51.4% 24.9%
Average ranking 1 21 18 19 N. A. 11 16 14 4 6
Participation2) 57.5% 17.3% 28.8% 24.4% N. A. 36.2% 7.8% 31.6% 48.0% 47.1% 32.3%
Note: 1) Percent of students who have sometimes or regularly attended courses in the language of assessment,
courses in other subjects, or extension or additional courses in the last three years.
2) Percent of students who have sometimes or regularly attend courses in the language of assessment,
remedial courses in other subjects, training to improve study skills or private tutoring in the last
three years.
172 Part II. Performance Management
By Ranking 27 18 4 1 19 24 7 6 21 13
Student1)
Mean -0.67 -0.17 0.34 0.50 -0.20 -0.34 0.21 0.31 -0.28 0.07 0.00
Ranking 26 10 18 13 N. A. 16 5 11 25 3
By
Principle2)
Mean -0.72 0.14 -0.04 0.02 N. A. -0.01 0.34 0.08 -0.69 0.39 0.00
Note: 1) Index of teacher support and performance on the combined reading literacy scale, by national
quarters of index.
2) Index of principals' perception of teachers' morale and commitment and performance on the
combined reading literacy scale
Source: OECD, Knowledge and Skill for Life, PISA 2000.
3. Performance-management in education
87
The index was scaled using a weighted maximum likelihood estimate, using a one-parameter item
response model (referred to as a WARM estimator; see Warm, 1985 with three stages: A). The question
parameters were estimated from equal-sized sub-samples of students from each OECD country. B) The
estimates were computed for all students and all schools by anchoring the question parameters obtained in the
proceeding step. C) The indices were then standardized so that the mean of the index value for the OECD
student population was zero and the standard deviation was one(countries being given equal weight in the
standardization process). It is important to not that negative values in an index do not necessarily imply that
students responded negatively to the underlying questions. A negative value merely indicates that a group of
students (or all students, collectively, in a single country) or principles responded less positively than all
students or principles did on average across OECD countries. Likewise, a positive value on an index indicates
that a group of students or principals responded more favorably, or more positively, than students or principals
did, on average, in OECD countries.
88
This section is heavily drawn from Lee, Myung-Hee (2000).
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 173
89
This paragraph is based heavily from Baek, Sun-Geun (1997) and KEDI (2003).
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 175
feedback and guidance for various educational activities and maintenance facilities.
Thus, it functions to boost efficiency and effectiveness. Finally, the disclosed
information provided by the assessment gives consumers of education a better idea
about each schools pedagogical activities and management programs to select schools,
teachers, and courses. However, as indicated by Baek, Sun-Gun (2003), most office and
school evaluations focus on achieving only the second goal outlined above.
Table 12-5. Areas of assessment, number of subjects and items, and distribution of the
office evaluation
Table 12-6. Budget distributed according to the results of the office evaluation
Table 12-7. Areas of assessment and contents of the school evaluation conducted by the
ministry of education and human resource development
- Studying methods
- Communication skills
- Logic and creativity
Scholastic Achievement
- Relationship with adults
- Ego-identity
- Responsibility
- Students
Satisfaction - Parents
- Teachers and administrators
- Degree of difficulty involved when administering the 7th
Curriculum
- Class utilizing ICT
Education Policy - Achievement Test
- Special ability/aptitude education
- Reducing students per class
- School Administration Committee
Source: Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development and Korea Education Development
Institute (2003), pp.14-17.
178 Part II. Performance Management
Table 12-8. Contents of the field evaluation conducted by the ministry of education and
human resource development to evaluate schools
Areas of Assessment Major Questions
Do the personnel of the school agree with the goals and plans?
Do the curricular-educational activities reflect each students
Curricular-Educational
specialty (student level, interests, abilities)?
Activities
Are curricular-educational activities developing voluntary studying
skills?
Are pedagogical activities outside the curriculum adequately
Pedagogical Activities exhibiting student skill and potential?
Outside the Curriculum Do pedagogical activities outside the curriculum help develop
qualities possessed by democratic citizens?
To provide better educational activities, is the school operated and
administered efficiently?
Is the school working to improve its teaching and quality?
Activities that Support
Does the school possess necessary facilities in conducting educational
Education
activities?
Are the parents, school, and the local community cooperating to
improve the quality of education?
While supervising the 7th Curriculum, to what degree has the school
faced difficulties?
Are ICT-utilizing classes aiding student comprehension?
Education Policy Are special-skill classes helping the development of student quality?
Is reducing class size helping to improve the school quality?
Is the Student Administration Committee contributing to the
democratic management of the school?
Source: Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development and Korea Education Development
institute (2003), p.22.
School evaluations held at the city and provincial offices of education level are
conducted periodically every two to three years, using the Primary and Secondary
School Evaluation Manual, of 1997 to inspect the progress of implementing education
policies and projects. In addition, these tests are acclimated to the trends and directions
of the individual city and provincial offices of education. More specifically, the Seoul
Metropolitan Office of Education has the following school-evaluation goals: first, it
should trigger the efficiency and the accountability of pedagogical activities, second, it
must promote autonomous and creative educational activities to alter the education
environment, and third, it should elevate the quality of education by discovering and
proliferating an excellent case of educational activity (Seoul Metropolitan Office of
Education, 2004). School evaluations administered by the Seoul Metropolitan Office of
Education are written and site surveys, composed not of qualitative tests but of
effort assessments, measuring the progress of educational activities geared toward
students and improvements in lecturing methods.
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 179
Table 12-9. Areas of assessment and evaluation tasks for general secondary schools of
Seoul metropolitan office of education
The problems associated with the current office and school evaluations are their
ambiguity: the vagueness of their secondary goals (Kong, Eun-Bae, 2002). More
specifically, the extravagance of evaluating items and the lack of consistency has also
been pointed (Baek, Sun-Geun and Baek Sung-Joon). Moreover, there has been negative
feedback regarding the inadequacy in actively using the test results. However, in this
case, the problem lies in examining the survey as a source of spreading excellent cases
and correcting bottlenecks as a reflux mechanism. Thus, rather than liming the
assessment to disclosing outstanding cases, there must be successive measures under
the auspices of the Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development or by a
regional office of education. Therefore, through rigorous project evaluations,
modifications must be made to the project and its affected budgeting system. For
evaluation results to influence the performance-management system, achievement goal
and indices must first be developed, while redefining the content and procedure of
assessment.
180 Part II. Performance Management
Education budget falls under the jurisdiction of the Ministry of Education and
Human Resource Development. The annual revenue for 2004 increased by 6.1 percent
(compared to the annual revenue of 2003) to 4.6 trillion won of which general-
accounting revenue increased by 5.7 percent to 252.7 billion won and special-
accounting revenue increased by 6.1 percent to 4.4 billion won (both figures compared
to 2003) (Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, 2004). Annual
expenditures were 4.0 trillion won for central-education finances and 22.4 trillion won
for provincial-education finances (84.9 percent of total budget).
In the process of producing the education budget, the city and provincial offices of
education present their annual revenue and expenditure budgets to the Minister of
Education and Human Resource Development. Consequently, the minister analyzes
the budget; for cities or provinces that have conspicuous declines in efficiency and
financial health, the minister is authorized to order inspections of the respective office
of education, disclose all results, and provide guidance and maintenance to retain
financial stability (Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, 2002).
Furthermore, to determine whether funds were used according to their respective
proposals, evaluations are conducted annually before the distribution of resources to
increase transparency, performance, and administrative skills. However, a large
portion of the budget is spent on personnel expenses and on school administration,
making performance management only possible for policy projects.
The long-term plan of the government is to sustain a sound financial basis,
construct performance-based financing, and maximize autonomy and participation
(Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, 2003a). Much attention has
been given to the construction of performance-based financing that the government
proposed, since it will foster performance analysis and evaluation of financial projects,
which will be reflected in the distributed budget.
The forecast for provincial finances look rigid due to projects improving education
environment, constructing facilities for the 7th Curriculum, executing the overall policy
to improve teaching professions, and promoting information and technology.
Moreover, with the implementation of new policies from the current administrating
government, difficulties are expected to be forthcoming in the finances of provincial
education (Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, 2003a). Making
efficiency and performance-lead finance system the main priority of the provincial
education finance, the introduction of performance-based budgeting and its simulation
will be conducted (Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, 2003a).
Furthermore, an analytical index of efficient investment on provincial education
finances will be developed and applied to promote soundness, efficiency, fairness,
investment return, and autonomy for individual schools.
According to the Special-Accounting Education Budgeting Proposal (Ministry of
Education and Human Resource Development, 2003b) to maximize financial
management and trigger efficient financial investment of performance-based financing
simulation, ten to twenty projects will be selected by each city and provincial offices of
education, compose performance index and proposal, which will be used for the
following year. In preparation, a budget-assessing committee will be formed to
evaluated and analyze financial priorities.
Performance-lead budgeting links projects and resources to performance. By
giving autonomy to each divisions expenditure and evaluating their performance, they
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 181
can assess the amount of money that can be distributed. Moreover, by disclosing
performance goals and actual results, this method generates transparency and
accountability.
At the moment, there are 27 performance-based budgeting projects administered
by the Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development via performance
index developed by the Ministry of Budget and Planning. For instance, the goals of the
curricular reform and continued support project have two goals: implementing a
national curriculum and developing specific performance goals and indices to support
research related to curricular improvement. Although the Ministry of Education and
Human Resource Development planned partial implementation of performance-based
budgeting, no specific strategic and performance goals and indices have been
developed.
To successfully introduce performance-based budgeting, transparent budgeting
and execution, complete disclosure of the entire process, and performance goals and
indices must first be developed. However, even with the planned simulation of
performance-based budgeting in 2004, the Ministry of Education and Human Resource
Development has not even developed a performance index. To include performance-
based budgeting to individual schools, an assessing body and evaluating methodology
must also be constructed.
Since 1999, the Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development has
simulated performance-based budgeting for the life-long education project, but did
not reap the results it wanted. The difficulty in assimilating an econometric and
performance index, unclear achievement results within a fiscal year, and the
unwillingness to cooperate to assess school performance by scholastic achievement,
academic level per school, and the rates of matriculation and employment, have
contributed to its failure. In any case, with high fixed cost associated with the budget of
city and provincial offices of education and the Ministry of Education and Human
Resource Development there are hopes that performance-based budgeting will be
implemented partially for national policy projects and projects at a city and provincial
offices of education level.
90
Since the year 2000, the Ministry of Planning and Budget is overseeing the performance-based funding
system for institutions capable of implementing such system and is increasing their targets (Ministry of
Planning and Budget, 2001).
182 Part II. Performance Management
diversity of the education system, increasing the scholastic ability of low-income and
low-performing students, and financially rewarding education institutions that have
attained the goals set by the government and objectives of the Accountability-
Strengthening Program are intended for all public and private schools. However,
before such programs can be implemented, research pertaining to measuring student
achievement and school performance should be conducted to set a standard for
assessing school accountability.
In the case of the No Child Left Behind Program in the US, which began in January 2002, success or
92
failure to improve student achievement make the basis for determining performance, intended for students in
the bottom 30 percent.
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 183
education program, and systemizing funds to be rewarded for education programs that
are more successful than others, which could be classified into three categories:
Diversifying the school system via strengthening accountability has been restricted
as a supplementary issue to other reform agendas, pursued by education reform
committees. Thus, the central idea underlying the strengthening of accountability
through school-system diversification lies in the increased selectivity of schools for
students and the competition among schools, which ultimately leads to improvement
of performance of education in schools. The Charter School system in the US and the
93
system outlined in the FKI-CEPRI report are specific examples of this program. By
providing individual schools comprehensive jurisdiction over school management and
curriculum, thereby diversifying education, accountability of education is strengthened
through enabling student selection. More specifically, by implementing a formula-
94
funding system concurrently with the accountability-strengthening program, funds
will be efficiently allocated to schools where students choose attend, increasing
primary and secondary education performance.
Furthermore, this paper proposes the implementation of accountability-
strengthening program via increasing student-achievement performance for students
of low-income and low-ability. This proposal is different from the first, because it is
intended for all public and private schools, including charter schools. The focus for this
95
program lies in remedial classes, which will increase the scholastic performance of
low-income and low-performing students. Policies for students of low-income are
geared toward financial assistance (tuition grants and the provision of meals at school)
and only directed toward the extreme poor. Moreover, remedial classes for low-
performing students were focused on assisting the extremely poor-performing
minority. In other words, programs intended to increase performance for low-income
and low-performing students are almost nonexistent.
This paper proposes government provision of assistance for programs geared
towards increasing scholastic performance for low-income and low-performing
students. In doing so, a systematic research pertaining to improve student performance
must be conducted beforehand. The No Child Left Behind Program of the US that
93
The FKI-CEPRI report proposed the implementation of a charter school operating along the following
principles: increased student selectivity of schools, provided comprehensive authority over school operation
and funds, and issued discriminated government funding contingent upon student size.
94
Formula Funding is the specification of the government-discriminated funding system based on student
size often used by charter schools. Formula funding can be divided into four categories basic student costs,
curriculum costs, remedial-educational costs, and school-operation costs and the calculation involved for each
category involve detailed conditions.
95
Remedial education refers to remedial classes aside from regular courses and livelihood guidance,
excluding curriculum guidance.
184 Part II. Performance Management
began in 2002 could be a good case to model. In addition, the government must also
provide assistance for remedial programs in each school, geared towards students
whose household income and scholastic performance is below a substantial level.
Furthermore, schools receiving aid from the government must provide remedial
96
education for low-income and low-performing students; continued government aid
97
must be contingent on the performance of the remedial program. Active student and
parent participation must also be considered, and research must also be conducted to
98
attract participants.
Finally, this paper proposes an accountability-strengthening program that utilizes
a rewarding system. In this program, individual schools that have accomplished goals
outlined by the government to improve education performance will be rewarded to
promote school effort to ameliorate their system. More specifically, the government
99
will set achievement goals and recruit schools that want to compete within this
condition. Among the participating schools, the government will financially reward the
school and its participating members. To strengthen accountability through a
rewarding mechanism, this paper proposes the following.
First, regulations pertaining to school affairs should be temporarily exempt for
participating schools so that they could conduct various experiments to achieve the
goals outlined by the government. If schools are restricted by regulations, their
attempts for experimenting will be limited. In other words, the director of a regional
education office may function as an exogenous variable, affecting education
performance. Thus, a temporary exception for regulations related to school affairs
could be implemented in the same manner as charter schools.
In regards to the reward bestowed by the government, there must also be benefits
for the members of the school, including teachers and students. Without the active
participation of teachers and students, it is difficult to conduct experiments to attain
100
performance goals. Hence, providing direct rewards (incentives) will promote the
active participation to achieve these goals.
96
Because remedial education could be operated separately from regular classes, accountability-
strengthening program must be intended for all public and private schools receiving aid from the government.
97
In the case of the American No Child Left Behind Program, direct selection of teachers and curriculum
by students and assessment of scholastic improvement have contributed to the strengthening of school
accountability.
98
In a society that stresses academic attainment, students may feel embarrassed to participate in a program
for low-income and low-performing students. (Stigma effect) Thus, to encourage active student participation,
direct and indirect incentives must be provided.
99
The government can choose diverse goals such as improving of scholastic achievement and curriculum,
innovating class lectures, and developing character.
100
Rewards for teachers could be a bonus in their salary or additional benefits; for students, scholarship could be
considered.
Chapter 12. Performance Management in Education: A Call for Paradigm Reform in Korea 185
Improving Scholastic Achievement for Low-Income and Low-Performing Students (for all
public and private schools)
z Implement a remedial education program to increase the performance of low-income and
low-performing students.
z Implement an achievement-evaluating system to assess the quality of remedial education.
z Test for accountability based on the improvement of student achievement.
Promoting Competition Among Schools via a Rewarding System (for Schools that desire
competition)
z Government will outline performance goals and recruit schools that want to participate in
this competition.
z Bestow autonomous operation rights for schools participating in the competition,
comparable to the level provided to charter schools.
z Direct rewards for the school, teacher, and students involved.
