United States v. Robert Chestman, 947 F.2d 551, 2d Cir. (1991)

Download as pdf
Download as pdf
You are on page 1of 54

947 F.

2d 551
60 USLW 2245, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 96,259

UNITED STATES of America, Appellee,


v.
Robert CHESTMAN, Defendant-Appellant.
No. 309, Docket 89-1276.

United States Court of Appeals,


Second Circuit.
Argued Nov. 9, 1990.
Decided Oct. 7, 1991.

Elkan Abramowitz, New York City (Alan J. Brudner, Barbara L. Hartung,


Alan P. Williamson, Morvillo, Abramowitz & Grand, New York City, of
counsel), for appellant.
David E. Brodsky, Asst. U.S. Atty., S.D.N.Y. (Roger S. Hayes, Acting
U.S. Atty. for S.D.N.Y., Gerard E. Lynch, Asst. U.S. Atty., S.D.N.Y.,
New York City, of counsel), for appellee.
Paul Gonson, Sol., S.E.C., Washington, D.C. (James R. Doty, Gen.
Counsel, Jacob H. Stillman, Associate Gen. Counsel, Richard A. Kirby,
Sr. Litigation Counsel, Brian Bellardo, Sr. Sp. Counsel, Randall W.
Quinn, Rada L. Potts, S.E.C., Washington, D.C., of counsel), for amicus
curiae S.E.C.
Before OAKES, Chief Judge, FEINBERG,* MESKILL, NEWMAN,
KEARSE, CARDAMONE, WINTER, PRATT, MINER, ALTIMARI,
MAHONEY and McLAUGHLIN, Circuit Judges.
ON REHEARING IN BANC
MESKILL, Circuit Judge, joined by CARDAMONE, PRATT, MINER
and ALTIMARI, Circuit Judges:

In this rehearing in banc, we consider for the first time the validity of Rule 14e3(a), 17 C.F.R. 240.14e-3(a), which was promulgated by the Securities and

Exchange Commission (SEC) under section 14(e) of the 1934 Act, 15 U.S.C.
78n(e); we then reexamine two familiar landmarks of the securities fraud
landscape, section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (1934 Act), 15
U.S.C. 78j(b), and the mail fraud statute, 18 U.S.C. 1341. The issues spring
from the alleged insider trading of defendant Robert Chestman. A jury found
Chestman guilty of thirty-one counts of insider trading and perjury: (1) ten
counts of fraudulent trading in connection with a tender offer in violation of
section 14(e), 18 U.S.C. 2, and Rule 14e-3(a),1 (2) ten counts of securities
fraud in violation of section 10(b), 18 U.S.C. 2, and 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5
(1988) (Rule 10b-5), (3) ten counts of mail fraud in violation of the mail fraud
statute and 18 U.S.C. 2, and (4) one count of perjury in violation of 18 U.S.C.
1621. A panel of this Court reversed Chestman's convictions in their entirety.
903 F.2d 75 (2d Cir.1990).
2

On in banc reconsideration, we conclude that the Rule 14e-3(a) convictions


should be affirmed and that the Rule 10b-5 and mail fraud convictions should
be reversed. We vacate the panel's decision on all three issues. We did not
rehear the appeal from the perjury conviction and, as a result, the panel's
reversal of that conviction stands.BACKGROUND

Robert Chestman is a stockbroker. Keith Loeb first sought Chestman's services


in 1982, when Loeb decided to consolidate his and his wife's holdings in
Waldbaum, Inc. (Waldbaum), a publicly traded company that owned a large
supermarket chain. During their initial meeting, Loeb told Chestman that his
wife was a granddaughter of Julia Waldbaum, a member of the board of
directors of Waldbaum and the wife of its founder. Julia Waldbaum also was
the mother of Ira Waldbaum, the president and controlling shareholder of
Waldbaum. From 1982 to 1986, Chestman executed several transactions
involving Waldbaum restricted and common stock for Keith Loeb. To facilitate
some of these trades, Loeb sent Chestman a copy of his wife's birth certificate,
which indicated that his wife's mother was Shirley Waldbaum Witkin.

On November 21, 1986, Ira Waldbaum agreed to sell Waldbaum to the Great
Atlantic and Pacific Tea Company (A & P). The resulting stock purchase
agreement required Ira to tender a controlling block of Waldbaum shares to A
& P at a price of $50 per share. Ira told three of his children, all employees of
Waldbaum, about the pending sale two days later, admonishing them to keep
the news quiet until a public announcement. He also told his sister, Shirley
Witkin, and nephew, Robert Karin, about the sale, and offered to tender their
shares along with his controlling block of shares to enable them to avoid the
administrative difficulty of tendering after the public announcement. He
cautioned them "that [the sale was] not to be discussed," that it was to remain

confidential.
5

In spite of Ira's counsel, Shirley told her daughter, Susan Loeb, on November
24 that Ira was selling the company. Shirley warned Susan not to tell anyone
except her husband, Keith Loeb, because disclosure could ruin the sale. The
next day, Susan told her husband about the pending tender offer and cautioned
him not to tell anyone because "it could possibly ruin the sale."

The following day, November 26, Keith Loeb telephoned Robert Chestman at
8:59 a.m. Unable to reach Chestman, Loeb left a message asking Chestman to
call him "ASAP." According to Loeb, he later spoke with Chestman between
9:00 a.m. and 10:30 a.m. that morning and told Chestman that he had "some
definite, some accurate information" that Waldbaum was about to be sold at a
"substantially higher" price than its market value. Loeb asked Chestman several
times what he thought Loeb should do. Chestman responded that he could not
advise Loeb what to do "in a situation like this" and that Loeb would have to
make up his own mind.

That morning Chestman executed several purchases of Waldbaum stock. At


9:49 a.m., he bought 3,000 shares for his own account at $24.65 per share.
Between 11:31 a.m. and 12:35 p.m., he purchased an additional 8,000 shares
for his clients' discretionary accounts at prices ranging from $25.75 to $26.00
per share. One of the discretionary accounts was the Loeb account, for which
Chestman bought 1,000 shares.

Before the market closed at 4:00 p.m., Loeb claims that he telephoned
Chestman a second time. During their conversation Loeb again pressed
Chestman for advice. Chestman repeated that he could not advise Loeb "in a
situation like this," but then said that, based on his research, Waldbaum was a
"buy." Loeb subsequently ordered 1,000 shares of Waldbaum stock.

Chestman presented a different version of the day's events. Before the SEC and
at trial, he claimed that he had purchased Waldbaum stock based on his own
research. He stated that his purchases were consistent with previous purchases
of Waldbaum stock and other retail food stocks and were supported by reports
in trade publications as well as the unusually high trading volume of the stock
on November 25. He denied having spoken to Loeb about Waldbaum stock on
the day of the trades.

10

At the close of trading on November 26, the tender offer was publicly
announced. Waldbaum stock rose to $49 per share the next business day. In

December 1986 Loeb learned that the National Association of Securities


Dealers had started an investigation concerning transactions in Waldbaum
stock. Loeb contacted Chestman who, according to Loeb, "reassured" him that
Chestman had bought the stock for Loeb's account based on his research. Loeb
called Chestman again in April 1987 after learning of an SEC investigation into
the trading of Waldbaum stock. Chestman again stated that he bought the stock
based on research. Similar conversations ensued. After one of these
conversations, Chestman asked Loeb what his "position" was, Loeb replied, "I
guess it's the same thing." Loeb subsequently agreed, however, to cooperate
with the government. The terms of his cooperation agreement required that he
disgorge the $25,000 profit from his purchase and sale of Waldbaum stock and
pay a $25,000 fine.
11

A grand jury returned an indictment on July 20, 1988, charging Chestman with
the following counts of insider trading and perjury: ten counts of fraudulent
trading in connection with a tender offer in violation of Rule 14e-3(a), ten
counts of securities fraud in violation of Rule 10b-5, ten counts of mail fraud,
and one count of perjury in connection with his testimony before the SEC. The
district court thereafter denied Chestman's motion to dismiss the indictment.
704 F.Supp. 451 (S.D.N.Y.1989). After a jury trial, Chestman was found guilty
on all counts.

12

Chestman appealed. He claimed that Rule 14e-3(a) was invalid because the
SEC had exceeded its statutory authority in promulgating a rule that dispensed
with one of the common law elements of fraud. He also argued that there was
insufficient evidence to sustain his Rule 10b-5, mail fraud and perjury
convictions.

13

A panel of this Court reversed Chestman's convictions on all counts, issuing


three separate opinions on the Rule 14e-3(a) charges. 903 F.2d 75 (2d
Cir.1990). Familiarity with the panel's opinions is assumed.

14

A majority of the active judges of the Court voted to rehear in banc the panel's
decision with respect to the Rule 14e-3(a), Rule 10b-5, and mail fraud
convictions. We directed the parties to file additional briefs on these issues and
heard oral argument on November 9, 1990.

DISCUSSION
A. Rule 14e-3(a)
15

Chestman challenges his Rule 14e-3(a) convictions on three grounds. He first

contends that the SEC exceeded its rulemaking authority when it promulgated
Rule 14e-3(a). He then argues that the government presented insufficient
evidence to support these convictions. Finally, he contends that his convictions
should be overturned on due process notice grounds. We begin with his facial
attack on the validity of Rule 14e-3(a).
1. Validity of Rule 14e-3(a)
16

Chestman's first challenge concerns the validity of a rule prescribed by the SEC
pursuant to a congressional delegation of rulemaking authority. The question
presented is whether Rule 14e-3(a) represents a proper exercise of the SEC's
statutory authority. While we have not heretofore addressed this question,
several district court judges in this Circuit have concluded that Rule 14e-3(a)
represents a valid exercise of rulemaking authority. See United States v.
Marcus Schloss & Co., Inc., 710 F.Supp. 944, 955-57 (S.D.N.Y.1989) (Haight,
J.); U.S. v. Chestman, 704 F.Supp. 451, 454-58 (S.D.N.Y.1989) (Walker, J.).
See also O'Connor & Assoc. v. Dean Witter Reynolds, Inc., 529 F.Supp. 1179,
1190-91 (S.D.N.Y.1981) (Lasker, J.) (rejecting contention that Rule 14e-3
exceeds the scope of section 14(e) because the rule covers transactions on the
open market, and not just transactions between the tender offeror and a
shareholder of a target company).

17

The enabling statutes for Rule 14e-3(a) are section 14(e) and section 23(a)(1) of
the 1934 Act. Section 14(e) provides:

18

It shall be unlawful for any person to make any untrue statement of a material
fact or omit to state any material fact necessary in order to make the statements
made, in the light of the circumstances under which they are made, not
misleading, or to engage in any fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative acts or
practices, in connection with any tender offer or request or invitation for
tenders, or any solicitation of security holders in opposition to or in favor of any
such offer, request, or invitation. The Commission shall, for the purposes of this
subsection, by rules and regulations define, and prescribe means reasonably
designed to prevent, such acts and practices as are fraudulent, deceptive, or
manipulative.

19

15 U.S.C. 78n(e). The first sentence of section 14(e) is a self-operative


provision, which Congress enacted as part of the Williams Act, Pub.L. No. 90439, 82 Stat. 454 (1968). Congress added the second sentence, a rulemaking
provision, in 1970. Section 23(a)(1), in turn, authorizes the SEC "to make such
rules and regulations as may be necessary or appropriate to implement the

provisions of this chapter for which [it is] responsible or for the execution of
the functions vested in [it] by this chapter." 15 U.S.C. 78w(a)(1).
20

Acting pursuant to the authority granted by sections 14(e) and 23(a)(1), the
SEC promulgated Rule 14e-3 in 1980. Rule 14e-3(a), the subsection under
which Chestman was convicted, provides:

21

If any person has taken a substantial step or steps to commence, or has


commenced, a tender offer (the "offering person"), it shall constitute a
fraudulent, deceptive or manipulative act or practice within the meaning of
section 14(e) of the Act for any other person who is in possession of material
information relating to such tender offer which information he knows or has
reason to know is nonpublic and which he knows or has reason to know has
been acquired directly or indirectly from:

22

(1) The offering person,

23

(2) The issuer of the securities sought or to be sought by such tender offer, or

24

(3) Any officer, director, partner or employee or any other person acting on
behalf of the offering person or such issuer, to purchase or sell or cause to be
purchased or sold any of such securities or any securities convertible into or
exchangeable for any such securities or any option or right to obtain or to
dispose of any of the foregoing securities, unless within a reasonable time prior
to any purchase or sale such information and its source are publicly disclosed
by press release or otherwise.

25

17 C.F.R. 240.14e-3(a).

26

One violates Rule 14e-3(a) if he trades on the basis of material nonpublic


information concerning a pending tender offer that he knows or has reason to
know has been acquired "directly or indirectly" from an insider of the offeror or
issuer, or someone working on their behalf. Rule 14e-3(a) is a disclosure
provision. It creates a duty in those traders who fall within its ambit to abstain
or disclose, without regard to whether the trader owes a pre-existing fiduciary
duty to respect the confidentiality of the information. Chestman claims that the
SEC exceeded its authority in drafting Rule 14e-3(a)--more specifically, in
drafting a rule that dispenses with one of the common law elements of fraud,
breach of a fiduciary duty.

27

In reviewing this claim, our scope of review is limited. "If Congress has

27

In reviewing this claim, our scope of review is limited. "If Congress has
explicitly left a gap for the agency to fill, there is an express delegation of
authority to the agency to elucidate a specific provision of the statute by
regulation. Such legislative regulations are given controlling weight unless they
are arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly contrary to the statute." Chevron,
U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 843-44,
104 S.Ct. 2778, 2781-83, 81 L.Ed.2d 694 (1984) (upholding the EPA's
construction of the Clean Air Act term "stationary source"). When Congress
delegates to an agency the power to promulgate rules,

28 [agency] adopts regulations with legislative effect. A reviewing court is not free
the
to set aside those regulations simply because it would have interpreted the statute in
a different manner....
29

The [rule] is therefore entitled to more than mere deference or weight. It can be
set aside only if the [agency] exceeded [its] statutory authority or if the
regulation is "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in
accordance with law."

30

Batterton v. Francis, 432 U.S. 416, 425-26, 97 S.Ct. 2399, 2405-06, 53 L.Ed.2d
448 (1977) (internal citations omitted) (quoting 5 U.S.C. 706(2)(A), (C))
(upholding the power of the Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare to
prescribe "standards" for determining what constitutes "unemployment" for
purposes of benefit eligibility). We thus will reject only those rules that are "
'inconsistent with the statutory mandate or that frustrate the policy that
Congress sought to implement.' " Securities Industry Ass'n v. Board of
Governors, 468 U.S. 137, 143, 104 S.Ct. 2979, 2982, 82 L.Ed.2d 107 (1984)
(quoting Federal Election Comm'n v. Democratic Senatorial Campaign Comm.,
454 U.S. 27, 32, 102 S.Ct. 38, 42, 70 L.Ed.2d 23 (1981)). See also 2 K. Davis,
Administrative Law Treatise 7:8, at 37 (2d ed. 1979) (noting the deferential
standard of review for "legislative rules"). Furthermore, we remain mindful
that, in construing legislation, we must " 'give effect, if possible, to every clause
and word of a statute.' " United States v. Menasche, 348 U.S. 528, 538-39, 75
S.Ct. 513, 520, 99 L.Ed. 615 (1955) (quoting Montclair v. Ramsdell, 107 U.S.
147, 152, 2 S.Ct. 391, 395, 27 L.Ed. 431 (1882)). Keeping these principles in
mind, we consider whether Congress authorized the SEC to enact Rule 14e3(a).

