Su and Lin (2014) PDF
Su and Lin (2014) PDF
Su and Lin (2014) PDF
Tourism Management
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/tourman
h i g h l i g h t s
Investigate in the positive inuence of world heritage sites on international tourist arrivals.
Divide the sample into several groups according to the number of WHSs to study effects of WHSs across these groups.
Explore the pooled, xed and random effect models with panel data (66 countries, 2000e2009).
Eliminate the problem of time-invariant variables in panel data model by increasing the number of countries.
a r t i c l e i n f o
a b s t r a c t
Article history:
Received 19 August 2012
Accepted 24 April 2013
This study examines the impact on inbound tourism caused by the presence of world heritage sites. The
statistics are derived from panel data for 66 countries for the period 2006e2009. The results indicate that
there exists a positive relationship between having such heritage sites and tourist numbers, and the
relationship is stronger for natural rather than for cultural heritage sites. The evidence also indicates the
presence of a U-shaped relationship between numbers of world heritage sites in a country and tourist
numbers. These relationships are found to be robust even though differences in patterns are found in
different regions.
2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
JELS:
L83
C23
Keywords:
WHSs
Tourism demand
Cultural sites
Natural sites
Panel data
1. Introduction
Tourism is one of the leading economic sectors in the world, and
represents a major source of income, employment, exports and
taxes. According to the World Travel and Tourism Council (WTTC),
in 2011 the tourism sector (domestic and international) contributed
almost 5992 billion USD to the global economy. With conrmed
strong linkage effects, the tourism industry also provides almost
260 million job opportunities, accounting for nearly 9% of global
employment. In addition, according to the World Bank Carbon
Finance Unit (CFU) the tourism sector is relatively eco-friendly
compared to the manufacturing sector, and has led to more
* Corresponding author. Tel.: 886 2 2321 7730; fax: 886 2 2322 5657.
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (Y.-W. Su), [email protected]
(H.-L. Lin).
0261-5177/$ e see front matter 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2013.04.005
sustainable development. Therefore, many countries are emphasizing the development of tourism to drive their green economic
growth.
As disposable incomes and the awareness of the importance of
leisure have increased, so too have the numbers of tourists (Lim,
2006). World Tourism Organization (WTO) statistics reveal the
growth of international tourist arrivals (the x-axis on the righthand side) between 1995 and 2011, as shown in Fig. 1. The number of international tourist arrivals increased from 538 million in
1995 to 940 million in 2010, representing growth of 4.7% on average
in each year. Meanwhile, according to the World Heritage Centre of
the United Nations Educational, Scientic and Cultural Organization (UNESCO), the total number of World Heritage Sites (WHSs)
has risen steadily. Fig. 1 also shows that the number of WHSs (the xaxis on the left-hand side) increased from 468 in 1995 to 936 in
2011, or by 6% per year on average. Thus, these growing trends
appear to suggest that, if the positive effect of WHSs on international tourism is proved, having such sites will lead to increases in
1000
1000
900
900
800
800
700
700
600
600
500
400
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
500
47
400
2011
Fig. 1. Numbers of world heritage sites and international tourist arrivals. Source: The
World Tourism Organization (The International tourist arrivals), The World Heritage
Centre, UNESCO (The number of WHSs).
international tourist arrivals and consequently tourism expenditure, thereby beneting the economies of the destination countries.
However, there have so far been few studies on this subject.
In this paper, we investigate the relationship between the WHSs
and tourism demand not only for specic countries but also on a
worldwide level. First, by using data on the number of WHSs in 66
countries between 2000 and 2009, we explore the positive inuence of these sites on international tourist arrivals (international
tourism demand). Second, we divide our sample into several
groups according to the number of WHSs and study the different
effects of WHSs on international tourism demand across these
groups. Third, we apply various xed and random effects models to
the panel data. In addition, we increase the number of countries in
the panel data model to eliminate the problem of time-invariant
variables, or rarely changing variables.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2,
we provide a literature review together with an analytical framework of WHSs and international tourism worldwide. In Section 3,
we introduce the models setting and the methodology of the panel
data. In Section 4, we present the results of the analysis and discuss
the economic implications. In Section 5, we conclude.
2. World heritage sites and international tourists
In this section, we provide a literature review and briey
describe the analytical framework of WHSs and international
tourism worldwide based on the current situation.
2.1. Literature review
As the number of tourists increase, governments and private
enterprises around the world have been eager to expand their
tourism. Many studies have examined the key elements affecting
tourism demand (e.g., Dhariwala, 2005; Dougan, 2007; Dritsakis,
2004; Naude and Saayman, 2005; Patsouratis, Frangouli, &
Anastasopoulos, 2005; Payne and Mervar, 2002; Tan, McCahon, &
Miller, 2002). It has also been found that tourism destinations
with typical cultural or natural elements constitute one of the chief
attractions for international tourists (e.g., Bille and Schulze, 2008;
Bonet, 2003; Cooke and Lazzaretti, 2008; Deng, King, & Bauer,
2002; Dritsakis, 2004).
