Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock Exchanges
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock Exchanges
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock Exchanges
1. Introduction
The decision on the capital structure is important in providing the supportive funds and
monitoring the creditors involvements. The capital structure might comprise a mixture of more equity
and lower debt, and vice versa. Therefore, it should be planned and budgeted for future operations. If
the firm incurs higher debt in the present, it will have a burden to pay higher interest in the future even
though certain tax shielding can be beneficial to the firm. On the other hand, if the firm issues more
equity, the increasing amount of outstanding shares imposes the pressure on the firm to pay higher
dividends in the future. As a result, the firm will experience less available cash flows for maintaining
its sustainable growth. Recognizing the executives influences on the execution of policy and
operation, managers of the firm have an obligation to make business decisions, not only hinge on
contractual agreement of wealth maximization via profit creation, but also on personal benefits and
utility, which can result in the so called agency problem. In general, the existence of asymmetric
information may induce executives to advocate less effort to generate real free cash flows for the firm
if they expect that the adverse impact on the firm is not harmful to their career. Another possibility is
that executives may concentrate on the amount of dividend distributed to shareholders. Investors and
shareholders do not only act as the principal, but also act as consumers by consuming the products
produced by the firm in the sense of overall aggregation. In addition, the shareholders possess the
right to switch their investment from stocks to bonds issued by the firm or switch their investment to
other firms. A change in dividend payment can cause misunderstanding and even conflicts among
partners due to the distrusts and uncertain decision on dividend policy. Theoretically, there are crucial
determinants of dividend policy that simultaneously reach a possible equilibrium solution for both
firm and its investors.
113
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock
Exchanges
In the era of rising Asian economies, emerging stock markets are evolving themselves in the
direction of more maturity and advancement. This can be observed by rising trend in market
capitalization during the past decades. Emerging market economies have experienced a dramatic
change and growth starting from 1994. This phenomenon was more pronounced from the year 2002 to
2003. The increased market capitalization in emerging stock markets further causes the characteristics
of dividend behavior to change, especially the size of dividend yield and the determinants for dividend
payouts. The upward movement of dividend yield shows an improvement of return on capital
investment in emerging markets.
The present study aims to apply an empirical model to the data of firms from New York and
Shanghai Stock Exchanges. The reason for choosing these two stock markets is that the New York
Stock Exchange (NYSE) is the well-developed stock market while the Shanghai Stock Exchange
(SSE) is an emerging one. Previous empirical studies indicate that dividend policy behavior of
corporations operating in emerging markets is significantly different from the widely accepted
dividend policy in developed markets (Adaoglu, 2000, among others). In addition, dividend policy of
firms in developed markets is stable while that of emerging markets is unstable. Contrary to the
finding of Adaoglu (2000), Aivazian et al. (2003) find that firms in the U. S. market and emerging
markets exhibit similar dividend behavior. However, emerging market firms are more sensitive to
some variables, which indicate the greater financial constraints under which they operate.
Furthermore, emerging market firms seem to be affected by asset mix, which seems to be due to their
greater reliance on bank debt under bank-dominated environments. We use firm-level panel data of
listed firms in NYSE and SSE. The data are retrieved from the Data Stream. The period covers the
year 1992 to 2008. The Shanghai Stock Exchange is the typical representative of largest size compared
to those of other emerging markets. The fast economic recovery coupled with the recent economic
strength cause China to play more important role in the world market. Our empirical results reveal that
financial leverage of firms (or debts), equity issuance, financial cost of debts considering tax shield,
interaction between equity finance and certain types of investment strategy, and combination effects of
all factors jointly explain dividend behavior of NYSE listed firms. On the contrary, these factors
poorly explain dividend behavior of SSE listed firms.
The organization of our paper is as follows. The following section reviews the previously related
studies on dividend policy of firms. The third section presents our empirical dividend policy model,
the sample data and the estimation method. The empirical results are presented in the fourth section.
The last section gives concluding remarks.
