Eden Reflections On OLI 2003
Eden Reflections On OLI 2003
Eden Reflections On OLI 2003
Introduction
When I was in kindergarten, my teacher taught me that the way to learn
about a new object was to ask five basic questions: Who or what, when,
where, why and how? I have always believed that the OLI (or eclectic)
paradigm was about a subset of those questions. The who or what is, of
course, the multinational enterprise (MNE). While John Dunnings writings
often start with a definition of the MNE, the focus of the eclectic paradigm
from its beginnings up to the present day has been O (why?), L (where?)
and I (how?).
For me, the OLI paradigm is best understood by reading three out of
the dozens of books that John Dunning has authored over the past 25
years: International Production and the Multinational Enterprise (1981b),
Explaining International Production (1988a) and Multinational Enterprises and
the Global Economy (1993a). Each book pulls together and synthesises
Dunnings writings from the previous period.1
In the concluding chapter to this book on the eclectic paradigm, what I
would like to do is provide an overview of the development of the OLI
paradigm as seen through my lens, and link the book chapters to its
development. My thesis is that OLI should best be seen as a way of looking
at the phenomenon of multinational enterprises and their activities. OLI
addresses three of the five kindergarten questions the why, where and
how of MNE activities. Each of these questions can be addressed at a dif-
ferent level: macro (big picture, country), meso (mid picture, industry) or
micro (firm, top management team). As examples of the why-where-how
questions I list some of the research questions that have or currently do
engage international business scholars in Table 13.1.
I argue that the OLI paradigm has been most successful at the macro and
meso levels, and less so at the micro level, but I do not see that as a
*
Acknowledgements: I would like to thank John Cantwell, Rajneesh Narula, Peter
Gray and Dan Li for their helpful comments. Any errors or omissions are my
own responsibility.
278 Lorraine Eden
Figure 13.1 macro, meso and micro research questions in international business.
weakness. Paradigms do not have to explain everything, nor does the big
tent of OLI have to shelter all theories under its umbrella.
This chapter is organised as follows. First, I address the issue of what is
OLI a paradigm, theory or model? I argue that OLI has moved from a
theory to a paradigm, the pre-eminent one in the international business
(IB) field. Second, I look at the development of OLI from its beginnings in
the 1970s to its latest evolution, highlighting major changes and new direc-
tions. As the IB field grew and developed, and as todays global economy
emerged, the OLI paradigm faced new challenges. It evolved in response
to these challenges similar to the way that a tent needs to grow to accom-
modate more children underneath it. I argue that OLI has gone through
four stages: Mark I (moving from a theory to a paradigm) and three chal-
lenges: Mark II (deepening the paradigm), Mark III (OLI and alliance
capitalism) and Mark IV (OLI and strategic management). Insights from
the chapters in this book are incorporated into each of these different
stages. Lastly, I conclude with some thoughts about new extensions and
challenges to the OLI paradigm.
Reflection and conclusions on OLI 279
What is OLI?
OLI has been called, variously, a framework, paradigm, theory and
model.2 Which is it? Let us start with a framework, which can be defined as
a basic, conceptual structure of ideas. Frameworks establish structures for
thinking about ideas. Nested within the concept of a framework is a para-
digm. Paradigms, according to Websters Dictionary, are philosophical and
theoretical frameworks within which theories, laws and generalisations, and
the experiments performed to test them, are formulated. A paradigm is an
archetype for modelling and solving problems. Inherent in a paradigm are
basic assumptions about the nature of problems and how they are to be
approached. In sum, paradigms are the way that we think about problems,
a set of background assumptions against which theories are developed.