Since cultural or natural attractions lead to increased tourism
demand, it could be argued that those attractions that are ofcially
authenticated, i.e., inscribed on the list of WHSs by UNESCO, should
be relatively appealing to international tourists. WHSs have been
found to have signicantly positive effects on the promotion of
domestic or foreign tourism in some specic countries, such as
England (e.g., Herbert, 2001; McIntosh and Prentice, 1999), China
Fig. 2. Number of world heritage sites by location in 2009. Source: The World Heritage
Centre, UNESCO.
(e.g., Li, Wu, & Cai, 2008; Yang, Lin, & Han, 2010) and Germany,
Hungary and Romania (Light, 2000). Nevertheless, studies on the
positive effect of WHSs on tourism have been limited to a single
country, and little research has been done to expand this effect to a
worldwide level.
In addition, in terms of the methodology adopted, some studies
employ the panel data model (e.g., Garin-Munoz and Amaral, 2000;
Ledesma-Rodriguez, Navarro-Ibanez, & Perez-Rodriguez, 2001;
Maloney and Montes-Rojas, 2005; Naude and Saayman, 2005; Yang
et al., 2010), because of the availability of the data. However, in the
panel data model, the problem of time-invariant variables, or rarely
changing variables, is widely discussed (Cellini, 2011; Yang and Lin,
2011). In this paper, we also use the panel data model, and the
number of countries is increased to eliminate the problem of timeinvariant variables.
Italy
Spain
China
Germany
France
Mexico
U.K.
India
Russia
U.S.
Greece
Brazil
Australia
Canada
Sweden
Japan
Poland
Portugal
Iran
Czech
Cultural site
Natural site
Mixed site
0
10
20
30
Number of world heritage sites
40
Fig. 3. Top 20 countries in terms of world heritage sites in 2009. Source: The World
Heritage Centre, UNESCO.
48
(1)
France
U.S.
Spain
China
Italy
U.K.
Turkey
Germany
Mexico
Austria
Canada
Greece
Thailand
Egypt
Poland
Netherlands
Croatia
Hungary
Morocco
Switzerland
0
10
20
30
40
50
Tourist arrivals (million)
60
70
80
Fig. 4. Top 20 countries in terms of international tourist arrivals in 2009. Source: The World Tourism Organization.
gj AREAjit
10
X
and cannot improve the model, so they are omitted from the model.
More details about our variables are shown in Table 1, which provides the denitions and descriptive statistics of the variables.
3.2. Varying marginal effect of world heritage sites
49
gk YEARkit qi 3 it
k1
(2)
where the dependent variable, ARRI, is the international tourist
arrivals in country i at time t, which is often treated as the tourism
demand in the literature (e.g., Lim, 2006; Song and Li, 2008). WHS
represents the number of world heritage sites, which is the main
explanatory variable (xit) we are interested in. If the sign of its coefcient, d, is positive, we could say that possessing WHSs would
enhance international tourism after controlling other variables. In
addition, we have replaced WHS by CULTURAL and NATURAL, the
numbers of cultural and natural WHSs, to differentiate the effects of
cultural and natural WHSs on international tourism demand.
The other explanatory variables (zit), are regarded as control variables capturing some possible factors which would inuence the demand. The gross domestic product (GDP) variable represents the
income level, which also captures the degree of economic development in the destination country. The population variable (POP) mainly
controls the size of the destination country. That is, after considering
POP, the effect of the GDP and other explanatory variables could be
measured accurately under the same scale of population. For example,
the positive coefcient of GDP means that among countries with the
same population, international tourists prefer to travel to the richer
one with higher income. Moreover, EX denotes the ofcial exchange
rate between the local currency unit (LCU) and the U.S. dollar, which
represents the price factor in the demand function. If EX goes up, the
traveling price (cost) increases, in which case the number of international tourist arrivals would decrease based on the law of demand.
In addition, the total railway lines (RAIL) in terms of kilometers in
destination countries is employed as a proxy variable for the availability of infrastructure. A country that possesses more railway lines is
a country in which it is more convenient to travel, and this will attract
more international tourists. The FREEDOM variable is the index of
political rights and civil liberties, which is measured on a one-toseven scale. Theoretically, a smaller value of FREEDOM represents a
freer political and civil environment that would make international
tourists feel more secure without red tape and increase their willingness to travel. Moreover, the HEALTH variable is the percentage of
health expenditure in GDP, and is used as a proxy variable for the
environmental sanitation in destination countries. If a country spends
more money caring for its residents health, the sanitary condition in
the country will be further improved. To measure the health quality of
residents and the educational environment in destination countries,
the percentage of expenditure on education in GDP (EDU) is also used
as a proxy variable. In addition, to control the time and regional factors, YEAR and AREA are dummy variables denoting the time from
2000 to 2009 and the geographical position of 6 areas, respectively.