186 Part II. Performance Management
References
(In Korean)
Baek, Sun-Geun, Proposal for connecting School Evaluations and the City and Provincial
Offices of Education Evaluation at the National Level, Prospects and Tasks for the Creation of
an Educational Society, presented at the Fall Academic Seminar of the Academic Association
of Korean Education Evaluation, Korea Education Evaluation Institute and Korea
Education Development Institute, 2003.
Chun, Sae-Young and Lee, Sun-Ho, Research on the Basic School Fee Distribution Model of
Formula Funding, Journal of Education Finance, Vol. 11, No.2, pp. 149-173, 2002.
Kim, Mynug-Suk, Goals and Uses of a National-Level Scholastic Achievement Test, Korea
Institute of Curriculum and Evaluation (KICE), 1998.
Kim, Sung-In, Problems, Analysis, and Improvement Proposals for College-Admission Policy,
Education Development: January/February, pp. 52-55, 2001.
Kong, Eun-Bae et al., Research to Propose an Improved Way of Conducting City and Provincial
Offices of Education Evaluations, Korea Education Development Institute, 2002.
Lee, Myung-Hee, Problems and Directions for Improvement for Koreas Scholastic
Achievement Evaluation System, Search for Koreas Curriculum and Education Evaluation for
the 21st Century, Education Policy Seminar, 2002.
Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development, Budget for 2004 Self-Governing
Bodies Special-Accounting for Education, Ministry of Education and Human Resource
Development website (http://www.moe.go.kr), 2003a.
, Summary of the Budget for 2004 Special-Accounting for Education, 2003b.
Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development and Korea Education Development
Institute, Survey of the Overall School Evaluation Results, 2003.
(In English)
Evers, Willianmson M. and Herbert J. Walberg, School Accountability, Hoover Institution Press,
2002.
Florida Information Resource Network, http://www.firn.edu.
Hassel, Bryan C., The Charter School Challenge, Brookings Institution Press, 2003.
Hill, Paul T., Robin J. Lake, and Mary Beth Celio, Charter School and Accountability in Public
Education, Brookings Institution Press, 2002.
Korea Education Development Institute, Research on the City and provincial Office of
Education Evaluation System and Methods for Improvement, 2002.
Lombardi, Joan, Time to Care, Temple University Press, 2003.
Ministry of Education and Human Resource Development and Korea Education Development
institute, Reports on the Results of the Overall School Evaluation, 2003b.
No Child Left Behind Program, http://www.nochildleftbehind.org
OECD, Student Engagement at School, www.oecd.org, 2003.
, Knowledge and Skills for Life, www.oecd.org, 2001.
Office Evaluation Committee, Report on City and provincial Office of Education Evaluation,
each year.
Seoul Metropolitan Office of Education, Report of School Evaluation for the 2003 Academic
Year, 2004.
CHAPTER 13
Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results
by
Harry P. Hatry and Ritu Nayyar-Stone, The Urban Insitute
1. Introduction
1.1. Rationale for performance management
Over the last several years, the Mayor of Baltimore has adopted the CitiStat approach as
a primary management tool for several of the citys agencies. Supervisors from different
agencies appear before the mayors cabinet every two weeks to discuss their agencies
performance data. A number of improvements were noticed very quickly.
- In the first three-month period there was a 25 percent decrease in overtime in the
Water and Waste Division.
- During the regular meetings, department performance graphs are displayed for all to
see, and trends of either good or bad performance are usually easy to see.
- City officials note that there is no longer any stigma of having to visit and respond to
questions from city leadership.
- There are more opportunities for interagency collaboration and for identifying and
sharing better practices.
Once it was decided to implement CitiStat it took three months to collect and analyze the
performance information and make a presentation at the Mayors office. Currently 14 agencies
are involved in the CitiStat process. The first agency (solid waste collection) made its
presentation on June 2000. Within four months seven agencies were included in the process
regularly reporting data to CitiStat and having bi-monthly meetings to use the information in
improving service quality.
The mayors office estimates a start-up cost of $20,000 that mostly includes infrastructure and
overhead cost and not staff salaries. Agencies can collect data with any software and in any
format. However, they all use a similar format in reporting the information to the Mayors
office.
Table 13-1 presents the categories of performance information that are relatively
familiar to agency managers. Data on the amount of resources expended for particular
programs (inputs), and the products and services that a program has completed
(outputs), are regularly used by governments to track program expenditure and service
provided. Results-based information (outcomes) is rarer, even though it is considerably
more helpful in determining the results and accomplishments of the service. Finally,
information that relates the amount of input to the amount of output or outcomes
measures efficiency (or its reciprocal) productivity.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 189
Efficiency and Productivity: The amount of input to the amount of output (or outcome).
The ratio of the amount of input to the amount of output (or outcome) is labeled
efficiency. The inverse, the ratio of the amount of output (or outcome) to the amount of
input, is labeled productivity.
z Cost per gallons of drinking water delivered to customers (output based)
z Cost per number of roads that were improved from poor to good condition
(outcome based)
Sources: Adapted from Hatry (1999), and Nayyar-Stone, Mark, Cowen, and Hatry (2002).
This report provides recommendations for a multi-year strategy and specific steps
for providing and using performance information to produce a truly citizen outcome-
oriented government. It provides a framework for the introduction of a performance
measurement/performance management system in governments throughout the
world. The basic assumption is that the purpose of government is to support its citizens
in achieving the highest quality of life for the funds that the government is spending.
Performance measurement/performance management systems basically serve two
purposes: providing accountability and improving programs and services so as to
make them more efficient and effective. The key question for accountability is: What
are citizens getting for their money? The key question for improving services is: How
can we make programs and services better?
Throughout this report the term performance measurement is used to cover
measurement of both outputs and outcomes. However, the report focuses primarily on
the need to measure and manage outcomes, the most neglected, and most important
category of measurement. Outputs are important to measure since they provide basic
information as to the governments physical products. The relation of outputs to
expenditures is much easier to assess than the relationship of outcomes to either
outputs or expenditures. However, outputs tell little about the success of government
programs and services in achieving results important to citizens.
190 Part II. Performance Management
Performance management occurs when managers use the information from the
performance measurement process to help them manage and improve programs and
services. Performance management, it can be argued, is the most important reason for
performance measurement, even more important in the long run than use of
performance measurement to make government accountable. Fortunately, a good
performance measurement system can simultaneously provide information useful for
both purposes: achieving accountability and improving services.
Government also involves elected officials. They play a major role, as will be
discussed, in moving a government to performance measurement and performance
management. They should be considered to be an integral part of Governing For
Resultsboth by their support for the effort and by themselves using the information
from the process.
This report does not discuss fiscal or financial planning. These, of course, are of
major importance for successful governing but are beyond the scope of this paper.
Section 2 provides a sample of a time-phased set of actions needed for
implementing a performance management process. Section 3 identifies the roles and
responsibilities of the major participants, such as: (a) national offices such as the
Ministry of Planning and Budget; (b) the line ministries and agencies; (c) the
supporting ministries and agencies; and (d) the legislature. Section 4 discusses a
number of key elements relating to designing a performance management system.
Section 5 discusses a number of important elements in implementing the design.
As of this time, many national governments have begun introducing some form of
performance measurement. However, few appear to have made major progress in
introducing performance management. Even these efforts have tended to focus on
outputs and not on the results of those outputs. In addition, the focus in almost all
national governments of which we are aware, has been to move as soon as possible, if
not immediately, into performance budgeting.
Much less attention has been focused on helping managers use the information to
improve their services to citizens. This, unfortunately, means that examples of good
performance management practice by national governments are rare. We have, thus,
had to draw from the experiences of sub-national governments, such as local
governments, where more active progress has been made. Overall, however, the reader
needs to recognize that while lip-service on performance management has been
present for years, the actual practice at any level of government, while growing
considerably, is still rare.
have made more progress in using performance information for internal management
uses, but this also has not happened overnight.
The Steering Committee might include representatives from the following types of
organizations:
z Finance Office.
z Outside expert
collection, and analysis). Figure 13-1 provides a sample three-year schedule that focuses
on the technical steps for any single agency or program within the agency.
Figure 13-1. Sample Performance Management System schedule for each program/service
36 month schedule
Step 2-3:
Market and conduct
training on PM
Steps 4:
Identify data sources and data
Collection plan
Step 5:
Develop & implement process for
Citizen input
Second and Third Year
Step 6-7:
Establish baseline, set targets, &
establish data quality control
Procedures
Steps 8:
Report performance
Information regularly
Step 12:
Begin performance review and
recognition awards
Estimate the start-up costs and subsequent on-going implementation costs for the
performance management system. Seek funding for any significant added start-up
costs. Over the long run, performance management is expected to become a basic part
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 193
Step 3: Develop guidance materials and a training plan for performance management
Step 4: Identify current data availability and develop a data collection plan
Identify the current performance data available and the major performance data
gaps in what performance information managers need. Ask agencies to identify
performance indicators for which regular data are desirable for each of their major
programs. The indicators should include both outputs (the amount of work
accomplished) and outcomes (the quality and effects of the programs work on
citizens). The indicators should include both those for which data are currently
available and those for which data are not currently available but can be obtained in
the future. (Many programs will probably not currently be systematically obtaining
outcome data.) Customer surveys and "trained observer" procedures are both likely to
be useful to many agencies for collecting outcome information for their performance
measurement systems.
Request that each agency develop a data collection plan for the performance
indicators, particularly the performance indicators for which data are not currently
being collected. The data collection plan should: define thoroughly each performance
indicator; identify how the data will be collected (the data collection procedure that is
expected to use); the timing and frequency with which the data for each indicator will
be collected and reported; who will be responsible for obtaining the data on each
indicator, and any special resources needed for collecting the data.
Given the considerable potential usefulness of customer surveys for many
agencies, the government should consider providing some national technical assistance
in customer survey procedures to agencies and their programs. Any agency, and any
program within an agency, that plans to use regular customer surveys will face a set of
common issues.
Develop and implement a process for the government and its individual programs
for obtaining input from citizens on the quality and effects of the agencies services.
First, develop and implement a process for obtaining input from citizens for selecting
the outcome indicators, such as through the use of focus groups or hearings. Second,
consider using citizens to help with data collection, such as doing trained observer
ratings of educational or health facilities, roads, or landfills in their city.
First obtain data for performance indicators to establish a baseline. This is vital for
future target setting by program managers. Such targets, of course, need to be related
to the resources expected to be available to the program.
Begin holding regular (perhaps quarterly) performance reviews whereby a
manager, at any level, meets with staff to discuss the findings and what needs to be
improved and how shortly after the performance report for the latest reporting
period has become available. In subsequent meetings assess the extent to which
changes have led to desired improvements.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 195
Develop procedures for data quality control. Such offices as those of an Auditor
General and any Agency Comptrollers might be encouraged to incorporate
performance data collection procedure reviews in their work. The purpose here is to
encourage, and ensure, that the outcome data are of satisfactory quality.
After the performance measurement process has been underway for a year or so,
ask each operating agency to develop annual reports for the public, ones that include
outcome information. Whenever possible, break out (disaggregate) outcome
information to show outcomes for different customer groups. Some examples of
candidate breakouts are income, age, gender, and location.
Involve citizens in group meetings to discuss the findings from the outcome
reports. These meetings would include discussion of customer/citizen responsibilities
in producing successful outcomes, as well as the role and improvement actions needed
by government programs.
Only by using performance information can each agency get the full benefit of
implementing a performance management strategy at the national level. Governments
initiating such a process often spend considerable time collecting data and then stop at
reporting the performance information the use of such information does not get
sufficient attention. One approach is to develop and implement service improvement
action plans. These focus attention on priority improvements by using performance
indicators to establish improvement targets and then track progress towards those
targets. This can be done towards the end of the first year after implementing a
performance management system.
A service improvement action plan is usually developed and implemented
through a working group created within the agency. This group can include senior
196 Part II. Performance Management
management, technical, and line staff. Researchers or external experts (from the
business or academic community) can also be members. The working group starts by
assessing the critical issues facing their agency. It then selects outcomes and indicators,
establishes baseline data, and sets improvement targets, develops and implements an
action plan with clear roles and responsibilities to achieve the targets, and collects data
again in 3, 6, or 9 months to identify the extent to which the desired
improvements in service outcomes have occurred.
As shown in the text box insert, a municipality in Albania has used these action
plans.
Step 12: Begin annual performance reviews and recognition awards to motivate
staff
3.1. The role of the national oversight office (such as a ministry of planning
and budget) and its relationship to the line ministries
Within the context of the Medium-term Philippine Development Plan 1999 to 2004, the national
government has implemented the Local Development Administrative Measurement System
(LDMAS). The LDMAS was developed in consultation with national and local government
agencies, civil society groups, donors and academics and is organized around 11 key local
government performance domains (e.g., fiscal management, service delivery, land use,
infrastructure, etc.). These domains are measured through 67 input, process, output, and
outcome indicators, and have been recently pilot tested in 6 municipalities with the following
impact:
- Each of the six municipalities reported that the indicators provided administrators
with important measures of performance that were previously not accessible.
- In the small GoA municipality, the indicators directed attention to poor fiscal
performance of the city administration, leading to the initiation of a series of measures
to improve the fiscal performance.
198 Part II. Performance Management
The national office would call for ministries and their agencies to provide data on
their major outputs, outcomes, and efficiency indicators. This would be a requirement
in budget submissions. The national office probably would also call for reporting on
these indicators at regular intervals throughout the year, such as quarterly. The latter is
particularly important for moving from a purely performance measurement system to
performance management. These regular reports provide a basis for program reviews,
permitting more timely mid-course modifications throughout the year.
The national office should establish basic common reporting formats that it needs
to review performance. For budget submissions, it might call for separate reports on
each agencys performance indicators. Or more commonly done it might call for
identifying the indicators and their values along with the funding information for each
program. The national office might request that indicators be reported by category of
indicator (such as whether the indicator measures an output, an intermediate outcome,
an end outcome, or efficiency). The form might contain separate columns for reporting
indicator values for some number of past years, columns for the budget-year
performance targets for each performance indicator. (The form might also call for
reporting anticipated values for performance indicators for programs whose budgets
are expected to produce products in years beyond the budget year. This appears to be
rare in current performance budgeting systems, at least as a formal requirement.) The
national office should also include requirements for agencies to provide explanations
when the indicator values are considerably worse, or better, than the targets. See the
Texas and Louisiana example in the text box insert.
The states of Texas and Louisiana in the United States have required formal explanations for any
performance indicator values that are not within either plus or minus five percent of the target
that the agency had set for the performance indicator for the reporting period.
Both states require quarterly reporting on performance to the governor and legislature, and
have established web-based reporting systems, so that agencies can easily enter their results
every quarter. For example, see the Louisiana Performance Accountability System (LaPAS) at
http://www.state.la.us/opb/lapas/lapas.htm
The national office also must be careful not to over-react to worse than expected
performance figures. It should avoid automatically blaming agency or program
management. Before acting, any reviewing office needs to first seek to determine the
reason for the poor results. For example, weak outcomes may have occurred not
because of any inherent problem with the program concept management but because
of external factors (such as worsening economic conditions that hampered the ability of
government employment programs to find jobs for unemployed workers).
Preferably the national office would act as a helper to line ministries and their
agencies in developing their own performance management processes. This is likely to
be a different perspective than is typical for national budget offices that consider their
role as solely to review agency budgets to keep them as low as possible.
The government is likely to need a separate unit from the unit that examines
budgets to develop the performance management guidance and provide assistance to
agencies (such as the management part of the Office of Management and Budget).
Each ministry and each operating agency will have its own special performance
measurement problems. The use of an across-the-government oversight group, as
discussed elsewhere in this report, can be used to help work out conflicts when they
arise between agency flexibility and the oversight offices needs for common reporting.