Nested within a paradigm are theories. A theory is an organised system of
accepted knowledge that applies in a variety of circumstances to explain a
specific set of phenomena; in other words, a theory is a general statement
of cause and effect relationships between phenomena. Theories are explan-
ations of observations or laws.3 Theories normally consist of assumptions,
causal laws (A causes B) and/or hypotheses (we expect A to cause B), and
explanations for the causal laws or hypotheses (A causes B because A
causes X, which causes Z, which causes B).4
Lastly, theories are modelled by using mathematical relationships to
formalise the relationships between assumptions, causal laws or hypotheses,
and explanations. A model is a description or analogy used to help visualise
something (e.g., an atom) that cannot be directly observed. It includes a
system of postulates, data and inferences presented as a mathematical des-
cription of an entity or state of affairs. Models describe observed behaviour
but simplify by ignoring certain details.5
It is clear that Dunning originally saw OLI as a theory, in particular, as
an eclectic theory, drawing together different strands of economic theories of
international production. His early writings consistently refer to the
eclectic theory of international production. It is not until the late 1980s
that Dunning adopted the term eclectic paradigm and began to argue that
other theories (e.g., internalisation) were partial explanations that focused
on particular issues with respect to international production.6 OLI was the
theoretical framework under which theories could be developed about
particular aspects of international production. Dunning (Chapter 2: page
) makes this point quite clearly:
[A] general framework of analysis that explains the level and pattern of
foreign value-added activities of firms, and/or of countries, and allows
for the co-existence of complementary and alternative theories in the
discipline of international economics in a logically consistent manner
without being inextricably wedded to any one particular approach.
(Tolentino Chapter 7: )
Dunning (2000b) makes the strongest case for arguing that OLI is not
only a paradigm, but also the reigning paradigm or envelope for all
economic theories of the MNE. He reviews an enormous literature of IB
theories, grouping them under the O, L and I sub-paradigms. The article
concludes that OLI is the reigning paradigm of MNE activities because: (1)
the value of OLI is greater than the sum of the theories that can be con-
tained under the envelope (i.e., the whole is greater than the sum of the
parts); (2) OLI continues to offer value-adding generic hypotheses about
MNE activity despite the growing complexities in O advantages; (3) the
paradigm continues to address significant problems; and (4) there are no
other IB paradigms that are serious contenders to OLI. Thus, OLI has
grown from a theory to a big tent.
How did OLI metamorphasise from a theory into the reigning paradigm
of international production? Were the changes internally or externally
driven? How influential were external critics relative to changes in insti-
tutional realities and the emergence of the global economy? In the next
section of this paper, I examine changes in OLI, pinpointing key turning
points in the development of the paradigm.
The criticisms continued, however (see, for example, Buckley and Casson
1985; Casson 1987). Dunning (1988a) explicitly addresses the criticisms of
the internalisation school. In a section entitled Criticisms of the Eclectic
Paradigm, he asks are competitive or ownership advantages necessary to
explain international production? (1988a: 42). His response is to dif-
ferentiate between the capability and the willingness of MNEs to internalise
markets. O advantages provide the capability to internalise markets whereas
I advantages provide the willingness. He also criticises internalisation theory
for assuming market imperfections are always exogenous to the firm. In
Dunnings paradigm, market imperfections can also be endogenous
because MNEs can erect barriers to entry and exploit their monopoly
power in cross-border markets.
received the attention that his work on other subjects (e.g., alliance capi-
talism) has received. Perhaps this is because inward and outward flows of
FDI have become much more equal for OECD member countries (where
the bulk of FDI occurs) so that international business scholars accept the
investment development path as straightforward. More likely, it is because
micro not macro research questions are currently in fashion in the
international business literature.
However, IB scholars who study developing countries and emerging
market economies continue to explore the macroeconomic implications of
the eclectic paradigm. The chapter by Ozawa and Castello (Chapter 4)
provides a good example of how OLI can provide a theoretical foundation
for MNC-cum-government driven endogenous growth. The authors see
MNEs and governments as co-drivers of economic growth, turning L dis-
advantages (growth constraints; savings, foreign exchange and human
resource gaps; macro-organisational weaknesses) into new opportunities for
O appropriation by MNEs. Thus, virtuous circles of economic development
can emerge through the interactions of government policies and MNE
activities.
The creation of these new-style MNEs cried out for an explanation, one
that John Dunning clearly wanted to fit within the OLI paradigm. A first
response was to broaden the definition of international production to in-
clude any value-adding activity owned or controlled, and organised by a
firm (or group of firms) outside its (or their) national boundaries (ibid.: 1).
This enabled international production to include modes of entry such as
joint ventures and strategic alliances.