However, there is a potential simultaneous relationship between tourist arrivals and some explanatory variables, such as GDP,
and so variables in the form of a lag of one period enter the equation. The results turn out to be quite consistent with those without
the lag term. Thus, to keep the sample size as large as possible
(using the lag term will reduce the sample size by 66 observations),
we choose the original models without lag terms. Other possible
explanatory variables, such as FDI (measuring the openness level),
WHSs in danger, global infectious diseases, or interaction terms,
have also been considered but have turned out to be insignicant
vARRIit
d
vWHSit
(3)
ARRIit a
S
X
s1
6
X
gj AREAjit
j1
10
X
gk YEARkit qi 3 it
k1
(4)
where gsit is the dummy variable for the sth group of the WHS. The
data are divided into S equal parts, according to the number of
WHSs. The WHSit multiplied by gits make us focus on the marginal
effect for a specic range of the number of WHSs.
However, when we decide to divide our sample, the rst question
is concerned with how many groups we would obtain. On the one
hand, if S is too large, which means that the number of groups is large,
the small size of the subsample would give rise to highly sensitive
estimated results. On the other hand, if S is too small, say, S 2 (as a
result of dividing the sample into two equal parts), the large subsample would reveal little of the varying marginal effect of the WHSs.
Moreover, we should note that the WHS is a discrete right-skewed
variable, which means that the number of WHSs is an integer and
the data are concentrated in small numbers. In this distribution, it is
impossible to divide the data into too many equal parts.
As a result, we start with three equal parts and extend this to
seven equal parts (S 3, 4 .7). It turns out that when S is equal to 4,
the decrease pattern is the same as the one when S is equal to 3.
When S is bigger than 5, the estimated results of the U-curve effect
would be similar to the case where S 5. Therefore, in this paper, we
present two representative results, S 3 and S 5, because they are
the smallest groups to capture the pattern of varying marginal effects and perform well in dividing the data into several equal parts.
3.3. Methodology
To understand the preliminary sign of each determinant, pooled
ordinary least squares (OLS) regression is employed at rst (e.g.,
Naude and Saayman, 2005; Yang et al., 2010). Thus, the pooled OLS
residual (uit) is the summation of the country-specic unobserved
variable (qi) and the error term with a normal distribution (3 it):
uit qi 3 it
(5)
We run the BreuschePagan test (BeP test) to test for heteroskedasticity (qi s 0) in the pooled OLS models (Breusch & Pagan,
50
Table 1
Denitions of variables and basic statistics.
Variable
Description
ARRI
WHS
CULTURAL
NATURAL
GDP
POP
EX
RAIL
FREEDOM
HEALTH
EDU
AREA
YEAR
Mean
Max
3.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
809.00
44.00
42.00
12.00
246.21
42.68
659.77
11545.25
5.19
6.35
15.48
1029.56
143.00
2078.67
25988.60
2.18
2.22
5.50
0.25
0.03
0.00
251.00
1.00
0.01
6.20
11670.80
1331.38
17065.08
228999.00
7.00
16.21
71.09
.25
Density
.15
.05
.05
.1
.1
.15
.2
Density
Min
1100.00
7.29
6.33
1.89
RAIL, HEALTH, and EDU) are collected from the World Development
Indicators (WDI) of the World Bank Online Resources. The data for
the freedom index (FREEDOM) come from the annual report of
Freedom House.
When combining these four data sets, we try to collect as many
informative observations as we possibly can. However, there are
missing data, more or less, for each variable, and especially for
some developing countries whose statistical surveys are less
comprehensive. To focus on countries with relatively more information and avoid too much missing data causing a severe problem
of data imbalance in the panel data, countries with too many kinds
of data unavailable are deleted without loss. We originally collected
the data for the WHSs of 148 countries. After combining data sets,
the data actually used consist of 66 countries. The data distributions
of WHSs before and after combining the data are shown in Fig. 5.
The countries deleted are mostly those containing few or no WHSs.
One thing we should mention is that, among these observations,
there is only one, Israel in 2000, that possesses zero WHSs.
Therefore, sifting the observations cannot only simplify the
analysis but also will not critically affect the estimated results. In
this research, the panel data comprise 66 countries over the period
from 2000 to 2009 with 359 observations after deducting the
missing data for each variable. The names of these 66 countries are
listed in Appendix A.
Two things should be mentioned. First, the literature shows that
the characteristics of the source country may somehow affect the
tourism demand. However, what we only know is the annual
.2
.25
S.D.
5355.10
5.50
4.23
1.09
10
20
30
40
Number of WHSs
10
20
Number of WHSs
Fig. 5. Distribution of WHSs.