It is likely highly desirable for the national ministry to select the terms for the various
types of indicators, define them carefully, and provide examples. Unfortunately,
considerable confusion has resulted in many governments because of lack of at least
some attempt at standardization.
As noted in section 2, implementation is likely to be eased considerably, and
ministry and agency resistance reduced, if the government establishes a government-
wide oversight group that involves ministries and agencies in guiding implementation.
Table 13-3 summarizes the key responsibilities of the national oversight office.
1. Establish ground-rules and guidelines for required regular reports and for budget
submissions (such as: definitions of required types of performance indicators; guidelines
for presenting budget period targets for individual performance indicators; number of
prior years for which data are to be reported, requirements for providing explanations
for unexpected numbers; and the format for presenting this information).
2. Provide training to budget examiners in performance analysis.
3. Establish requirements, if any, for long-range strategic planning (including the number of
years to be covered and the content see Table 13-6 for suggestions on content).
4. Provide support and at least some resources for initial agency training and technical
assistance in performance measurement and performance budgeting.
5. Design incentives to agencies for performance measurement and performance
management (with an emphasis during at least the initial years in non-monetary rewards
for good performance, such as recognition awards for agencies and programs with
sustained good outcomes).
200 Part II. Performance Management
102
3.2. Role of ministries and agencies
The work of ministries and their agencies are, of course, essential to the successful
implementation of a performance management system. Each Ministry will have to
make a number of decisions specific to its own implementation of the system. These
decisions are listed in Table 13-4. Each decision is discussed below.
Who will take the lead in establishing a performance management system in the ministry?
Who will take the lead in establishing performance management in the agencies?
Who is responsible for what (strategic missions and policy objectives; agency objectives,
indicators and targets)?
Who will select the performance indicators?
Will there be a strategic plan and when?
Who will be trained, in what, and by whom?
What resources are needed and available to implement the process?
What reporting requirements will be assigned?
How will performance information be used in preparing and justifying budgets?
How will internal performance targets be established?
What kind of IT support system will be necessary?
What kind of incentives will be used to encourage improved performance?
What is the role of performance information in contracting for services?
What will be the role of local governments?
What will be the role of customers, businesses, and nongovernmental organizations in
performance management?
What quality control procedures will be used?
When and in what form should performance information be shared with the public?
3.2.1. Who will take the lead in establishing performance management in the Ministry?
Each minister will need to designate a senior person to lead in establishing a
performance management system at the ministry. The day-to-day management and
supervision of this system will usually not be feasible for the minister. If possible, the
designated individual would be a non-political appointee, to assure continuity to the
system even with a change in government. This person should have sufficient authority
to make some key decisions on behalf of the minister. (Management and supervision of
full-scale performance management within a ministry might require, perhaps, 40
percent of this persons time over a one-to-two year period.)
Each ministry will likely find it very useful to establish a ministerial oversight
committee of, say, 8-12 individuals to oversee development and implementation of
performance management. In addition to the person appointed by the minister to guide
this process, the committee might consist of:
102 Some of the issues discussed in this section are drawn from Hatry (2002) and Nayyar-Stone, Mark,
3.2.2. Who will take the lead in establishing performance management in the agencies?
Each agency will need to identify personnel who will lead the agencys effort. The
agency head will need to designate that individual. Probably the agency should also
form an overall coordinating/oversight group consisting of representatives from a
number of programs, if not all major programs, in the agency that would work
together. The group would recommend agency strategies for such performance
management elements as developing an overall schedule, training of staff, common
reporting formats that supplement those required by the ministry, and obtaining
resources where needed.
z Developing an overall mission for the ministry and specific missions for the
103
individual agencies and their individual programs.
z Identifying the outcomes sought by each agency and each program,
developing the specific performance indicators needed to track progress of
each desired outcome, and who and how will targets be developed for each
performance indicator.
z Prioritizing and defining the agencies and programs that will be the initial
pilots adopting performance management if the government decides to
start with a pilot rather than full-scale adoption of performance management.
(It is probably preferable to cover the entire ministry from the start, rather
than specifying a few agencies as a pilot. This issue is discussed further in
Section 5.)
103 It is very difficult to define the word program very specifically. In general, a program is a group of
government activities that has a particular mission and is sufficiently substantial to warrant being identified as
a specific entity with its own budget. Each government needs to establish its own set of programs. Some
examples of what might be separate programs are: road maintenance, road construction, communicable disease
prevention (but the health agency might want to have separate programs aimed at particular diseases, such as
AIDS-prevention), water pollution control, and foreign trade development.
202 Part II. Performance Management
The overall mission for the ministry and its strategic/policy objectives are a major
basis for agency goals, objectives, performance indicators and targets. Therefore, it is
important that they are clear and specific enough to provide guidance to the agencies.
104 This was noted by Gustafsson in this conference volume in describing the Swedish system. It appears to
apply equally to most, if not all, the other major country efforts to date.
105
One form of strategic planning is appraisal or situational analysis (also known as a strength,
weaknesses, opportunity, and threat analysis (SWOT)).
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 203
3.2.7. What resources are needed and available to implement the process?
The ministry with its agencies and programs will need to consider what added
financial costs and time will likely be needed. Then it will need to consider where that
cost and time will come from. Some initial assistance preferably would come from the
national ministry sponsoring the performance management effort, such as for initial
training. Some might come from outside funding sources such as the multi-lateral
banks and bilateral organizations.
204 Part II. Performance Management
Over the long run, however, the ministry and its agencies will need to be
responsible for their own performance management efforts. Performance management
should be considered to be just a part of good management. The potential costs of a
performance management process are discussed further in Section 5.
While each agency and each program may choose to track a relatively large
number of indicators for internal use, each will need to select a shorter list for
external reporting.
In addition, the ministry and/or agencies, with their programs, need to develop
guidelines for analysis of the performance data, especially outcome data. The raw data
are rarely useful to managers and staff. Data on individual events need to be
aggregated and then grouped in ways that can be really useful. For example, outcome
data will usually be considerably more useful to managers if the performance data are
grouped by such characteristics as the following:
z By demographic groups, such as: age group, gender, race/ethnicity, and income group
z By geographical areas, such as: regions, districts, and municipality
z By the particular office or facility providing the service (it is a basic principle
of performance management that each manager should be provided
performance data related to each manager's own area of responsibility).
3.2.9. How will performance information be used in preparing and justifying budgets?
Budget preparation and justification is of major concern to ministries and their
agencies and programs. Some budget instructions will come from the national budget
ministry. In a performance management system, a major new budgeting element is
performance budgeting the inclusion and consideration of output and, particularly,
outcome information as part of budget submissions.
However, each ministry and its agencies will likely want to determine the way
budgets will be prepared and submitted in more detail than that included in the
guidance provided to it by the national budget ministry. The ministry and agencies will
want to select those performance indicators that are most appropriate for inclusion in
budget submissions. Agencies and their programs will inevitably need for internal
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 205
3.2.11. What kind of information technology (IT) support system will be necessary?
Computerized data-processing capability and skills in the ministry and agencies
will make it much easier to collect and analyze performance information and in a
timely manner. The extent of technical assistance from IT offices (whether coming from
the national level of government and/or from the ministry) will likely be important to
each program attempting to provide accurate and timely performance data on many
performance indicators.
If possible, information on each agency can also be placed on the world-wide-web
for easy accessibility and update.
z The agency needs to have capacity to establish such contracts so they are fair
to both the public and the contractor.
z The agency needs to have the capacity to monitor contractors carefully to
obtain the info it needs to determine the extent to which contractors have met
their targets and be able to judge the validity of claimed reasons outside
their control preventing them from meeting their targets.
z Performance targets should be compatible with, and support, the performance
indicators in the programs performance measurement system.
z The program will probably need to encourage, and help, contractors maintain
their own performance measurement processes but require them to allow the
program to undertake periodic quality control audits of the contractor's data
systems.
3.2.14. What will be the role of local governments?
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 207
3.2.15. What will be the role of customers, businesses, and nongovernmental organizations?
These stakeholders have important role in at least three stages of implementing
a performance management system. Here are some potential roles:
z They are important sources of ideas for determining what outcome indicators
the program should track. This information can be obtained by holding focus
group meetings with customers, businesses, and NGOs.
z They can be important source of data for measuring outcomes. Reliable
feedback can be obtained from citizens and businesses by sponsoring quality
surveys.
z They are important potential customers for performance reports. They can
become supporters of the activities of the ministry if the reports focus on
outcomes (and not outputs) and provide clear, understandable, information of
interest to them.
NGOs can also join together in identifying the principal interests of their
constituents, and prepare report cards (see text box insert) to monitor the governments
performance.
In 1993 and 1994 the Public Affairs Center (an NGO), concerned about the deteriorating quality of
public services, developed and implemented a citizen satisfaction survey that measured user
perception on the quality, efficiency and adequacy of basic services extended by 12 municipal
agencies. The results of the survey were translated into a quantitative measure of citizen
satisfaction and presented in various media in the form of a report card. The 1994 survey was
followed up in 1999.
- Eight of the 12 agencies covered in the 1994 report card made attempts to respond to
public dissatisfaction. The worst rated agency the Bangalore Development Authority
reviewed its internal systems for service delivery, trained junior staff and began to co-
host a forum for NGOs and public agencies to consult on solving high priority civic
problems such as waste management.
- The report cards were also successful in generating political momentum for reforms.
Popular local and regional media carried regular stories on the report card findings.
Citizens have also been inspired to take initiative towards improving services and have
subsequently engaged in the state-citizen Swabhimana partnership in Bangalore a
program to arrive at sustainable solutions to longstanding city-level problems. The Chief
Minister of Karnataka has also established a Bangalore Agenda Task Force of prominent
citizens to make recommendations for the improvement of basic services.
Report cards have also been used as an effective tool in Ukraine, US, the Philippines and
elsewhere.
208 Part II. Performance Management
3.2.17. When and in what form should performance information be shared with the public?
Depending on the agency (and type of service), performance information can be
communicated to citizens on a quarterly, half-yearly, or annual basis. Reports should
not focus only on agency missions and activities, but also on service quality and
outcomes. Performance information is also most useful when adequately broken out
into categories such as gender, income, age, education levels, and geographical location
(rural or urban for example, or district/zone within a city). For external reporting
such as to the public it is important to keep in mind the following:
z Be selective as to how many and which indicators are included. Ministries and
agencies will internally track several more performance indicators than are
reported to the public. However, when selecting indicators for external
reporting, include the data on pre-selected performance indicators whether
performance has been good or bad. This will help establish the credibility of
the information.
z Make the reports easily understandable. As appropriate, use charts, graphs,
and diagrams to supplement tables and descriptive information.
z Obtain feedback from the public about the usefulness and readability of the
reports.
z If performance has been poor, consider attaching information identifying
plans for improvement.
The legislature is both a major motivator for, and a major user of, performance
information. Having legislation that requires the government to report performance
information provides one basic building block for performance measurement and
performance management.
Whether, and how, the legislature uses the performance information that it
receives can also have significant effects on the success of a performance management
system. Legislatures in some countries may have little real power so they cannot make
much use of such information even if they had good relevant results-based
information. In a parliamentary government the executive and legislative functions
tend to blend together. Nevertheless, most of these same issues apply.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 209
Whether or not the government has a parliamentary system, line agencies usually
are reluctant and apprehensive about providing performance information to the
legislature. And many legislators may not be interested in, or may not trust, the
quantitative data provided by line agencies. Agencies may provide too much data on
too many indicators, many of which may not be very important (usually being output,
not outcome, data). For all of these reasons, thus far, use of performance information
by legislatures to make policy or even appropriation decisions seems quite sparse. The
lack of such use, while perhaps acceptable to the line agencies, also means that the
legislature is not motivating the agencies to strengthen their performance measurement
and performance management processes.
At some point, we expect that legislatures will become more interested in
performance information, especially information which represents important outcomes
for their citizens. Legislatures are likely to be interested, when good data on these
become available to them, in such data as that on educational achievement, on
indicators of health, on crime statistics, on measurements of air and water quality, on
transportation safety indicators.
z That staff adopt the values, beliefs, and behavior that enable the government
to achieve its goals.
z That performance improvement becomes a way of life.
z That the various parts of the government begin to use the performance
information to help them operate their agencies and programs (for example,
by using regular program reviews and recognition awards to motivate
employees and underpin the performance culture).
Performance information can be used not only to identify problem areas, but also to
provide appropriate commendations or rewards to staff for high performance in the
face of adverse external factors. Problem areas can also be viewed as a signal for a need
for greater training and/or technical assistance. This, rather than the punitive element
of performance information, needs to be stressed to make managers less wary about
collecting performance information.
The North Carolina Womens and Childrens Health Division reports on performance to all
100 county health directors. Outcomes are compared, and used to identify those that need
most technical assistance (provided through regional consultants). Indicators include
adolescent pregnancy rate and percent women with short birth interval.
National governments, of course, differ in many ways. They can have different
cultures, different levels of resources, different degrees to which managers have
authority to take various actions, different degrees to which staffs have had training or
other background in analytical processes, different levels of IT capacity, different
histories as to the collection of performance data, different degrees of red tape that
reduces managers ability to implement performance measurement and use the
performance information to make changes, and so on. In addition, agencies within a
national government can also differ considerably in all these elements.
The features of performance management described throughout this report apply
in general to all governments and agencies (and programs). However, the degree to
which these elements can be accomplished, and when, can differ considerably. For
example, some countries, some programs, will need considerably more time before
they can obtain important outcome data. In such instance, these programs will need, at
least initially, to use less sophisticated data collection procedures, with less detailed
coverage, and less frequent data collection than are preferable. Manual data processing
procedures may need to be used until adequate computer technology and the training
to use it are obtained.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 211
In some countries, or some agencies, managers may have little flexibility to use the
data to change service procedures or even suggest such changes. This can significantly
reduce the value of the information collected.
Some agencies in some countries already are collecting data of reasonable quality
useful for performance reporting. For example, agencies may be collecting data on
infant mortality, unemployment, incidence of various diseases, school dropouts, school
attendance rates, etc. (Even if such data are being collected, countries may not be using
this information for management purposes. Also, data collected are usually not broken
out by age, gender, location, income, education, etc. information likely to be
especially useful for identifying needed improvements.)
To the extent that outcome data are being collected on a regular basis, countries
can use this as a model for initiating performance management in the collecting agency
and other agencies. A national government might start its performance management
effort by identifying programs that already collect data that can be readily adapted to
performance information. Similarly, some programs, some agencies, might have
expertise in particular data collection procedures. For example, some agencies, and
programs, might be undertaking at least periodic surveys of citizens. The persons
knowledgeable about the procedures might be able to help other agencies, and
programs, use surveys, say of their own customers, to obtain outcome information.
(For example, if the National Statistics Offices already undertakes periodic national
surveys of the population, the staff of these offices might be able to provide training or
technical assistance to other agencies, or might be able to undertake the survey work
for the other agency.)
Other public sector strengths and skills that can be taken into consideration while
designing a performance management system are:
and more difficult, than those in the pilot. Thus, they will argue that the pilot was not
helpful to them, even if the pilot has been successful.
The Government of Thailand in the mid-1990s experimented with plots in three of
its agencies, but without a wider level of support the initiative waned by the time the
plots were completed, even though the pilots appeared to be successful.
The United States in 1993 passed performance measurement/performance
budgeting/performance management legislation that was also agreeable to the
executive branch with reporting by all agencies to begin in fiscal year 1999. A three-
year pilot effort was called for by the legislation, involving a small number of federal
programs. Most other agencies and programs stood by and waited, probably expecting
the new requirements to go away. The pilot effort appears to have delayed many
agencies from taking the effort seriously until it became clear that the government was
serious about the requirement. The pilot did have the advantage of providing time for
getting across the basic concepts. However, the initial reports from most federal
agencies were quite weak, probably because the non-pilot agencies and programs
delayed full-scale effort.