31

The plain language of section 14(e) represents a broad delegation of rulemaking


authority. The statute explicitly directs the SEC to "define" fraudulent practices
and to "prescribe means reasonably designed to prevent" such practices. It is
difficult to see how the power to "define" fraud could mean anything less than
the power to "set forth the meaning of" fraud in the tender offer context. See

Webster's Third New International Dictionary 592 (1971). This delegation of


rulemaking responsibility becomes a hollow gesture if we cabin the SEC's
rulemaking authority, as Chestman urges we should, by common law
definitions of fraud. Under Chestman's construction of the statute, the separate
grant of rulemaking power would be rendered superfluous because the SEC
could never define as fraud anything not already prohibited by the selfoperative provision. Such a narrow construction of the congressional grant of
authority would cramp the SEC's ability to define fraud flexibly in the context
of the discrete and highly sensitive area of tender offers. And such a delegation
of "power," paradoxically, would allow the SEC to limit, but not extend, a
trader's duty to disclose.
32

Even if we were to accept the argument that the SEC's definitional authority is
circumscribed by common law fraud, which we do not, the SEC's power to
"prescribe means reasonably designed to prevent" fraud extends the agency's
rulemaking authority further. The language of this portion of section 14(e) is
clear. The verb "prevent" has a plain meaning: "[T]o keep from happening or
existing esp[ecially] by precautionary measures." Webster's New Third
International Dictionary 1798 (1971). A delegation of authority to enact rules
"reasonably designed to prevent" fraud, then, necessarily encompasses the
power to proscribe conduct outside the purview of fraud, be it common law or
SEC-defined fraud. Because the operative words of the statute, "define" and
"prevent," have clear connotations, the language of the statute is sufficiently
clear to be dispositive here. Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842-43, 104 S.Ct. at 2781-82.
We note, however, other factors that bolster our interpretation.

33

Nothing in the legislative history of section 14(e) indicates that the SEC
frustrated congressional intent by enacting Rule 14e-3(a). To the contrary, what
legislative history there is suggests that Congress intended to grant broad
rulemaking authority to the SEC in this instance.

34

As originally enacted, section 14(e) was part of the Williams Act. The
Williams Act, the Supreme Court has concluded, was "a disclosure provision,"
Piper v. Chris-Craft Indus., Inc., 430 U.S. 1, 27, 97 S.Ct. 926, 942, 51 L.Ed.2d
124 (1977), whose "sole purpose ... was the protection of investors who are
confronted with a tender offer." Id. at 35, 97 S.Ct. at 946. Although the
legislative history "specifically concerning 14(e) is sparse," Schreiber v.
Burlington Northern, Inc., 472 U.S. 1, 11, 105 S.Ct. 2458, 2464, 86 L.Ed.2d 1
(1985), the congressional reports indicate that section 14(e) was directed at
ensuring "full disclosure" in connection with the trading of the securities of a
tender offer target. Id. (quoting H.R.Rep. No. 1711, 90th Cong., 2nd Sess. 11
(1968); S.Rep. No. 550, 90th Cong., 1st Sess. 11 (1967) U.S.Code Cong. &

Admin.News 1968, 2811) (emphasis supplied by Supreme Court). Analyzing


the legislative history of section 14(e), the Schreiber Court explained:
35
Section
14(e) adds a "broad antifraud prohibition" modeled on the antifraud
provisions of 10(b) of the Act and Rule 10b-5.... It supplements the more precise
disclosure provisions found elsewhere in the Williams Act, while requiring
disclosure more explicitly addressed to the tender offer context than that required by
10(b).
36

Id. at 10-11, 105 S.Ct. at 2463-64 (quoting Piper, 430 U.S. at 24, 97 S.Ct. at
940) (footnote omitted). The "very purpose of the [Williams] Act," we have
said, was "informed decisionmaking by shareholders." Lewis v. McGraw, 619
F.2d 192, 195 (2d Cir.) (per curiam), cert. denied, 449 U.S. 951, 101 S.Ct. 354,
66 L.Ed.2d 214 (1980).

37

The legislative history of the 1970 amendment to section 14(e), the rulemaking
provision, likewise suggests a broad grant of congressional authority. Senator
Williams, the bill's sponsor, asserted the "utmost necessity" of granting "full
rulemaking powers" to the SEC in the area of tender offers. 116 Cong.Rec.
3024 (Feb. 10, 1970). The amendment "would add to the Commission's
rulemaking power," Senator Williams explained, "and enable it to deal
promptly and ... flexib[ly]" with problems in that area. Hearings on S.3431
before the Subcom. on Securities of the Senate Comm. on Banking and
Currency, 91st Cong., 2nd Sess. 2 (1970) [hereinafter S.3431 Hearings]; see
also H.R.Rep. No. 1655, 91st Cong., 2nd Sess. 4, reprinted in 1970 U.S.Code
Cong. & Admin.News 5025, 5028. During hearings on the 1970 Amendment,
moreover, Senator Williams asked the SEC chairman for "examples of the
fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative practices used in tender offers which the
proposed [SEC] rulemaking powers would prevent," noting that the
information "would be most helpful to the committee as we continue
developing this legislation." S. 3431 Hearings, at 11. Responding to the
Senator's request, the SEC identified one such "problem" that the SEC's
proposed rulemaking authority would be used to prevent:

38 person who has become aware that a tender bid is to be made, or has reason to
The
believe that such bid will be made, may fail to disclose material facts with respect
thereto to persons who sell to him securities for which the tender bid is to be made.
39

Id. at 12. Notably, this hypothetical does not contain any requirement that the
trader breach a fiduciary duty. All told, the legislative history indicates that
Congress intended to grant broad rulemaking power to the SEC under section
14(e). This delegation of authority was aimed at promoting full disclosure in

the tender offer context and, in so doing, contributing to informed


decisionmaking by shareholders.
40

In promulgating Rule 14e-3(a), the SEC acted well within the letter and spirit
of section 14(e). Recognizing the highly sensitive nature of tender offer
information, its susceptibility to misuse, and the often difficult task of ferreting
out and proving fraud, Congress sensibly delegated to the SEC broad authority
to delineate a penumbra around the fuzzy subject of tender offer fraud. See
generally Loewenstein, Section 14(e) of the Williams Act and the Rule 10b-5
Comparisons, 71 Geo.L.J. 1311, 1356 (1983) ("It is difficult to see why
Congress would grant such broad powers to the SEC if the SEC was not
expected to have some leeway in utilizing its powers."). To be certain, the
SEC's rulemaking power under this broad grant of authority is not unlimited.
The rule must still be "reasonably related to the purposes of the enabling
legislation." Mourning v. Family Publications Service, Inc., 411 U.S. 356, 369,
93 S.Ct. 1652, 1661, 36 L.Ed.2d 318 (1973) (quoting Thorpe v. Housing
Authority of the City of Durham, 393 U.S. 268, 280-81, 89 S.Ct. 518, 525-26,
21 L.Ed.2d 474 (1969)). The SEC, however, in adopting Rule 14e-3(a), acted
consistently with this authority. While dispensing with the subtle problems of
proof associated with demonstrating fiduciary breach in the problematic area of
tender offer insider trading, the Rule retains a close nexus between the
prohibited conduct and the statutory aims.

41

Legislative activity since the SEC promulgated Rule 14e-3(a) further supports
the Rule's validity. Congress acknowledged and left untouched the force of
Rule 14e-3(a) when it enacted the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984
(ITSA), 15 U.S.C. 78u-1. ITSA imposes treble civil penalties on those who
violate SEC rules "by purchasing or selling a security while in possession of
material, nonpublic information," id. 78u-1(a)(1), an activity covered by Rule
14e-3(a). Congress, in fact, was advised that a Rule 14e-3 violation would
trigger treble damages under ITSA. See H.R.Rep. No. 355, 98th Cong., 1st
Sess. 4, 11, 13 n. 20, reprinted in 1984 U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 2274,
2277, 2284, 2286 n. 20; see also H.R.Rep. No. 910, 100th Cong., 2nd Sess. 14,
reprinted in 1988 U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 6043, 6051 (in enacting the
Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, Congress noted
that Rule 14e-3 had triggered efforts by private securities firms "to detect
insider trading and other market abuses by their employees").

42

These references to Rule 14e-3 during debates on proposed insider trading


legislation may not amount to congressional ratification of the Rule, see Red
Lion Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 395 U.S. 367, 381-82, 89 S.Ct. 1794, 1801-03,
23 L.Ed.2d 371 (1969), but they do support the Rule's validity. Congressional

silence in the face of administrative construction of a statute lends support to


the validity of that interpretation. See United States v. Rutherford, 442 U.S.
544, 554 n. 10, 99 S.Ct. 2470, 2476 n. 10, 61 L.Ed.2d 68 (1979) ("once an
agency's statutory construction has been 'fully brought to the attention of the
public and the Congress,' and the latter has not sought to alter that interpretation
although it has amended the statute in other respects, then presumably the
legislative intent has been correctly discerned") (citations omitted); Red Lion
Broadcasting Co., 395 U.S. at 381, 89 S.Ct. at 1802; Zemel v. Rusk, 381 U.S.
1, 11, 85 S.Ct. 1271, 1278, 14 L.Ed.2d 179 (1965) ("Congress' failure to repeal
or revise in the face of ... administrative interpretation has been held to
constitute persuasive evidence that that interpretation is the one intended by
Congress.").
43

In sum, the language and legislative history of section 14(e), as well as


congressional inactivity toward it since the SEC promulgated Rule 14e-3(a), all
support the view that Congress empowered the SEC to prescribe a rule that
extends beyond the common law.

44

Chestman points to nothing in the language or legislative history of section


14(e) to refute our construction of the statute. Instead he relies principally on
Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d 348
(1980), and Schreiber, 472 U.S. 1, 105 S.Ct. 2458, to advance his argument that
section 14(e) parallels common law fraud. That reliance is misplaced.

45

Chiarella considered whether trading stock on the basis of material nonpublic


information in the absence of a fiduciary breach constitutes fraud under section
10(b). Confronted with both congressional and SEC silence on the issue, see
section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5, the Court applied common law principles of
fraud. It concluded, based on those principles, that liability under section 10(b)
requires a fiduciary breach.

46

Several factors limit Chiarella's precedential value in this case. First, Chiarella
of course concerns section 10(b), not section 14(e). Section 10(b) is a general
antifraud statute, while section 14(e) is an antifraud provision specifically
tailored to the field of tender offers, an area of the securities industry that, the
Williams Act makes clear, deserves special regulation.

47

Second, section 14(e) evinces a clear indication of congressional intent, while


section 10(b) does not. See Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 226, 100 S.Ct. at 1113
("neither the legislative history nor the statute itself affords specific guidance
for the resolution of this case"). Section 10(b) speaks in terms of the use "in

connection with the purchase or sale of any security" of "any manipulative or


deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of such rules and regulations
as the [SEC] may prescribe as necessary or appropriate in the public interest or
for the protection of investors." 15 U.S.C. 78j(b). Section 14(e) directly
proscribes, in self-operative fashion, "any fraudulent, deceptive, or
manipulative acts or practices" in connection with a tender offer. Then, in a
separate sentence, the statute directs the SEC to draft rules to define these
practices and to prevent them: "The [SEC] shall, for the purposes of this
subsection, by rules and regulations define, and prescribe means reasonably
designed to prevent, such acts and practices as are fraudulent, deceptive, or
manipulative." The contrast in statutory language is telling. It underscores, first
of all, the dubious premise of Chestman's argument--that section 14(e) was
modeled after section 10(b). The two provisions are hardly identical in scope.
The language of section 14(e)'s rulemaking provision, instead of tracking
section 10(b), in fact mirrors section 15(c)(2), 15 U.S.C. 78o(c)(2), which
concerns broker-dealer relations. "The language of the addition to section 14(e)
is identical to that contained in section 15(c)(2) of the Securities Exchange Act
concerning practices of brokers and dealers in securities transactions in the
over-the-counter markets." H.R.Rep. No. 1655, 91st Cong., 2nd Sess. 4,
reprinted in 1970 U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 5025, 5028. The contrast
also illustrates that section 14(e) provides a more compelling legislative
delegation to the SEC to prescribe rules than does section 10(b). While section
10(b) refers to such rules as the SEC "may prescribe as necessary or
appropriate," section 14(e) commands the SEC to prescribe rules that will
"define" and "prevent" fraud. See Loewenstein, supra, 71 Geo.L.J. at 1356
("By comparison, the Commission's rulemaking authority under section 10(b)
does not include the power to define manipulative or deceptive" acts or to adopt
prophylatic measures.).
48

Indeed, in Chiarella, the Court even distinguished sections 10(b) and 14(e). The
Court acknowledged that the SEC had recently acted pursuant to its rulemaking
authority under section 14(e) to bar warehousing, a form of insider trading
involving tender offers:

49 this case, as in warehousing, a buyer of securities purchases stock in a target


In
corporation on the basis of market information which is unknown to the seller. In
both of these situations, the seller's behavior presumably would be altered if he had
the nonpublic information. Significantly, however, the Commission has acted to bar
warehousing under its authority to regulate tender offers [citing proposed Rule 14e3] after recognizing that action under 10(b) would rest on a "somewhat different
theory" than that previously used to regulate insider trading as fraudulent activity.
50

Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 234, 100 S.Ct. at 1117-18 (footnotes omitted). That

50

Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 234, 100 S.Ct. at 1117-18 (footnotes omitted). That
"somewhat different theory" is one that does not embrace "any fiduciary duty to
[the target] company or its shareholders." 1 SEC Institutional Investor Study
Report, H.R.Doc. No. 64, 92nd Cong. 1st Sess., pt. 1, at xxxii (1971) (cited in
Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 234 n. 19, 100 S.Ct. at 1118 n. 19). Significantly, the
Chiarella Court did not disapprove of this exercise of the SEC's rulemaking
power under section 14(e).

51

Finally, Chiarella faced not only statutory silence on the issue before it but also
administrative reticence. Neither the language of Rule 10b-5, SEC discussions
of the rule, nor administrative interpretations of the rule offered any evidence
that the SEC, in drafting Rule 10b-5, intended the rule to go beyond common
law fraud. See Rule 10b-5 (referring to "artifice to defraud" and to "fraud ...
upon any person"); see also Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 226, 100 S.Ct. at 1113
("When Rule 10b-5 was promulgated in 1942, the SEC did not discuss the
possibility that failure to provide information might run afoul of 10(b).")
(footnote omitted); id. at 230, 100 S.Ct. at 1115; id. 445 U.S. at 233, 100 S.Ct.
at 1117 ("neither the Congress nor the Commission ever has adopted a parityof-information rule"). The language of Rule 14e-3(a), on the other hand,
reveals express SEC intent to proscribe conduct not covered by common law
fraud. And "[p]resumably the SEC perceived Rule 14e-3 as a valid exercise of
its statutory authority." United States v. Marcus Schloss & Co., Inc., 710
F.Supp. 944, 956 (S.D.N.Y.1989).

52

Thus, the question presented here differs markedly from that presented in
Chiarella. It is not whether section 14(e), standing alone, prohibits insider
trading in the absence of a fiduciary breach. It is whether section 14(e)'s broad
rulemaking provision, together with SEC action under that authority in the form
of Rule 14e-3(a), represent a valid exercise of administrative rulemaking. In
Chiarella, the Court refused to recognize "a general duty between all
participants in market transactions to forgo actions based on material nonpublic
information ... absent some explicit evidence of congressional intent." 445 U.S.
at 233, 100 S.Ct. at 1117. Our task is easier. Rule 14e-3(a) creates a narrower
duty than that once proposed for Rule 10b-5--a parity of information rule--and,
as the language and legislative history of section 14(e) make clear, the rule has
Congress' blessing.

53

Equally unavailing is Chestman's reliance on Schreiber. The Schreiber case


arose from a hostile tender offer initiated by Burlington Northern, Inc. for El
Paso Gas Co. stock. After a majority of El Paso's shareholders subscribed to the
tender offer, Burlington rescinded its offer, deciding to enter into a friendly
takeover agreement with El Paso. Pursuant to its agreement with El Paso,

Burlington substituted a new tender offer, which was soon oversubscribed.