2. Literature Review
Earlier empirical evidence of the impact of dividends on share prices is contributed by Cambell
and Beranek (1955), which indicates that dividends can signal information of firms to shareholders
with different characteristics of tax preference. Lintner (1956) proposes a path-breaking mathematical
dividend policy model explaining how companies decide on dividend rates. The emergence of
dividend model proposed by Miller and Modigliani (1961) states that managed dividend policies
neither increase nor decrease shareholders wealth in a complete and perfect capital market unless they
cause the investment policies of companies to change. A number of studies have focused on the socalled dividend puzzle. This puzzle called by Black (1976) stipulates that a substantial portion of
firms earnings are paid as dividends. Researchers have tried to investigate this puzzle empirically.
One of the main themes of previous empirical studies is to examine the influence of various factors on
the dividend behavior of companies in both developed and emerging stock markets.
There seems to be no consensus as to what factors affecting corporate dividend policy.
Furthermore, it is not clear how these factors interact. Even though a number of theories have been
proposed, extensive theoretical proposition is based on information asymmetry. This theory
documents on whether or not dividends convey information about current and future earnings
(Bhattacharya, 1979; Miller and Rock, 1985, among others). On the other hand, the agency theory
proposed by Easterbrook (1984) indicates the importance of agency costs to dividend payout. When
firms pay dividends, agency cost will increase because agencies will monitor and discipline the
financial markets due to their expectations that firms will raise additional capital through these
markets.
114
International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, Vol. 3, No. 1, 2013, pp.113-121
In the finance literature, dividend policy is the practice of management decision on the size and
pattern of cash distributions to stockholders over time. This practice can be observed by dividend
payout behavior of firms. Some previous studies have paid attention to what factors determine
dividend policy or dividend payout ratio. Glen et al. (1995) find that emerging market firms tend to
have a target dividend payout ratio like those in developed markets, but are less concerned with
dividend volatility over time. Therefore, dividend smoothing over time may be less important.
Adaoglu (2000) finds the evidence similar to that of Glen et al. (1995). In addition, there are
significant differences between dividend policies of firms in the Istanbul Stock Exchange and those in
developed markets.
Some empirical studies have focused on the impacts of capital structure and cost of debt on
dividend payout ratio. Jalillvand and Harris (1984) examine financing decisions of U. S. firms by
paying attention to capital structure and dividend targets. Using individual firm data, they find that
financing decisions on the issuances of long-term and short-term debts, maintenance of corporate
liquidity, issuance of new equity and payment of dividends are interdependent. Furthermore, firm size,
interest rate condition, and stock price levels affect the speeds of adjustment to long-run financial
targets even though the speeds of adjustment may vary among companies. The cost of debt can be
controlled by firms when they decide on the capital structure. An increase in the cost of debt is
attributed by the decision to pay more for bondholders when firms decide to borrow. The important
factor that affects both cost of debt and cost of capital is the tax rate. Suppose higher tax rate is
imposed on dividend and capital gain, stocks will become less attractive to investors if the tax rate on
interest income is constant.
The conflict between bondholders and stockholders can cause the agency cost of debt to rise. The
principal-agent model of Jensen and Meckling (1976) can explain this phenomenon. Kim and
Sorensen (1986) test the relation between agency-principal problem and debt policy. They find that
firms with higher insider ownership have greater debt ratio than those with lower insider ownership. In
addition, high growth firms use less debt and the size of firms is not related to the level of debt. Mello
and Parsons (1992) demonstrate the contingent claim model and show that the agency costs of debt
arise from the conflicts among agencies. Jensen et al. (1992) find that insiders ownership, investment
spending on debt and dividend policy are directly and indirectly related across firms. Their results
support a modified pecking order hypothesis1. In addition, firms with high insider ownership choose
lower level of debt and dividends. Leland (1998) examines the joint determination of capital structure
and finds that optimal capital structure reflects the tax advantages of debt. Furthermore, agency costs
restrict leverage and debt maturity of firms, but their importance is small. Faccio et al. (2001) find that
firms in Western Europe pay more dividends than those in East Asia due to better shareholder
protection. Their finding implies that East Asian firms are likely to incur higher cost of debt resulting
from lower dividend payment than interest income payment. Frank and Goyal (2003) test the pecking
order theory using a broad cross section of publicly traded U. S. firms over the period 1971-1988.