Chapter 13 provided a nice discussion of three major drivers of the new-
style MNEs (the introduction of information technologies; the increased
importance of non-market forces especially government policies for inter-
national production; and the rise of international alliances). Porters value
chain was used to illustrate the range of value-adding activities that can
occur within the MNE network.16 A discussion of networks followed. After
reviewing alliances and networks, Dunning argued that the conceptual and
analytical structure of the paradigm remains largely unimpaired, but
worried that its operational usefulness decreases as the complexity of the
variables making up the OLI configuration increases (ibid.: 342). He
concluded with the observation that MNEs should now be seen as
organizers and co-ordinators of clusters of cross-border producing and
transacting activities; to which a latitudinal dimension, which embraces a
series of co-operative inter-firm relationships is added (ibid.: 345).
In 1993, Dunnings major opus, Multinationals and the Global Economy, was
published (Dunning 1993a). Inter-firm relations were examined in detail in
Chapter 9 with a full discussion of the variety of entry modes. Technology-
based alliances were also analysed in Dunning (1993b: Chapter 8).
Reflection and conclusions on OLI 287
OLI plus S?
The third major challenge to the OLI paradigm appeared in the mid-
1980s; however, this challenge was a theoretical one, not empirical.
International business scholarship had been dominated by economists
throughout the 1970s and 1980s; with the emergence of strategic manage-
ment as a separate discipline, strategy scholars began asking questions
and developing theories that were drawn from disciplines such as
sociology, psychology and labour relations. Initially, strategy research
focused on domestic firms, but scholars such as Michael Porter, Sumatra
Ghoshal, Christopher Bartlett and Michael Hitt began to develop a new
subfield in international/global strategic management, linking strategy
with international business. Could OLI expand to incorporate this new
discipline?
Dunnings first attempt to incorporate strategy into the OLI paradigm
(Dunning 1993b: Chapter 4) compares and contrasts OLI with strategy.
Perhaps the most telling statement is:
Personally, I have never liked this attempt to weld strategy on at the end
of OLI. It does not work. Going back to my kindergarten questions at the
beginning of this essay, strategic management, as a discipline, addresses all
the Who, what, where, when, why and how? research questions. Strategy
questions, however, are micro questions at the level of the individual firm,
or even go inside the firm to focus on the entrepreneur, top management
team or board of directors. Strategy therefore cuts across all the kinder-
garten questions, but at the micro level. The OLI paradigm, on the other
hand, has been focused on the why, where and how research questions,
primarily at the macro and meso levels. If we think of the kindergarten
questions as a matrix with who/what, where, why, how and when as columns
and macro, meso and micro as rows, OLI fits primarily into the why-where-
how columns and macro-meso rows; whereas strategy, as a discipline,
crosses all the columns but primarily at the micro row level. Therefore, for
me, adding S as the last column in OLI does not and cannot fully inte-
grate strategy into the eclectic paradigm.
Along a similar vein, Guisingers revision of the OLI paradigm to OLMA
(Guisinger, Chapter 6) attempts to shift OLI down to the micro level of the
firm by replacing I with M (mode of entry) and adding A (adaptation of
businesses processes to the environment) to the end, where A is basically S
(strategy formulation and implementation). As such, OLMA suffers from
the same problems as OLIS.
A more promising route to accommodating strategic management
within OLI would follow the same approach that Dunning adopted with
Porters diamond of competitive advantage, where he incorporated
international dimensions (defined as multinational business activity) into
each of the diamond factors (Dunning 1992). Dunning (1988a: Chapter
12) began this process of linking OLI to strategy by reviewing eight
different disciplinary approaches to international production ranging
from strategic management to law and economic history. In each case, he
showed how insights about international production from a discipline could
be included under the O, L and I umbrella. He concluded that the eclectic
paradigm was robust and offer[ed] a powerful tool of analysis for
understanding MNE activities (1988: 325).
In this volume, Devinney, Midgley and Venaik (Chapter 8) also provide
an example of how strategy and the OLI paradigm can be integrated. The
authors argue that the eclectic paradigm pays insufficient attention to what
goes on inside the firm; that is, to the role played by managers and the
dynamic evolution of the MNE. Recognising that O, L and I affect S and
that S also affects O, L and I, they develop a theory where OLI is both exo-
genous and endogenous. The initial environment (O, L and I) determines
the set of all possible strategic orientations for the firm. The MNEs
existing structure acts as a constraint, determining the technologically
feasible set of strategic orientations open to the MNE. Managers beliefs
about the feasible set then determine the strategies they choose. As the
Reflection and conclusions on OLI 289
MNEs managers implement their chosen strategy, this in turn affects the
firms OLI advantages. Because certain strategies dominate others in terms
of profitability and market contestability, MNEs make adjustments over
time to move to the optimal position. Thus, strategic considerations and
managers beliefs are incorporated into the OLI paradigm. In my view, the
intertwining of strategy and OLI in this chapter has potential, but needs to
be fleshed out through application to particular strategic decisions.