Several shareholders who had tendered their shares during the first tender offer
received a diminished payment due to the oversubscription of the second tender
offer. They claimed that Burlington's conduct violated section 14(e) as a
"manipulative" distortion of the market for El Paso stock. Absent congressional
guidance concerning the meaning of the term "manipulative," it fell to the
Court to determine whether misrepresentation or nondisclosure is a necessary
element of a violation of section 14(e). Schreiber, 472 U.S. at 6-8, 105 S.Ct. at
2461-62. The Court looked to the ordinary and common law meaning of the
term, as well as the legislative history of section 14(e), with its focus on
nondisclosure. Relying on these sources, the Court held that misrepresentation
or nondisclosure was an indispensable element of a section 14(e) violation. Id.
at 8, 105 S.Ct. at 2462.
54

Chestman claims that Schreiber demonstrates that section 14(e), like section
10(b), projects no further than common law fraud. To support this argument, he
points to a statement in Schreiber indicating that section 14(e) is "modeled on
the antifraud provisions of 10(b)." Id. at 10, 105 S.Ct. at 2463. What
Chestman ignores, however, is that Schreiber contrasted as well as compared
the two statutes. Following the language Chestman quotes, the Court stated that
section 14(e) "supplements" the other disclosure provisions in the Williams Act
and requires "disclosure more explicitly addressed to the tender offer context
than that required by 10(b)." Id. at 10-11, 105 S.Ct. at 2464. In addition, the
Court's reference to the similarity between sections 10(b) and 14(e) only refers
to section 14(e)'s substantive provision. Section 10(b), as we have emphasized,
lacks a separate rulemaking grant akin to section 14(e). Moreover, even to the
extent section 10(b) may be accurately described as the father of section 14(e),
as well as all later antifraud provisions under the 1934 Act, we cannot agree
that section 10(b) therefore confines section 14(e), and its other antifraud
progeny, to an identical reach.

55

Chestman also attempts to draw support from footnote 11 in Schreiber. There,


in rejecting petitioner's argument that the 1970 amendment to section 14(e), the
rulemaking provision, would be meaningless if section 14(e) concerned
disclosure only, the Court observed:In adding the 1970 amendment, Congress
simply provided a mechanism for defining and guarding against those acts and
practices which involve material misrepresentation or nondisclosure. The
amendment gives the [SEC] latitude to regulate nondeceptive activities as a
"reasonably designed" means of preventing manipulative acts, without
suggesting any change in the meaning of the term "manipulative" itself.

56

Id. at 11 n. 11, 105 S.Ct. at 2464 n. 11. Whatever may be gleaned from the

footnote on the SEC's definitional authority under section 14(e), the footnote
plainly endorses the SEC's authority to draft prophylactic rules under section
14(e). It states that the rulemaking provision "gives the [SEC] latitude to
regulate nondeceptive activities as a 'reasonably designed' means of preventing
manipulative acts." Id. (emphasis added). Chestman offers no persuasive
explanation why the authority "to regulate nondeceptive activities" would not
also allow the SEC to regulate nonfraudulent conduct.
57

As for the SEC's authority to define the operative words of section 14(e),
Schreiber seems to be saying only that section 14(e)'s rulemaking provision
does not itself change the common law meaning of "manipulative." The Court
was not confronted with the question raised here--whether SEC action pursuant
to the rulemaking delegation exceeds statutory authority--because the petitioner
did not point to any SEC rules drafted under section 14(e) that covered
Burlington's activities. Moreover, even if we were to agree with Chestman that,
under Schreiber, the common law confines the SEC in defining "manipulative,"
we would still uphold the validity of Rule 14e-3(a). In Schreiber, the definition
of "manipulative" proffered by the plaintiff would have eliminated a
requirement that there be a nondisclosure or material misrepresentation, the
primary evils at which section 14(e) took aim. Rule 14e-3(a), in contrast, does
not stray from congressional intent; it remains a disclosure provision.

58

Therefore, based on the plain language of section 14(e), and congressional


activity both before section 14(e) was enacted and after Rule 14e-3(a) was
promulgated, we hold that the SEC did not exceed its statutory authority in
drafting Rule 14e-3(a).
2. Sufficiency of the Evidence

59

Chestman also argues that the evidence was insufficient to sustain his Rule 14e3(a) convictions. In an argument raised for the first time in his in banc brief,
Chestman contends that the government failed to present sufficient evidence to
show that he knew that the information had been acquired "directly or
indirectly" from the Waldbaum company, a Waldbaum company insider, or a
person acting on the company's behalf. This argument merits only brief
consideration.

60

The jury heard the following evidence. Chestman knew that Keith Loeb was a
member of the Waldbaum family. Chestman knew that the information
concerned the Waldbaum family business. He also knew that the information
was not publicly available. Furthermore, he had heard Loeb describe the

information as "definite" and "accurate." While more than one inference could
be drawn from this evidence, the jury's conclusion was far from an irrational
one. A jury could reasonably infer that Chestman knew that the information
originated from a Waldbaum insider. We disagree with Chestman's intimation
that Loeb had to describe the information to Chestman as "confidential." A
description of the information as "definite" and "accurate," together with
Chestman's knowledge that Loeb was a Waldbaum relative, provided the
crucial basis from which to infer confidentiality. It was not necessary that
Chestman be told the family channels through which the information had
travelled. In sum, Chestman's knowledge of Loeb's status as a Waldbaum
family member and the nature of the information conveyed provided sufficient
evidence from which a rational trier of fact could infer that the information
originated, "directly or indirectly," from a Waldbaum insider.
3. Due Process
61

Chestman next argues that his Rule 14e-3(a) convictions violate due process
because he did not have fair notice that his conduct was criminal. Given the
explicit language of Rule 14e-3(a), we also reject this claim.

62

The purpose of the "fair notice" requirement of due process is "to give a person
of ordinary intelligence fair notice that his contemplated conduct is forbidden
by the statute." United States v. Harriss, 347 U.S. 612, 617, 74 S.Ct. 808, 812,
98 L.Ed. 989 (1954). That requirement was met here. As we have seen, Rule
14e-3(a) explicitly proscribes trading on the basis of material nonpublic
information derived from insider sources. Unlike Rule 10b-5, Rule 14e-3(a) is
not a general, catchall provision. It targets specific conduct arising in a unique
context--tender offers. The language of the rule gave Chestman, a sophisticated
stockbroker, fair notice that the conduct in which he engaged was criminal.

63

That leaves Chestman with the dubious argument that, while he had notice that
Rule 14e-3(a) prohibited his activity, he could not have known whether a court
would find the rule valid. Due process does not extend this far. When statutory
language provides notice that conduct is illegal, the notice requirements of due
process have been met. The government need not await every conceivable
challenge to a law's validity before it prosecutes conduct covered by a statute.
Chestman "treaded closely enough along proscribed lines ... to find that [he]
had adequate notice of the illegality of [his] acts." United States v. Carpenter,
791 F.2d 1024, 1034 (2d Cir.1986), aff'd, 484 U.S. 19, 108 S.Ct. 316, 98
L.Ed.2d 275 (1987).

B. Rule 10b-5

64

Chestman's Rule 10b-5 convictions were based on the misappropriation theory,


which provides that "one who misappropriates nonpublic information in breach
of a fiduciary duty and trades on that information to his own advantage violates
Section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5." SEC v. Materia, 745 F.2d 197, 203 (2d
Cir.1984), cert. denied, 471 U.S. 1053, 105 S.Ct. 2112, 85 L.Ed.2d 477 (1985).
With respect to the shares Chestman purchased on behalf of Keith Loeb,
Chestman was convicted of aiding and abetting Loeb's misappropriation of
nonpublic information in breach of a duty Loeb owed to the Waldbaum family
and to his wife Susan. As to the shares Chestman purchased for himself and his
other clients, Chestman was convicted as a "tippee" of that same
misappropriated information. Thus, while Chestman is the defendant in this
case, the alleged misappropriator was Keith Loeb. The government agrees that
Chestman's convictions cannot be sustained unless there was sufficient
evidence to show that (1) Keith Loeb breached a duty owed to the Waldbaum
family or Susan Loeb based on a fiduciary or similar relationship of trust and
confidence, and (2) Chestman knew that Loeb had done so. We have heretofore
never applied the misappropriation theory--and its predicate requirement of a
fiduciary breach--in the context of family relationships. As a prologue to that
analysis, we canvass past Rule 10b-5 jurisprudence.

65

Section 10(b) prohibits the use "in connection with the purchase or sale of any
security ... [of] any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in
contravention of such rules and regulations as the Commission may prescribe."
15 U.S.C. 78j(b). Pursuant to that mandate, the SEC promulgated Rule 10b-5,
which, in pertinent part, makes it unlawful "[t]o employ any device, scheme, or
artifice to defraud" or "[t]o engage in any act ... which operates ... as a fraud or
deceit upon any person, in connection with the purchase or sale of any
security." 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5 (1988). While more than one interpretation
has been given to this expansive language, fraud has remained the centerpiece
of a Rule 10b-5 criminal violation. At this juncture, two general theories of
Rule 10b-5 fraud have emerged to fill the interstitial gaps of the rule.

66

1. Traditional Theory of Rule 10b-5 Liability

67

The traditional theory of insider trader liability derives principally from the
Supreme Court's holdings in Chiarella, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, and Dirks
v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 103 S.Ct. 3255, 77 L.Ed.2d 911 (1983). A securities
trader commits Rule 10b-5 fraud, the Chiarella Court held, only if he "fails to
disclose material information prior to the consummation of a transaction ...
when he is under a duty to do so." Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 228, 100 S.Ct. at 1114.
The Chiarella Court then delineated when a person possessing material
nonpublic information owes such a duty--what it called "[t]he obligation to

disclose or abstain" from trading. Id. at 227, 100 S.Ct. at 1114. It held that this
duty "does not arise from the mere possession of nonpublic market
information." Id. at 235, 100 S.Ct. at 1118. That is, the duty inquiry does not
turn on whether the parties to the transaction have "equal information." Dirks,
463 U.S. at 657, 103 S.Ct. at 3263 (construing Chiarella ). Rather, a duty to
disclose or abstain arises only from " 'a fiduciary or other similar relation of
trust and confidence between [the parties to the transaction].' " Chiarella, 445
U.S. at 228, 100 S.Ct. at 1114 (quoting Restatement (Second) of Torts 551(2)
(a) (1976)).
68

In Dirks, an action concerning the liability of a tippee of material nonpublic


information, the Court built on its holding in Chiarella. Dirks again rejected a
parity of information theory of Rule 10b-5 liability, reiterating the "requirement
of a specific relationship between the shareholders and the individual trading on
inside information." Dirks, 463 U.S. at 655, 103 S.Ct. at 3261. It then examined
when a tippee inherits a fiduciary duty to the corporation's shareholders to
disclose or refrain from trading. Noting the "derivative" nature of tippee
liability, id. at 659, 103 S.Ct. at 3264, the Court held that tippee liability
attaches only when an "insider has breached his fiduciary duty to the
shareholders by disclosing the information to the tippee and the tippee knows
or should know that there has been a breach." Id. at 660, 103 S.Ct. at 3264.

69

Dirks established, in dictum, an additional means by which erstwhile outsiders


become fiduciaries of a corporation's shareholders. Justice Powell explained:

70

Under certain circumstances, such as where corporate information is revealed


legitimately to an underwriter, accountant, lawyer, or consultant working for
the corporation, these outsiders may become fiduciaries of the shareholders.
The basis for recognizing this fiduciary duty is not simply that such persons
acquired nonpublic corporate information, but rather that they have entered into
a special confidential relationship in the conduct of the business of the
enterprise and are given access to information solely for corporate purposes....
For such a duty to be imposed, however, the corporation must expect the
outsider to keep the disclosed nonpublic information confidential, and the
relationship at least must imply such a duty.

71

Id. at 655 n. 14, 103 S.Ct. at 3262 n. 14 (citations omitted). This theory clothes
an outsider with temporary insider status when the outsider obtains access to
confidential information solely for corporate purposes in the context of "a
special confidential relationship." The temporary insider thereby acquires a
correlative fiduciary duty to the corporation's shareholders.

72

Binding these strands of Rule 10b-5 liability are two principles--one, the
predicate act of fraud must be traceable to a breach of duty to the purchasers or
sellers of securities, 2 two, a fiduciary duty does not run to the purchasers or
sellers solely as a result of one's possession of material nonpublic information.
2. Misappropriation Theory

73

The second general theory of Rule 10b-5 liability, the misappropriation theory,
has not yet been the subject of a Supreme Court holding,3 but has been adopted
in the Second, Third, Seventh and Ninth Circuits. See, e.g., SEC v. Cherif, 933
F.2d 403 (7th Cir.1991); SEC v. Clark, 915 F.2d 439 (9th Cir.1990); Rothberg
v. Rosenbloom, 771 F.2d 818 (3d Cir.1985), rev'd on other grounds after
remand, 808 F.2d 252 (3d Cir.1986), cert. denied, 481 U.S. 1017, 107 S.Ct.
1895, 95 L.Ed.2d 501 (1987); United States v. Newman, 664 F.2d 12 (2d
Cir.1981), aff'd after remand, 722 F.2d 729 (2d Cir.1983), cert. denied, 464
U.S. 863, 104 S.Ct. 193, 78 L.Ed.2d 170 (1983). Under this theory, a person
violates Rule 10b-5 when he misappropriates material nonpublic information in
breach of a fiduciary duty or similar relationship of trust and confidence and
uses that information in a securities transaction. See, e.g., Carpenter, 791 F.2d
at 1028-29; Materia, 745 F.2d at 201; Newman, 664 F.2d at 17-18. In contrast
to Chiarella and Dirks, the misappropriation theory does not require that the
buyer or seller of securities be defrauded. Newman, 664 F.2d at 17. Focusing
on the language "fraud or deceit upon any person" (emphasis added), we have
held that the predicate act of fraud may be perpetrated on the source of the
nonpublic information, even though the source may be unaffiliated with the
buyer or seller of securities. See Carpenter, 791 F.2d at 1032. To date we have
applied the theory only in the context of employment relationships. See
Carpenter, 791 F.2d at 1032 (financial columnist breached duty to his
newspaper); Materia, 745 F.2d at 202 (copyholder breached duty to his printing
company); Newman, 664 F.2d at 17 (investment banker breached duty to his
firm). District courts in this Circuit have applied the theory in other settings as
well as in the employment context. See, e.g., United States v. Willis, 737
F.Supp. 269 (S.D.N.Y.1990) (denying motion to dismiss indictment of
psychiatrist who traded on the basis of information obtained from patient, in
breach of duty arising from relationship of trust and confidence); United States
v. Reed, 601 F.Supp. 685 (S.D.N.Y.), rev'd on other grounds, 773 F.2d 477 (2d
Cir.1985) (allegation that son breached fiduciary duty to father, a corporate
director, withstood motion to dismiss indictment); SEC v. Musella, 578 F.Supp.
425 (S.D.N.Y.1984) (office services manager of law firm breached duty to law
firm and its clients by trading on the basis of material nonpublic information
acquired in the course of his employment).

74

One point at which the misappropriation theory and the traditional theory of
insider trading merge warrants brief consideration. Our first applications of the
misappropriation theory, in Newman and Materia, concerned conduct that
occurred before the Supreme Court's holding in Dirks. Dirks noted that an
outsider could obtain temporary insider status by gaining access to confidential
information through certain relationships with a corporation--as, for example,
an underwriter, lawyer or consultant. 463 U.S. at 655 n. 14, 103 S.Ct. at 3262
n. 14. A temporary insider theory of prosecution might well have covered the
activities of the investment banker in Newman and the printer in Materia. In
Newman and Materia, the defendants appeared to have "entered into a special
confidential relationship in the conduct of the business of the enterprise and
[were] given access to information solely for corporate purposes." Dirks, 463
U.S. at 655 n. 14, 103 S.Ct. at 3262 n. 14. In view of the overlap between
Newman and Materia on the one hand and the Dirks concept of temporary
insiders on the other, we arguably did not break ranks with the traditional
theory of insider trading until our holding in Carpenter. In Carpenter none of
the prongs of liability under the traditional theory applied. That is, the
defendants did not owe the people with whom they traded a duty to disclose or
abstain from trading--absent resurrection of the twice-rejected parity of
information theory. Carpenter, then, represents the first fact pattern we have
considered that is clearly beyond the pale of the traditional theory of insider
trading.