Clearly, different agencies, and different programs within agencies, will have
different levels of implementation success. It is very hard to tell in advance which
agencies and which programs will readily take to performance management and
develop more sound processes. Starting with wide coverage will at least get each
agency moving towards performance management even though, as expected, wide
differences in implementation quality occur.
One possibility that might be considered is while starting with a government-
wide implementation to select 3 or 4 agencies with whom to work intensively so as
to accelerate the process. This can have several beneficial results: more quickly yield
results in order to show other agencies the promise of the system; reveal problems with
the system that could then more swiftly be fixed; serve as a source for examples and
trainers for the rest of the government.
Some governmental activities can be labeled projects. Projects have a fixed time
period and, usually, a somewhat narrow focus (such as individual road or wastewater
treatment construction projects). Many donor-funded activities fall into this category.
But much of what government and its agencies do are continuing activities, such as
maintaining roads, educating children, providing health care, regularly inspecting
business and natural resources for environmental problems, etc.
Performance management is an important approach for both programs and
projects.
1. Can the results of the evaluation influence decisions about the program?
- Programs for which a decision regarding continuation, modification, or termination needs
to be made are obvious candidates.
- Poor candidates are those about which decision makers have strong preconceptions of
program value or for which there is considerable support by influential interest groups if
these circumstances make it very unlikely that the program would be altered. In some
cases, however, the program may be of such great importance to a community that
government officials may proceed with the evaluation and be prepared to seek changes
despite political risks.
- Can the evaluation be completed in time to be helpful to decision makers? Evaluations
completed after public officials become committed to a decision are useless.
z The need to obtain and report performance data in sufficient detail to enable
managers to identify and compare performance achieved for the various key
client groups the program serves, such as client demographic characteristics
(such as for various age, gender, income, and ethnicity groups).
z The need to obtain and report performance data in sufficient detail to enable
managers to identify and compare performance achieved for key service
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 217
The training, such as that described above, preferably will encompass all levels of
management and supervision. Professionals who are involved in some way in program
and policy issues also are likely to need at least some training in performance
measurement and its use. Provision also needs to be made, not only for initial training
in the initial years of the introduction of the performance management process, but also
for training for new managers and new professional staff, whether they come from
inside or outside the government.
Such wide coverage, while highly desirable, will likely put a strain on the
resources of a government and its ministries. Of course, not all the training needs to be
done at once but rather over a period of years. Much training will come internally,
through the on-the-job training of staff by persons who have had obtained some
previous experience and knowledge in performance measurement and performance
management issues. Some agencies in many countries will have staff that have
experience in performance data collection, analysis, and reporting, such as staff in
health education, and transportation agencies. These persons and their experience
might be drawn upon for training and technical assistance.
One strategy, that has been used, is to use persons that have completed the
training to help train others. Those persons might come from outside the agency or
218 Part II. Performance Management
even outside the ministry. In the long run, providing adequate training is the
responsibility of the agency itself. An agency can choose to use outside consultants or
inside the government personnel, or some combination. As far as the cost of such
training (and technical assistance), a good argument can be made that such training is
just a basic part of management, and the costs should be borne by the agency itself.
means that agencies are asked, as part of the formal budget process, to provide out-
year estimates of out-year outcomes for those programs for which significant outcomes
are expected to occur in later years. The authors of this report have seldom seen this
done, at least not in a systematic way.
There is a timing issues that are should consider. Full scale performance budgeting
cannot be done until agencies have a performance measurement process that provides
performance data. However, governments just beginning to develop performance
measurement systems can at least qualitatively address the question of what they are
getting for the money. Programs and agencies preparing budgets but lacking
performance data need to consider at least qualitatively the outcomes achievable from
requested amounts. Similarly, those examining budget requests will need to seek
qualitative information from requestors as to what outcomes they expect even if no data
are available. This at least will begin to encourage agencies and their programs to begin
thinking about, and giving consideration to, outcomes.
In the initial year, before any historical performance data are available, so that the
agency has had little experience with the data, relating budget amounts to the
performance indicators and target setting are not likely to be meaningful. The initially
available past data might be reported, but any targets set for those performance
indicators for the budget period probably should be considered to be questionable.
After experience is gained with the data, the performance indicator targets estimated
for the budget period, based on the budget amounts requested, will have a better basis.
Performance budgeting fully occurs when budget amounts are linked to outputs
and outcomes. This may mean simply displaying the amount of output or outcomes
expected for each budget program line. This is currently what is most often initially
done by governments that are introducing some form of performance budgeting.
However, real performance budgeting does not occur until agencies and their program
use the performance information to help make and justify their budget choices.
A special problem arises for performance budgeting for governments that only use
some form of line item budgeting. To be meaningful, linking performance to the
budget requires that the government have program/service categories to which
performance information can be related. Thus, this is a prerequisite for performance
budgeting.
A word of caution is in order at this point. Governments and other stakeholders
need to recognize that linking future outcomes to budget amounts will probably
seldom, if ever, be precise. Too many outside factors can affect outcomes to enable
agencies and their programs to have precise formulas that link funds to outcomes.
Here we discuss issues involved with program and policy planning that contains a
major focus on results (and not only fiscal planning) beyond the budget year. These
plans represent an opportunity for a government, agency, and/or program to review
thoroughly what it is doing, how it went about it, and to identify what it should do in
the future, including possible major changes. To do this properly can take considerable
time and effort, including: making projections as to the nature and amount of the
future demand for the governments service; predicting the environment in which the
service will find itself; and analyzing various options as to what the government/
agency/program should do.
A first issue is whether strategic plans need to precede the development of a
performance measurement system. Performance monitoring does not appear to require
a strategic plan. Agency and program mission statements and general statements of the
220 Part II. Performance Management
z Examination of the future environment within which the agency and its programs operate
(such as demographic, economic, and social factors and trends)
z Identification of the latest available baseline values for each outcome indicator
z Examination of alternatives and practical options for achieving outcomes, including the
current service delivery approach
z Analysis of each options likely cost, feasibility, and effect on the outcomes, including
estimates of the out-year values for each outcome indicator included in the plan
z A process for obtaining input from the legislature, agency customers, agency employees,
and interest groups
Typically, most such long-range, strategic, plans have neglected many of the
elements listed in Table 13-6. They often provide little indication that the planners have
examined thoroughly future environmental characteristics (such as likely population
and technology changes). Seldom do they appear to have examined in a systematic way
alternative service delivery approaches to what they are currently doing. (Rather, the
plans merely present what agencies have been doing in the past and extend the current
process into the future.)
At which level or levels should long-range plans be prepared? Should each
Ministry, each agency, each program, have its own long-range plan? And should the
government as a whole have a go-wide strategic plan? Probably each ministry and each
agency within ministries should have its own plans. Probably major agency programs
should each have their own plans. Conceptually, a government-wide strategic plan is
also an excellent idea. A problem is that such plans can become quite political and be
revised every time there is a change in presidents and prime ministers. These plans,
thus, can become wish lists, and get-elected statements than thoughtful reviews of
what the government is about and what it should be aiming for in the future.
A key question is what are the purposes of long-range plans? Are they worth the
time and effort? One purpose often claimed for plans is that they provide a vision for
the future. As noted earlier, the planning process provides an opportunity for a
government, ministry, agency, or major program to examine from a fresh perspective
what it is supposed to be doing and how to do it. Such a plan, if it contains outcome
targets for the future, also provides a basis for assessing the governments progress
over time in achieving those objectives. And the plan should provide key input into
decision that need to be made in the next budget period.
222 Part II. Performance Management
Once performance data become available on a regular basis and become used for
high stakes purposes, public officials and key outsiders will become very concerned
about the quality and accuracy of the performance data. Government organizations
need to plan early how to maintain reasonable control and thus confidence in the data.
Inevitably, the primary responsibility for performance data quality will be that of
the organizations responsible for collecting the data and as a practical matter, this
responsibility will usually need to reside with the ministries and their agencies. Even in
those situations when an independent, outside organization is conducting an in-depth
program evaluation, the evaluation will likely require some data obtained by the
agency itself rather than new data obtained by the evaluating organization.
Some outside quality checks will need to be established, with outside-the-agency
review of at least a sample of performance indicators and performance data. The
sources might include periodic reviews by:
The State Auditors Office of the State of Texas in the United States is required by
state legislation to review annually a sample of performance indicators in each major
agency to assess the quality of the data collection procedure for the performance
indicators. It has established a regular process for these reviews. The United States
federal government has a somewhat looser approach. Agency inspector generals
offices may undertake such reviews, but these are not formally required, nor does the
U.S. General Accounting Office undertake such reviews as an on-going activity. The
federal budget examiners who try to become familiar with the programs whose
budgets they review conceptually are in a position to make some appraisals of the
quality of the data that are provided to them. However, again this is not an officially-
required activity.
Performance data quality control appears throughout the world to be an
underdeveloped area. This is partly because the collection, reporting, and use of
performance data, particularly data on program outcomes, is still a new activity form
most governments and most agencies. A major problem is that agencies will be
generating large amounts of performance data, making it infeasible to review more
than a small portion of the data each year. A key ingredient for maintaining data
quality may be data transparency. When agencies report and disseminated
performance data widely, such as to the public, this is likely to place pressure on the
reporting agencies to provide data that can pass open review.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 223
lateral funding organizations are also a source of funding for the start-up costs and
initial training associated with developing and implementing performance
management. Subsequent costs for the training of staff and on-going implementation
can be considered the responsibility of individual ministries and their agencies and be
funded from their own resources as has been done by all the governments that we
have examined.
Chapter 13. Establishing a Performance Management Strategy: Governing for Results 225
References
Gustafsson, Allan, Performance Management and Budgeting: a Case Study of Sweden, World
Bank Working Paper, undated.
Hatry, P. Harry, Performance Measurement: Getting Results, 1999. Washington, D.C.: The Urban
Institute.
Hatry, P. Harry, Richard E. Winnie, and Donald M. Fisk., Practical Program Evaluation for State
and Local Governments, Second Edition, Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute, 1981.
Kim, Dong Yeon, Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea,
Washington, D.C.: The World Bank Working Paper, 2003.
Kim, Jay-Hyung, Performance Evaluation and Management System in Korea, prepared for a
conference on Performance Evaluation System and Guidelines with Application to Large-scale
Construction, R&D and Job Training Investments, jointly held by the World Bank and Korean
Development Institute, July 24-25, 2003.
Liner, Blaine, Harry P. Hatry, Elisa Vinson, Ryan Allen, Pat Dusenbury, Scott Bryant, Ron Snell,
and NCSL, Making Results-Based State Government Work, Washington, D.C.: The Urban
Institute, 2001.
Nayyar-Stone, Ritu, Katharine Mark, Jacob Cowen, and Harry P. Hatry, Developing a
Performance Management System for Local Governments: An Operational Guideline,
prepared for UN-HABITAT and the World Bank, June 2002.
CHAPTER 14
Results Based Budgeting in Australia
by
Richard Murray, Australia
1. Outline
z Overview of the fiscal framework
z Guides rather than mandates the conduct of fiscal policy. Requires the
Government to:
Projections
Estimates
Outcomes
15 15
10 10
5 5
0 0
-5 -5
1982-83 1986-87 1990-91 1994-95 1998-99 2002-03 2006-07
Chapter 14. Results Based Budgeting in Australia 229
70 70
60 60
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
Germany Total OECD European Japan United States Australia
Union
- compares assets and liabilities (rather than just inflows and outflows of cash)
z The focus is on change and consequences: what effect can government have on the
community, economy and/or national interest?
The actual deliverables goods and services agencies produce to generate the desired
outcomes specified by government.
z They are identified separately from outputs because they involve different
accountability requirements.
Outputs and
Outputs and Administered
Administered
Items for Outcome E
Items for
Outcome B
Chapter 14. Results Based Budgeting in Australia 231
3.2.1. Outcomes
Outcomes should:
Outcomes should:
Be succinct
Outcome 3: Australia has a
strong science, research and
innovation capacity and is
engaged internationally on
science, education and training to
advance our social development
and economic growth.
Fair
Chapter 14. Results Based Budgeting in Australia 233
Outcomes should:
Outcome 1: Individuals achieve
high quality foundation skills
and learning outcomes from
schools and other providers.
Very Good
Outcomes should:
Outcome 1: Individuals achieve
high quality foundation skills and
learning outcomes from schools
and other providers.
Very Good
Be stated in a way that
allows the target group to be
Outcome 3: Australia has a
identified
strong science, research and
innovation capacity and is
engaged internationally on
science, education and training to
advance our social development
and economic growth.
Fair
234 Part II. Performance Management
Outcomes should:
Outcomes should:
Be free of value-laden,
generalized or aspirational Outcome 3: Australia has a
strong science, research and
innovation capacity and is
engaged internationally on
science, education and training to
advance our social development
and economic growth.
Good / Fair
Chapter 14. Results Based Budgeting in Australia 235
Outcomes should:
Be amenable to
extension across
agency boundaries
Outcome 3: Australia has a strong
science, research and innovation
capacity and is engaged
internationally on science, education
and training to advance our social
development and economic growth.
Good
Outcomes should:
Be able to be related to
Budget documentation
Outcome 3: Australia has a strong
science, research and innovation
capacity and is engaged
internationally on science, education
and training to advance our social
development and economic growth.
Fair
236 Part II. Performance Management
3.2.2. Outputs
- if this cannot be done the agency should cease to produce the output or
identify an additional outcome that the agency should achieve.
Output Groups
Output 1.1: Funding Output 2.1: Funding for Output 3.1: Research
for schools vocational education and infrastructure
Output 1.2: Assistance training Output 3.2:
to individuals Output 2.2: New Assistance for science
including those with apprenticeships collaboration and
special needs Output 2.3: Assistance for innovation
Output 1.3: Assistance skills and career Output 3.3: Support
for quality teaching development for the Australian
and learning Output 2.4: Funding for education and
Output 1.4: Assistance higher education training export
for transition through Output 2.5: Assistance to industry and
and from school post school student international
including those with special relationships
needs
Defines what is being provided, price and quantity are measurable and Outputs
relate well to Outcomes.
Chapter 14. Results Based Budgeting in Australia 237
Figure 14-4. Mean scores of Australian students in reading, mathematical and scientific
literacy compared with OECD average for 2000 (set to 500)
R e a d in g lite ra c y 528
525 526 527 528 529 530 531 532 533 534
Bachelor VET
60.3
2002 82.7
60.2
2001 85.8
60.8
2000 84.2
59.9
1999 81.6
0.0 10.0 20.0 30.0 40.0 50.0 60.0 70.0 80.0 90.0 100.0
per cent
238 Part II. Performance Management
2001/02 1,763
2000/01 1,418
1999/00 1,295
1998/99 1,419
z Many outcomes are too broad. For example The Defense of Australia
- In this case the Government has moved to define 7 sub outcomes for reporting
purposes
z A devolved management model and relative financial autonomy has led to a lack
of central knowledge on financial information
z The Government has acted to provide the Department of Finance with additional
resources and mandated program and cash reporting
by
Allan Gustafsson, Mapsec
1. Country Context
Sweden is a constitutional monarchy and the King is the formal Head of State. The
Constitution is based on the principles of popular sovereignty, representative
democracy, and parliamentarism. Sweden has a unicameral parliament, the Riksdag,
with 349 seats. All elections are by proportional representation. A party must gain at
least 4 percent of the national vote to qualify for representation. There are presently
seven parties represented in the Riksdag.
Swedish politics has, since the 1930s, been dominated by the Social Democratic
Party. The party has since then, except for two short periods, been in power as the
dominant party in a formal coalition, or as a minority government with the explicit
backing of one or more minor parties in the Riksdag. Presently the Social Democratic
Party is backed by the Greens and the Leftist Party but their collaboration is limited to
economic matters.