The chapter by Oxelheim, Randy and Stonehill (Chapter 10) suggests
how this can be done in terms of financial strategies. They argue that a
firms financial strength affects its ability to engage in FDI. Finance-specific
strategies can be either proactive (efficiency-based) or reactive (arbitraging
market imperfections). Proactive financial strategies generate OLI advan-
tages that can be exploited through international production. What is
missing from this chapter is managerial beliefs, which link the feasible set
of strategies to the chosen strategy (see Devinney, Midgley and Venaik,
Chapter 8). The juxtaposition of these two chapters, to me, suggests the
way that OLI might better incorporate strategic decision-making. (The
Oxelheim, Randy and Stonehill chapter is important for a second reason:
the OLI paradigm underplays the financial aspects of international prod-
uction. The effects of exchange rate changes, over/under-valued currencies
and international financial management are seldom examined through the
OLI lens; this chapter is a rare and welcome exception.)
Another comment linking OLI and strategy should be made here. The
bottom line for strategic management scholars is firm performance; that
is, how strategy affects financial and market returns to the firm. The links
between OLI and firm performance are particularly slim in the inter-
national business literature. This is not surprising: OLI outlines advantages
and disadvantages of international production; the link to firm per-
formance is not straightforward unless one makes the simplifying
assumption that the greater the OLI advantages, the better the per-
formance. Benito and Tomassen (Chapter 9) begin the process of
unpacking the relationship between OLI and firm performance by ap-
plying the resource-based view to the OLI paradigm. This enables them to
create an inventory list of performance implications for each component.
The next step would be to operationalise this list and engage in empirical
tests.
There have been few empirical attempts to explicitly link the eclectic
paradigm to firm performance. Robins, Tallman and Fladmoe-Lindquist
(2002) applied OLI to the performance of joint ventures in Mexico. Inter-
estingly, they argued for and found evidence of some resources provided by
the US parent to the Mexican joint venture actually reducing the ventures
performance. This suggests that not all OLI factors must have positive
impacts. Eden, Thomas and Olibe (forthcoming) also examined the
influence of O and L advantages on the performance of US MNEs. They
decomposed L into two components measuring firm depth (foreign market
290 Lorraine Eden
Conclusions
My review of the OLI paradigm and its evolution over the past 30-plus
years supports Dunnings contention that OLI can be and is an envelope
292 Lorraine Eden
or big tent for all theories that address the why, where and how of MNE
activity (Dunning 2000b). The paradigm has shifted its focus from ex-
plaining international production as the exploitation of OLI advantages
through wholly owned foreign subsidiaries in manufacturing to a rich,
complex analysis of globalised businesses at the beginning of the twenty-
first century.
The chapters in this book point to ways in which the OLI paradigm is
being interpreted and altered by international business scholars. Many of
these contributions focus on strategic management and the need for OLI
to better incorporate the resource-based view and managerial perspectives.
In terms of my matrix (see Figure 13.1) of macro, meso and micro levels of
analysis, the thrust of these extensions is at the micro level. One advantage
of moving down the level of analysis is the increased ability to perform
econometric analysis; that is, we can examine how OLI affect firm strategies
and performance using firm-level data rather than FDI statistics. However,
a fully fledged integration of strategy into OLI even of the resource-based
view into OLI has yet to appear. The chapters in this volume point the way,
but more work is needed here.
Second, I agree with the authors in this book that OLI should better
integrate insights from institutional theory. The new institutional econo-
mics is a vibrant and thriving discipline, crossing management, economics,
sociology and law. Institutional theory has brought new insights into inter-
national business literature, for example, liability of foreignness, relational
capital, public corruption, and property rights. One can speculate how
liability of foreignness and public corruption, for example, could quite
easily be incorporated into the OLI big tent. However, I do not agree that
NIE should, or even could, replace OLI as the reigning paradigm of
international business.