They find that internal financing is not sufficient to cover investment spending on average, but
external financing is heavily used instead. However, debt financing does not dominate equity
financing. This evidence is contrary to previous empirical findings. Fama and French (2002) indicate
that more profitable firms and firms with fewer investments have higher dividend payouts. This
finding confirms the trade-off and pecking order theory. Their finding that more profitable firms have
lower leverage confirms the pecking order model, but contradicting the trade-off model, which
indicate that firms will balance the cost and benefit when deciding on equity and debt financing. In
short, they find negative relationship between leverage and dividend payment. In general, firms with
more current investment have lower long-term dividend payouts. Gul and Kealey (1999) find that the
Korean corporate sector is dominated by Chaebol (giant conglomerates) and is likely to encourage
more debt financing. Results based on 411 firms show that the giant conglomerates carry higher debt.
Moreover, growth options of firms are negatively related to leverage and dividend. They conclude that
firms in the Korean corporate sector behave differently from those in the U. S. Employing a crosssection of the largest Chinese listed firms; Tong and Green (2005) find a significantly positive
correlation between past dividends and current leverage from debt financing. Some studies find
1
Pecking order theory posits that firms finance their projects by giving priority to internal funds first, followed
by debt and equity financing. The modified theory stipulates that these financing strategies are related.
115
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock
Exchanges
;negative relationship between leverage and dividend payout (see Al-Twajiry, 2007 for Malaysian
firms and Al-Malakawi, 2008 for Jordanian firms). When shareholders are well- protected, the ability
of firms to issue debt instrument is limited. Milton (2004) shows that firm-level corporate governance
and country-level investor protection are associated with higher dividend payouts. These two factors
help reduce agency problem of firms in emerging market. However, Brockman and Unlu (2009) use a
large sample of firms in 52 countries to test the notion that creditor rights can influence dividend
policies. They find that the agency costs of debt play a more decisive role in determining dividend
policies than the agency costs of equity.
3. Methodology
3.1 Empirical Model
A simple model of determinants of dividend payout is expressed as the following function:
(1)
where ER is earnings per share, RE is retained earnings, and CIP is corporate income tax rate.
However, the simplified model may not be able to sufficiently capture dividend policy of a firm. More
complicated model should be used.
The dividend policy model is based on the two-period dividend theory. The model with
asymmetric information proposed by Miller and Rock (1985) among others is important in deriving
optimal dividend payout. Certain variables or determinants are relevant to the dividend policy of a
firm. The optimal level of dividend policy should accommodate satisfactions from the firm, agency
and principal. We emphasize crucial variables that are relevant to dividend policy of the firm. The
optimal dividend can be expressed in the following function:2
ln Divit 0 1 ln( Bit ) 2 ln( Eit ) 3 ln( CBit ) 4 ln( EK it ) 5 ln( COM it ) it
(2)
where B denotes debt financing and E represents the equity financing of the firm, which in fact is the
sum of originally assumed equity in one unit and additional shares issued. This is simply the book
value of equity, because only the book-value of equity represents the actual amount of capital that the
firm raises from issuing stock, rather than the market value of stock or market capitalization. CB is the
cost of debt financing, which is equal to one plus the after-tax rate of return. Pedhazur and Schmelkin
(1991) suggest using multiple effects in multiple regression. If multiple effects are not included, the
interpretation of each individual variable may be misleading. Therefore, EK is the interaction effect of
equity financing and market investment preferences. This variable represents the interaction between
equity financing and investors preferences, specifically the impact of equity financing on investors
preferences in the capital market. We follow the procedure proposed by Desai and Dharmapal (2008)
who demonstrate how important the interaction effect is. The last variable COM is the combination
effect redefined as the factor that represents the combined effects of equity financing and debt
financing along with other factors, i.e., cost of capital, tax shield, personal income tax on dividend,
and investment strategy.