75

After Carpenter, the fiduciary relationship question takes on special


importance. This is because a fraud-on-the-source theory of liability extends
the focus of Rule 10b-5 beyond the confined sphere of fiduciary/shareholder
relations to fiduciary breaches of any sort, a particularly broad expansion of
10b-5 liability if the add-on, a "similar relationship of trust and confidence," is
construed liberally. One concern triggered by this broadened inquiry is that
fiduciary duties are circumscribed with some clarity in the context of
shareholder relations but lack definition in other contexts. See generally Reed,
601 F.Supp. 685 (and authorities cited therein). Tethered to the field of
shareholder relations, fiduciary obligations arise within a narrow, principled
sphere. The existence of fiduciary duties in other common law settings,
however, is anything but clear. Our Rule 10b-5 precedents under the
misappropriation theory, moreover, provide little guidance with respect to the
question of fiduciary breach, because they involved egregious fiduciary
breaches arising solely in the context of employer/employee associations. See
Carpenter, 791 F.2d at 1028 ("It is clear that defendant Winans ... breached a
duty of confidentiality to his employer"); Newman, 664 F.2d at 17 ("we need
spend little time on the issue of fraud and deceit"); Materia, 745 F.2d at 201
(same). For these reasons we tread cautiously in extending the misappropriation

theory to new relationships, lest our efforts to construe Rule 10b-5 lose method
and predictability, taking over "the whole corporate universe." United States v.
Chiarella, 588 F.2d 1358, 1377 (2d Cir.1978) (Meskill, J., dissenting) (quoting
Santa Fe Industries, Inc. v. Green, 430 U.S. 462, 480, 97 S.Ct. 1292, 1304, 51
L.Ed.2d 480 (1977)), rev'd, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d 348
(1980).
76

3. Fiduciary Duties and Their Functional Equivalent

77

Against this backdrop, we turn to our central inquiry--what constitutes a


fiduciary or similar relationship of trust and confidence in the context of Rule
10b-5 criminal liability? We begin by noting two factors that do not themselves
create the necessary relationship.

78

First, a fiduciary duty cannot be imposed unilaterally by entrusting a person


with confidential information. Walton v. Morgan Stanley & Co., 623 F.2d 796,
799 (2d Cir.1980) (applying Delaware law). Walton concerned the conduct of
an investment bank, Morgan Stanley. While investigating possible takeover
targets for one of its clients, Morgan Stanley obtained unpublished material
information (internal earnings reports) on a confidential basis from a
prospective target, Olinkraft. After its client abandoned the planned takeover,
Morgan Stanley was charged with trading in Olinkraft's stock on the basis of
the confidential information. Observing that the parties had bargained at "arm's
length" and that there had not been a pre-existing agreement of confidentiality
between Morgan Stanley and Olinkraft, we rejected the argument that

79
Morgan
Stanley became a fiduciary of Olinkraft by virtue of the receipt of the
confidential information.... [T]he fact that the information was confidential did
nothing, in and of itself, to change the relationship between Morgan Stanley and
Olinkraft's management. Put bluntly, although, according to the complaint,
Olinkraft's management placed its confidence in Morgan Stanley not to disclose the
information, Morgan Stanley owed no duty to observe that confidence.
80

Walton, 623 F.2d at 799. See also Dirks, 463 U.S. at 662 n. 22, 103 S.Ct. at
3265 n. 22 (citing Walton approvingly as "a case turning on the court's
determination that the disclosure did not impose any fiduciary duties on the
recipient of the inside information"). Reposing confidential information in
another, then, does not by itself create a fiduciary relationship.

81

Second, marriage does not, without more, create a fiduciary relationship. "
'[M]ere kinship does not of itself establish a confidential relation.' ... Rather, the

existence of a confidential relationship must be determined independently of a


preexisting family relationship." Reed, 601 F.Supp. at 706 (quoting G.G.
Bogert, The Law of Trusts and Trustees 482, at 300-11 (Rev. 2d ed. 1978))
(other citations omitted). Although spouses certainly may by their conduct
become fiduciaries, the marriage relationship alone does not impose fiduciary
status. In sum, more than the gratuitous reposal of a secret to another who
happens to be a family member is required to establish a fiduciary or similar
relationship of trust and confidence.
82

We take our cues as to what is required to create the requisite relationship from
the securities fraud precedents and the common law. See Chiarella, 445 U.S. at
227-30, 100 S.Ct. at 1114-16. The common law has recognized that some
associations are inherently fiduciary. Counted among these hornbook fiduciary
relations are those existing between attorney and client, executor and heir,
guardian and ward, principal and agent, trustee and trust beneficiary, and senior
corporate official and shareholder. Reed, 601 F.Supp. at 704 (citing Coffee,
From Tort to Crime: Some Reflections on the Criminalization of Fiduciary
Breaches and the Problematic Line Between Law and Ethics, 19
Am.Crim.L.Rev. 117, 150 (1981); and Scott, The Fiduciary Principle, 37
Cal.L.Rev. 539, 541 (1949)); Black's Law Dictionary 564 (5th ed. 1979). While
this list is by no means exhaustive, it is clear that the relationships involved in
this case--those between Keith and Susan Loeb and between Keith Loeb and
the Waldbaum family--were not traditional fiduciary relationships.

83

That does not end our inquiry, however. The misappropriation theory requires
us to consider not only whether there exists a fiduciary relationship but also
whether there exists a "similar relationship of trust and confidence." As the
term "similar" implies, a "relationship of trust and confidence" must share the
essential characteristics of a fiduciary association. Absent reference to the
adjective "similar," interpretation of a "relationship of trust and confidence"
becomes an exercise in question begging. Consider: when one entrusts a secret
(read confidence ) to another, there then exists a relationship of trust and
confidence. Walton, however, instructs that entrusting confidential information
to another does not, without more, create the necessary relationship and its
correlative duty to maintain the confidence. A "similar relationship of trust and
confidence," therefore, must be the functional equivalent of a fiduciary
relationship. To determine whether such a relationship exists, we must ascertain
the characteristics of a fiduciary relationship.

84

"[A]t the heart of the fiduciary relationship" lies "reliance, and de facto control
and dominance." United States v. Margiotta, 688 F.2d 108, 125 (2d Cir.1982)
(citations omitted) (nonpublic office holder found to owe a fiduciary duty to

general citizenry, breach of which created predicate for violation of mail fraud
statute) (construing New York law), cert. denied, 461 U.S. 913, 103 S.Ct. 1891,
77 L.Ed.2d 282 (1983). The relation "exists when confidence is reposed on one
side and there is resulting superiority and influence on the other." Mobil Oil
Corp. v. Rubenfeld, 72 Misc.2d 392, 400, 339 N.Y.S.2d 623, 632 (Civ.Ct.1972)
(discussing fiduciary duty in the franchisee context), aff'd, 77 Misc.2d 962, 357
N.Y.S.2d 589 (Sup.Ct.App.1974), rev'd on other grounds, 48 A.D.2d 428, 370
N.Y.S.2d 943 (2d Dep't 1975), aff'd, 40 N.Y.2d 936, 390 N.Y.S.2d 57, 358
N.E.2d 882 (1976)). One acts in a "fiduciary capacity" when
85 business which he transacts, or the money or property which he handles, is not
the
his own or for his own benefit, but for the benefit of another person, as to whom he
stands in a relation implying and necessitating great confidence and trust on the one
part and a high degree of good faith on the other part.
86

Black's Law Dictionary 564 (5th ed. 1979). See also 29 U.S.C. 1002(21)(A)
(defining a fiduciary for purposes of ERISA as one "who exercises any
discretionary authority or discretionary control").

87

A fiduciary relationship involves discretionary authority and dependency: One


person depends on another--the fiduciary--to serve his interests. In relying on a
fiduciary to act for his benefit, the beneficiary of the relation may entrust the
fiduciary with custody over property of one sort or another. Because the
fiduciary obtains access to this property to serve the ends of the fiduciary
relationship, he becomes duty-bound not to appropriate the property for his
own use. What has been said of an agent's duty of confidentiality applies with
equal force to other fiduciary relations: "an agent is subject to a duty to the
principal not to use or to communicate information confidentially given him by
the principal or acquired by him during the course of or on account of his
agency." Restatement (Second) of Agency 395 (1958). These characteristics
represent the measure of the paradigmatic fiduciary relationship. A similar
relationship of trust and confidence consequently must share these qualities.

88

In Reed, 601 F.Supp. 685, the district court confronted the question whether
these principal characteristics of a fiduciary relationship--dependency and
influence--were necessary factual prerequisites to a similar relationship of trust
and confidence. There a member of the board of directors of Amax, Gordon
Reed, disclosed to his son on several occasions confidential information
concerning a proposed tender offer for Amax. Allegedly relying on this
information, the son purchased Amax stock call options. The son was
subsequently indicted for violating, among other things, Rule 10b-5 based on
breach of a fiduciary duty arising between the father and son. The son then

moved to dismiss the indictment, contending that he did not breach a fiduciary
duty to his father. The district court sustained the indictment.
89

Both the government and Chestman rely on Reed. The government draws on
Reed's application of the misappropriation theory in the family context and its
expansive construction of relationships of trust and confidence. Chestman,
without challenging the holding in Reed, argues that Reed cannot sustain his
Rule 10b-5 convictions because, unlike Reed senior and junior, Keith and
Susan Loeb did not customarily repose confidential business information in one
another. Neither party challenges the holding of Reed. And we decline to do so
sua sponte. To remain consistent with our interpretation of a "similar
relationship of trust and confidence," however, we limit Reed to its essential
holding: the repeated disclosure of business secrets between family members
may substitute for a factual finding of dependence and influence and thereby
sustain a finding of the functional equivalent of a fiduciary relationship. We
note, in this regard, that Reed repeatedly emphasized that the father and son
"frequently discussed business affairs." Id. at 690; see also id. at 705, 709, 71718.

90

We recognize, as Reed did, that equity has occasionally established a less


rigorous threshold for a fiduciary-like relationship in order to right civil wrongs
arising from non-compliance with the statute of frauds, statute of wills and
parol evidence rule. See Bogert, supra 482, at 286 (explaining that equity's
flexible treatment of confidential relationships has been particularly useful in
evading the harsh consequences of the statute of frauds). Commenting on the
boundless nature of relations of trust and confidence, one scholar observed:

91
Equity
has never bound itself by any hard and fast definition of the phrase
"confidential relation" and has not listed all the necessary elements of such a
relation, but has reserved discretion to apply the doctrine whenever it believes that a
suitable occasion has arisen.
92

Reed, 601 F.Supp. at 712 n. 38 (quoting G.G. Bogert, The Law of Trusts and
Trustees 482, at 284-86 (Rev. 2d ed. 1978)). Useful as such an elastic and
expedient definition of confidential relations, i.e., relations of trust and
confidence, may be in the civil context, it has no place in the criminal law. A
"suitable occasion" test for determining the presence of criminal fraud would
offend not only the rule of lenity but due process as well. See Chiarella, 445
U.S. at 235 n. 20, 100 S.Ct. at 1118 n. 20 ("a judicial holding that certain
undefined activities 'generally are prohibited' by 10(b) would raise questions
whether either criminal or civil defendants would be given fair notice that they
have engaged in illegal activity"). See also Dirks, 463 U.S. at 658 n. 17, 103

S.Ct. at 3263 n. 17 (In rejecting an SEC variation on the parity of information


theory, the Court wrote: "[T]his rule is inherently imprecise, and imprecision
prevents parties from ordering their actions in accord with legal
requirements."). More than a perfunctory nod at the rule of lenity, then, is
required. We will not apply outer permutations of chancery relief in addressing
what is frequently the core inquiry in a Rule 10b-5 criminal conviction-whether a fiduciary duty has been breached.
93

4. Application of the Law of Fiduciary Duties

94

The alleged misappropriator in this case was Keith Loeb. According to the
government's theory of prosecution, Loeb breached a fiduciary duty to his wife
Susan and the Waldbaum family when he disclosed to Robert Chestman
information concerning a pending tender offer for Waldbaum stock. Chestman
was convicted as an aider and abettor of the misappropriation and as a tippee of
the misappropriated information. Convictions under both theories, the
government concedes, required the government to establish two critical
elements--Loeb breached a fiduciary duty to Susan Loeb or to the Waldbaum
family and Chestman knew that Loeb had done so.

95

Chestman challenges the sufficiency of the evidence to establish each of these


elements of the convictions. Although such a challenge carries a "heavy
burden," United States v. Chang An-Lo, 851 F.2d 547, 553 (2d Cir.), cert.
denied, 488 U.S. 966, 109 S.Ct. 493, 102 L.Ed.2d 530 (1988), that burden was
carried here.

96

We have little trouble finding the evidence insufficient to establish a fiduciary


relationship or its functional equivalent between Keith Loeb and the Waldbaum
family. The government presented only two pieces of evidence on this point.
The first was that Keith was an extended member of the Waldbaum family,
specifically the family patriarch's (Ira Waldbaum's) "nephew-in-law." The
second piece of evidence concerned Ira's discussions of the business with
family members. "My children," Ira Waldbaum testified, "have always been
involved with me and my family and they know we never speak about business
outside of the family." His earlier testimony indicates that the "family" to which
he referred were his "three children who were involved in the business."

97

Lending this evidence the reasonable inferences to which it is entitled, United


States v. Zabare, 871 F.2d 282, 286 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 493 U.S. 856, 110
S.Ct. 161, 107 L.Ed.2d 119 (1989), it falls short of establishing the relationship
necessary for fiduciary obligations. Kinship alone does not create the necessary

relationship. The government proffered nothing more to establish a fiduciarylike association. It did not show that Keith Loeb had been brought into the
family's inner circle, whose members, it appears, discussed confidential
business information either because they were kin or because they worked
together with Ira Waldbaum. Keith was not an employee of Waldbaum and
there was no showing that he participated in confidential communications
regarding the business. The critical information was gratuitously communicated
to him. The disclosure did not serve the interests of Ira Waldbaum, his children
or the Waldbaum company. Nor was there any evidence that the alleged
relationship was characterized by influence or reliance of any sort. Measured
against the principles of fiduciary relations, the evidence does not support a
finding that Keith Loeb and the Waldbaum family shared either a fiduciary
relation or its functional equivalent.
98

The government's theory that Keith breached a fiduciary duty of confidentiality


to Susan suffers from similar defects. The evidence showed: Keith and Susan
were married; Susan admonished Keith not to disclose that Waldbaum was the
target of a tender offer; and the two had shared and maintained confidences in
the past.

99

Keith's status as Susan's husband could not itself establish fiduciary status. Nor,
absent a pre-existing fiduciary relation or an express agreement of
confidentiality, could the coda--"Don't tell." That leaves the unremarkable
testimony that Keith and Susan had shared and maintained generic confidences
before. The jury was not told the nature of these past disclosures and therefore
it could not reasonably find a relationship that inspired fiduciary, rather than
normal marital, obligations.

