Principles Short History
Principles Short History
Principles Short History
n contrast to the bottom-up evolution of cooperatives in Europe and North America, where
cooperative laws generally followed and recognized the initial development of a cooperative
sector, colonial administrators in many developing countries sought to promote cooperatives
from the top-down. Cooperative law in many countries, beginning in India at the start of the
20th century and spreading to countries of varied colonial and ideological backgrounds, created a
government bureaucracy to guide and develop, rather than merely grant legal recognition to a cooperative sector. The promotion of cooperatives was, in turn, often linked to colonial development
projects; cooperative laws were introduced as a means to increase the production and quality of
crops meant for export, to drag the indigenous population into the monetary economy which would
lead to easier taxation and to introduce a system of politically controlled economic activity.1
1 HANS-H. MNKNER & A. SHAH, INTL LABOUR OFFICE, CREATING A FAVOURABLE CLIMATE AND CONDITIONS FOR COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT IN AFRICA, Working
Paper 7 (1993); see also HANS-H. MNKNER, General Report, in COMPARATIVE STUDY OF THE RELEVANT LAW ON COOPERATIVE SOCIETIES AND OTHER
SELF-HELP ORGANIZATIONS IN AFRICA 26 (1986) (describing introduction of cooperatives to fight against social problems such as dependence
of farmers on merchants or money lenders, and to spread the value systems and norms of behaviour of the colonial master among the
indigenous population (acculturation).).
2 RITA RHODES, Colonial Co-operatives through the eyes of their Cooperative Registrars, in 100 YEARS CO-OPERATIVE CREDIT SOCIETIES ACT, INDIA
1904, 228 (Hans-H. Mnkner ed., 2005).
3 Id. at 229-30.
4 MADHAV V. MADANE, A Century of Cooperative Legislation: From State Control to Autonomy to State Partnership, in 100 YEARS CO-OPERATIVE
CREDIT SOCIETIES ACT, INDIA 1904, 55-57 (Hans-H. Mnkner ed., 2005).
5 HANS-H. MNKNER, The Classical British Indian Pattern of Cooperation: From State-Sponsorship to State Control, in 100 YEARS CO-OPERATIVE
CREDIT SOCIETIES ACT, INDIA 1904, 106-14 (2005).
43
ing societies, but lack the power to coerce and punish.6 Over time, the role of the registrar was to
diminish as the developing cooperatives achieved economic sustainability and the capacity for
self-governance.
Daniel Hamilton, a member of the Imperial Legislative Committee that drafted the 1904 law,
described the active role of the colonial state in cooperative development as linked to the broader
colonial ambitions of the British government.[N]ever forget, he explained,it is to weld India into
one and so enable her to take her rightful place in the world, that the British Government is here
and the wedding hammer in the hand of the government is the Cooperative Movement.7
Contrary to the original intent of diminishing government role in cooperative development, subsequent legislative enactments responded to perceived weaknesses or slowed
growth of the cooperative sector by increasing the registrars powers.
6 Id. at 113-14.
7 Quoted in AKE EDEN, Oriental Economic Thoughts and Cooperative Development on the Pre-Colonial Indian Subcontinent, in 100 YEARS COOPERATIVE CREDIT SOCIETIES ACT, INDIA 1904, 22 (Hans-H. Mnkner ed., 2005).
8 MADHAV V. MADANE, A Century of Cooperative Legislation: From State Control to Autonomy to State Partnership, in 100 YEARS CO-OPERATIVE
CREDIT SOCIETIES ACT, INDIA 1904, 62 (Hans-H. Mnkner ed., 2005).
9 Id. at 62.
10 Id. at 65.
11 Id. at 66-69.
12 HANS-H. MNKNER & A. SHAH, INTL LABOUR OFFICE, Creating a Favourable Climate and Conditions for Cooperative Development in Africa,
9-13 (1993); cf. KRISHAN TAIMNI, INTL LABOUR OFFICE, CREATING A FAVOURABLE CLIMATE AND CONDITIONS FOR COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT IN ASIA (1994)
(discussing implementation of the Classical British Indian model in Asian countries).