The ideological pillars of the Social Democrats can be said to be three: private
production, public redistribution, and public provision of welfare services. The
economic policy of the Social Democrats has generally been pragmatic, but the 1960s
and 1970s saw a rapid growth in the size of the share of national income that passed
through the government. Most of that growth was in the directly redistributive part of
government spending, i.e. in entitlement programs. Another basic tenet of the
Swedish model has been and continues to be that social benefits shall be general in
nature. That is they shall not focus uniquely on the most disadvantaged of society but
rather every tax payer should feel that he gets something in return for his tax
contribution. The trend towards an ever-growing public sector stopped abruptly in the
early 1990s when a fiscal crisis, in the form of a ballooning deficit, forced the
Government to dramatically curtail spending. As a result the share of General
Government in GNP was rapidly brought down from 70 percent during the height of
the crises to approximately 55 percent where it has now leveled off.
In the context of the topic of this paper it is noteworthy that the dominant share of
government spending more than 50 percent refers to individually consumed social
services. A little less than one third can be classified as individually consumed private-
type services while only one tenth refer to classic collective goods.107 In other words:
107 A service is classified as individual if it is associated with positive marginal costs for each person
consuming it. It is conventionally classified as being of a social type because they are traditionally provided by
the public sector and/or the public sector determines its price and availability for example health care,
education, child care, care for the elderly, culture, etc. The category individually consumed private-type
services refer, for example, to support to agriculture and housing allowances. Collective goods refer to defense,
central administration, etc.
242 Part II. Performance Management
there is an individual, identifiable consumer at the receiving end of the vast majority of
the activities of the Swedish public sector!
z the Riksdag (Parliament) and the Government would focus less on the details
but rather provide general guidance and define the objectives of government
activities;
z decision that customarily had been taken outside the budget process, but
which had an impact on the budget, should be handled within the budget
process;
z a longer-term perspective was introduced in the budget process;
z productivity and efficiency would be enhanced allowing the provision of
more relevant services;
z agencies were given greater responsibility for the use of the appropriations
provided for the running of the agencies and for the organization of its
activities; and
z the analysis and the reporting on results achieved would be improved.
One important and concrete change of the budget process was the introduction of
three-year cycles for the presentation of the agencies budget proposals. Every third
year, the agency was to produce a more ambitious and soul-searching document in
which it was expected to critically review what it was doing and how it went about it.
The proposals for year 2 and 3 needed not go to the same depth but were rather to
serve as bridges between the more thorough reviews. The cycles of the agencies were
staggered so as not to overburden the Government Offices. On the basis of the more
thorough review carried out every three years, the agency would receive a firm three-
year budget frame.
The system was maintained for a few years but was dropped in the middle of the
nineties when the urgency to reduce spending left no room for elaborate and
thoughtful prioritization processes. The whole idea that the agencies would voluntarily
question their own activities at least beyond the margin was probably unrealistic
anyway and it is doubtful that the system would have survived even in calmer seas.
A reform ushered in by the 1988 bill a reform that has survived is the
requirement that each agency shall produce a yearly report on results. After the
introduction of accrual accounting in 1992, the report on results is normally combined
with a statement of accounts.
The 1988 bill furthermore announced a number of changes in the legal framework
for the management of the agencies as regarded:
coverage, basis, and structure of the budget, the definition of appropriations, the
control and management of investments in infrastructure and in the defense area, and
on the structure and flow of performance information. A first Ministry of Finance
White Paper was prepared in 2001. The work of the project has now been integrated
into the normal development work of the Budget Department of the Ministry of
Finance and continues. Some of the original ideas of the project are shelved for the
moment, while others are pursued. A new white paper resulting from the continued
work is expected during the first part of 2004. The most recent reform initiatives are
discussed below in the section on outstanding issues.
The driving force of the reforms has been the conviction that efficiency is a
function of authority and accountability. If institutions and individuals are given
authority to decide on how best execute a task they will behave responsibly and
efficiently, provided they are held accountable for the result.
The listing of the elements of the Swedish performance management model is thus
divided into elements that give authority to institutions and individuals, and those that
are put in place to achieve accountability.
3.2. Authority
108 There is a long-standing debate whether or not the county councils should be eliminated and its
responsibilities assumed by the municipalities singly or, where needed, in collaboration. Such a reform may
come in the next few years.
246 Part II. Performance Management
only 2 percent (excluding the Foreign Office) in the Government Offices, i.e. the
equivalent of traditional ministries. In the UK the proportion is 75 to 25 percent.
The responsibilities of an agency are specified in an Agency Ordinance. A
minister is not allowed to intervene directly in the operations of an agency or in any
decision within its area of authority made by it. To a degree, but in a subtle way
and behind the scenes, the independence of agencies has, however, become
compromised by an increasing politicization of the appointment of the director
generals of the agencies.
Block appropriations
In order to achieve the objectives set forth in the letter of appropriation an agency
is given one or several block appropriations, i.e. a total expenditure ceiling for the
area(s) that are its responsibility. If the agency is responsible for only one global task,
like for example the Prosecution Services, it receives only one single appropriation.
This allocation it is free to allocate to whatever inputs it deems necessary to carry out
its work. Agencies with a range of responsibilities may receive a number of
appropriations. The County Administrations, an extreme case, may finance their
operations form over twenty different appropriations. Agencies, like the National
Insurance Board which handle a number of entitlement programs, receive one
appropriation for their administrative expenditure and are responsible for execution of
the different entitlement appropriations.
Personnel
The agencies are free to hire whomever and however they desire and to set the
salary at the necessary competitive level. The latter right is, however, to some extent
tempered by the formal process of wage negotiations between the unions concerned
and the representative of the Government, the Swedish Agency for Government
Employers. There is of course also the restriction set by total available resources. An
agency will not, in principle, be compensated for cost increases resulting from wages
increases beyond index. Should it, however, choose to reallocate resources from other
types of expenses it is free to do so.
Facilities
Agencies rent their premises and pay market price even if and when the property
is owned by the Government. Government commercial type property is managed by a
public company which is expected to behave like a normal commercial operator.
Chapter 15. Performance Management and Budgeting: a Case Study of Sweden 247
To balance the large degree of freedom that the agencies have to shape their
operations and decide on the input mix, a number of instruments and processes have
evolved to foster responsible behavior and to uphold accountability. It is worth
pointing out that responsible behavior and accountability in Sweden does not depend
on one single mechanism but is rather the (hoped for) outcome of a number of factors
that together are expected to create responsible behavior.109 In the end, every public
institution is accountable to the public that it is to serve. That accountability can be
ensured by direct or indirect mechanisms. Here they are grouped into mechanisms that
involve the Government, mechanisms that involve the public directly or indirectly, and
mechanisms that involve the elected bodies directly.
Agency ordinance
The Agency Ordinance (Verksfrordningen) establishes the general rights and
responsibilities of agencies.
Letters of appropriation
Yearly letters of appropriation are prepared for single appropriation and/or for a
set of appropriations under the jurisdiction of a specific agency. The letters of
appropriation vary a bit in character depending on the nature of the appropriation, but
when it concerns the operations of an agency they contain sections on:
z objectives;
z results indicators;
z special reporting requirements;
z assignments (tasks) for the coming year; and
z financing of the activities of the agency.
The latter includes:
109 In the discussion of the reforms in New Zealand an important distinction has been made between
responsibility and accountability, the former being the broader concept relating to the spirit and not merely the
letter of the objectives set for an agency.
248 Part II. Performance Management
The letters of appropriation establish or confirm the objectives that are set out for
the activities that the agencies carry out and spell out the results indicators that the
agencies are supposed to report on. The objectives defined for the activities have
tended to be rather vague in nature and the results indicators more or less ad hoc. What
has been missing in terms of preciseness has often been made up for by increasing the
number. The problems with objectives and results indicators are discussed further on.
In addition to the more or less formalized results indicators, the agencies may be
requested in the letters of appropriation to report on specific issues that are of interest
to the Government.
External audits
Agency financial accounts are audited every year by external auditors.
Performance audits are carried at the initiative of the National Audit Office when
deemed important by the latter.110
110 The National Audit Office was moved in 2003 from being under Ministry of Finance to being under
Parliament. Its modus operandi have, however, remained largely the same with the one exception that they are
now empowered to audit the Government including the consolidated accounts.
Chapter 15. Performance Management and Budgeting: a Case Study of Sweden 249
Management Authority. The agencies have been rated in a number of areas and then
ranked. The top-ranking agency receives a prestigious award.
Consumer choice
As pointed out above, much of the services produced by the public sector have an
identifiable consumer-citizen at the receiving end. Perhaps the most efficient way of
enforcing accountability in these circumstances is to give the consumer a choice as to
from whom he chooses to receive the service.
This latter philosophy has shaped much of the development at the local
government level. At the central level this tendency has not been quite as strong but
there are areas where it applies, for example higher education. At local educational
levels freedom of choice is ensured through the voucher system. This system is
partially introduced at university level when it comes to students wishing to study
abroad. Swedish universities are instead financed on a piece basis, i.e. per student year,
differentiated by type of education.
Application processes
Some services, in particular research, are financed by grants for which the
institutions have to apply and on the use and the results of which they have to report.
The same procedures apply to EU-grants made available to individual public
institutions.
Media
Media serves as a very powerful, albeit often a bit erratic, watch-dog keeping
public institutions and officials on their toes. A very potent instrument in the hand of
the media is the very far-reaching Swedish Freedom of Information Act.
spring. Earlier it was tabled too late to have any impact on the deliberations on the
Budget Bill.
One of the core arguments for moving away from traditional input focused
management to performance management was the felt need to reassess and prioritize
government spending. There was a hope that, with the new approach and the new
tools, continuous reassessment and prioritization would become an integral part of the
normal budget process. That has not really happened. The faith put in the three-year
in-depth reviews cum budget proposals to be prepared by the agencies quickly proved
unfounded. It has happened that agencies have proposed their own elimination, but
those are rare exceptions. Normally institutional self-preservation or expansionist
ambitions tended to take over. The three-year in-depth reviews/budget proposals have
now been abandoned.
The traditional way of initiating structural changes has been and continues to be
the appointment of a committee giving it, sometimes, very clear terms-of-references
to the point of more or less prescribing its conclusions. When the Government is less
sure what it wants to do, the terms-of-reference are more open-ended. Committees may
or may not have parliamentary representation and draw more or less on external
academic and other expertise. Over 100 Swedish Government Official Reports
produced by the committees are published every year. Committees may deal with just
about any issue of public concern, and it does not necessarily have to be budget-
related.
Changes budget-related or not may also be initiated by appointing internal
working groups within the Government Offices. Their deliberations and proposals are,
when they are expected to translate into legislative proposals, normally presented in
the different ministries publication series.
Committee reports and the reports published in the publication series of the
different ministries are all formally referred to a large number of selected bodies for
consideration and comment. These bodies may be public authorities, local government
authorities, NGOs, advocacy groups or voluntary associations.
Impetus to change may also come from the semi-autonomous research institutes
that have been set up for a number of areas; for example the Swedish Institute for
Transport and Communications Analysis and the Institute for Labour Market Policy
Evaluation. An Expert Group for the Study of Public Economics, attached to the
Ministry of Finance but fiercely defending its independence, financed a large number
of critical studies on a wide range of topics.
3.5. Tools
Accrual accounting
The reforms carried out during the last thirty years have moved Swedish public
management in the direction of that of the private sector. The legal and regulatory
framework is still important, but agencies and their managers have been given greater
authority to manage their operations and their finances. In regard to the latter it is no
longer merely a question of executing the budget. Agencies are financed from a
number of sources and manage a wide range of programs and projects.
As complexity increased it became obvious that traditional budgetary accounting
was inadequate and the whole central government, without much ado, moved to
standard accruals in 1992/93.
Chapter 15. Performance Management and Budgeting: a Case Study of Sweden 251
Agencies are free to choose their own accounting system and their own chart of
accounts provided that they can report in the format of the central chart of accounts
used for the consolidated government accounts.
Central FIMS
A web-based central Financial Information Management System is now being
developed. The system, when its complete parts are up and running, will contain
budget, accounting, and results information.
4. Implementation
As already pointed out, the move towards performance management has been a
very drawn out process involving a number of successive initiatives. It is therefore
difficult to provide a simple and single answer to what has been driving it and where
the resistance has come from.
However, one can say what it has not been. It has not been a reform process driven
by politicians. There has been no Tony Blair seeing the political benefits to be drawn
from public sector reform. It does not mean that the politicians have always been on
the sideline. They have been supportive but the original initiatives have not come from
the political sphere but rather from within the administration. And politicians have
generally not, perhaps with the exception of the move to top-down budgeting, invested
much political capital in the reforms. Nor have the reforms, again with the exception of
the move to top-down budgeting, been the result of a crisis. The Swedish reform
process is thus very different from that of New Zealands.
When attempts at writing the history of the reforms are being made the
definitive one is still to be written it is customary to refer to the different committee
reports and to other initiatives like VESTA. International influences like program
budgeting in the US in the sixties and new public management in general and the
reforms in New Zealand in particular are also highlighted. Surprisingly little
influence is deemed to have come from developments in local Swedish local
governments despite their geographic and cultural proximity.111
The conceptual champions of change and external influence are important. But the
question is if it is not the thirst for authority by the institutions that actually do the
job and their acutely felt management needs that have been the most important force
111 For some reason, central governments seem to turn to each other for inspiration rather than to their
brethren in lower levels of government. Perhaps it is precisely because of this institutional pecking order.
252 Part II. Performance Management
motrice. It is worth noting that local governments have been many years ahead of
central government in their reforms and it probably has to do with the fact that they
are primarily service providers and as such in close contact with their clients.
At the central government level, the reforms have also started from below. The
move to accruals, for example, was driven by agencies most acutely suffering from the
inadequacies of traditional public sector accounting. Agencies within the central
government have a long history of constitutionally protected independence and they
enjoy having the authority. Perhaps as a reaction to this, the more recent reforms in this
field have actually been presented as a way of bringing the politician back in the
drivers seat rather than as a means to letting the managers manage. Agencies do not
need to be empowered; politicians do.
The one vociferous opposition to the notion of performance management has also
come from a group of more or less leftist-leaning academics who see performance
management as a technocratic exercise, depriving the politicians of their right to
govern. The fact that some of the management techniques and tools come from the
private sector and from abroad is also seen as suspicious and has made some
politicians wonder whether it is all a Trojan horse. The enthusiasm expressed by some
of the opposition parties has not helped allay the fears of Social Democrat
parliamentarians either. Given their rather lukewarm interest it is actually surprising
how far the reforms have got.
On the other hand no one, particularly not the academics who staunchly defend
that it is not their role, has been able to present an alternative to performance
management. It is like with post-soviet Russia, people gripe about it but very few
would want to return to the old ways.
Thus, while there has not been any strong political leadership there has not been
any active resistance either. The biggest brake on reform has rather been inertia
political and bureaucratic. Reforms have thus had to be introduced one step at a time.
The boon: easier acceptance. The drawback: a lack of consistency. When accrual
accounting was introduced, for example, its architects initially also wanted to introduce
accrual budgeting but decided against it because they feared that it would be too big a
bite for the Government Offices.
Another reason for why the reforms have tended to be piecemeal and gradual is
that the agents and managers of change have been outside the Government Offices at
least during most of the 1990s. Of particular importance during that period were the
National Audit Office and eventually the National Financial Management Authority
(ESV). The Swedish Agency for Public Management also played a role. Being at arms
length from the Government Offices and with a direct mandate to foster the
development of financial management at agency level, they were very well placed to
initiate and implement reforms that were largely limited to the agency sphere. Their
authority to drive reform processes that had a direct impact on the work of the
Government Offices was, however, much more limited; vide accrual budgeting. The
weakest link in the performance management chain has thus become the Government
Office which in turn has left the Riksdag in limbo. Despite the latters oft-expressed
desire to receive and factor in performance information in its decisions, it has been
given little chance to do so because of the Government Offices failure to deliver it in an
intelligible format.