Third, the focus on international finance, bringing finance back in to OLI,
is a welcome sign. As international business researchers increasingly adopt
the tools of finance (e.g., real options theory, foreign exchange exposure,
currency unions) the OLI model needs also to redirect its attention to risk
and uncertainty in connection with the financing of international production.
To restate my initial thesis at the beginning of this chapter, the focus of
OLI was and remains the why, where and how of international production.
The chapters in this book focus primarily on deepening the OLI in terms of
these three questions by incorporating the micro level of analysis (the firm
and its managers).
Let me suggest, as a counterpoint, that the eclectic paradigm might also
usefully be broadened by an explicit focus on the when question; that is, the
issue of timing of international production.19 International business and
strategy scholars are increasingly preoccupied by timing issues; for ex-
ample, de novo versus sequential FDI, FDI as platform investments, incor-
porating real options theory into IB research, the big step hypothesis, the
recent issue of Academy of Management Review on timing.
Reflection and conclusions on OLI 293
Notes
1 My latest purchase, the two-volume set of Dunnings selected essays, Theories and
Paradigms of International Business Activity (2002b), is also a must have since the
first volume gathers together many of Dunnings OLI writings in one place from
1973 to the present. There is one problem with the Selected Essays; they have
been updated from the originals in places, making it harder to trace Dunnings
own theory development from one paper to the next. For example, Chapter 4,
Explaining the international direct investment position of countries, published
originally in 1981, contains references to 1993 publications. A second problem
is that some of my favorite OLI readings (e.g., Dunning 1979; 1988a: Chapters
11 and 13) are missing.
2 For example, in this volume, OLI is referred to as a framework (Maitland and
Nicholas) and as a theory evolving into a paradigm (Tolentino). Dunning in his
earliest OLI writings (1977, reprinted in 1981, page 33) shares this uncertainty
about where OLI fits; the eclectic model can be perceived as a general theory of
international production in so far as it provides an analytical framework for
explaining all forms of such production.
3 Laws are generalisations about observed regular relationships between two
phenomena, from which we can generalise about what we expect to happen
(e.g., the law of one price or Greshams Law).
4 According to Van Evera (1997), a good theory has large explanatory power,
importance, parsimony and a wide explanatory range. A good theory is appli-
cable to the real world, clearly framed and satisfying. A good theory should be,
in principle, falsifiable. It should have prescriptive richness and explain impor-
tant phenomena.
5 As a result, models allow complex systems to be understood and behaviours
predicted, but may give incorrect predictions for situations outside the models
assumptions.
6 The first major statement of OLI as a paradigm is Dunning (1988b), which
draws his previous writings on OLI together, shifting from eclectic theory to
paradigm.
7 Dunning (1981b) pulls together his first eight years of publications on the MNE,
organised into three topics: OLI, impacts of MNEs on home and host countries,
and lessons for governments.
8 To recap the three conditions: (1) It possessed net ownership advantages over
firms from other countries in serving a particular national market (O advan-
tage). (2) It was more beneficial for the firm to use these net ownership
advantages itself rather than sell or lease them (I advantage). (3) These net
ownership advantages were more profitably exploited when used with factor
inputs outside the home country (L advantage).
9 This distinction was important later for incorporating, first, internalisation theory,
then strategic management and finally, sequential FDI into the OLI envelope.
10 Published as Narula (1996).
11 These included the spatial distribution of inputs and markets; prices, quality
and productivity of inputs; transport and communication costs; government
intervention and policies; infrastructure; psychic distance; and scale economies.
12 Personally, I also teach L as broken into E + S + P but use a different grouping
that I find more intuitively appealing: E(economic), S (socio-cultural) and P
(political-legal). This is closer in spirit to Guisingers breakdown of the
international environment (this volume).
13 This is a short chapter, but it has always been one of my favourites.
14 We now refer to these processes as investment-led and policy-led regional
integration.
Reflection and conclusions on OLI 295
15 Piscitello (this volume) is also notable as an empirical piece using OLI to predict
location.
16 And right side up too upstream activities are at the top and downstream at the
bottom, rather than moving from left to right horizontally! Thus, horizontally
integrated activities can be shown horizontally (e.g., the component supply
stage in Figure 13.1 on page 340) and vertically integrated activities in a vertical
direction. See also Chapter 9 in Dunning (1993a) for a full discussion of value
chains in MNE entry and expansion strategies.