44
The rules governing Rochdale Society practices later became known as the Rochdale
Principles, which were used to form other consumer cooperatives around England
and elsewhere.
45
dent businesses.13 And in socialist or former Soviet countries, cooperatives were made arms of the
party and state responsible for implementing central planning decrees.14
Similar to the history in India, many indigenous governments in the post-independence period amended their laws and regulations to increase the role of governments over cooperatives.15
By the 1960s and 1970s, common elements of the legal and institutional frameworks in eastern
block and post-colonial countries included:
Cooperative departments with powers to appoint and remove cooperative management ofcials and to approve basic business decisions;
Legal restrictions on cooperatives to access courts, make contracts, or assume debt without
obtaining permission of the government;
Restrictions of cooperatives to certain lines of business, often excluding them from protable
sectors, such as export agricultural markets;
Restrictions on forming federations to provide necessary services, including insurance, education, and auditing assistance;
In addition to crippling cooperatives economically, heavy state restrictions on business practices led cooperatives in many countries to acquire the stigma of being a state-dominated enterprise. Membership enrollment and involvement in many cooperatives dwindled. State subsidies
became increasingly necessary to sustain enterprises, stressing state budgets.
In the 1980s, structural adjustment programs dictated by the International Monetary Fund
and the World Bank began targeting government expenditures generally, and expenditures on cooperatives in particular. In many countries, when subsidies were decreased or cut off, cooperative
businesses failed.
46
to detect and eliminate provisions contained in laws and regulations which may
have the effect of unduly restricting the development of cooperatives through
discrimination, for instance in regard to taxation or the allocation of licenses and
quotas, or through failure to take account of the special character of cooperatives or of the particular rules of operation of cooperatives;
b.
c.
11. There should be laws or regulations specically concerned with the establishment
and functioning of cooperatives, and with the protection of their right to operate on
not less than equal terms with other forms of enterprise. These laws or regulations
should preferably be applicable to all categories of cooperatives.
12.
1. Such laws and regulations should in any case include provisions on the following
matters:
a. a denition or description of a cooperative bringing out its essential characteristics, namely that it is an association of persons who have voluntarily joined
together to achieve a common end through the formation of a democratically
controlled organization, making equitable contributions to the capital required
and accepting a fair share of the risks and benets of the undertaking in which
the members actively participate;
b. a description of the objects of a cooperative, and procedures for its establishment and registration, the amendment of its statutes and its dissolution;
c. the conditions of membership, such as the maximum amount of each share
and, where appropriate, the proportion of the share due at the moment of
subscription and the time allowed for full payment, as well as the rights and
duties of members, which would be laid down in greater detail in the by-laws
of cooperatives;
d. methods of administration, management and internal audit and procedures for
the establishment and functioning of competent organs;
e. the protection of the name cooperative;
f. machinery for the external audit and guidance of cooperatives and for the
enforcement of the laws and regulations.
2. The procedures provided for in such laws or regulations, in particular the
47
to members at no prot. As the Society developed, it increased its margins and sold goods at normal retail prices, with the prots shared among the members on a pro rata basis according to the
amount spent on purchases during the year. The rules governing Rochdale Society practices later
became known as the Rochdale Principles, which were used to form other consumer cooperatives
around England and elsewhere.16
Variations on the Rochdale Principles were used by national and international cooperative
movements around the world, including by the Patrons of Husbandry (the Grange) in the United
States in 187617 and the International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) in 1937.18 The initial cooperative
development efforts of colonial governments were often based on the Rochdale Principles in form.
But their efforts to cast the state as the ofcial leader of the movement challenged the principle
that cooperatives are subject to democratic control of their members.
In 1995, ICA adopted a new Statement on Cooperative Identity that applies equally to all
cooperatives, and highlights the need to recognize all cooperatives as autonomous businesses, independent from governments.