100 In the absence of evidence of an explicit acceptance by Keith of a duty of


confidentiality, the context of the disclosure takes on special import. While
acceptance may be implied, it must be implied from a pre-existing fiduciarylike relationship between the parties. Here the government presented the jury
with insufficient evidence from which to draw a rational inference of implied
acceptance. Susan's disclosure of the information to Keith served no purpose,
business or otherwise. The disclosure also was unprompted. Keith did not
induce her to convey the information through misrepresentation or subterfuge.
Superiority and reliance, moreover, did not mark this relationship either before
or after the disclosure of the confidential information. Nor did Susan's
dependence on Keith to act in her interests for some purpose inspire the
disclosure. The government failed even to establish a pattern of sharing
business confidences between the couple. The government, therefore, failed to
offer sufficient evidence to establish the functional equivalent of a fiduciary

relation.
101 In sum, because Keith owed neither Susan nor the Waldbaum family a
fiduciary duty or its functional equivalent, he did not defraud them by
disclosing news of the pending tender offer to Chestman. Absent a predicate act
of fraud by Keith Loeb, the alleged misappropriator, Chestman could not be
derivatively liable as Loeb's tippee or as an aider and abettor. Therefore,
Chestman's Rule 10b-5 convictions must be reversed.
C. Mail Fraud
102 The fortunes of Chestman's mail fraud convictions are tied closely to his
securities fraud convictions. "Chestman's mail fraud convictions," the
government concedes, "were based on the same theory as his Rule 10b-5
convictions." The same fraudulent scheme that underlay the Rule 10b-5
convictions also was the basis for the mail fraud convictions. A scheme to
misappropriate material nonpublic information in breach of a fiduciary duty of
confidentiality may indeed constitute a fraudulent scheme sufficient to sustain a
mail fraud conviction. See Carpenter, 484 U.S. at 27-28, 108 S.Ct. at 321-22;
Newman, 664 F.2d at 19. However, whatever ethical obligation Loeb may have
owed the Waldbaum family or Susan Loeb, it was too ethereal to be protected
by either the securities or mail fraud statutes.
CONCLUSION
103 Accordingly, we affirm the Rule 14e-3(a) convictions and reverse the Rule
10b-5 and mail fraud convictions. The reversal of these convictions does not
warrant reconsideration of the sentence since the sentences on the Rule 10b-5
and mail fraud convictions are concurrent with the sentences in the Rule 14(e)3(a) counts. The panel's reversal of the perjury conviction remains intact.
104 WINTER, Circuit Judge (joined by OAKES, Chief Judge, NEWMAN,
KEARSE, and McLAUGHLIN, Circuit Judges), concurring in part and
dissenting in part:
105 I concur in the decision to affirm Chestman's convictions under Section 14(e) of
the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (" '34 Act"), and under Rule 14e-3. I
respectfully dissent, however, from the reversals of his convictions under
Section 10(b) and under the mail fraud statute, 18 U.S.C. 1341 (1988).
1) INSIDER TRADING

106 The difficulty this court finds in resolving the issues raised by this appeal stems
largely from the history of the development of the law concerning insider
trading. For that reason, I begin by tracing that history in somewhat tiresome
fashion.
107 a) Statutory Law and Caselaw
108 The legal rules governing insider trading under Section 10(b) are based solely
on administrative and judicial caselaw. This caselaw establishes that some
trading on material nonpublic information is illegal and some is not. The line
between the two is less than clear. Although Congress has enhanced the
penalties for illegal insider trading, see Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984,
Pub.L. No. 98-376, 98 Stat. 1264,1 it has not defined the criteria by which legal
insider trading is separated from illegal trading. And, although the Securities
and Exchange Commission ("SEC") seems to take a somewhat more expansive
view of what is illegal than the courts, see Complaint in SEC v. Phillip J.
Stevens, No. 91 Civ. 1869 (S.D.N.Y. filed Mar. 19, 1991) (insider trading suit
where sole allegation of benefit to insider was that selective leaking would
enhance insider's reputation); see also Coffee, The SEC and the Securities
Analyst, N.Y.L.J. May 30, 1991, at 5, col. 1, the SEC has, apart from Rule 14e3, forgone the opportunity to use its rulemaking power to define what insider
trading is.
109 Federal regulation of insider trading began with the passage of Section 16(b) of
the '34 Act. 15 U.S.C. 78p (1988). That provision regulates short-swing
trading by insiders and requires that they disgorge any profits from such trading
to the corporation. Until 1961, it constituted the sole federal regulation of
insider trading. Section 16(b) regulates trading over a statutorily-defined sixmonth period without regard to the purpose of the trading or its basis in
nonpublic information, id. 78p(b) ("irrespective of any intention"), defines
insider precisely as a holder of 10 percent of the corporation's shares ("directly
or indirectly the beneficial owner of more than 10 per centum"), or as a director
or an officer, id. 78p(a), and provides a mechanical method of determining
"profits" under which disgorgement is required even when the trades as a whole
have resulted in losses, id. 78p(b) ("any sale and purchase ... within any
period of less than six months"); see Gratz v. Claughton, 187 F.2d 46, 50-52
(2d Cir.), cert. denied, 341 U.S. 920, 71 S.Ct. 741, 95 L.Ed. 1353 (1951). As a
result, Section 16(b)'s enforcement by courts has led to no more, and perhaps
fewer, problems of statutory interpretation than have resulted from any other
provision of federal securities law.
110 The existence of Section 16(b), which indicates that Congress expressly

110 The existence of Section 16(b), which indicates that Congress expressly
addressed the issue, might well have led the SEC and the courts to conclude
that Congress intended that Section 16(b) be the sole provision governing
insider trading. No other provision explicitly addresses the problem, and
Section 16(b) eliminates what is perhaps the most obvious danger inherent in
insider trading, namely the creation of an incentive for directors or officers to
make share price volatile in order to profit from short-swing trading.2
Moreover, one might have inferred from Section 16(b)'s mechanical approach,
ignoring purpose and actual profit, that regulation of insider trading without
legislative or regulatory guidelines would involve a mare's nest of analytic and
definitional problems.
111 Nevertheless, in 1961 the SEC held that insider trading might also violate
Section 10(b) of the '34 Act. See Cady, Roberts & Co., 40 SEC 907 (1961).
Although Section 10(b) is familiar to any federal judge with a month of service,
it is worth quoting its pertinent language:
It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly
112
******
113
114 (b) To use or employ, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security ...
any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of such
rules and regulations as the Commission may prescribe....
115 15 U.S.C. 78j (1988). The regulation promulgated by the SEC pertinent to the
instant case is Rule 10b-5. That rule reads:
116 It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly ...
117 (a) To employ any device, scheme, or artifice to defraud,
118 (b) To make any untrue statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material
fact necessary in order to make the statements made, in the light of the
circumstances under which they were made, not misleading, or
119 (c) To engage in any act, practice, or course of business which operates or
would operate as a fraud or deceit upon any person,
120 in connection with the purchase or sale of any security.
121 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5 (1990).

121 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5 (1990).


122 Even the most fervent opponents of insider trading must concede that the
language of Section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5 is at best a general authorization to
the SEC and to the courts to fashion rules founded largely on those tribunals'
judgments as to why insider trading is or is not fraudulent, deceptive or
manipulative. That much was evident in Cady, Roberts & Co. itself, which was
decided almost a generation after Section 10(b) had been passed and yet was
without direct precedent. The grounds for the decision are also worth quoting in
detail:
123 We have already noted that the anti-fraud provisions are phrased in terms of
'any person' and that a special obligation has been traditionally required of
corporate insiders, e.g., officers, directors and controlling stockholders. These
three groups, however, do not exhaust the classes of persons upon whom there
is such an obligation. Analytically, the obligation rests on two principal
elements; first, the existence of a relationship giving access, directly or
indirectly, to information intended to be available only for a corporate purpose
and not for the personal benefit of anyone, and second, the inherent unfairness
involved where a party takes advantage of such information knowing it is
unavailable to those with whom he is dealing.... Thus our task here is to
identify those persons who are in a special relationship with a company and
privy to its internal affairs, and thereby suffer correlative duties in trading in its
securities. Intimacy demands restraint lest the uninformed be exploited.
******
124
125 We cannot accept respondents' contention that an insider's responsibility is
limited to existing stockholders and that he has no special duties when sales of
securities are made to non-stockholders. This approach is too narrow. It ignores
the plight of the buying public--wholly unprotected from the misuse of special
information.
126 ... Whatever distinctions may have existed at common law based on the view
that an officer or director may stand in a fiduciary relationship to existing
stockholders from whom he purchases but not to members of the public to
whom he sells, it is clearly not appropriate to introduce these into the broader
anti-fraud concepts embodied in the securities acts.
127 Respondents further assert that they made no express representations and did
not in any way manipulate the market, and urge that in a transaction on an
exchange there is no further duty such as may be required in a 'face-to-face'

transaction. We reject this suggestion. It would be anomalous indeed if the


protection afforded by the antifraud provisions were withdrawn from
transactions effected on exchanges, primary markets for securities transactions.
If purchasers on an exchange had available material information known by a
selling insider, we may assume that their investment judgment would be
affected and their decision whether to buy might accordingly be modified.
Consequently, any sales by the insider must await disclosure of the
information.
128 (footnotes omitted). Cady, Roberts & Co. thus adopted a rule against insider
trading with two elements: (i) a trader's relationship giving special access to
corporate information not intended for private use and (ii) the unfairness
resulting from trading with those who lack the informational advantage
afforded by that special access. Under the theory of Cady, Roberts & Co., the
second element furnishes the fraud or deception that links the prohibition on
insider trading to Section 10(b).
129 In SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833 (2d Cir.1968), cert. denied,
394 U.S. 976, 89 S.Ct. 1454, 22 L.Ed.2d 756 (1969) ("TGS "), we adopted the
dual element rule of Cady, Roberts & Co. We also noted, however, that Cady,
Roberts & Co.--which involved a tippee who was a partner in a brokerage firm
that employed a director, the tipper, of the corporation in question--had stated
that Section 10(b)'s ban on insider trading applied to more than traditional
insiders such as officers, directors and controlling stockholders. 401 F.2d at
848. We thus stated that "anyone in possession of material inside information
must either disclose it to the investing public, or, if he is disabled from
disclosing it in order to protect a corporate confidence, or he chooses not to do
so, must abstain from trading in or recommending the securities concerned
while such inside information remains undisclosed." Id. We stressed that
Congress wanted investors to "be subject to identical market risks." Id. at 852.
Section 10(b)'s ban on insider trading was thus designed to eliminate
"inequities based upon unequal access to knowledge." Id.
130 TGS thus emphasized the second element in Cady, Roberts & Co., the
perceived unfairness to those who trade with the insider. Although each trader
in TGS probably had a relationship to the corporation with regard to the
information in question sufficient to satisfy the first element of Cady, Roberts
& Co., TGS suggested that possession of material, nonpublic information,
however acquired, was sufficient by itself to trigger an obligation to disclose or
abstain from trading.
131 In a subsequent decision, United States v. Chiarella, 588 F.2d 1358 (2d

Cir.1978), rev'd, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d 348 (1980), we
affirmed the conviction of an employee of a printer who determined from
coded takeover documents the identity of target corporations and thereafter
purchased stock in those corporations. The basis for our decision tracked TGS,
namely, the perceived unfairness of trading on information that is not generally
available. We thus stated, "[a ]nyone --corporate insider or not--who regularly
receives material nonpublic information may not use that information to trade
in securities without incurring an affirmative duty to disclose. And if he cannot
disclose, he must abstain from buying or selling." 588 F.2d at 1365 (emphasis
in original, footnote omitted). In a footnote to the quoted passage, we noted that
Chiarella was legally disabled from disclosing because he owed a duty to his
employer not to reveal confidential information belonging to the employer's
clients. Id. at 1365 n. 9. Chiarella thus extended the ban on insider trading to
"anyone," limited only by the phrase "regularly receives," and relegated the role
of Cady, Roberts & Co.'s first element--a relationship to the firm giving access
to confidential corporate information--to eliminating the option of disclosure
(and thus trading) by insiders.
132 Our rationale seemed overbroad to many, including the Solicitor General,
whose task it was to defend the judgment we had affirmed. The brief filed in
the Supreme Court on behalf of the government thus downplayed the fact that
Chiarella had traded on information unavailable to others and instead relied
upon the first reason given in Cady, Roberts & Co., namely, that Chiarella's
trading was based on information that belonged to his employer's clients. See
Brief for Government at 70-71 n. 48, Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222,
100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d 348 (1980); Easterbrook, supra, at 314-15.
133 The Supreme Court reversed Chiarella. However, rather than making an ab
initio determination of whether Section 10(b) prohibited insider trading, the
Court described the state of the caselaw in the SEC and lower federal courts,
including Cady, Roberts & Co. and TGS, and impliedly adopted that caselaw.
445 U.S. at 225-30, 100 S.Ct. at 1113-16. Notwithstanding its seeming
adoption of that caselaw, the Court's opinion rejected the view that any trading
on material nonpublic information triggered a duty to disclose. Id. at 231-35,
100 S.Ct. at 1116-18. It reasoned that fraud must be shown under Section 10(b)
and that silence cannot constitute a fraud absent a duty to speak owed to those
who are injured. Id. at 232-33, 100 S.Ct. at 1116-17. Because Chiarella had no
prior dealings with those from whom he bought the stock, was not their agent,
fiduciary or someone in whom they placed trust--as is true of all buyers and
sellers trading on impersonal exchanges--Chiarella owed those from whom he
purchased stock no duty to disclose before trading. Id. The Court declined to
decide whether his conviction might be affirmed on the theory advanced by the

Solicitor General that he had breached a duty to his employer's clients, the
acquiring corporations, because the instructions to the jury did not include that
theory. Id. at 235-36, 100 S.Ct. at 1118-19.
134 Although Chiarella's description of prior caselaw appeared to adopt Cady,
Roberts & Co. and TGS, it cannot be reconciled with those decisions. By
explicitly holding that Chiarella's access to material nonpublic information did
not create a duty on Chiarella's part to those from whom he purchased stock of
the target corporations, Chiarella is inconsistent with Cady, Roberts & Co.,
which explicitly found a duty to those with whom the trader dealt even when
the trade was made on an impersonal exchange. 40 S.E.C. at 912-13. Moreover,
Chiarella stated that even if the informational edge insiders have over those
with whom they trade is unfair, that advantage was not fraud under Section
10(b). 445 U.S. at 232, 100 S.Ct. at 1116-17.
135 The Chiarella opinion is thus an enigma. It appears to state that Section 10(b)
bars some kinds of insider trading. However, it rejects the element of Cady,
Roberts & Co. that provided the fraud or deception linking the conduct to the
provisions of Section 10(b).
136 Matters were clarified a tad in Dirks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 103 S.Ct. 3255, 77
L.Ed.2d 911 (1983). Dirks had learned from employees of Equity Funding that
the corporation had systematically and fraudulently overstated its assets. Id. at
649, 103 S.Ct. at 3258-59. Dirks informed his clients and the Wall Street
Journal as well. His clients, who could sell their Equity Funding shares without
risking a libel action, acted on Dirks' information while the Journal did not. Id.
at 649-50, 103 S.Ct. at 3258-59. The SEC commenced a proceeding against
Dirks on the ground that he had illegally aided and abetted insider trading by
informing his clients of the material nonpublic information that Equity Funding
was a fraud. The Supreme Court disagreed.
137 In the Court's view, a tippee such as Dirks may be liable under Section 10(b) if
the tipper breaches a fiduciary obligation by transmitting the material nonpublic
information to the tippee. Id. at 661-64, 103 S.Ct. at 3265-66. Whether the tip
breaches such a fiduciary obligation depends upon whether the tipper "receives
a direct or indirect personal benefit from the disclosure, such as a pecuniary
gain or a reputational benefit that will translate into future earnings." Id. at 663,
103 S.Ct. at 3266. "The elements of fiduciary duty and exploitation of
nonpublic information also exist when an insider makes a gift of confidential
information to a trading relative or friend. The tip and trade resemble trading by
the insider himself followed by a gift of profits to the recipient." Id. at 664, 103
S.Ct. at 3266.