30
40
51
between the pooled OLS regression and the panel data model (both
the xed and random effects models). This result proves that the
country-specic effect should be considered. If we were to just grab
the data and run the regression directly, the estimated results
would be unreliable.
According to the Hausman test, in which the Chi-square statistics are insignicant at the 5% signicance level, the random effects
model, as in Model (3) and Model (6), performs better. This result is
quite reasonable. Because the data comprise a cross section of
countries, in considering the sampling problem, it makes sense to
assume that the omitted variable is distributed randomly. Note that
Model (5), the xed effects model, unexpectedly performs better at
the 10% signicance level. This may be caused by the imprecise
setting of the WHSs, which are assumed to have constant effects.
When the varying effects of WHSs are considered later, all the
random effects models are found to perform better.
In Model (3), the number of WHSs has a signicantly positive
effect on international tourist arrivals. That is, adding one WHS
would on average increase the number of international tourist arrivals by 382,637 in just one year after controlling other variables.
Thus, this positive effect proves that a country possessing more
WHSs would promote international tourism, not only for some
specic countries but for the whole world. Moreover, possessing
more WHSs increases the international tourism demand, which
also brings in relatively more tourist expenditures to the tourismrelated industries, such as accommodation, transportation or
even retail outlets located around the site. These industrial linkages
will generate several times the revenue earned from the visits to
the WHSs themselves.
In Model (6), both the cultural and natural WHSs have significantly positive effects on the number of international tourist arrivals when other variables are controlled. Increasing the number
of cultural sites by one would create an additional 396,659 international tourist arrivals, while adding one more natural site
would increase international tourist arrivals by 418,606, which is
on average 21,947 more tourist arrivals than for an additional
cultural one. To sum up, both the cultural and natural world heritage sites could enhance international tourism, and the effect is
greater for the natural world heritage sites than for the cultural
ones.
Models (3) and (6) assume that the marginal effect of WHSs is
constant, which is quite a simplication. However, the marginal
Table 2
Estimated results of international tourist arrivals (with constant effects of WHSs).
WHS
(1)
Pooled OLS
(2)
Fixed effects
(3)
Random effects
533384.15***
[11.77]
89416.14
[0.64]
382637.04***
[4.69]
CULTURAL
NATURAL
Control var.
Constant
Yes
6461538.15***
[3.54]
BeP test
116.26***
(p-value 0.000)
Hausman test
R-square
Chi-square
Observations
Yes
3396688.79
[1.43]
Yes
3148908.15
[1.41]
(4)
Pooled OLS
(5)
Fixed effects
(6)
Random effects
563357.95***
[10.79]
637057.13***
[4.57]
15548.61
[0.09]
292458.01
[1.07]
396658.60***
[4.16]
418605.71**
[2.10]
Yes
6531921.78***
[3.60]
Yes
3631736.20
[1.53]
Yes
3099144.91
[1.38]
111.78***
(p-value 0.000)
0.815
22.00
(p-value 0.143)
0.539
359
359
0.737
461.239***
359
0.818
25.27*
(p-value 0.089)
0.547
359
359
0.739
460.099***
359
52
effect may vary according to the number of WHSs. That is, the effect
of WHSs on international tourist arrivals may differ between
countries with an abundant supply of WHSs and countries with few
WHSs. Thus, to better understand the marginal effect of WHSs for a
specic range of numbers, we have divided our sample into three
and ve equal parts. Still, the pooled OLS, xed effects and random
effects models of Eq. (4) are estimated. The pooled OLS model is
tested for heteroskedasticity by BeP test, and the latter two models
are judged using the Hausman test. According to the test results, all
the random effects models, i.e., Model (9), (12), (15) and (18), are
more accurate (Table 3).
In Model (9), just like in the previous analysis, the marginal
effect of the WHSs is positive. Moreover, this positive effect declines
as the number of WHSs rises. For countries possessing 0e5, 6e11
and more than 12 WHSs, the marginal effects of WHSs are around
692, 495, and 408 thousand, respectively. The positive effect of
WHSs on international tourist arrivals is larger in countries with
fewer WHSs. This result is quite reasonable. For WHS-poor countries, once unknown sites become famous after being included on
the WHS list, this will attract more visits from international tourists. On the contrary, for WHS-abundant countries, which already
possess many attractions and are famous in the global tourism
market, adding one more WHS will result in a smaller increase in
inbound tourists than for WHS-poor countries.
Correspondingly, in Model (12), both cultural and natural sites
have positive effects on international tourist arrivals. These effects
also decrease as the number of cultural and natural WHSs increases. The marginal effects are 562, 490 and 402 thousand for
countries with 0e5, 6e11 and more than 12 cultural WHSs,
respectively. Meanwhile, for countries with 0e3 and more than 4
natural WHSs, the marginal effects are 514 and 419 thousand,
respectively. Note that because the sample size of natural WHSs is
relatively small, it is divided into two equal parts only.