Financing policy of the firm is based on issuance of stock (equity instrument) and bonds with
different maturities (debt instrument). A change in firms capital structure over a certain time period
exhibits a change in financing preference. In other words, a change in the ratio of equity to debt is a
good proxy of firms capital structure. Firms may rely on increasing debts when tax saving from
deduction of interest expenses and the gain from issuing debt are higher than the cost paid for loans.
Furthermore, the monitoring effect by stockholders may be working on improving the performance of
firms. Otherwise, it will be the loss to firms using debt financing. On the contrary, issuing more shares
of stock saves interest payments and increases the degree of distribution of dividends to shareholders.
In fact there are passive and active effects of debt and equity financing. There should be changes in
capital structure that accommodate the optimal dividend payment to shareholders.
Investors investment strategy is difficult to observe. We rely on the assumption of theoretical
model of principals utility maximization, which allows wealth transferring among two periods and a
switch between debt and equity instruments by investors. Investment strategy and dividend policy are
2
We employ the log-linear equation because it provides the interpretation of the estimated results in terms of
elasticity, which are easy to understand.
116
International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, Vol. 3, No. 1, 2013, pp.113-121
related by the fact that all firms in different industries face the same or similar investment preferences
of investors in any given time period. Without losing generality, the growth rate of GDP can represent
the accumulation of wealth. In addition, stock market capitalization can be a proxy showing that the
amount of wealth will flow into the capital market. An increasing trend of growth rate over time
causes changes in investors preferences. Therefore, the proportion of stock market capitalization and
GDP should not be constant.
3.2 Data
The annual data of 378 listed companies in Shanghai Stock Exchange are collected. The period of
this study covers the year 1992 to 2008, which is 17 year period. The data in this study are panel data
that include each firms variables: interest expenses, capital structure, growth of dividends and
personal tax on dividends, and investment strategy. For the New York Stock Exchange, we choose 537
listed firms with annual data of the same variables from the year 1992 to 2008. All the data are
obtained from Data Stream. The collected data are used to formulate the dependent variable (dividend
payout) and four independent variables (debt financing, equity financing, interaction effect, and
combination effect). These four determinants or independent variables are expected to affect dividend
payout. All variables in our panel regression are transformed to logarithmic data.
3.3 Estimation Method
We use panel regression for both stock markets. First, we employ pooled data least square
estimate of equation (2). In pooled regression, the results are not reliable since the estimated
coefficients may be biased. Furthermore, it is difficult to overcome serial correlation that may be
present. Therefore, performing an analysis of fixed and random effects should be more preferable. The
fixed effect estimation with cross-section fixed is performed on equation (3). However, we decide to
include the time dummies in the fixed effect analysis. This fixed effect model assumes that the slopes
are constant, but the intercepts differ according to time. The equation to be estimated is the following
equation:3
(3)
where D denotes time dummy variable for each year from 1993 to 2007. In estimating the time fixed
effect, we use sixteen dummy variables for 1992 to 2007. In the analysis, we treat the year 2008 as the
base year. We then perform the random effect least-square estimate. Finally, the Hausman tests are
used to test whether the random effect model is suitable in the analysis.
4. Empirical Results
We conduct the fixed and random effect analyses. The results of cross-section fixed effect are
reported in Table 1. The results for the two stock markets are quite different. The estimated coefficient
of debt financing of firms in NYSE is positive and significant at the 10 percent level while that of
firms in SSE is insignificantly positive with a negligible size. For firms in NYSE, a one percent
increase in debt financing causes dividend payout to increase by 0.852 percent while an increase in
debt financing has no effect on dividend payout of firms in SSE. However, the estimated coefficients
of equity financing are significantly negative for firms in both markets with a large coefficient for
firms in NYSE. This indicates that a one percent rise in equity financing causes dividend payout in
decrease by 3.936 and 0.315 percent for firms in NYSE and SSE respectively. The different
relationship between dividend payout and cost of debt in the two markets can be observed by the
negative coefficient for firms in SSE and the positive one for firms in NYSE. A one percent rise in the
cost of debt causes dividend payout to rise by 1.098 percent for firms in NYSE, but causes dividend
payout to fall by 0.006 percent for firms in SSE. The effects of interaction and combination of factors
are not significant in SSE, but are highly significant in NYSE. The combined effect of variables is
negatively related to dividend payout of firms in NYSE. In addition, the high value of R2 explicitly
suggests that there is high percentage of variation in dividend payout that is explained by the
combination of all variables. This is not true for firms in SSE, i. e., the fixed effects at cross-section
that the slopes are fixed and the intercepts vary over time reject the notion that these two variables
(interaction and combination effects) are crucial determinants of dividend policy of firms for SSE. The
3
The dummy variables are added to equation (2) to detect the role of time fixed effect in panel regression.