138 However, the Court concluded that Dirks owed no duty to Equity Funding, its
shareholders, or, under Chiarella, to those who purchased stock from his
clients. Id. at 665, 103 S.Ct. at 3267. Moreover, it also held that the employees
of Equity Funding who had provided information to Dirks breached no duty to
Equity Funding or its shareholders. Id. at 666, 103 S.Ct. at 3267. The Court
noted that the employees neither had received a benefit from their disclosure to
Dirks nor had intended to make a gift of such information to Dirks. Id. at 667,
103 S.Ct. at 3268. Instead, they were motivated soley by a desire to expose
fraud. Id. It also noted that their action prevented the fraud from continuing and
injuring yet new victims. Id. at 666, n. 27, 103 S.Ct. at 3267, n. 27.
139 Apart from the 4-4 vote in Carpenter v. United States, 484 U.S. 19, 108 S.Ct.
316, 98 L.Ed.2d 275 (1987), regarding the so-called misappropriation theory,
Supreme Court caselaw regarding insider trading under Section 10(b) stops
with Dirks. Omitted from the Court's opinions is a statement of the reasons why
Section 10(b) prohibits the kind of trading the Court has declared to be illegal.
Having rejected the Cady, Roberts & Co. theory of fraud or deception in the
superiority of information available to the inside trader and a resultant duty in
the trader to the persons with whom trading occurs, the Court's decisions have
severed the link to Section 10(b) perceived in prior caselaw. While Dirks has
established a rule concerning the insider's breach of an obligation to the
corporation whose shares are traded, the Court's rationale is obscure, and, as a
result, so is the scope of the rule.
140 Notwithstanding the ambiguities surrounding Section 10(b)'s impact on insider
trading--including its very definition--Congress has increased the penalties for
violations of that prohibition. See Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984,
Pub.L. No. 98-376, 98 Stat. 1264. The SEC in turn has failed to promulgate
rules outside the area of tender offers but its decisions have continued to march,
in the eyes of one commentator, to the beat of its own drummer. See Coffee,
supra, at 5., col. 1 ("in Stevens ... the SEC has announced a theory that
trivializes Dirks ").
141 It is hardly surprising that disagreement exists within an in banc court of
appeals as to the import of present caselaw. Nor is it surprising that the lower
courts have added to the Dirks breach of duty doctrine a misappropriation of
information doctrine, which prohibits trading in securities based on material,
nonpublic information acquired in violation of a duty to any owner of such
information, whether or not the owner is the corporation whose shares are
traded. See SEC v. Materia, 745 F.2d 197, 203 (2d Cir.1984) ("one who
misappropriates [material] nonpublic information in breach of a fiduciary duty
and trades on that information" violates Section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5); cert.

denied, 471 U.S. 1053, 105 S.Ct. 2112, 85 L.Ed.2d 477 (1985); accord SEC v.
Cherif, 933 F.2d 403, 408-10 (7th Cir.1991); SEC v. Clark, 915 F.2d 439, 44349 (9th Cir.1990); Rothberg v. Rosenbloom, 771 F.2d 818, 822 (3d Cir.1985).
142 b) Property Rights in Inside Information
143 One commentator has attempted to explain the Supreme Court decisions in
terms of the business-property rationale for banning insider trading mentioned
in Cady, Roberts & Co. See Easterbrook, supra, at 309-39. That rationale may
be summarized as follows. Information is perhaps the most precious
commodity in commercial markets. It is expensive to produce, and, because it
involves facts and ideas that can be easily photocopied or carried in one's head,
there is a ubiquitous risk that those who pay to produce information will see
others reap the profit from it. Where the profit from an activity is likely to be
diverted, investment in that activity will decline. If the law fails to protect
property rights in commercial information, therefore, less will be invested in
generating such information. Id. at 313.
144 For example, mining companies whose investments in geological surveys have
revealed valuable deposits do not want word of the strike to get out until they
have secured rights to the land.3 If word does get out, the price of the land not
only will go up, but other mining companies may also secure the rights. In
either case, the mining company that invested in geological surveys (including
the inevitably sizeable number of unsuccessful drillings) will see profits from
that investment enjoyed by others. If mining companies are unable to keep the
results of such surveys confidential, less will be invested in them.
145 Similarly, firms that invest money in generating information about other
companies with a view to some form of combination will maintain secrecy
about their efforts, and if secrecy cannot be maintained, less will be invested in
acquiring such information. Hostile acquirers will want to keep such
information secret lest the target mount defensive actions or speculators
purchase the target's stock. Even when friendly negotiations with the other
company are undertaken, the acquirer will often require the target corporation
to maintain secrecy about negotiations, lest the very fact of negotiation tip off
others on the important fact that the two firms think a combination might be
valuable. See, e.g., Staffin v. Greenberg, 672 F.2d 1196, 1207 n. 12 (3d
Cir.1982) ("If, as is often the case, a merger will benefit both the acquired
company and its shareholders, an insider may be obliged to maintain strict
confidentiality to avoid ruining the corporate opportunity through premature
disclosure. Indeed, the record is clear in this case that [the buyer] very nearly
withdrew from merger discussions upon hearing of [the seller's] ... press

release."); Flamm v. Eberstadt, 814 F.2d 1169, 1174-79 (7th Cir.) ("[P]otential
acquirers ... may fear that premature disclosure may spark competition that will
deprive them of part of the value of their effort, so that bids in a world of early
disclosure will be lower than bids in a world of deferred disclosure."), cert.
denied, 484 U.S. 853, 108 S.Ct. 157, 98 L.Ed.2d 112 (1987). In the instant
matter, A & P made secrecy a condition of its acquisition of Waldbaum's.
146 Insider trading may reduce the return on information in two ways. First, it
creates incentives for insiders to generate or disclose information that may
disregard the welfare of the corporation. Easterbrook, supra, at 332-33. That
risk is not implicated by the facts in the present case, and no further discussion
is presently required.
147 Second, insider trading creates a risk that information will be prematurely
disclosed by such trading, and the corporation will lose part or all of its
property in that information. Id. at 331. Although trades by an insider may
rarely affect market price, others who know of the insider's trading may notice
that a trader is unusually successful, or simply perceive unusual activity in a
stock and guess the information and/or make piggyback trades.4 Id. at 336. A
broker who executes a trade for a geologist or for a financial printer may well
draw relevant conclusions. Or, as in the instant matter, the trader, Loeb, may
tell his or her broker about the inside information, who may then trade on his or
her account, on clients' accounts, or may tell friends and relatives. One inside
trader has publicly attributed his exposure in part to the fact that the bank
through which he made trades piggybacked on the trades, as did the broker who
made the trades for the bank. See Levine, The Inside Story of An Inside Trader,
Fortune, May 21, 1990, at 80. Once activity in a stock reaches an unusual stage,
others may guess the reason for the trading--the corporate secret. Insider
trading thus increases the risk that confidential information acquired at a cost
may be disclosed. If so, the owner of the information may lose its investment.
148 This analysis provides a policy rationale for prohibiting insider trading when
the property rights of a corporation in information are violated by traders.
However, the rationale stops well short of prohibiting all trading on material
nonpublic information. Efficient capital markets depend on the protection of
property rights in information. However, they also require that persons who
acquire and act on information about companies be able to profit from the
information they generate so long as the method by which the information is
acquired does not amount to a form of theft. A rule commanding equal access
would result in a securities market governed by relative degrees of ignorance
because the profit motive for independently generating information about
companies would be substantially diminished. Easterbrook, supra, at 313-14.

Under such circumstances, the pricing of securities would be less accurate than
in circumstances in which the production of information is encouraged by legal
protection.
149 One may speculate that it was for these reasons that the Supreme Court
declined in Chiarella to adopt a broad ban on trading on material nonpublic
information 5 and then imposed in Dirks a breach of fiduciary duty requirement-not running to those with whom the trader buys or sells. Under the Dirks rule,
insider trading is illegal only where the trader has received the information as a
result of the trader's or tipper's breach of a duty to keep information
confidential.
150 The misappropriation theory adopted by several circuits fits within this
rationale. Misappropriation also involves the misuse of confidential information
in a way that risks making information public in a fashion similar to trading by
corporate insiders. In U.S. v. Carpenter, 791 F.2d 1024 (2d Cir.1986), aff'd, 484
U.S. 19, 108 S.Ct. 316, 98 L.Ed.2d 275 (1987), for example, where the
information belonged to the Wall Street Journal rather than to the corporations
whose shares were traded, the misuse of information created an incentive on
the part of the traders to create false information that might affect the efficiency
of the market's pricing of the corporations' stock. Moreover, the potential for
piggybacking would add to that inefficiency.
151 It must be noted, however, that, although the rationale set out above provides a
policy for prohibiting a specific kind of insider trading, any obvious
relationship to Section 10(b) is presently missing because theft rather than
fraud or deceit, seems the gravamen of the prohibition. Indeed, Carpenter
analogized the conduct there to embezzlement. 791 F.2d at 1033 n. 11.
Nevertheless, the law is far enough down this road--indeed, the Insider Trading
Sanctions Act seems premised on Section 10(b)'s applicability--that a court of
appeals has no option but to continue the route.
152 c) The Instant Case
153 When this analysis is applied to a family-controlled corporation such as that
involved in the instant case, I believe that family members who have benefitted
from the family's control of the corporation are under a duty not to disclose
confidential corporate information that comes to them in the ordinary course of
family affairs. In the case of family-controlled corporations, family and
business affairs are necessarily intertwined, and it is inevitable that from time to
time normal familial interactions will lead to the revelation of confidential

corporate matters to various family members. Indeed, the very nature of


familial relationships may cause the disclosure of corporate matters to avoid
misunderstandings among family members or suggestions that a family
member is unworthy of trust.
154 Keith Loeb learned of the pending acquisition of Waldbaum's by A & P
through precisely such interactions. His wife Susan was asked one day by her
sister to take carpool responsibilities for their children. When Susan inquired as
to why this was necessary, the sister was vague and said that she had to take
their mother somewhere. After further inquiry, the sister flatly declined to tell
Susan what was going on. Susan did not say, "Gee, confidential corporate
information must be involved, and I have no right to such information." Instead,
concerned about her mother's ongoing health problems, Susan made direct
inquiry of her mother, who revealed that Susan's sister took her to get stock
certificates to give to Ira Waldbaum for the initial phase of the A & P
acquisition. The mother swore Susan to secrecy, telling Susan that the
acquisition would be very profitable to the family and premature disclosure
could ruin the deal. Susan then asked whether she could tell her husband Keith.
Instead of saying, "No, Keith may be your husband but you are to button your
lips in his presence," her mother assented but warned against disclosure to
anyone else.
155 Susan and Keith Loeb jointly owned a large number of Waldbaum shares at
that time, all of which had been a gift from her mother. The Loebs' children also
owned shares received as a gift from their grandmother. Susan told Keith about
the A & P acquisition in the course of discussing the financial benefits they and
their children would receive as a result of that transaction. She stressed the need
for absolute secrecy. Susan testified that she and her husband had shared
confidences in the past and that on each such occasion they had indicated to
each other that the confidences would be respected. Thereafter, Keith Loeb
informed Chestman about the A & P acquisition in the hope of making a profit.
156 I have little difficulty in concluding that Chestman's convictions can be
affirmed on either the Dirks rule or on a misappropriation theory. The
disclosure of information concerning the A & P acquisition among Ira
Waldbaum's extended family was the result of ordinary familial interactions
that can be expected in the case of family-controlled corporations. Members of
a family who receive such information are placed in a position in which their
trading on the information risks financial injury to the corporation, its public
shareholders and other family members. When members of a family have
benefitted from the family's control of a corporation and are in a position to
acquire such information in the ordinary course of family interactions, that

position carries with it a duty not to disclose. The family relationship gives such
members access to confidential information, not so that they can trade on it but
so that informal family relationships can be maintained. The purpose of
allowing this access can hardly be fulfilled if there is no accompanying duty not
to trade. Such a duty is of course based on mutual understandings among family
members--quite explicit in this case--and owed to the family. However, the
duty originates in the corporation and is ultimately intended to protect the
corporation and its public shareholders. The duty is thus also owed to the
corporation, to a degree sufficient in my view to trigger the Dirks rule. Because
trading on inside information so acquired by family members amounts to theft,
the misappropriation theory also applies.
157 Under my colleagues' theory, the disclosure of family corporate information
can be avoided only by family members extracting formal, express promises of
confidentiality or by elderly mothers in poor health refusing to tell their
daughters about mysterious travels. If disclosure is made, daughters may not
disclose their mother's doings or potential financial benefits to the daughters'
husbands without a formal, express promise of confidentiality. If, for example,
Susan had earlier shared with Keith her concerns about her mother's mysterious
travels before learning of their purpose, she would not have been able to tell
him what she later learned about those travels no matter how persistently he
asked. For my colleagues in the majority, the critical gap in the government's
case was that Susan did not testify either that on this occasion Keith agreed not
to disclose the pending acquisition by A & P or that prior confidential
communications between her and her husband had involved the Waldbaum's
corporation.
158 I have no lack of sympathy with my colleagues' concern about the difficulty of
drawing lines in this area. Nevertheless, the line they draw seems very
unrealistic in that it expects family members to behave like strangers toward
each other. It also leads to the perverse and circular result that where family
business interests are concerned, family members must act as if there are no
mutual obligations of trust and confidence because the law does not recognize
such obligations. Under such a regime, parents and children must conceal their
comings and goings, family members must cease to speak when a son-in-law
enters a room, and offended members of the family must understand that such
conduct is always related only to business.
159 The law may have been reluctant to recognize obligations based solely on
family relationships. However, the failure to recognize these commonly
observed obligations as legal obligations is in large part derived from a concern
that intra-family litigation would exacerbate strained relationships and weaken

rather than strengthen the sense of mutual obligation underlying family


relationships. See, e.g., Kilgrow v. Kilgrow, 268 Ala. 475, 107 So.2d 885
(1958) (judicial intervention in family affairs more likely to serve as "spark to a
smoldering fire" than to prevent disruption); McGuire v. McGuire, 157 Neb.
226, 59 N.W.2d 336 (1953) (no action for maintenance and support where
married couple living together).
160 This concern, however, is of no weight where insider trading is concerned. In
such cases, the litigation is almost universally brought by the government or
third party. Moreover, where the family connection to the corporation has
benefitted the trader, the relationship is commercial as well as familial, and
disclosure is potentially injurious to the corporation and public shareholders as
well as other members of the family.
161 I thus believe that a family member (i) who has received or expects (e.g.,
through inheritance) benefits from family control of a corporation, here gifts of
stock, (ii) who is in a position to learn confidential corporate information
through ordinary family interactions, and (iii) who knows that under the
circumstances both the corporation and the family desire confidentiality, has a
duty not to use information so obtained for personal profit where the use risks
disclosure. The receipt or expectation of benefits increases the interest of such
family members in corporate affairs and thus increases the chance that they will
learn confidential information. Disclosure in the present case occurred in the
course of a discussion that included, inter alia, an examination of the benefits of
the A & P acquisition to Susan, Keith and their children. Susan's warning to
Keith about secrecy was clearly intended to protect the corporation as well as
the family and clearly had originated with Ira Waldbaum. In such
circumstances, Susan's saying "Don't tell" is enough for me. Not to have such a
rule means that a family-controlled corporation with public shareholders is
subject to greater risk of disclosure of confidential information than is a
corporation that is entirely publicly owned.
162 I see no room for argument over whether there was sufficient evidence for the
jury to find that Chestman knew Keith Loeb was violating an obligation. The
record fairly brims with Chestman's consciousness that Keith Loeb was
behaving improperly. Loeb's initial message asked for a return call "asap."
When they spoke, Loeb told Chestman that he, Loeb, had some "definite, some
accurate information" that Waldbaum's was about to be sold at a price
substantially greater than that at which it was trading. Chestman had been a
broker for fourteen years, and the jury would have little trouble finding that he
knew that, if word of the A & P acquisition had not already gotten out, profiting
from purchases of Waldbaum's stock was as close to a sure thing as there can be