In 1966, ICA distinguished between principles applicable to fully developed cooperatives and
cooperatives at the beginning of their development.19 For fully developed cooperatives, ICA explained that democracy in the management of cooperative organizations necessarily implies autonomy in the sense of independence of external control. But in the newly-developing countries,
ICA concluded that people who are just beginning to learn cooperation are not always sufciently
well equipped by themselves to manage their societies successfully.20 Thus, the report concluded
that governments in developing countries may insist that proper technical advice is being taken,
including by ask[ing] that its representatives shall sit on boards of management for a time.21
In the same year, the International Labour Organization (ILO) adopted Recommendation 127
concerning the role of cooperatives in the economic and social development of developing countries.22 Although the Recommendation provides a positive set of principles for legal reform, the
section on Administrative Aid endorsed imbuing cooperative supervisory authorities for an initial
period only, with the kinds of powers to appoint cooperative staff and give guidance and advice
that were then being used to dominate cooperatives in many developing countries.
The problems faced by state-dominated cooperatives through the 1970s and 1980s prompted
a reexamination of the state role in cooperative development.23 In 1995, ICA adopted a new State16 David Thompson, Cooperative Principles Then and Now, 53 COOPERATIVE GROCER (July-Aug. 1994), available at www.cooperativegrocer.
coop/articles/index.php?id=158.
17 JAMES R. BAARDA, COOPERATIVE PRINCIPLES AND STATUTES: LEGAL DESCRIPTIONS OF UNIQUE ENTERPRISES, U. S. Dept of Agric., AGRIC. COOP. SERV. RESEARCH
REP. NO. 54 (1986).
18 See INTL CO-OP. INFO. CTR., PRINCIPLES, available at www.wisc.edu/uwcc/icic/def-hist/gen-info/.
19 INTL COOP. INFO. CTR., Report of the ICA Commission on Co-operative Principles (1966), available at www.wisc.edu/uwcc/icic/def-hist/geninfo/Report-of-the-ICA-Commission-on-Co-opera1/index.html.
20 Id. (explaining that it must be recognised that, in co-operatives which are themselves at the beginning of their development, their
democratic organs also are very probably underdeveloped and, likewise, the capacity of their members for carrying out democratic
procedures efciently and for submitting readily to democratic discipline.).
21 Id.
22 INTL LABOUR OFFICE, RECOMMENDATION 127: THE ROLE OF COOPERATIVES IN THE ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES (1996).
23 See ALFRED HANEL, STATE-SPONSORED COOPERATIVES AND SELF-RELIANCE: SOME ASPECTS OF THE REORGANIZATION OF OFFICIALIZED COOPERATIVE STRUCTURES WITH
REGARD TO AFRICA (1989); HANS-H. MNKNER, African Co-operatives and the State in the 1990s, in YEARBOOK OF COOP. ENTER. (1992); INTL LABOUR
OFFICE, THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE STATE AND COOPERATIVES IN COOPERATIVE LEGISLATION: REPORT OF A COLLOQUIUM HELD AT GENEVA, 14-15 Dec. 1993
(1994); SANJEEV CHOPRA, CTR. FOR CO-OPS. & RURAL DEV., CO-OPERATIVES: FROM CONTROLS TO A REGULATORY FRAMEWORK: POLICIES FOR THE SAARC REGION
(Book World 1999).
48
49
ment on Cooperative Identity that applies equally to all cooperatives, and highlights the need
to recognize all cooperatives as autonomous businesses, independent from governments.24 Soon
thereafter the ILO initiated a multi-year process to reconsider Recommendation 127, resulting in
the adoption of Recommendation 193 in 2002. Recommendation 193 eliminates the previous endorsement of administrative intervention in cooperative affairs and adopts ICAs Statement on
Cooperative Identity as applying to all cooperatives.25
Today, there is a new consensus among cooperative movements and development practitioners that rejects separate standards for laws for cooperatives in developing countries and strongly
endorses the autonomy of all cooperatives from government control.26 CLARITY evolves out of this
new consensus and aims to push its ideals into implementation.
50