117
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock
Exchanges
coefficient of determination or R2 is 0.916 and 0.654 for the cases of NYSE and SSE respectively. The
estimated equation for firms in NYSE gives significant coefficients for all variables. However, the
positive relationship between leverage and dividend found for firms in NYSE is contradictory to the
prediction by Fama and French (2002). For SSE, only two determinants (equity financing and cost of
debt) impose no impact on dividend policy of firms. The results also show that equity financing is
more important than debt financing in both stock markets, which is contrary to the prediction of the
pecking order theory.
Table 1. Results of Fixed Effect Least-Square Estimates: Cross-Section fixed
New York Stock Exchange
Shanghai Stock Exchange
Coefficient
Coefficient
0.852*
0.001
(0.484)
(0.005)
[1.762]
[0.239]
Equity financing
-3.936***
-0.315***
(1.361)
(0.063 0
[2.892]
[-4.979]
Cost of debt
1.098*
-0.006***
(0.618)
(0.017)
[1.779]
[-3.459]
Interaction effect
5.228***
-0.060
(0.281)
(0.008)
[2.791]
[-0.782]
Combination effect
-0.784***
0.032
(0.280)
(0.025)
[-2.790]
[1.256]
R2
0.916
0.654
F-statistic
11.566
11.313
Mean dependent variable
-0.997
0.021
S. D dependent variable
14.443
0.945
Note: The interaction effect is between equity finance and market preference while the combination effect is
between equity and debt finance along with other crucial factors. The number in parenthesis is standard error,
and the number in bracket is t-statistic. ***, **and * denote significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent
respectively.
Variable
Debt financing
We further analyze the random effect using least square method, and the results are reported in
Table 2. The results are almost the same as those in Table 1. However, the R2 for firms in both market
from random effect estimates are substantially lower than those of fixed effect estimates. This implies
that are lower variations in dividend payout that is explained by all independent variables. In a similar
manner, the results from random effect estimates show that estimated coefficients of all variables are
significant in NYSE with the prominent size of coefficients for equity finance and interaction effect.
On the contrary, the size of estimated coefficients of variables in SSE is quite small. It can be
concluded that these results show that crucial factors affecting firms dividend policy in NYSE cannot
explain dividend policy of firms in SSE.
We compare the results from fixed and random effects under the null hypothesis that individual
effects are uncorrelated to explanatory variables in our panel regression. The Gauss-Markov
assumptions should not be violated. If the null hypothesis of no correlation is rejected, the random
effect is biased. Therefore, the results from fixed effect will be more preferable. We use the Hausman
test by Hausman (1978) and the results are reported in Table 3. The results show that the Chi-square
statistics for both NYSE and SSE are large enough to reject the null hypothesis that individual effects
are uncorrelated. This test indicates that the random effect model should be rejected. Thus the fixed
effect results are suitable for both stock markets.
118
International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, Vol. 3, No. 1, 2013, pp.113-121
Table 2. Results of Random Effect Least-Square Estimates
New York Stock Exchange
Shanghai Stock Exchange
Coefficient
Coefficient
0.941**
0.001
(0.428)
(0.004)
[2.201]
[0.340]
Equity financing
-5.272***
0.227***
(1.231)
(0.267)
[-4.248]
[8.506]
Cost of debt
0.689*
-0.017***
(0.484)
(0.006)
[1.423]
[-3.054]
Interaction effect
5.973***
-0.113***
(1.613)
(0.014)
[5.134]
[-9.277]
Combination effect
-1.151***
0.028
(0.268)
(0.021)
[-4.287]
[1.331]
R2
0.411
0.039
F-statistic
121.933
19.618
Mean dependent variable
-4.409
-0.022
S. D dependent variable
6.587
0.634
Note: The interaction effect is between equity finance and market preference while the combination effect is
between equity and debt finance along with other crucial factors. The number in parenthesis is standard error,
and the number in bracket is t-statistic. ***, **and * denote significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent respectively.