In the Government Office the institutional responsibility for public management
reforms has shifted around. During the 1980s the Ministry for Public Administration
(now defunct) was the driving force. A remnant part of that ministry, responsible for
public reform in general, has had an itinerant life. For a while it was located in the
Ministry of Finance; then it was moved to Ministry of Justice. At the end of the 1990s,
Chapter 15. Performance Management and Budgeting: a Case Study of Sweden 253
the VESTA project based in the Budget Department took the lead and, in close
collaboration with ESV, drove the process for a while but not without opposition.
The ambition of VESTAs was to extend the performance management chain all the
way to the Riksdag and to tie up a number of loose ends left by the piecemeal reform
process. Some of the proposed reforms are moving ahead true to the piecemeal
tradition while others are deferred, mostly for fear112 of loosing control of cash.
Changes in the management framework have always been backed up by training.
ESV offers courses directed at the agencies and the Government Offices have internal
training units responsible for offering the needed training. When accrual accounting
was introduced, agencies sometimes had to recruit new blood from the private sector
but that demand was easily met.
5. Incentives
The attractiveness of performance management to agencies is the greater authority
accorded them. No special, direct financial incentives have been linked to the reforms
as such, but the greater freedom to set wage levels has had the effect of
narrowing/eliminating the wage gap between the public and the private sector.
The incentives to the staff of the Government Offices are less clear-cut. One
possible benefit could be work satisfaction. Rather than simply applying norms and
rules defined by others, all officials need to get involved in the substance which is more
intellectually stimulating. In the short term, a common, very human and difficult-to-
avoid reaction to any change one certainly seen in during the long course of reforms
in Sweden is that it will increase the workload. The consequences of that type of
resistance very much has depended on the leadership exercised by the ministers and by
the other high officials of the Government Offices. When taking a clear stance, the
political leadership of the organization has been able to count on the solidarity of the
organization; when not, things can quickly get bogged down.
6. Results
Most observers would probably agree that the Swedish version of public
performance management has led to greater efficiency and to greater responsiveness to
its citizen-clients.113 To statistically prove it is, however, next to impossible for want of
any counterfactual information. The fact that the reforms have been carried out over
such a long period also makes it very difficult to attribute efficiency improvements to
particular components of the reform. Attempts at calculating cost effectiveness at a
disaggregate level have, unfortunately, been abandoned. The global estimate in the
national accounts is that productivity in the public sector is growing by, on an average,
1 percent a year.
It is less clear whether the reforms have led to greater effectiveness. It has proven
difficult to develop mechanisms for systematically reassessing what the government is
doing and for reprioritizing when society changes. The latter failure is, however, not, in
this authors opinion, the result of a failure of the basic conceptual framework. It is not
a design flaw.
It is rather a political failure; a failure to recognize that a more systematic use of
information on outputs and outcome on costs and effects, an unbiased search for
alternatives, and readiness to accept failures can be turned into good and vote-winning
politics.
7. Outstanding issues
The Swedish public sector has come a long way on its way from public
administration to public management. Nobody would, however, claim that the present
model is the final, definite one. There are a number obvious outstanding issues and
history will not stop even if and when the latter are resolved.
Performance budgeting
Most of the reforms, so far, have concerned the internal operation of agencies and the
relationship between the Government and the agencies. The relationship between parliament
and the Government in many ways is a vestige of pre-performance management days.
The Budget
The Central Government budget is still based on different principles and is
presented in a format and with a coverage which is different from that of the accounts.
A process is, however, on its way to change that. A shadow budget compatible with the
accounts will be presented in next years budget bill and eventually the old type
budget will be phased out.
Programmatic structure
A three-tier programmatic structure has been elaborated and will be used for
performance follow-up. The budget is, however, still organized in expenditure areas
and appropriations. This duality forecloses one of the fundamental objectives of
performance management; the possibility of contrasting costs and results. Besides it is
untenable for practical reasons and single structure will have to be agreed upon.
Coordination
Performance management in Sweden has been based on a successively more
definite programmatic structure with programs sometimes spanning ministries and
agencies. At the same time agencies are the executive agents and need to be given
guidance as such. The internal processes within the Government Offices have not really
fully adapted to and developed the preparation and decision-making processes that are
necessary to handle this matrix.
Agency coordination also leaves a lot to be desired.
Global priorities
The lack of analytical capacity within the Government Offices and the still limited
capacity in semi-attached think-tanks has hampered the much-emphasized need for
reassessment and reprioritization. It could, possibly, be argued that a part of the
problem is that politicians are not always too terribly keen on independent evaluations.
In specific situations that may be true, but generally speaking it is not a tenable
argument.
8. Lessons
114 ESV at the end of the nineties carried out an extensive survey to find out how the agencies looked upon
z Other types of skills and other types of managers are needed; entrepreneurs
vs. administrators.
z A programmatic approach increases the need for coordination between
ministries and agencies.
z Performance management presumes professionalism. There is no room for
cronyism and patronage. Promotion should be made on the basis of ability
rather than seniority.
z Performance management implies a change of management culture from
hierarchical to participatory.
z Mobility within the public sector and between the private and the public
sector can facilitate change.
z Strong owners are needed to balance empowered agencies.
z Good analytical capacity in the ministries is essential.
z Tools important are important: modern accounting, customer relations
measures, etc..
z Clear objectives and results indicators are important but surprisingly difficult
to arrive at and easily become a stumbling block.
z Mechanisms for reassessing and reprioritizing are essential but do not
necessarily have to be part of the normal budget process.
z Other instruments have a complementary role to play: performance audit,
independent evaluations, academic research etc..
z It is desirable that reforms are carried out within a consistent framework but it
is not always possible.
z Strong political leadership makes the implementation of the reforms much
easier but it is not impossible without it; it just takes longer.
CHAPTER 16
Performance Budgeting in the United States
by
Bill Dorotinsky, The World Bank
1. Outline
z Context
z GPRA Strategic Planning Requirements
z GPRA Performance Planning Requirements
z Key Implementing Guidance
z Lessons and Observations
z Future Directions
z Performance Budgeting in a Federal system: Collaboration
2. Context
z U.S. has a long history of trying to improve performance and assess what public
monies buy
z Attempts have varied between using the budget process and directly through
management of programs
3. GPRA
z GPRA represents another step in the historical search to grasp whether agencies
are fulfilling their mission, and whether programs are effective
Additionally, agencies must consult with Congress and entities potentially affected by
or interested in the plan, and the plan must be drafted by Federal employees.
8. Future Directions
z Program evaluation must be integrated into GPRA performance planning: deep
look at why programs are or are not working.
z Auditing of data systems
z Auditing of performance reports
z Inclusion of performance data in annual financial statements
z Integration of performance and financial systems
z Program Purpose & Design to assess whether the programs purpose and design
are clear and sound.
z Strategic Planning to assess validity of long-term and annual measures and targets
for the program
z Program Management to rate agency management of the program, including
financial oversight and program improvement efforts
z Program Results/Accountability to rate program performance on measures and
targets reviewed in the strategic planning section and through other evaluations
Part III
Fiscal Transparency
CHAPTER 17
Coverage of Public Finance in Korea
by
Dong suk Oak, Incheon University
1. Introduction
The objectives of public expenditure management are generally viewed as
maintaining aggregate fiscal discipline, allocating resources in accordance with
government priorities, and promoting the efficient delivery of services. The fiscal
targets and indicators used most commonly in maintaining aggregate fiscal discipline
are the fiscal deficit and fiscal debt, regarding which many countries have laws and
rules to restrict fiscal policy.115 The establishment of explicit fiscal targets allows the
government to state clearly its fiscal policy and enable the legislature and the public to
monitor the implementation of government policy, and ultimately make the
government politically as well as financially accountable.
Fiscal deficit is defined as the difference between fiscal revenue and fiscal
expenditure. In order to measure the fiscal deficit, the government needs, among other
things, to determine the coverage of public finance in a sufficient and appropriate
manner. Determining the coverage of public finance implies that the government
should decide which public institutions, funds, and accounts are to be included in
measuring the fiscal deficit. The coverage of public finance is also instrumental in
measuring fiscal debt. Which public institutions, funds and accounts are to be included
in measuring the public debt?
Since every country has its own historical tradition and institutional system for
public finance, countries differ greatly in their governmental and fiscal coverage. While
the statistics on the coverage must reflect the institutions and practices of each country,
a common system of definitions and classifications is helpful to users because it allows
comparisons with other countries. It is desirable for the fiscal statistics to follow the
conventions and classifications in constructing the national accounts for the entire
economy, as laid out in the United Nations A System of National Accounts 1993 (SNA).
Following the fiscal coverage of the SNA, the European Union publishes more
specified criteria, in the Manual on Government Deficit and Debt in order to obtain
reliable and comparable statistics for evaluating fiscal convergence concerning both the
fiscal deficit-to-GDP and the debt-to-GDP ratios.
In the SNA five mutually exclusive institutional sectors are identified. They are the
nonfinancial corporations sector, the financial corporations sector, the general
government sector, the nonprofit institutions serving households sector, and the
household sector. The IMFs Manual on Government Finance Statistics (GFS) harmonized
with sectorization of the SNA, defines the coverage of the statistics to be a country's
115 Fiscal targets and indicators should cover three areas: current fiscal position (e.g., fiscal deficit), fiscal
sustainability (e.g., debt-, tax-, or expenditure-to-GDP ratios), and vulnerability (e.g., analysis of the
composition of the foreign debt).
264 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
general government sector, which is defined on the basis of institutional units. The
coverage can also be extended to the public sector by including the fiscal activities of
public corporations. The public sector is defined as consisting of the general
government sector plus government-controlled market entities, known as public
corporations.
In spite of the SNA's definition of the general government sector, the coverage of
government expenditure, being the baseline of government deficit and government
debt, varies in a number of countries. Especially many developing countries, having a
relatively short history in operating the modern public management system and rare
opportunities to share the experiences of other countries, have problems in
transparency, responsibility, and efficiency because their coverage of government and
public finance is not defined comprehensively and systematically.116
In the developed countries the coverage of government expenditure is not all
consistently the same through the stages of budget preparation, parliamentary votes,
funds release, accounts and statistics. A significant share of public expenditure is
usually managed through special procedures. The objectives of the special
arrangements include: avoiding excessive negotiation during the budget preparation
process, resolving difficulties in the legislative debates and scrutiny, and providing
greater flexibility in the use of funds by the executive.
This study draws lessons for the Korean government from the comparative study
of Korea, Japan, and the UK. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses
some key factors in determining the general government sector in the SNA and EU
Manual, and summarizes several concepts on the coverage of the public finance
according to the management process of public expenditures. Section 3 explains the
Korean government's coverage of the public finance, while Sections 4 and 5 provide a
broad overview on the UK and the Japanese governments coverage of the public
finance. Section 6 concludes with policy implications for reforming public expenditure
management in Korea.
The SNA, a cornerstone for the other international manuals on statistics, divides
the economy into five sectors in addition to the rest of the world: (1) non-financial
corporations sector; (2) financial corporations sector; (3) general government sector; (4)
non-profit institutions serving households sector; and (5) households sector. The public
sector includes the general government sector plus all public non-financial and
financial corporations. The total resident economy except the public sector is the
private sector, so there should not be no gray area between the public and private
sectors.
The general government sector and the public sector are the basis for the
government finance and public finance statistics. In deciding if an entity is to be
included in the general government sector, the steps to be followed could be
summarized as three-staged. These are provided by the EU Manual, describing more
116 The two terms, public finance and government finance are generally used in the literature without
distinction. Fiscal deficit of the general government sector and the public sector, however, are defined as
government deficit and public deficit, respectively.
Chapter 17. Coverage of Public Finance in Korea 265
specifically the concepts and criteria of the SNA for the Excessive Deficit Procedure
required in the Article 104 of the Maastricht Treaty.
The first step to be taken is to ask whether the entity is an institutional unit.
Sectorization decisions in the SNA must be taken at the level of institutional units,
defined in the SNA as units having the autonomy of decision and a complete set of
accounts. Autonomy of decision means that it must be able to own goods or assets in
its own right; be entitled to make economic decisions and carry out economic activities
for which it is held directly responsible and accountable by law; and be able to incur
liabilities on its own behalf, to take on other obligations or further commitments and to
enter into contracts. In order to keep a complete set of accounts, a unit must keep
accounting records covering all its economic and financial transactions carried out
during the accounting period, as well as a balance sheet of assets and liabilities.
The second step is to ask whether the institutional unit is private or public. A
public unit is one controlled by the general government, whereas a private unit is one
not controlled by the general government. Control, defined as the ability to determine
general policy, is an essential criteria for sectorization between the public and private
sectors. The general government of a country consists of the public authorities, their
agencies and instrumentalities, which are established through political processes and
exercise a monopoly of compulsory power. The form that administration or accounting
for a entity takes whether budgetary, extra-budgetary, special account, etc.
should not affect its inclusion for the general government sector. When a public unit,
by virtue of special legislation, is recognized as an independent legal entity, it can be
considered as an institutional unit, to be classified in the general government sector,
and if it is not a public corporation.
The third step is to ask whether the public institutional unit is market or non-
market. When the principal function of the public institutional unit is to supply certain
public goods and services and fulfill certain public purposes not for commercial or
financial reasons, or, if of a commercial or financial nature, not on a major basis or not
primarily for profit, this unit is to be classified in the general government sector. In the
SNA, the distinction between market (i.e., for commercial reasons or for profit) and
non-market producers depends on whether or not prices charged are economically
significant. A price is said to be not economically significant when it has little or no
influence on how much the producer is prepared to supply and is expected to have
only a marginal influence on the quantities demanded. In practice, the public
institution whose production costs are not covered by more than 50 percent through
sales is classified as a non-market producer and general government.
The general government sector, which is determined by the three steps, normally
includes the ministries, departmental agencies, other decentralized public bodies, and
local authorities. The principal function of the general government sector is to carry out
public policy through the production of non-market services primarily for collective
consumption and the transfer of income, financed mainly by compulsory levies on
units in other sectors. The public institutions in the general government sector are
being called in different terminology in different countries, making international
comparative research difficult. Institutions other than the ministerial agencies are
sometimes named as authorities, autonomous bodies or organisms, quangos, non-
departmental public bodies, extra-governmental organizations, subsidiary
organizations, etc.
Public policy may be also carried out by public corporations outside the general
government sector, and these are sometimes called as quasi-fiscal activities. To the
extent that the quasi-fiscal activities are funded by grants from the general government
sector, those can be included in the coverage of the public finance. The total receipts
266 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
and expenditures of public corporations should not be treated equally to those of the
governmental institutions, because they collect sales proceeds only by incurring
corresponding production costs.
For the purposes of control and accountability, the general government sector is an
appropriate coverage for the public resources and finance. The general government
sector includes all the ministerial departments, departmental agencies, the public and
private law non-market bodies which are directly and indirectly controlled by the
ministers. The finances of those are ultimately the responsibility of the government, so
those are to be answerable and accountable to the legislature and managed and
controlled by the ministers. Public corporations, not included in the general
government but in the public sector, are usually private law bodies whose owners have
limited liabilities and can control them only with voting shares. However, some
considerations should be given to public corporation established by public law, since
the law provides implicit guarantee and financing for it seems to be the responsibility
of the government.
Planning
(Budget Preparation)
Reporting Approval
(Accounts and Statistics) (Parliamentary Votes)
Execution
(Funds Release)
Chapter 17. Coverage of Public Finance in Korea 267
117 Since public corporations in general do not use tax or other compulsory levies, they are not included in
be minimized. In most countries, the government has a number of funds and accounts
to administer public money irrespective of the institutional unit. Every country has a
consolidated fund or account, the main fund into which all receipts are deposited and
from which all payments are made, and some earmarked special funds. The central
bank is, in most countries, the main cashier of the government, so the consolidated
fund or account is held at the central bank. Special or earmarked funds and accounts
may be held in commercial banks, whether the funds and accounts are automatically
swept at the end of each day or not.