in the securities market. Instead of telling Loeb to buy, however, Chestman said
that he could not tell him what to do "in a situation like this" and told Loeb to
make up his own mind. Clearly, Chestman's and Loeb's concerns were not
about the commercial wisdom, but rather about the propriety, of Loeb's trading
on the "definite" and "accurate" information. Indeed, Loeb did not give
Chestman an order to buy Waldbaum's shares, and their conversation ended on
an inconclusive note.
163 The only explanation for Chestman's and Loeb's failing to agree upon the
entirely obvious course of buying Waldbaum's stock was their consciousness
that Loeb's trading would be improper. This conclusion is strengthened by
Chestman's conduct thereafter. Having failed to advise Loeb to buy, Chestman
sought information as to whether there was unusual activity in Waldbaum's
stock, and, learning there was not, bought Waldbaum's stock for his and his
clients' accounts, including Loeb's. Chestman's attempt at concealment when he
recorded the purchases for all of his clients but Loeb further showed
Chestman's knowledge that Loeb was acting improperly. The evidence was
thus more than sufficient to show Chestman's knowledge that Loeb was
breaching an obligation of non-disclosure.
2) RULE 14e-3
164 I have little difficulty in concurring in the affirmance of Chestman's conviction
for violating Section 14(e) and Rule 14e-3. Although the rule lacks a specific
reference to a duty not to disclose, the sources of information specified in that
rule--"(1) The offering person, (2) The issuer ... or (3) Any officer, director,
partner or employee or any other person acting on behalf of the offering person
or such issuer"--all have such a duty under state law not to disclose nonpublic
information concerning tender offers. Information relating to tender offers is
always either notoriously public or a carefully guarded secret. The sources of
information designated by the rule are necessarily under an obligation by
reason of their very position not to disclose such nonpublic information. One
who receives such information knowing the source can be held to know of a
breach of duty. The rule is thus in the nature of a traditional prophylactic rule.
Although the use of the word "indirectly" may lend itself to some extension
down the line of tippees and tippers, it is sufficiently cabined to circumstances
in which the defendant knows of the source. Chestman easily fits that
definition.
3) MAIL FRAUD
165 With regard to appellant's convictions for mail fraud, my view that they should

be affirmed follows from my discussion of the conviction for violations of


Sections 10(b) and Rule 10b-5.
166 I would add a brief observation, however. I am unclear as to whether the breach
of duty and the tippee's knowledge of that breach as required by Dirks is
coextensive with the similar requirements in Carpenter. The Dirks rule is
derived from securities law, and its limitation to information obtained through a
breach of a fiduciary duty is, as noted, influenced by the need to allow persons
to profit from generating information about firms so that the pricing of
securities is efficient. The Carpenter rule, however, is derived from the law of
theft or embezzlement, and a tippee's liability may be governed by rules
concerning the possession of stolen property. Logic is therefore certainly not a
barrier to the growth of disparate rules concerning a tippee's liability depending
on whether Section 10(b) or mail fraud is the source of law. However, because
under any such disparity in rules the Section 10(b) charge would be harder to
prove than a mail fraud charge, I need not explore the issue further.
MINER, Circuit Judge, concurring:
167 I concur in the comprehensive opinion of Judge Meskill, which I take to be
wholly in accordance with the views I expressed in the original panel opinion as
to all the issues before us. See United States v. Chestman, 903 F.2d 75 (2d
Cir.1990). I write only to comment upon the "familial relationship" rule of
insider trading proposed by Judge Winter in his partially dissenting opinion.
168 The rule urged upon us would impose a duty of nondisclosure upon "a family
member (i) who has received or expects (e.g., through inheritance) benefits
from family control of a corporation, here gifts of stock, (ii) who is in a
position to learn confidential corporate information through ordinary family
interactions, and (iii) who knows that under the circumstances both the
corporation and the family desire confidentiality." At 580. The duty is said to
consist of an obligation "not to use information so obtained for personal profit
where the use risks disclosure." Id.
169 The rationale for the proposed rule apparently is rooted in the notion that
family members would be encouraged to speak freely on all matters pertaining
to the family, knowing that the lips of those who receive confidential corporate
information in the course of ongoing family interchanges would be sealed.
Thus, in this case, so the argument goes, Ira Waldbaum could reveal the
pending stock sale to his sister, Shirley Witkin, who could reveal it to her
daughter, Susan Loeb, who could reveal it to her husband, Keith Loeb, all with

the understanding that a duty imposed by law on each family member would
protect against use of the confidential information for profit. Without the rule, it
is maintained, family members in this case would have been inhibited from
discussing such matters as the reason for Shirley Witkin's unusual absence
from her home, because such a discussion inevitably would lead to disclosure
of the confidential information regarding the sale of Waldbaum stock to A & P.
170 It seems to me, however, that family discourse would be inhibited, rather than
promoted, by a rule that would automatically assure confidentiality on the part
of a family member receiving non-public corporate information. What speaker,
secure in the knowledge that a relative could be prosecuted for insider trading,
would reveal to that relative anything remotely connected with corporate
dealings? Given the uncertainties surrounding the definition of insider trading,
a term as yet unclarified by Congress, what family members would want to
receive any information whatsoever that might bear on the family business?
How could family news be disseminated freely in an atmosphere where the
members must be ultra-sensitive to whether "both the corporation and the
family" are seeking some measure of confidentiality "under the circumstances."
171 The difficulty of identifying those who would be covered by the proposed
familial rule adds an additional element of uncertainty to what already are
uncertain crimes. It is not clear just who would be subject to the duty of
confidentiality: family members "who ha[ve] received or expect[ ] ... benefits
from family control of a corporation" belong to a very broad category indeed.
Here, those who have received gifts of stock are included. But does the
category include those who have received only small amounts of stock? Does it
matter what proportion the stock bears to the total issued and outstanding
shares? Does the category include one who expects to receive stock through
inheritance but never receives any? Does it include grandchildren who expect
ultimately to inherit assets purchased with the proceeds of the sale of the
family-controlled corporation? The net would be spread wider than appropriate
in a criminal context. Cf. Cantwell v. Connecticut, 310 U.S. 296, 308, 60 S.Ct.
900, 905, 84 L.Ed. 1213 (1940) ("Here we have a situation analogous to a
conviction under a statute sweeping in a great variety of conduct under a
general and indefinite characterization, and leaving to the executive and judicial
branches too wide a discretion in its application").
172 In the same vein, it is conceivable that minor children could find themselves "in
a position to learn confidential corporate information through ordinary family
interactions." If they came into the possession of such information and
somehow acquired the knowledge "that under the circumstances both the
corporation and the family desire[d] confidentiality," would they become

tippers who would expose other family members to criminal liability as tippees
when they passed the information along?
173 It is important to note that in the case at bar we deal with an attenuated trail of
family confidences in which information was received without any assurance of
confidentiality by the receiver and without any prior sharing of business
information within the family. Neither Shirley Witkin nor her daughter nor her
son-in-law were involved in any way in the operation of the Waldbaum
business or privy to any of its past secrets. Family relationships being what they
are, it makes little sense under the circumstances to imply assurances that
confidentiality would be maintained. Of course, a different situation obtains
where the giver of business confidences, in addition to having a family
relationship with the receiver, also has a history of reposing such confidences in
the receiver. See United States v. Reed, 601 F.Supp. 685, 712, 717 (S.D.N.Y.),
rev'd on other grounds, 773 F.2d 477 (2d Cir.1985) (son of corporate director as
receiver of non-public corporate information). Under those circumstances, the
duty of confidentiality is implied from the business relationship coupled with
the family one.
174 Finally, to further extend the concept of confidential duty would be to take the
courts into an area of securities regulation not yet entered by Congress. It
would give the wrong signal to prosecutors in their continuing efforts to push
against existing boundaries in the prosecution of securities fraud cases. "
[P]rosecutors can often claim that some confidential relationship was abused-whether between lovers, family members, longtime friends, or simply that wellknown confidential relationship between bartender and drunk. Such a test
inherently creates legal uncertainty and invites selective prosecutions." Coffee,
Outsider Trading, That New Crime, Wall St.J., Nov. 14, 1990, at 16, col. 4. I
would await further instructions from Congress before sailing into this
unchartered area.
175 MAHONEY, Circuit Judge, concurring in part and dissenting in part:
176 I concur in Judge Meskill's opinion for the majority except as to its ruling that
the SEC did not exceed its rulemaking authority when it promulgated rule 14e3(a), from which I respectfully dissent. Accordingly, I am also in disagreement
with the brief discussion of this issue in Judge Winter's separate opinion, which
concurs in Judge Meskill's resolution of the question.
177 The majority concludes that: "based on the plain language of section 14(e), and
congressional activity both before section 14(e) was enacted and after Rule 14-

3(a) was promulgated, we hold that the SEC did not exceed its statutory
authority in drafting Rule 14e-3(a)," adding that neither Chiarella v. United
States, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d 348 (1980), nor Schreiber v.
Burlington Northern, Inc., 472 U.S. 1, 105 S.Ct. 2458, 86 L.Ed.2d 1 (1985),
poses any barrier to this ruling. I will therefore address: (1) the pertinent
language of section 14(e), (2) its pre- and post-enactment legislative history,
and (3) the impact of Chiarella and Schreiber upon this issue.
178 As the majority notes, rule 14e-3 "creates a duty in those traders who fall
within its ambit to abstain or disclose, without regard to whether the trader
owes a preexisting fiduciary duty to respect the confidentiality of the
information." The question presented is whether, in doing so, rule 14e-3(a)
properly derives from the second sentence of section 14(e), which states: "The
Commission shall, for the purposes of this subsection, by rules and regulations
define, and prescribe means reasonably designed to prevent, such acts and
practices as are fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative."
179 The majority opinion swiftly collapses this language into an authorization for
the SEC to "define fraud." If this is a legitimate construction of the statutory
language, of course, the issue is decided and does not warrant extended
discussion. It is clear, however, that the statute says something significantly
different.
180 The second sentence of section 14(e) authorizes the SEC to define, and
prescribe preventive measures for, "such acts and practices as are fraudulent,
deceptive, or manipulative." This statutory mandate became law in 1970, two
years after the Williams Act was originally enacted and in the early years of the
tender offer phenomenon and its attendant regulation.
181 Especially in view of this context, the plain meaning of the dispositive language
is that the SEC is empowered to identify and regulate, in this (then) novel
context, the "acts and practices" that fit within the existing legal categories of
the "fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative," but not to redefine the categories
themselves. Furthermore, these venerable terms are used in section 14(e) in
their normal, accepted legal definitions. The Supreme Court has made clear that
in adding the 1970 amendment, Congress did not "suggest[ ] any change in the
meaning of the term 'manipulative' itself." Schreiber, 472 U.S. at 11 n. 11, 105
S.Ct. at 2464 n. 11. There is no reason to reach a different conclusion as to the
term "fraudulent." Finally, the focus upon novel and emerging "acts and
practices" rebuts the majority's view that unless the 1970 amendment is deemed
to authorize the SEC to engage in creative redefinitions of the terms
"fraudulent, deceptive or manipulative," the amendment will become a

meaningless repetition of the preexisting self-operative provisions of section


14(e).
182 In the majority's view, moreover, even the meaning of the term "fraudulent" as
used in the second sentence of section 14(e) is irrelevant. Because the statute
empowers the SEC to "prescribe means reasonably designed to prevent ... such
acts and practices as are fraudulent," the majority concludes that the statutory
authorization "necessarily encompasses the power to proscribe conduct outside
the purview of fraud, be it common law or SEC-defined fraud."
183 This is a truly breathtaking construction of a delegation to the SEC, we must
bear in mind, of the authority to prescribe a federal felony. See 15 U.S.C.
78ff(a) (1988) (defining any willful violation of the Securities Exchange Act of
1934, "or any rule or regulation thereunder," as a felony subject to ten years
imprisonment and a $1,000,000 fine); Touby v. United States, --- U.S. ----, 111
S.Ct. 1752, 1756, 114 L.Ed.2d 219 (1991) (reserving for future consideration
question whether enhanced guidance must be provided "when Congress
authorizes another Branch to promulgate regulations that contemplate criminal
sanctions"). In any event, the majority's gloss on the statutory language is
transparently implausible. While the SEC was authorized to utilize flexible
regulatory means in this emerging area, those means had to be directed at "such
acts and practices as are fraudulent" within the meaning of the statute. It is thus
clearly unacceptable to conclude that Chestman can be validly convicted of a
felony violation of section 14(e) and rule 14e-3(a) for, in the words of the
majority, "conduct outside the purview of fraud, be it common law or SECdefined fraud."
184 The legislative history of the 1970 amendment similarly lends little support to
the majority's position. Aside from some amiable generalities by Senator
Williams, the majority points only to a memorandum by the SEC Division of
Corporation Finance that, in response to an inquiry by Senator Williams, listed
the following as one of the seven "problem areas which may be dealt with by
[the] rule-making authority" provided by the 1970 amendment to section 14(e):
"5. The person who has become aware that a tender bid is to be made, or has
reason to believe that such bid will be made, may fail to disclose material facts
with respect thereto to persons who sell to him securities for which the tender
bid is to be made." Additional Consumer Protection in Corporate Takeovers
and Increasing the Securities Act Exemptions for Small Businessmen, Hearings
on S. 336 and S. 3431 before the Subcomm. on Securities of the Senate Comm.
on Banking and Currency, 91st Cong., 2d Sess. 12 (1970).
185 It is plainly inappropriate to suggest that this rough outline of a regulatory

"problem area" should be read to provide a precise delineation of the scope and
purpose of the 1970 amendment. I note, for example, that this scenario does not
suggest the source of the hypothetical buyer's knowledge, or "reason to
believe," that a tender offer is imminent. Are we therefore to conclude that the
derivation of the information is irrelevant? For example, would the buyer be
guilty of a federal felony if his information as to the likelihood of a tender offer
was derived from his observation of heavy trading in the target company's
stock, without any direct or indirect input from the target company or the
offeror? I am not aware of any responsible authority that reads the 1970
amendment of section 14(e) as authorizing so sweeping a revision of federal
securities law, and the SEC made no such assertion in promulgating rule 14e3(a), but such a purchaser would clearly fall within the "problem area" outlined
in the SEC memorandum. Similarly, I suggest, this thumbnail sketch of a
"problem area" should not be accorded significance in determining whether the
1970 amendment empowered the SEC to disregard existing legal concepts of
fraud in devising regulations addressed to the definition and prevention of "such
acts and practices as are fraudulent."
186 The post-enactment history is even less supportive of the majority's position.
The majority points to legislative reports accompanying Congress' enactment of
the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984 and the Insider Trading and
Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988 as somehow indicating
Congressional support of the SEC's 1980 departure from prior law in
promulgating rule 14e-3(a). As I stated in my concurring opinion during the
panel consideration of this appeal, in addressing the identical legislative
history:
187 very casual references to rule 14e-3 in H.R.Rep. No. 910, 100th Cong., 2d
[T]he
Sess. 14 (1988), reprinted in 1988 U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 6043, 6051, and
H.R.Rep. No. 355, 98th Cong., 1st Sess. 13 n. 20 (1983), reprinted in 1984
U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 2286 n. 20, provide no basis for concluding that
later statutory enactments have recognized not only the promulgation and existence
of rule 14e-3, but also the Commission's claim that rule 14e-3 effects an implied
repeal of any fiduciary duty requirement in the area of tender offer fraud.
188 In particular, H.R.Rep. No. 98-355 explicitly states that the legislation on
which it reports, the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984, "does not change
the underlying substantive case law of insider trading as reflected in judicial
and administrative holdings." Id. at 13. Similarly, H.R. No. 100-910 makes
clear that the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988
does not address the substantive law of insider trading. Id. at 7.