Variable
Debt financing
119
Capital Structure, Cost of Debt and Dividend Payout of Firms in New York and Shanghai Stock
Exchanges
Based on the results in Table 1, dividend policy of firms in NYSE and SSE is determined by
different factors. This confirms the finding of Aivazian et al. (2003) that emerging market firms are
sensitive to some factors relating to greater financial constraints under which they operate.
Relying on the results from fixed effect analyses, we can conclude that all variables in the
estimated equations are important in determining dividend policy of firms in NYSE. However, only
equity financing and cost of debt play important roles in dividend policy of firms in SSE, but with
minimal impacts.
The Chinese bond market is not well-developed even though it has been growing quite fast in the
last few years. However, the bond outstanding is much smaller than those of more mature markets. In
addition, the composition of bonds has been heavily biased towards government bonds (See Aglietta
and Maarek, 2007). The situation forces firms in China to rely more on bank credits than issuing
bonds. Furthermore, the significant impact of cost of debt on dividend policy of firms in NYSE
implies that managers perceive the monitoring pressure from bondholders. However, the case cannot
be applied to firms in SSE. Even if incurring liability can benefit firms via tax shield, investors will
prefer investing in government bonds. Therefore, debt financing by issuing corporate bonds play no
role in dividend policy of Chinese firms. Furthermore, the insignificance of the combination effect of
all factors in SSE firms shows that the level of advancement and management intelligence are much
more inferior to those of NYSE. The implication from the results of this study is that firms in an
emerging stock market should change the capital structure by relying more on debt financing such that
it will not delay their future expansion. The suggestion is that the Chinese financial system should not
be heavily tilted towards the role of commercial banks. The well-developed bond market is desirable
because it encourages firms to borrow more. Also, investors can invest more on corporate bonds with
higher level of safety without taking high default risk.
5. Concluding Remarks
In previous empirical studies, there has been an argument about which factors influence the
dividend policy of corporations. In this paper, we attempt to identify factors influencing dividend
payouts of firms in NYSE and SSE. We use the panel data of 378 listed firms in SSE and select 537
listed firms in NYSE. These data are annual data from 1992 to 2008. In the panel data analysis, we
conduct the fixed and random effect regressions. We then compare the results from fixed and random
effects under the null hypothesis that individual effects are uncorrelated to explanatory variables. The
results of Hausman test indicates that the results from fixed effect regresssion are preferable to draw a
conclusion because the random effect model is rejected.
The fixed-effect panel regression estimates show that equity financing is more pronounced in
determining dividend payout of firms in NYSE than those in SSE. When the time is fixed, we find that
debt financing is less important for firms in SSE than in NYSE. Other variables such as interaction
effect and combination effect play no role in determining dividend payout SSE. This evidence implies
that investors care more for dividend than interest payment of firms in an emerging stock market. The
main implication from our study is that firms in an emerging stock market, SSE in our study, should
consider the optimal capital structure by relying more on debt financing such that investors can invest
more on fixed-income securities. This will provide room for investors to diversify their portfolios.
Moreover, policymakers should implement measures to enhance the advancement of Chinese bond
and stock markets. The development of bond market should be the main focus so that firms will not
rely heavily on bank loans. Furthermore, investors can invest more on corporate bonds with lower
level of default risk.
References
Adaoglu, C. (2000), Instability in the Dividend Policy of the Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE)
Corporations: Evidence from an Emerging Market. Emerging Markets Review, 1(3), 252-270.
Aglietta, M., Maarek, P. (2007), Developing the Bond Market in China: The Next Step Forward in
Financial Reform. Economie Internationale, 3(11), 29-53.
Al-Malakawi, H-A.N. (2008), Factors Influencing Corporate Dividends Decision: Evidence from
Jordanian Panel Data. International Journal of Business, 13(2), 177-195.