Table 3
Estimated results of international tourist arrivals (with 3 variant effects of WHSs).
WHS (0e5)
WHS (6e11)
WHS (12 up)
(7)
Pooled OLS
(8)
Fixed effects
(9)
Random effects
649675.36***
[3.42]
524222.32***
[6.37]
552693.31***
[11.03]
471627.62***
[2.34]
261853.32*
[1.74]
148088.03
[1.07]
691823.08***
[4.30]
494946.73***
[5.13]
408442.34***
[4.91]
CULTURAL (0e5)
CULTURAL (6e11)
CULTURAL (12 up)
NATURAL (0e3)
NATURAL (4 up)
Control var.
Constant
Yes
6738359.51***
[3.50]
BeP test
132.97***
(p-value 0.000)
Hausman test
R-square
Chi-square
Observations
Yes
1631441.45
[0.67]
Yes
4313752.97*
[1.87]
(10)
Pooled OLS
(11)
Fixed effects
(12)
Random effects
343297.35
[1.60]
415442.66***
[4.64]
574952.78***
[10.33]
328116.38
[1.44]
149397.07
[0.78]
45192.87
[0.26]
561704.25***
[2.96]
489724.36***
[4.35]
402313.64***
[4.14]
1245048.05***
[4.24]
525079.02***
[3.59]
431978.19
[1.39]
319811.62
[0.85]
514498.16*
[1.88]
419242.31*
[1.82]
Yes
6414358.53***
[3.40]
Yes
2276009.67
[0.93]
Yes
3789343.37
[1.63]
165.27***
(p-value 0.000)
0.816
22.37
(p-value 0.216)
0.537
359
359
0.733
466.364***
359
0.823
23.03
(p-value 0.288)
0.537
359
359
0.734
455.597***
359
53
Table 4
Estimated results of international tourist arrivals (with 5 variant effects of WHSs).
WHS (0e3)
WHS (4e6)
WHS (7e10)
WHS (11e20)
WHS (21 up)
(13)
Pooled OLS
(14)
Fixed effects
(15)
Random effects
717354.26***
[2.38]
585643.22***
[3.95]
531494.95***
[5.83]
299724.16***
[4.54]
716652.88***
[13.62]
759195.41***
[2.86]
346695.08*
[1.91]
254907.28*
[1.64]
107881.51
[0.76]
184221.66
[1.27]
975394.75***
[4.15]
580418.01***
[4.06]
498169.26***
[4.61]
356668.67***
[4.01]
474846.97***
[5.42]
CULTURAL (0e3)
CULTURAL (4e6)
CULTURAL (7e10)
CULTURAL (11e20)
CULTURAL (21 up)
NATURAL (0e3)
NATURAL (4 up)
GDP
(16)
Pooled OLS
(17)
Fixed effects
(18)
Random effects
214136.49
[0.86]
389665.43***
[2.75]
289594.82***
[3.21]
354390.56***
[5.20]
913255.68***
[12.23]
446149.55
[1.59]
33589.64
[0.16]
45539.87
[0.23]
129725.75
[0.73]
131702.65
[0.79]
776329.93***
[3.29]
360513.45***
[2.34]
373257.65***
[3.08]
284574.55***
[2.75]
508761.04***
[5.16]
1259993.21***
[4.52]
439219.79***
[3.26]
599675.81**
[2.13]
158265.28
[0.44]
750817.04***
[2.93]
298612.05
[1.34]
1011.06***
[4.09]
22989.06***
[7.83]
392.67***
[2.96]
168.28***
[10.78]
167820.66
[1.18]
200791.39
[1.48]
354455.52***
[7.00]
3912.38***
[2.73]
25653.01
[0.76]
158.20
[1.02]
47.84*
[1.83]
460859.81***
[2.37]
516818.85***
[3.00]
51271.76
[1.17]
1191.96***
[2.36]
14762.50***
[3.31]
102.65
[0.81]
102.34***
[6.07]
217766.63*
[1.69]
308048.78**
[2.01]
1071.33
[0.03]
351.46
[1.29]
18369.94***
[6.30]
514.67***
[3.85]
206.62***
[11.49]
258111.45*
[1.80]
157775.79
[1.16]
332053.13***
[6.65]
3096.00**
[2.17]
22490.11
[0.69]
149.48
[1.00]
61.58***
[2.39]
518235.42***
[2.69]
359633.58**
[2.14]
48415.31
[1.14]
1026.69**
[1.99]
11419.79***
[2.46]
115.16
[0.92]
109.33***
[6.56]
273159.23*
[1.64]
231209.95
[1.52]
7087.38
[0.17]
AREA
YEAR
Constant
Yes
Yes
6039499.56***
[3.12]
Yes
Yes
1659178.51
[0.68]
Yes
Yes
4300985.68*
[1.85]
Yes
Yes
6256850.52***
[3.46]
Yes
Yes
4221109.45*
[1.75]
Yes
Yes
2887056.58
[1.23]
BeP test
181.48***
(p-value 0.000)
POP
EX
RAIL
FREEDOM
HEALTH
EDU
Hausman test
R-square
Chi-square
Observations
223.73***
(p-value 0.000)
0.841
19.79
(p-value 0.471)
0.558
359
359
0.749
486.3***
359
0.843
11.37
(p-value 0.955)
0.486
359
359
0.739
506.274***
359
1600
Tourist arrivals(1000)
WHSs
Cultural WHSs
Natural WHSs
1200
800
400
0-3
4-6
7-10
11-20
Number of WHSs
20 up
natural sites that are included in the model. In Model (15), for
example, the marginal effect of GDP is positive, which means that
tourism demand benets from economic development. When the
GDP of the destination country (GDP) increases by 1 billion USD,
international tourist arrivals will increase by 1192. Meanwhile, the
signicantly negative effect of the population (POP) indicates that,
when other things are equal, international tourists would like to
travel to destinations with fewer people or smaller country size.