189 United States v. Chestman, 903 F.2d 75, 86 (2d Cir.1990) (MAHONEY, J.,
concurring in part and dissenting in part).
190 The cases cited by the majority on this issue are easily distinguished. In United
States v. Rutherford, 442 U.S. 544, 99 S.Ct. 2470, 61 L.Ed.2d 68 (1979), the
committee reports accompanying amendatory legislation subsequent to the
agency ruling at issue explicitly approved the challenged agency position. See
id. at 553, 99 S.Ct. at 2475-76. In Red Lion Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 395 U.S.
367, 89 S.Ct. 1794, 23 L.Ed.2d 371 (1969), Congress had adopted explicit
statutory language that "vindicated" the agency position on the issue in
litigation. See id. at 380, 89 S.Ct. at 1801. Zemel v. Rusk, 381 U.S. 1, 85 S.Ct.
1271, 14 L.Ed.2d 179 (1965), noted that "[u]nder some circumstances,"
Congressional silence in the face of an administrative position has been deemed
acquiescent in that position, but stated that "[i]n this case ... the inference is
supported by more than mere congressional inaction." Id. at 11, 85 S.Ct. at
1278 (emphasis added).
191 As indicated above, the circumstances presented here provide no support for a
finding of Congressional acquiescence in the novel legal theory embodied in
rule 14e-3(a). Congress' subsequent consideration of enhanced penalties for
insider trading violations, explicitly eschewing any intention to address the
pertinent issues of substantive law, does nothing to validate rule 14e-3.
Furthermore, the majority opinion surprisingly disregards the most germane
Supreme Court authority on this issue. In Aaron v. SEC, 446 U.S. 680, 100
S.Ct. 1945, 64 L.Ed.2d 611 (1980), the Court rejected a similar argument for
Congressional ratification of an SEC position, stating:
192 The Commission finds further support for its interpretation of 10(b) as not
requiring proof of scienter in injunctive proceedings in the fact that Congress
was expressly informed of the Commission's interpretation on two occasions
when significant amendments to the securities laws were enacted--The
Securities Act Amendments of 1975, Pub.L. 94-29, 89 Stat. 97, and the Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act of 1977, Pub.L. 95-213, 91 Stat. 1494--and on each
occasion Congress left the administrative interpretation undisturbed. See S.Rep.
No. 94-75, p. 76 (1975), U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1975, p. 179;
H.R.Rep. No. 95-640, p. 10 (1977). But, since the legislative consideration of
those statutes was addressed principally to matters other than that at issue here,
it is our view that the failure of Congress to overturn the Commission's
interpretation falls far short of providing a basis to support a construction of
10(b) so clearly at odds with its plain meaning and legislative history. See SEC
v. Sloan, 436 U.S. 103, 119-121, 98 S.Ct. 1702, 1712-1713, 56 L.Ed.2d 148

[1978].
193 Id. at 694 n. 11, 100 S.Ct. at 1954 n. 11 (emphasis added). In Sloan, the Court
rejected the SEC's interpretation of a statute despite subsequent reenactment of
that statute coupled with an endorsement of the SEC's view in a committee
report addressing the issue. See 436 U.S. at 119-20 & n. 10, 98 S.Ct. at 1712-13
& n. 10. A fortiori, no ratification has occurred as to rule 14e-3(a).
194 Rule 14e-3(a) was enacted in the immediate aftermath of the Supreme Court's
ruling in Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222, 100 S.Ct. 1108, 63 L.Ed.2d
348 (1980). Addressing section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934,
15 U.S.C. 78j (1988), and rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder, 17 C.F.R.
240.10b-5 (1991), the Court ruled in Chiarella that "[w]hen an allegation of
fraud is based upon nondisclosure, there can be no fraud absent a duty to
speak." 445 U.S. at 235, 100 S.Ct. at 1118. If that rule applies in the area of
tender offers and section 14(e), of course, rule 14e-3(a) is clearly illegal. See
American Bar Association Committee on Federal Regulation of Securities,
Report of the Task Force on Regulation of Insider Trading, 41 Bus.Law. 223,
252 (1985) ("Rule 14e-3 squarely raises the issue whether the [SEC] has the
authority to impose a limited equal-access rule in the aftermath of Chiarella,
Dirks [v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 103 S.Ct. 3255, 77 L.Ed.2d 911 (1983) ], and
Schreiber."); id. at 251 & n. 109 (collecting commentaries expressing doubt as
to validity of rule).
195 The majority would confine Chiarella's authority to section 10(b) and rule 10b5, deeming it entirely without precedential value as to section 14(e) and rule
14e-3(a). Chiarella drew heavily, however, upon common law concepts of
fraud. Its key ruling is that "the duty to disclose arises when one party has
information 'that the other [party] is entitled to know because of a fiduciary or
other similar relation of trust and confidence between them.' " 445 U.S. at 228,
100 S.Ct. at 1114. The internal quotation is from the Restatement (Second) of
Torts 551(2)(a) (1976), with an added notation that the American Law
Institute regards the rule as applicable to "securities transactions." See id. at 228
n. 9, 100 S.Ct. at 1114 n. 9. No reason appears why this generally applicable
rule of law, not derived in any way from the language or history of section
10(b) and rule 10b-5, should have definitive force in the construction and
interpretation of those provisions, but none where section 14(e) and rule 14e3(a) are concerned.
196 Furthermore, both the Supreme Court and this court have explicitly recognized
that section 14(e) is modeled upon the antifraud provisions of 10(b) and Rule
10b-5. See Schreiber, 472 U.S. at 10 & n. 10, 105 S.Ct. at 2463 & n. 10;

Connecticut Nat'l Bank v. Fluor Corp., 808 F.2d 957, 961 (2d Cir.1987) (citing
Chris-Craft Indus. v. Piper Aircraft Corp., 480 F.2d 341, 362 (2d Cir.), cert.
denied, 414 U.S. 910, 94 S.Ct. 231, 232, 38 L.Ed.2d 148 (1973)).
197 Against this background, the majority's efforts to distinguish Chiarella are less
than convincing. It is true that section 14(e), unlike section 10(b), directly
proscribes "fraudulent" acts and practices, but this is a barely discernible
departure from section 10(b)'s prohibition of "deceptive device[s] or
contrivance[s]," see Restatement (Second) of Torts at 55 (1977) (equating
"fraudulent representation" and "deceit"), and both sections envision
implementation by SEC regulations. In any event, this proscription hardly
heralds an intention to change the meaning of the term "fraud" as previously
understood in both the general law and securities law. Nor does the slight
difference in language between the two provisions' delegation of rulemaking
authority to the SEC plausibly signify that Congress vested the SEC with the
power to make such a change. Further, while the language of rule 14e-3(a)
concededly "reveals express SEC intent to proscribe conduct not covered by
common law fraud," as the majority states, that revelation poses, rather than
decides, the question that we must resolve.
198 The majority opinion notes a passage in Chiarella that alludes to (then)
proposed rule 14e-3 as a bar to warehousing of target stock in a tender offer "on
a 'somewhat different theory' than that previously used to regulate insider
trading as fraudulent activity." Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 234, 100 S.Ct. at 1118
(quoting 1 SEC Institutional Investor Study Report, H.R.Doc. No. 64, 92nd
Cong., 1st Sess., pt. 1 (the "Report"), at xxxii (1971)). The majority then
identifies the "theory" as "one that does not embrace 'any fiduciary duty to the
[target] company or its shareholders,' " quoting the Report at xxxii. In fact, the
Report only states that people who plan takeovers do not "usually have any
fiduciary duty to [the target] company or its shareholders." Further, the majority
vests significance in the fact that "the Chiarella Court did not disapprove of this
exercise of the SEC's rulemaking power under section 14(e)." Such a
disapproval would have been wholly gratuitous in the circumstances. In sum,
this passage cannot fairly be read as obviating the fact that Chiarella establishes
a general rule linking securities fraud to a breach of fiduciary duty, and that rule
14e-3(a) represents an obvious effort by the SEC to circumvent that rule by
exercising an authority that has not been entrusted to that body.
199 Schreiber, as I have noted, establishes that section 14(e) was modeled upon
section 10(b) and rule 10b-5, see 472 U.S. at 10 n. 10, 105 S.Ct. at 2463 n. 10,
thus reinforcing the precedential value of Chiarella for the present case; and
discountenances any notion that the 1970 amendment to section 14(e) intended

any change in the meaning of the fundamental term "manipulative," see 472
U.S. at 12 n. 11, 105 S.Ct. at 2464 n. 11, undercutting the notion that the term
"fraudulent" was invested by the same amendment with the novel content for
which the SEC contends. Dirks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 653, 103 S.Ct. 3255,
3260-61, 77 L.Ed.2d 911 (1983), explicitly rejected, in the section 10(b)/rule
10b-5 context, the SEC's view "that anyone who knowingly receives nonpublic
material information from an insider has a fiduciary duty to disclose before
trading." Rule 14e-3(a) purports to avoid the impact of Dirks by simply
discarding the concept of fiduciary duty in the tender offer context.
200 I am aware, of course, that we ordinarily defer to the interpretation of a statute
provided by an agency charged with its enforcement. See Chevron, U.S.A., Inc.
v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 842-45, 104 S.Ct.
2778, 2781-83, 81 L.Ed.2d 694 (1984); IBT v. Daniel, 439 U.S. 551, 566 n. 20,
99 S.Ct. 790, 800 n. 20, 58 L.Ed.2d 808 (1979). As the Court made clear in
Daniel, however:
201 deference is constrained by our obligation to honor the clear meaning of a
[T]his
statute, as revealed by its language, purpose, and history. On a number of occasions
in recent years this Court has found it necessary to reject the SEC's interpretation of
various provisions of the Securities Acts. See SEC v. Sloan, 436 U.S. 103, 117-119,
98 S.Ct. 1702, 1711-1712, 56 L.Ed.2d 148 (1978); Piper v. Chris-Craft Industries,
Inc., 430 U.S. 1, 41 n. 27, 97 S.Ct. 926, 949 [n. 27], 51 L.Ed.2d 124 (1977); Ernst &
Ernst v. Hochfelder, 425 U.S. 185, 212-214, 96 S.Ct. 1375, 1390-1391, 47 L.Ed.2d
668 (1976); [United Hous. Found., Inc. v.] Forman, 421 U.S. [837, 858 n. 25, 95
S.Ct. 2051, 2063 n. 25, 44 L.Ed.2d 621 (1975) ]; Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug
Stores, 421 U.S. 723, 759 n. 4, 95 S.Ct. 1917, 1936 [n. 4], 44 L.Ed.2d 539 (1975)
(POWELL, J., concurring); Reliance Electric Co. v. Emerson Electric Co., 404 U.S.
418, 425-427, 92 S.Ct. 596, 600-602, 30 L.Ed.2d 575 (1972).
202 439 U.S. at 566 n. 20, 99 S.Ct. at 800 n. 20; see also Aaron, 446 U.S. at 694 n.
11, 100 S.Ct. at 1954 n. 11 (rejecting SEC view that scienter not required in
10(b) injunctive proceedings); Business Roundtable v. SEC, 905 F.2d 406, 407
(D.C.Cir.1990) (holding that SEC exceeded its statutory authority in
promulgating rule 19c-4 to bar national securities exchanges and associations
from listing stocks violative of one share/one vote principle).
203 In promulgating rule 14e-3(a), the SEC has once again, in my view, acted in
excess of its statutory authority. This is especially so because its action
implicates serious criminal penalties. See Touby, 111 S.Ct. at 1756. Thus, to
the extent that there is any ambiguity as to the authority vested in the SEC by
the 1970 amendment of section 14(e), it should be resolved in Chestman's

favor. As the Supreme Court said in Crandon v. United States, 494 U.S. 152,
110 S.Ct. 997, 1001, 108 L.Ed.2d 132 (1990), "because the governing standard
is set forth in a criminal statute [here, 15 U.S.C. 78ff(a) in tandem with rule
14e-3], it is appropriate to apply the rule of lenity in resolving any ambiguity in
the ambit of the statute's coverage.".
204 Accordingly, I would reverse all of Chestman's convictions, in accordance with
the panel disposition. See Chestman, 903 F.2d at 84. I therefore dissent from
the majority's affirmance of Chestman's convictions under section 14(e) and
rule 14e-3, while joining in the balance of the majority opinion.

Judge Feinberg participated in the decision to rehear the appeal in banc and
heard oral argument. He subsequently retired from regular active service,
however, and thus did not vote in the in banc decision. See 28 U.S.C. 46(c);
United States v. American-Foreign S.S. Corp., 363 U.S. 685, 80 S.Ct. 1336, 4
L.Ed.2d 1491 (1960)

The indictment and judgment of conviction charge Chestman with violating


Rule 14e-3(a) as well as Rule 14e-3(d). The record provides no other
indications, however, that Rule 14e-3(d) was involved in this case. In fact, in
the government's Memorandum of Law in Opposition to Defendant's Pretrial
Motions, the government states:
The rule [Rule 14e-3] also contains limited exceptions pertaining to multiservice financial institutions and brokerage transactions and establishes an
"anti-tipping" rule with respect to material, nonpublic information concerning a
tender offer. Rule 14e-3(b), (c), and (d). These provisions are not at issue here.
The indictment invokes only subsection (a) of Rule 14e-3.
Thus, like the district court, 704 F.Supp. 451, 456 n. 4 (S.D.N.Y.1989), and the
panel, 903 F.2d 75, 85 (2d Cir.1990), we assume that Chestman was convicted
only under subsection (a) of Rule 14e-3.

The insider's fiduciary duties, it should be noted, run to a buyer (a shareholderto-be) and to a seller (a pre-existing shareholder) of securities, even though the
buyer technically does not have a fiduciary relationship with the insider prior to
the trade. As the Court explained in Chiarella:
The transaction in Cady, Roberts involved sale of stock to persons who
previously may not have been shareholders in the corporation. The
Commission embraced the reasoning of Judge Learned Hand that "the director
or officer assumed a fiduciary relation to the buyer by the very sale; for it

would be a sorry distinction to allow him to use the advantage of his position to
induce the buyer into the position of a beneficiary although he was forbidden to
do so once the buyer had become one."
445 U.S. at 227 n. 8, 100 S.Ct. at 1114 n. 8 (quoting Cady, Roberts & Co., 40
S.E.C. 907, 914 n. 23 (1961) (quoting Gratz v. Claughton, 187 F.2d 46, 49 (2d
Cir.), cert. denied, 341 U.S. 920, 71 S.Ct. 741, 95 L.Ed. 1353 (1951))) (internal
citation omitted).
3

In Carpenter v. United States, 484 U.S. 19, 24, 108 S.Ct. 316, 320, 98 L.Ed.2d
275 (1987), an "evenly divided" Court affirmed the securities fraud convictions
brought pursuant to the misappropriation theory. An affirmance by an evenly
divided court is "not entitled to precedential weight." See Neil v. Biggers, 409
U.S. 188, 192, 93 S.Ct. 375, 379, 34 L.Ed.2d 401 (1972). Thus, Supreme Court
support for the misappropriation theory is still unclear

Although the public appears to have a strongly negative view of insider trading,
there are academics who believe it to be beneficial, see H. Manne, Insider
Trading and the Stock Market (1966), and considerable diversity as to why
insider trading should be regulated exists among its academic opponents, see,
e.g., Kaplan, Wolf v. Weinstein: Another Chapter on Insider Trading, 1963
Sup.Ct.Rev. 273; Brudney, Insiders, Outsiders, and Informational Advantages
Under the Federal Securities Laws, 93 Harv.L.Rev. 322 (1979); Easterbrook,
Insider Trading, Secret Agents, Evidentiary Privileges, and the Production of
Information, 1981 Sup.Ct.Rev. 309

Some commentators have suggested that Section 16(b) is designed, or at least


operates, to increase management's autonomy from shareholder control because
it limits the freedom of owners of large blocs of stock to trade and thus deters
institutional investors from acquiring such blocs. Roe, A Political Theory of
American Corporate Finance, 91 Colum.L.Rev. 10, 27 (1991)

Although TGS stressed the unfairness of insider trading to those who deal with
the trader, the reason for the nondisclosure that allowed insider trading in TGS
stock was the company's insider trading in real estate

Section 16(a) of the '34 Act requires insiders to report trades in a corporation's
stock (i) at the time of a new issue, (ii) when they become an insider, and (iii)
each month thereafter in which trades occur. Where insiders are able to avoid
"profits" as defined in Section 16(b) and trade heavily--e.g., a series of
purchases that cannot be matched with sales during the six months at either end
of the activity--other traders may well draw accurate inferences. In that respect,
federal law causes the information on which insiders are trading to become
known

Comprehensive protection of those who trade with insiders is unattainable


because the most common form of insider trading by far is failing to trade. An
insider possessing nonpublic information may purchase or sell other securities
or borrow instead of trading in the corporation's stock. Such trading seems
virtually undiscoverable and unregulable, however, although it is functionally
indistinguishable from insider trading so far as those who deal with the trader
are concerned
Under the business property rationale, not-trading because of inside
information is not the functional equivalent of trading because not-trading
creates at most a negligible risk of disclosure of corporate secrets. Unlike
trading, not-trading does not involve persons other than the trader, such as
brokers, and does not create an unusual volume. But see Easterbrook, supra, at
336-37 (discussing signals sent to such parties by not trading).

You might also like