120
International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, Vol. 3, No. 1, 2013, pp.113-121
Al-Twajiry, A.A. (2007), Dividend Policy and Payout Ratio: Evidence from Kuala Lumpur Stock
Exchange. Journal of Risk Finance, 8(4), 349-363.
Aivazian, V., Booth, L., Cleary, S. (2003), Do Emerging Market Firms follow Different Dividend
Policies from U.S. Firms? Journal of Financial Research, 26(3), 371-387.
Bhattacharya, S. (1979), Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy and the Bird in the Hand Fallacy.
Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 259-270.
Black, F. (1976), The Dividend Puzzle. Journal of Portfolio Management, 2(2), 5-8.
Brockman, P., Unlu, E. (2009), Dividend Policy, Creditor Rights, and the Agency Cost of Debt. Journal
of Financial Economics, 92(2), 276-299.
Campbell, J.A., Beranek, W. (1955), Stock Price Behavior on Ex-dividend Dates. Journal of
Finance, 10(2), 425-429.
Desai, M.A., Dharmapala, D. (2008), Tax and Corporate Governance. MPI Studies on
Intellectual Property, Competition and Tax Law, 3(1), 13-30.
Easterbrook, F.H. (1984), Two Agency Cost Explanations of Dividends. American Economic Review,
74(4), 650-659.
Faccio, M., Lang, L., Young, L. (2001), Dividend and Expropriation. American Economic Review,
91(1), 54-78.
Fama, E. F., French, K. R. (2002), Testing Trade-off and Pecking Order Predictions about Dividend and
Debt. Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 1-33.
Frank, M.Z., Goyal, V.K. (2003), Testing the Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure. Journal of
Financial Economics, 67(2), 217-248.
Glen, J.D., Karmokolias, Y, Miller, R.R., Shah, S. (1995), Dividend Policy and Behavior in
Emerging Markets: To Pay or Not to Pay. IFC Discussion Paper, No. 26.
Gul, P.A., Kealey, B.T. (1999), Chaebol, Investment Opportunity Set and Corporate Debt and
Dividend Policies of Korean Companies. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting,
13(4), 401-416.
Hausman, J. (1978), Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, 46(6), 1251-1272.
Jalillvand, A., Harris, R.S. (1984), Corporate Behavior in Adjusting to Capital Structure and
Dividend Targets: An Econometric Study. Journal of Finance, 39(1), 127-145.
Jensen, G.R., Solberg, D.P., Zorn, T.S. (1992), Simultaneous Determination of Insider Ownership,
Debt, and Dividend Policies. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 27(2), 247-263.
Jensen, M., Meckling, W. (1976), Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and
Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(2), 305-360.
Kim, W., Sorensen, E. (1986), Evidence on the Impact of Agency Costs of Debt on Corporate
Debt Policy. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 21(2), 131-144.
Leland, H. (1998), Agency Costs, Risk Management and Capital Structure. Journal of Finance,
53(4), 1213-1243.
Lintner, J. (1956), Distribution of Incomes of Corporations among Dividend, Retained Earnings,
and Taxes. American Economic Review, 46(2), 97-133.
Mello, A., Parsons, J. (1992), Measuring the Agency Cost of Debt. Journal of Finance, 47(5),
1887-1904.
Miller, M., Modigliani, F. (1961), Dividend Policy, Growth and the Valuation of Shares. Journal
of Business, 34(4), 411-443.
Miller, M., Rock, K. (1985), Dividend Policy under Asymmetric Information. Journal of Finance,
40(4), 1031-1051.
Milton, T. (2004), Corporate Governance and Dividend Policy in Emerging Markets. Emerging
Markets Review, 5(4), 409-426.
Pedhazure, E.F., Schmelkin, L.P. (1991), Measurement, Design, and Analysis: An Integrated
Approach. Hillsdale, New Jersey.
Tong, G., Green, C.J. (2005), Pecking Order or Trade-off Hypothesis? Evidence on the Capital
Structure of Chinese Companies. Applied Economics, 37(19), 2179-2189.
121