For instance, among countries with the same numbers of WHSs,
economic achievements, and infrastructure, etc., international
tourists would be more likely to choose those smaller in size or
that are less crowded. This kind of destination may be easier to
travel around or more suitable for short vacation arrangements. In
addition, railway lines (RAIL) have a positive effect on international tourist arrivals, with the number of international tourist
arrivals increasing by 102 for each extra kilometer that the
54
railroad route is extended. It thus makes sense that the destination will be more attractive to international tourists when the
basic transportation is more convenient. The political and civil
freedom (FREEDOM) variable negatively affects the tourism demand at the 10% signicance level. When the index of freedom,
measured on a one-to-seven scale, increases by one (becoming
less free), the number of international tourist arrivals declines by
217,767. That is, freer countries attract more international tourists.
In addition, the health expenditure share of GDP (HEALTH) has a
positive inuence. When a country spends more money on health,
say, 1% of GDP, it will improve the sanitary conditions and increase
its inbound tourist visits by 308,048.
The effects of other controlled variables, namely, the exchange
rate (EX) and the expenditure proportion of education (EDU), are
insignicant in Model (15). However, it should be noted that the
sign of the exchange rate is negative, which means that
increasing the relative price will make the number of international tourist arrivals drop. Thus, the price effect of tourism exists, even though the coefcient is insignicant at the 10%
signicance level.
4.2. Comparison of regions and time periods
The behavior of tourists may vary in different destinations, and
some effects may also change over time. Therefore, based on Model
(15), we separate our observations according to the region and the
time period to reveal more details. This further research may also
be seen as a robustness check of our model, especially for WHS
variables. The estimated results of eight models are classied
Table 5
Estimated results of international tourist arrivals (by region).
(19)
Africa
(20)
Asia
(21)
Europe
(22)
America
WHS (11e20)
311945.43
[1.48]
700653.37***
[5.26]
668600.19***
[8.44]
e
569240.22
[1.21]
306748.19
[1.18]
578652.66***
[2.35]
27387.03
[0.18]
52326.23
[0.31]
1556751.62***
[3.48]
895027.86***
[4.09]
633983.70***
[4.54]
428506.56***
[3.38]
465289.26
[1.41]
1491710.19
[0.59]
368894.77
[0.31]
601731.02
[1.50]
1309071.96***
[3.57]
1133299.43***
[5.19]
GDP
6097.11
[0.30]
21793.65
[0.57]
102.11
[0.52]
226.39***
[2.61]
88542.01
[0.80]
119010.42
[0.60]
71233.96
[1.53]
350.46
[0.63]
15756.36***
[4.51]
134.88
[1.06]
245.68***
[4.93]
11224.13
[0.05]
271410.15
[1.10]
78745.46
[1.02]
4338.24
[0.86]
455643.96***
[6.01]
1130.06
[1.00]
278.66*
[1.72]
1270677.58***
[3.07]
450324.73**
[2.04]
107376.01
[0.79]
4629.76***
[2.73]
108256.42***
[2.46]
1709.17
[0.43]
43.47
[0.58]
1696149.2
[0.54]
689745.98
[0.95]
522070.2
[1.34]
AREA
YEAR
Constant
No
Yes
2510878.64
[1.56]
No
Yes
92106.25
[0.03]
No
Yes
2528566.8
[1.11]
No
Yes
19603323.34
[1.14]
R-square
Chi-square
Observations
0.956
719.79***
53
0.542
109.96***
126
0.891
1003.18***
145
0.997
5060.39***
35
WHS (0e3)
WHS (4e6)
WHS (7e10)
POP
EX
RAIL
FREEDOM
HEALTH
EDU
55
Table 6
Estimated results of international tourist arrivals (by time period).