To minimize borrowing costs or maximize interest-bearing deposits, operating
cash balances should be kept to a minimum. Idle balances of special earmarked funds
or accounts increase the borrowing needs of the government, which must borrow to
finance the payments of some funds, even if other funds have excess cash. Whatever
the institutional arrangements, the centralization of funds and accounts is required and
should cover as many of the government funds and accounts used for payment
transactions. In this paper, funds and accounts held at the central bank will be denoted
as FA1, and funds and accounts held at commercial banks, as FA2. The coverage of
FA1 and FA2 will vary greatly according to the country.
The last stage of the expenditure management will be government accounting and
financial reporting. Government finance statistics can be distinguished from two other
data systems. The CBB or other ministerial departments will publish the government
finance statistics from the government budgets and accounts, maintained by operating
units for purposes of control and accountability. In the national accounts, data for the
government are recast in a form common to all sectors so as to measure and aggregate
their production, income, consumption, capital accumulation, and finance, and
delineate inter-sectoral transactions. Even if the office responsible for preparing the
national accounts will vary according to the country, the statistical guidelines and
concepts of the SNA should be observed. In this paper the de-facto coverage of
government finance statistics published by the CBB or other ministerial department
will be denoted as FS (Financial Statistics), and the coverage of national accounts NAS
(National Accounts Statistics).
departments and departmental agencies have no separate legal identities from the state
and their staff are comprised of civil servants. They are equivalent to NDPBs of the UK.
The resources of which the decentralized public bodies have control are not
reflected in the government accounts except government's grants to them. The
coverage of the General Account, Special Accounts and Funds do not reach all the
expenditures of the decentralized public bodies. The coverage of the General Account
and Special Accounts is approximately equal to the coverage of ministerial
departments and departmental agencies. However, the 55 Funds do not cover all the
decentralized public bodies.
Some NDPBs are managing government Funds, and some are not. In the case of
NDPBs managing Funds, their expenditures funded from the Funds can be reflected in
the government accounts. Since the expenditures of NDPBs have never been published
in Korea, it is impossible to identify the share of the resources of the decentralized
public bodies (NDPBs in the Figure 17-2) covered in the resources of Funds. All the
resources of the NDPBs' own accounts, whose amount is usually alleged as equivalent
to that of the General Account, are excluded in the coverage of government accounts.
General Account
Fund Own
Account
While the budgetary resources in the coverage of the General Account, Special
Accounts and some Funds are under the control of the CBB (the Ministry of Planning
and Budget), the resources of the NDPBs' own accounts are outside the control of the
CBB and approved just by line ministries. In other words, the budgetary resources of
the general government sector are all controlled by the government, but some are not
controlled by CBB. That means the Budget does not equal to the Budgetctr. Additionally,
some funds are not controlled by the CBB, so are not included in the Budgetctr. Those 10
Funds are related to financial intermediation activities, and are managed by the
Ministry of Finance and Economy. They are not legally included in the Votes. Their
operational plans are submitted and scrutinized by the National Assembly, but their
approval is not legally required for execution.
Most of the Funds are held at the Bank of Korea, like the General Account and
Special Accounts. While it is legally binding that the Bank of Korea holds General and
Special Accounts, Funds' account can be held either at the Bank of Korea or at
commercial banks. Some Funds and NDPBs' own accounts are all held in the
commercial bank owing to banking services.
Since the coverage of public finance has long been recognized as the General
Account, Special Accounts and Funds, both the Government Finance Statistics
published by the CBB and the National Account Statistics published by the Bank of
Korea reports only the Budgetctr. The coverage of the public finance according to the
management stages can be shown as follows.
Budgetctr
Votes
non-Votes - -
FA1 - -
FA2 - -
NAS1)
PFS
Note: 1) Only a few NDPBs are included in the National Accouns, but those can be neglected.
B. Gross Saving plus Capital Taxes (C-D) 615 20,846 27,714 33,183 30,754
C. Current Receipts 305,959 333,968 349,872 375,797 391,558
D. Current Expenditure 305,344 313,122 322,158 342,614 360,804
E. Depreciation 12,392 12,586 12,606 12,931 13,389
H. Public Sector Net Borrowing (F-A) 16,441 -2,384 -9,972 -15,416 -8,884
The Blue Book, United Kingdom National Accounts, shows the surplus on current
budget (net saving plus capital taxes), net debt, net borrowing, and the public
expenditure measures. The surplus on current budget measures achievement against
the Golden Rule, and the public sector net debt is related to the Sustainable Investment
Rule. General government net borrowing is closely related to government deficit in the
context of the Maastricht Treaty, which requires governments to keep their deficits
below 3 per cent of GDP. The public expenditure measures in the UK is denoted as
total managed expenditure (TME). TME is the present government's main measure of
118 The Golden rule is that over the economic cycle, the government will borrow only to invest and not to
fund current spending. In other words current spending must be matched by current receipts such as taxation
and social security contributions. The Sustainable Investment Rule is that net public debt as a proportion of
GDP will be held over the economic cycle at a stable and prudent level. The current government's intention is to
hold this ratio below 40 percent.
272 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
Some discrepancies in the numbers can exist between the Treasury statistics and
National Accounts. Needless to say it reflects the differences of the fiscal year and the
calendar year on the statistical period and the fact that the Treasury's accounting and
budgeting concepts are based on the UK's generally accepted accounting practice while
the National Accounts follows the international guidelines of the SNA. Those
discrepancies are very minor.
The UK's budget covers all the public institutions of the general government sector
and the capital expenditures of public corporations. Vote, approved by the Parliament,
covers the resources drawn from the Consolidated Fund, which is the main Treasury
Chapter 17. Coverage of Public Finance in Korea 273
fund. Therefore, total expenditures of NDPBs, public corporations and local authorities
are not included in the Vote, but grants to them are included in the Vote.
The main funds in the UK are the Consolidated Fund and the National Loans
Fund, but there are other important funds such as the National Insurance Fund and
Exchange Equalization Account and the Paymaster General's Accounts, National Debt
Commissioners' Accounts (the National Lottery Distribution Fund Investment Account,
the Court Funds Investment Account, the National Savings Bank Fund, Crown Estate
Account, Donations and Bequests Account, Insolvency Services Investment Account,
National Endowment for Science, Technology and the Arts, National Heritage
Memorial Fund, Northern Ireland Court Service Investment Account, Northern Ireland
National Insurance Fund Investment Account), the Northern Ireland Funds and
Accounts, and a host of smaller accounts (Customs and Excise Account, Inland
Revenue Account, etc.).
The Consolidated Fund was inaugurated in 1787, which collects every stream of
public revenue and issues the supply of funds for every service. The legislation
governing both the Consolidated Fund and the NLF ensures that government finances
are centrally accountable to Parliament. Generally speaking, all money collected by the
government must, unless Parliament specifies otherwise, be paid into one of these two
main funds. And in general no money can be paid out of the Consolidated Fund or the
National Loans Fund without the specific legal authority of Parliament, and the prior
274 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
Budget
Budgetctr
Votes
Non- Votes - -
FA1
FA2 - -
NAS
PFS
There are three types of public institutions which may be classified into the public
sector; Related Enterprises of SEs (RESs, kankeikaisha), Joint Enterprises between SEs
and private corporations (JESs, shusshikaisha), Appointed Entities (AEs, siteihouzin).
RESs are the enterprises on which SEs exercise a power in determining their general
policies. The number of RESs of which SEs' ownership is more than 50 percent is 923 in
1997, while that of RESs below 50 percent is 91. All RESs should be classified into the
general government sector or public corporations, since they are controlled by the
central government. JESs are normally used as a policy tool for channelling funds into
public-private partnership programs. The number of JESs of which the proportion of
SEs' ownership is above 20 percent is 240 in 1997. Some of them can be classified into
the public sector according to the nature of SEs' ownership and control.
AEs are nonprofit institutions which perform activities related to administrative
procedure for public policies. They may charge administrative fees or be funded by the
government. Nonprofit institutions which are established by private law are called
Public Interest Entities (PIEs, kouekihouzin). PIEs which perform executive, advisory,
tribunal, inspection and authorization role by the law, order or other administrative
actions will be regarded as AEs. Those, numbering 720 in 1997, can also be classified
into the general government sector.
The total number of RESs, JESs, AEs, which are currently classified into private
sector but controlled and mainly financed by government are approximately 2,000. If a
systematic classification would be performed observing the SNA manual, most of
RESs, JESs, AEs would be classified into the public sector. Therefore, there is no
government publication in Japan which can show the consolidated statistics of the
general governmment and the public sector.
The coverage of public finance statistics published by the Japanese government is
only the General Account and Special Accounts. The budget, which is submitted to
Parliament for its approval, includes 11 Government Related Institutions (GRIs,
seibukankeikikan) in addition to the General Account and Special Accounts. Eleven GRIs
are all SEs which principally engage in financial intermediation for the purpose of
public policy. Budget and public finance statistics do not include any other SEs than
GRIs to say nothing of RESs, JESs, AEs. Government deficit and government debt,
reported annually by the Japanese government, are not observing the international
standard of the SNA and GFS.
References
by
Junghun Cho, The World Bank119
1. Introduction
The Korean government is now preparing to introduce a medium-term
expenditure framework (MTEF) and other public expenditure reforms. These reforms
are intended to increase efficacy and transparency of the way public resource are
allocated and spent in Korea. Among the many challenges for the Korean government
to succeed with these reforms and generate anticipated benefits is to have its financial
management information system (FMIS) updated to meet the new, additional
information needed to operate MTEF.
Usually, MTEF requires significant, wide-ranging changes in the way a county
allocates public resources. As a fundamental component to a countrys decision-
making process, the FMIS must provide the necessary financial and performance
information if MTEF reform is to succeed. A successful MTEF will clearly define multi
years total spending and sectoral ceilings, delegate more budgetary discretion to line
ministries and, in return, hold them accountable for their performance. For this to
occur, the governments financial information system must supply necessary and
timely information throughout the budgetary process on macro-forecasting, sectoral
expenditure analysis, and costing and performance management of programs/projects.
The existing Korean FMIS is inadequate to meet the new challenges of MTEF due
to the fragmented networks between ministries and low level of utilization for high-
level decision-making. Also, the underlying Korean regulatory framework, including
budget classification, coverage, and chart of accounts is not suitable for MTEF
operation, and needs substantial changes as well. Finally, to minimize reform fatigue,
the Korea government should pay careful attention to sequencing and pacing of its
efforts to introduce MTEF and the updated FMIS, and carefully consider the
institutional, organizational, and cultural elements impacted by the reform.
This paper consists of five sections. Following the Introduction in Section One, Section
Two explains how successful reform of MTEF and FMIS also depends closely on other
public sector reforms, and introduces the Korean MTEF framework that is the basis for
subsequent FMIS analysis. Section Three introduces a stylized chart that illustrates the
preferred information flow between the central budget office and line ministries for MTEF
operation. Section Four evaluates the adequacy of the existing Korean FMIS to meet the
information needs identified above in Section Three. Finally, Section Five proposes an
119 This paper incorporates substantial contributions from Dong Yeon Kim, Bill Dorotinsky, Mike Stevens,
and Il-Whan An of the World Bank, and Sang Dae Choi, Ho-Joong Shin, Seok-Kyun Lee, Su-Min Park of Korean
Ministry of Planning and Budget, Kwang-Ho Kwon of the Korean Ministry of Finance and Economy, and Allan
Gusfasson, a former Director of Budget Department of Swedish Ministry of Finance.
280 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
implementation strategy to improve FMIS and MTEF that will minimize internal resistance
and avoid reform fatigue.
During the 1990s, many countries, both developed and developing, have
introduced medium-term expenditure framework (MTEF). Most OECD countries have
adopted the full plethora of features of MTEF: 73 percent have multi-year expenditure
estimates incorporated into their budgets and 67 percent have a medium-term fiscal
framework with ceilings for expenditures, deficits, and revenues over multiple years as
part of their budget. 120 MTEF is also widely spread out to many middle- and-low-
income countries including 19 African countries.121
However, specific framework of MTEF significantly differs among countries and it
reflects different purposes of MTEF and countrys unique environment. While MTEF is
meant to improve all three goals of public expenditure management122 a) maintaining
fiscal sustainability by controlling aggregate, b) linking budget allocation with national
policy priorities, c) improving efficiency of public service delivery specific
framework of each country differs according to its focus among three objectives. For
example, Sweden adopted MTEF to contain and reduce fiscal deficit; since the
introduction of MTEF, fiscal balance has improved from the deficit of 10.8 percent of
GDP in 1994 to the surplus of 4.8 percent in 2001. 123 On the other hand, the U.K.
intended to increase public investment that continued to decrease; through MTEF,
public investment has increased from 20 UK billion pound in 1997 to 31 UK billion
pound in 2003.124
Strengthening the linkage between budgetary allocation with national policy
priorities is the main purpose for the Korean government to introduce MTEF.
According to the National Resource Allocation Improvement Plan, the Korean
governments main purpose of MTEF is to change a rigid expenditure allocation
structure, meeting social demands that have changed significantly since the 1970s. It is
self-diagnosed by the MPB that current budgeting process is in effect unable to change
swiftly sectoral allocation according to changing environment.
120 World Bank/OECD Survey on Budget Practices and Procedures, 2003. Available at: http://ecde.dyndns.org.
As of December 2003, 27 (of 30 total) OECD and 17 developing countries are included in the database
121 Benin, Burkina Faso, Chad, Ethiopia, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Kenya, Lesotho, Malawi, Mali,
2.3. MTEF and other public sector reforms; performance management and
fiscal decentralization
126 For example, the Canadian Department of Finance systematically revises the private sector forecasts
downwards as a further measure of prudence. This takes the form of the government adding 50-100 basis
points (0.5-1.0 percentage points) to the average private sector economic forecasts for interest rates and then
feeding this through its entire econometric model, thus producing lower forecast economic activity. This
provides a buffer in order to maintain the governments fiscal objectives (OECD, 1999, p.9).
284 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
127 Expenditure update usually consist of a) cost estimate of existing programs/projects for year t and t+1,
using updated indicators such as price index, unemployment rates, estimated number of students by grade,
and b) new policy proposal for year t+2 and its cost estimate.
Chapter 18. Information Flow for Successful MTEF Operation and its Implication for the Korea Government 285
will be given to line ministries once sectoral ceiling is agreed, central budget offices
critical review at this stage becomes more important.
Stage III can be done using a simple set of linked spreadsheets until sophisticated
software is developed. Once national policy priority is set and the line ministries
budget update is analyzed, the central budget office begins to categorize all
expenditure in terms of priority. It will calculate all statutory spending and highest
priority spending and then move down to the next priority level spending until the
sum of expenditure reaches pre-determined total aggregate ceiling for ensuring
accountability of public spending.
For this task, codifying each expenditure account by priority, functional
/programmatic classification, 128 and netting out all internal transfers will be a
prerequisite. Especially, it will be important to clarify and simplify the flow of
expenditure among the general account, special accounts and funds within a sector. In
many countries, program expenditure usually consists of direct spending as well as
transfer to other accounts or institutions and these transfers are often counted twice by
both giving and receiving institutions. In order to make the sum of all sectoral
spending equal to total aggregate ceiling, netting out all the internal transfers within a
sector should be readily available from the FMIS.
128 According to OECD Guidelines, functional or programmatic classification is most suitable for sectoral
The central budget offices FMIS should be linked to treasury system and other
execution system. Once the National Assembly approves the draft executive budget,
the approved budget needs to be automatically registered in the treasury system. In
this integrated network, if situations such as low revenue collection, cash shortage, and
natural disasters arise so initial disbursement plan needs to change in terms of both
amount and timing of allocation the central budget office can immediately effect this
change by restricting line ministries spending authority through FMIS, which is a
necessary control mechanism in a fiscal emergency.