17 Other motives (escape, support and passive investments) are also discussed
although they appear to have been dropped from subsequent Dunning papers,
leaving only the first four. In the OLI paradigm, the key verbs used to describe
motivations are exploit and acquire; however, there are other verbs such as
arbitrage (market imperfections) and avoid (risk) that now are seldom heard.
18 Originally cast as exploiting O advantages, the eclectic paradigm now includes
seeking O assets. Note the shift from advantages to assets, which may come from
the resource-based view. Dynamic capabilities should be next.
19 Although I do believe that paradigms do not have to explain everything, nor
does the OLI big tent have to shelter all theories under its umbrella.
20 See also Contractor and Loranges new book where Dunning (2002a) appears.
21 For example, I deliberately omitted the World Investment Reports, where Dunning
has served for many years as the lead intellectual scholar, and his work on MNE-
state relations and the benefits and costs of FDI, which are tangential to the OLI
paradigm.
References
Barney, J. (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage, Journal of
Management, 17: 99-120.
Buckley, P.J. (1981) A critical review of theories of the multinational enterprise,
Aussenwirtschaft, 36: 70-8.
Buckley, P.J. (1983) New theories of international business: Some unresolved issues,
in M.C. Casson (ed.), The Growth of International Business, London: Allen & Unwin.
Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M.C. (1985) The Economic Theory of the Multinational
Enterprise, London: Macmillan.
Casson, M.C. (1987) The Firm and the Market, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Contractor, F.J. and Lorange, P. (eds) (1988) Cooperative Strategies in International
Business, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Dunning, J.H. (1973) The determinants of international production, Oxford
Economic Papers, November, 25: 289-325.
Dunning, J.H. (1977) Trade, location of economic activity and the MNE: A Search
for an eclectic approach, in B. Ohlin, P.O. Hesselborn and P.M. Wijkman (eds),
The International Allocation of Economic Activity, London: Macmillan.
Dunning, J.H. (1979) Explaining changing patterns of international production: In
support of the eclectic theory, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 41(4):
269-95.
Dunning, J.H. (1980) Trade, location of economic activity and the multinational
enterprise: some empirical tests, Journal of International Business Studies 11(1): 9-31.
Dunning, J.H. (1981a) Explaining the international direct investment position of
countries: Towards a dynamic or developmental approach, Weltwirtschaftliches
Archiv, 117: 30-64.
296 Lorraine Eden
Dunning, J.H. and Narula, R. (eds.) (1996) Foreign Direct Investment and Governments,
London and New York: Routledge.
Eden, L. Thomas, D.E. and Olibe, K.O. (forthcoming) Why multinationality
matters: Exploring the L in the OLI paradigm, in P. Gray (ed.), Extending the
Eclectic Paradigm in International Business: Essays in Honor of John Dunning,
London: Edward Edgar.
Giddy, I. and Young, S. (1982) Conventional theory and unconventional
multinationals: Do new forms of multinational enterprise require new theories?,
in A.M. Rugman (ed.), New Theories of the Multinational Enterprise, London and
Canberra: Croom Helm.
Itaki, M. (1991) Critical Assessment of the Eclectic Theory of the MNE, Journal of
International Business Studies, 22(3): 445-60.
Kojima, K. (1978) Foreign Direct Investment: A Japanese Model of Multinational Business
Operations, London: Croom Helm.
Narula, R. (1993) An Examination of the Evolution and Interdependence of Foreign Direct
Investment and Economic Structure: The Case of Industrialized Countries, Ph.D
Dissertation, Newark, NJ: Rutgers University.
Narula, R. (1996) Multinational Investment and Economic Structure, London:
Routledge.
Robins, J., Tallman, S. and Fladmoe-Lindquist, K. (2002) Autonomy and
dependence of international cooperative ventures: An exploration of the
strategic performance of US ventures in Mexico, Strategic Management Journal,
23: 881-901.
Rugman, A.M. (1980) Internalization as a general theory of foreign direct
investment, a reappraisal of the literature, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 116(2): 365-
79.
Van Evera, S. (1997) Guide to Methods for Students of Political Science, Ithaca and
London: Cornell University Press.
Wilkins, M. and Schrter, H. (1998) The Free-Standing Company in the World Economy,
18301996, Oxford: Oxford University Press.