WHS (0e3)
WHS (4e6)
WHS (7e10)
WHS (10e20)
WHS (21 up)
GDP
POP
EX
RAIL
FREEDOM
HEALTH
EDU
(23)
2000e2001
(24)
2002e2003
(25)
2004e2006
(26)
2007e2009
479370.55
[0.08]
411201.49*
[1.82]
343859.20**
[2.09]
360265.29***
[2.54]
376666.37***
[2.77]
403720.74
[1.05]
394058.86
[1.32]
307086.84**
[2.08]
245966.27*
[1.88]
542954.80**
[4.32]
613022.27*
[1.65]
442751.21*
[1.92]
510984.50***
[2.64]
271689.13*
[1.70]
834250.42***
[5.95]
1227144.45***
[4.47]
309651.41
[1.50]
284435.48*
[1.70]
224635.71
[1.48]
909319.29***
[4.93]
685.57
[1.04]
18545.22***
[3.36]
1047.28
[0.90]
179.00***
[3.73]
256215.71
[0.63]
311163.79
[0.78]
24163.51
[0.32]
828.67
[1.47]
21720.38***
[4.94]
475.25
[1.38]
162.64***
[3.94]
527021.99
[1.43]
340883.73
[1.36]
106243.45*
[1.91]
853.48
[0.91]
4842.39
[0.27]
344.05
[0.81]
52.80***
[3.69]
13912.68
[0.04]
2511.2
[0.01]
64066.16
[1.11]
711.92
[0.64]
175.16
[0.01]
193.14
[0.75]
318.41***
[4.22]
123137.59
[0.65]
82209.48
[0.62]
50353.33
[1.04]
2306389.69***
[3.72]
SARS
359981.67
[0.57]
H1N1
AREA
YEAR
Constant
Yes
No
3827725.47
[0.58]
Yes
No
2939585.09
[0.81]
Yes
No
2011503.17
[0.57]
Yes
No
2696260.86
[0.86]
R-square
Chi-square
Observations
0.825
170.96
72
0.889
262.29
70
0.839
207.1
120
0.782
188.65
97
1600
1600
Africa
Asia
Europe
America
(B)
Tourist arrivals(1000)
(A)
Tourist arrivals(1000)
1200
2000-2001
2002-2003
2004-2006
2007-2009
7-10
11-20
20 up
1200
800
400
800
400
0
0-3
4-6
7-10
11-20
20 up
0-3
Number of WHSs
Fig. 7. Marginal effects of WHSs (by region and time period).
4-6
Number of WHSs
56
Table 7
Contribution of newly-inscribed WHSs in 2011.
Newly-inscribed WHSs in 2011
In-sample countries
Petroglyphic Complexes of the Mongolian Altai
Coffee Cultural Landscape of Colombia
Selimiye Mosque and its Social Complex
The Persian Garden
Hiraizumi (Temples, Gardens and Archaeological
Sites Representing the Buddhist Pure Land)
Ogasawara Islands
Ningaloo Coast
Fagus Factory in Alfeld
The Causses and the Cvennes, Mediterranean
agro-pastoral Cultural Landscape
West Lake Cultural Landscape of Hangzhou
Cultural Landscape of the Serra de Tramuntana
Longobards in Italy. Places of the Power (568e774 A.D.)
Country
# of
WHSs
Marginal effect of
WHSs (1000)
(A)
Average
receipt (USD)
(B)
C
C
C
C
C
Mongolia
Colombia
Turkey
Iran
Japan
3
7
10
13
16
975
498
498
357
357
616
1244
965
1136
1846
600
620
480
405
659
N
N
C
C
Japan
Australia
Germany
France
16
19
36
37
357
357
475
475
1846
4990
1959
763
659
1781
931
362
C
C
C
China
Spain
Italy
41
43
47
475
475
475
838
1141
970
398
542
461
United Arab
Emirates
Barbados
Sudan
Nicaragua
Jordan
Ukraine
Syrian Arab
Republic
Kenya
Kenya
Senegal
Vietnam
Ethiopia
975
1032
1006
1
2
2
4
5
6
975
975
975
580
580
580
2162
712
358
916
209
621
2108
694
349
531
121
360
6
6
6
7
9
580
580
580
498
498
807
807
542
814
3391
468
468
314
405
1689
Out-of-sample countries
Cultural Sites of Al Ain (Hat, Hili, Bidaa
Bint Saud and Oases Areas)
Historic Bridgetown and its Garrison
Archaeological Sites of the Island of Meroe
Len Cathedral
Wadi Rum Protected Area
Residence of Bukovinian and Dalmatian Metropolitans
Ancient Villages of Northern Syria
C
C
C
M
C
C
C
N
C
C
C
Contribution of
WHSs (million USD)
(A) (B)
Type
57
Argentina
Belgium
Chile
Armenia
Benin
China
Australia
Brazil
Colombia
Austria
Bulgaria
Croatia
Azerbaijan
Cameroon
Czech
Republic
Egypt
Estonia
Finland
France
Georgia
Greece
Hungary
Indonesia Iran
Ireland
Italy
Japan
Korea
Kyrgyzstan Latvia
Madagascar Malaysia
Mali
Mexico
Moldova
Morocco
Netherlands Norway
Pakistan
Peru
Poland
Portugal
Romania Russia
Saudi Arabia
Slovenia
South Africa Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Tunisia
Turkey
Ukraine
U.K.