While effective budget execution and fiscal reporting requires many types of
information, what is needed under MTEF is not much different from the existing
system. Thus, this paper deals with only information that needs to change or add
under MTEF. For more detailed information regarding the role and working
mechanism for execution process, please refer to the Hashim and Moon (2004).
Even though MTEF allows more discretion to line ministries in operating their
budget within ceiling, the central budget office should have access to detailed accounts
of line ministries throughout a fiscal year, not just at the end of fiscal year. The fact that
the central budget office has access to what and where line ministries are spending
serves as a check-and-balance system for line ministries increased budgetary power.
However, line ministries are very likely to resist sharing information with the central
budget office. Therefore, legal mandate and political support is a critical element for
central budget offices accessibility to these information.
As maintaining fiscal sustainability is one of the objectives of MTEF, an FMIS
should cover expenditure spent not just by central ministries but also by agencies and
sub-national governments. This is particularly important, for many countries now
delegate spending decision into local government and central ministries spending is
often made through agencies and local governments. While integrating local
government information system into a central FMIS is the most desirable setting,
manual data transfer may be the initial step to feed local government spending
information into a central FMIS.
More important action than the network integration is the integration of budget
classification and chart of accounts between central and local governments. For central
budget office to effectively monitor and control sub-national level expenditure, it is
very important to ensure local governments use same classification and chart of
accounts as those of central government. Otherwise, central budget office will have
great difficulty aggregating and analyzing them.
The MPB, the central budget office, and Ministry of Finance and Economy (MoFE),
the treasury, have two separate information systems and they are not sufficiently
integrated. Currently, the MoFE is in charge of macroeconomic and treasury
management, and the MPB is in charge of budget formulation and execution. For an
effective public expenditure control, two systems need to be integrated so that the
central budget office can regularly monitor budget execution progress, cash balances,
and other important indicators and enact any changes on spending amount and
schedule, if necessary.
An information system that ministries use to submit their budget request is
different from the one that ministries use for budget execution such as allotment,
commitment, and cash rationing. Within the MPB, two separate software are used for
line ministries budget submission and budget execution. There is hardly any
justification to operate two systems for budget formulation and execution other than
that two softwares were developed separately in different period. With two separate
systems, line ministries tend to care more on formulation and less on execution and
this can potentially lead to brakeage and inconsistency when transferring budget
information from one to another.
The e-procurement system in the Public Procurement Service (PPS) needs to be
linked with the MoFE and MPB systems to reduce opportunity cost from idle cash. The
PPS has its own e-procurement system,130 a very advanced feature for effective and
transparent public procurement, but it is not sufficiently linked with neither the
MoFEs nor the MPBs network. For example, e-payment function of the PPSs e-
procurement system is not linked with the treasury system so that PPS needs to keep
large amount of cash in its account to ensure sufficient fund to pay goods and services
it purchases, which incurs significant opportunity costs from idle cash balance. If the
PPSs network is linked with the treasury, PPS doesnt need to keep cash in its account.
The Internal Tax Office and the Customs use separate and stand-alone information
systems. These systems need to be linked with the central budget offices system to
give updated cash inflow information, which is critical for effective cash management
and budget execution.
A financial information system for sub-national governments does not exist and is
now prepared by the Ministry of Home Affairs, with little consideration of integrating with
the MPBs information system. While developing an information system that overarches all
local government spending is worth pursuing in the long run, it is very important to ensure
the local FMIS is compatible, if not integrated, with the central governments FMIS to ease
the burden of aggregation and consolidation. MTEFs function of maintaining fiscal
sustainability doesnt work well if significant amount of public expenditure is spent on
sub-national level and the central budget office has a very poor handle on it.
information between ministries on line so that most of paper works get eliminated,
its analytical features are still underdeveloped and inadequate for sectoral and other
aggregate-level spending analysis even though FMIS can potentially equip the central
budget office with strong analytical tools.
Both senior officials lack of interest and understanding of FMIS and FMIS
inability to provide aggregate analysis information attribute to the low utilization of
FMIS. Like a vicious circle, lack of analytical tools in FMIS disinterests senior officials
from using FMIS and, in turn, lack of interest of senior officials makes it hard for
information specialists to gather inputs and feedback from senior officials to
strengthen FMIS analytical features.
National debt management system is not integrated with the MPBs information
system. The Korean government expects the national debt level to increase
significantly in the coming decades due to the rapidly aging population and potential
unification costs. Effective debt management requires accurate forecasting and
prudent management on macroeconomics, cash balance, and capital market
monitoring. The current MPBs debt management system is, however, far from
comprehensive and integrated, thus needs much work in this area.
4.3. Lack of capacity to record and monitor costing and performance information
The FMIS currently does not produce any performance information, output or
outcome of each program/project, on which decision-makers need to base their
judgment to make in-year and out-year budgetary adjustment. Past efforts of the
Korean government to implement performance budgeting has been mixed.132 A few
selected ministries and agencies prepared and submitted performance reports
manually only at the end of fiscal year. During the fiscal period, however, central
budget office doesnt have any control over line ministries performance. Also,
central budget office hardly makes any budgetary decision based on the performance
report. As a system is as strong as the weakest link, the lack of performance
information feedback to budgetary process can considerably weaken the MTEFs
overall trustworthiness.
Also, the FMIS doesnt have built-in functions to calculate costs of major, if not
all, projects or programs so the MPB staff has to manually compute the costs.
Accurate and timely cost information for major projects/program is an indispensable
source for performance evaluation. The Korean governments expenditure system has
an extremely complicated accounting structure and flows of fund between accounts
and special funds. Manually sorting out all the internal transfers and double
accounting is in effect prohibitive, and therefore, computerized FMIS is the
prerequisite for cost accounting in a modern government expenditure system.
137 According to IMFs GFS (p.15), the public sector consists of the general government and public
corporations. The general government includes the central, state, and local governments, and public
corporations include financial public corporations, non-financial public corporation, monetary public
corporations including the central bank, and non-monetary financial public corporations.
138 International Monetary Fund (2001).
290 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
2005
By Function
Education
Health Total = 100
Defense
.
By Policy
Wage/benefit Total < 100
IT Investment (only major
R&D programs)
By Organization
Ministry of Education
Total = 100
Ministry of Construction
---------
awareness to reformers that more often than not projects with good intention and
design fail when the implementation strategy is not well thought out.
Continued commitment and support at the highest level to improve and make better
use of FMIS is a primary success factor for successful change. This is arguably the most
important success factor for any public sector reforms. Any trial without continued
commitment and support is in effect most likely to fail. While it is likely that MTEF reform
gets sufficient supports from the highest level in the MPB141 and the Office of the President,
the importance of improving FMIS to successfully implement MTEF seems to be less
appreciated within the government. The fact that current FMIS suffers from low utilization
for policy-level budgetary decision-making reinforces this concern.
One way to increase the support for FMIS reform is to piggyback with national e-
government initiative that the President puts high priority during his term. Good example of
the effectiveness of piggybacking strategy is e-procurement reform, which was one of the
eight e-government reforms that Korean government initiated since 2001.142 As one of the
Presidents high priority policy, the e-procurement reform received lots of media attention
and political support during the reform. Today, it is generally agreed that the e-procurement
system in Korea is one of the most successful in the world.143 Likewise, the FMIS reform,
framed as a national issue, not a MPBs, has a better chance to get much needed support from
line ministries.
141
For MTEF, the current vice-minister of MPB is a champion of reform and he makes a strong drive to
introduce MTEF into the Korean Government.
142
PPS started to computerized procurement in 1998 but it became nation-wide project in 2001.
143 It receives UNs Public Service Award (PSA) in 2003, http://www.unpan.org/dpepa_psaward.asp
144 For historical evolution of two ministries, please refer to Annex 18-4.
292 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
as an intrusion of its territory and hold back any information generated by its treasury
system and other information systems.
While the Korean public sector seems to have technical capacity and infrastructure
sufficient to manage complicated information system, cultural bias against technology
specialists needs deliberate efforts and time to overcome. As evidenced by the lack of
FMIS usage among senor officials, Korean public sector seems to have imbedded bias
against technical specialist over generalist. This issue has a long historical root and is
unlikely to change over night. However, efforts should be made to bring deeper
understanding and appreciation for technical specialist. Getting rid of separate job
grading between generalist and specialist positions and rotating all staff between the
budget department and the information system department may gradually diminish
the bias.
12
MPB provides Guideline
for long-term fiscal plan
Estimate of new and on-going 1
projects spending request
Line ministries submit of long-term
no line ministrys input
spending plan and major project exp. plan
2 MPB draft total/sectoral ceiling for three
years
MPB reports to N.A. and party 4 MPB reports to N.A. and major parties
Budget formulation
MPB reviews proposals
- review of individual
6-8 sectoral/ministerial overview
projects
update of Marchs macro conditions
Ministry of Finance
(1948)
References
Allen, Richard and Daniel Tommasi, (eds.), Managing Public Expenditure, OECD, 2001.
Department for International Development (DFID), Good Practice in Developing Sustainable
Information Systems, London, UK, 1997.
Dorotinsky, Bill, and Junghun Cho, World Banks Experience With Financial Management
Information , System (FMIS) Project, the World Bank, Washington, D.C., 2003.
Hashim, Ali and Richard Allan, Information Systems for Government Fiscal Management, the
World Bank, Washington, D.C., 2002.
Hashim, Ali and Allister J. Moon, Treasury Diagnostic Toolkit, World Bank Working Paper
No.19, 2004, the World Bank.
IMF, Korea: Further Reforms in Fiscal Management, Washington, D.C., 2001.
Kim, Dong Yeon Key Issues for Introducing MTEF and Top-down Budgeting in Korea, the
World Bank, Washington DC, 2004.
Koh, Youngsun, Public Expenditure Management in Korea, Korea Development Institute, 2003.
Korean Ministry of Finance and Economy, National Financial Management Information System:
Overview, Seoul, Korea, 2003.
, Government Finance Statistics, 1999.
Korea Ministry of Planning and Budget, Current Status and Future Issues on National Budget
Information System, Seoul, Korea, 2003.
OECD, Budgeting in Canada, France, Paris, 1999.
Passman, Liz, Presentation on Public Expenditure Planning and Control, UK Treasury, November
2003.
Schick, Allan, The Changing Roles of Central Budget Office, OECD, 1997.
Swedish Ministry of Finance, Budget Statement, 2003.
UNs Public Service Award (PSA), http://www.unpan.org/dpepa_psaward.asp.
World Bank, Public Expenditure Management Handbook, Washington, DC, 1998.
World Bank/OECD, Survey on Budget Practices and Procedures, 2003. http://ecde.dyndns.org.
.
CHAPTER 19
Medium -Term Expenditure Frameworks, Performance, and
Transparency
by
Bill Dorotinsky, The World Bank
1. Introduction
The connections between these three public sector reform areas may not be
immediately obvious. Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks (MTEFs) are about
improving budget decision-making processes and incentives to lead to better
outcomes. Performance budgeting and management are about getting more output or
impact from any given level of public spending. And transparency, broadly, is about
greater provision of information on public sector operations, finance and performance.
How might these relate?
This paper briefly explores the relationship between the three areas. The paper
first provides a brief overview of each of the three topics and their salient features. The
remainder of the paper explores the relationships between a MTEF, performance, and
transparency.
3. Performance budget/management
Many different approaches to performance budgeting and management have been
tried over the years. Reforms from program budgeting, performance budgeting,
program-planning-budgeting systems (PPBS), management by objectives (MBO), and
zero-based budgeting (ZBB) fall within this genre of reforms. Program evaluation and
impact analysis are also initiatives that properly fall within this genre as well.
300 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
z Reforms that try to assess whether programs are working or can work better,
to provide incentives for resources to be used more efficiently through
linkages with resource allocation, and to reallocate resources from mess to
more effective uses (e.g. impact analysis);
z Reforms that directly trying to improve use of resources through management
oversight and action (e.g. MBO); and
z Reforms that attempt both.
Many early attempts at performance budgeting fall into the first category, focusing
on developing and publishing information on performance for government activities.
In this respect, organization of activities within ministries into programs can assist in
easing the challenge by grouping like activities with common objectives into one
program, and then developing measures of impact or at least output.
With lessons of experience, it has become clear that producing the information is in
itself not sufficient. The act of measuring performance can have a positive impact, but
more along the lines of the Hawthorne Effect, where the novelty of measurement
modifies performance of those being measured, but only for a limited period of time.
The collection and production of information does not result in a sustainable cultural
change or modification of incentives. Some reforms have attempted to address this by
developing a process of performance measure development that is done by the line
ministries and agencies themselves (e.g. U.S. prohibited use of consultants to develop
the GPRA performance measures or plans).
The more enduring issues that have emerged in performance management involve
the following questions: What is done with the performance information once
produced? Who uses the information, for what end, and how? How can decision-
makers productively use the information? How can the system be structured to
produce more enduring changes in incentives for better performance? How can the
information be made more user-friendly to policy officials?
Some selected lessons from international experience indicate both the challenge
and promise of performance management and budgeting. For example, implementing
effective performance monitoring145 requires:
From reviewing these lists, some common patterns emerge. First, groups or
stakeholders that are to be served or are expected to use the information are many and
varied. To enable full use of the information, it must be disseminated broadly. It must
be transparent.
Further, use of the information must be clear: who is using it, for what end, and
how? This applies to agencies, policy officials, finance staff, etc.
And in terms of linking with the budget process, full-costing of programs and
having a program structure and an MTEF provide a vehicle for pursuing these.
4. Transparency
The theme of transparency has many dimensions. At a broader conceptual level,
it is about having open decision-making process and easy access to information by the
public. It is an enabler of accountability and performance assessments, and a
prerequisite for sound decision-making (e.g. MTEFs).
More specifically, the IMF has developed an instrument for assessing many
dimensions of transparency, operationalizing the concept. For the IMF Fiscal ROSC,
improved transparency is a necessary basis for improving the efficiency and
effectiveness of fiscal management through:
However, transparency is a public good and merit good gainers dont pay and
losers dont support. Taking the first steps of providing the information and improving
accountability must be an exercise in leadership. Once done, market analysts and civil
society organizations can demand the information, making it very difficult to turn
back. More importantly, private sector and civil society organizations, as noted
previously, can exert pressure on government for better decisions. The broad objective
is to create a virtuous cycle, whereby better information strengthens policy and leads to
demands for continuing improvement in information and policy making.
The focus of Fiscal ROSC is on data quality improvement and improved definition
of public sector roles and scope of public finances.
The Code of Fiscal Transparency includes many principles and questions, but
some examples will bring greater clarity. For example, IMF ROSC questions 4.1.1,
2.1.2, 3.1.3, 3.1.1, 3.1.4, 3.1.3, and 3.1.5 all address the extent of a countrys medium-
term budget framework. Question 2.1.3 address off-budget activity. And, questions
2.1.1, 3.2.1, 3.3.1, and 4.1.2, address issues of accounting and data quality. As is evident,
the ROSC actually tracks the key components of an MTEF, and through it one can
monitor country progress in implementing the MTEF.
It should also be evident that data and accounting quality are essential for effective
performance management or monitoring. Bad data do not allow accountability or
performance assessment.
148 For more on the IMF Code of Fiscal Transparency and markets, see Petrie (2003).
149 See Chapter 1 in this volum.
150 IBID. Pages 2-3.
304 Part III. Fiscal Transparency
References
Mayne, John and Eduardo Zapico-Goni, Monitoring Performance in the Public Sector: Future
Directions from International Experience, Transaction Publishers; London, 1997.
OECD, Integrating Financial Management and Performance Management, July 1999a. p. 9.
OECD/PUMA, Improving Evaluation Practices: Best Practices Guidelines for Evaluation and
Background Paper, January 1999.
Petrie, Murray, Promoting Fiscal Transparency: The Complementary Roles of the IMF,
Financial Markets, and Civil Society, IMF Working Paper WP/03/199, October 2003.