U.S.
Bangladesh
Canada
Denmark
Germany
Israel
Lithuania
Mongolia
Philippines
Slovakia
Thailand
Uruguay
References
Bille, T., & Schulze, G. G. (2008). Culture in urban and regional development. In
V. A. Ginsburgh, & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of art and
culture). Amsterdam: North Holland-Elsevier.
Bonet, L. (2003). Cultural tourism. In R. Towse (Ed.), A handbook of cultural economics). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Breusch, T. S., & Pagan, A. R. (1979). Simple test for heteroscedasticity and random
coefcient variation. Econometrica, 47(5), 1287e1294.
Cellini, R. (2011). Is UNESCO recognition effective in fostering tourism? A comment
on Yang, Lin and Han. Tourism Management, 32, 452e454.
Chamberlain, G. (1984). Panel data. InHandbook of econometrics, Vol. 2, (pp. 1247e
1318). Amsterdam: North Holland.
Cooke, P., & Lazzaretti, L. (2008). Creative cities, cultural clusters and local economic
development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Deng, J., King, B., & Bauer, T. (2002). Evaluating natural attractions for tourism.
Annals of Tourism Research, 29(2), 422e438.
Dhariwala, R. (2005). Tourist arrivals in India: how important are domestic disorders? Tourism Economics, 11(2), 185e205.
Dougan, J. W. (2007). Analysis of Japanese tourist demand in Guam. Asia Pacic
Journal of Tourism Research, 12(2), 79e88.
Dritsakis, N. (2004). Cointegration analysis of German and British tourism demand
for Greece. Tourism Management, 25(1), 111e119.
Garin-Munoz, T., & Amaral, T. P. (2000). An econometric model for international
tourism ow in Spain. Applied Economics Letters, 7, 525e529.
Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specication test in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251e1271.
Herbert, D. (2001). Literary places, tourism and the heritage experience. Annals of
Tourism Research, 28(2), 312e333.
Ledesma-Rodriguez, F. J., Navarro-Ibanez, M., & Perez-Rodriguez, J. V. (2001). Panel
data and tourism: a case study of Tenerife. Tourism Economics, 7, 75e88.
Li, M., Wu, B., & Cai, L. (2008). Tourism development of world heritage sites in
China: a geographic perspective. Tourism Management, 29, 308e319.
Light, D. (2000). Gazing on communism: heritage tourism and post-communist
identities in Germany, Hungary and Romania. Tourism Geographies, 2(2), 157e176.
Lim, C. (2006). A survey of tourism demand modeling practice: issues and implications. In International handbook on the economics of tourism (pp. 45e72).
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
McIntosh, A., & Prentice, R. (1999). Afrming authenticity: consuming cultural
heritage. Annals of Tourism Research, 26, 589e612.
Maloney, W. F., & Montes-Rojas, G. V. (2005). How elastic are sea, sand and sun?
Dynamic panel estimates of the demand for tourism. Applied Economics Letters,
12, 277e280.
Naude, W. A., & Saayman, A. (2005). The determinants of tourist arrivals in Africa: a
panel data regression analysis. Tourism Economics, 11(3), 365e391.
Patsouratis, V., Frangouli, Z., & Anastasopoulos, G. (2005). Competition in tourism
among the Mediterranean countries. Applied Economics, 37, 1865e1870.
Payne, J. E., & Mervar, A. (2002). A note on modeling tourism revenues in Croatia.
Tourism Economics, 8, 103e109.
Song, H., & Li, G. (2008). Tourism demand modeling and forecasting: a review of
recent research. Tourism Management, 29, 203e230.
Tan, A. Y. F., McCahon, C., & Miller, J. (2002). Modeling tourist ows to Indonesia and
Malaysia. Journal of Travel and Tourism Marketing, 13, 61e82.
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Basic linear unobserved effects panel data models. In
Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data (pp. 247e291). Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Yang, C.-H., & Lin, H.-L. (2011). Is UNESCO recognition effective in fostering
tourism? A comment on Yang, Lin and Han: reply. Tourism Management, 32,
455e456.
Yang, C.-H., Lin, H.-L., & Han, C.-C. (2010). Analysis of international tourist arrivals in
China: the role of world heritage sites. Tourism Management, 31, 827e837.
58