Indiana University Press
Indiana University Press
Indiana University Press
Informal Networks and Access to Power to Obtain Housing in Urban Slums in Ghana
Author(s): Jeffrey W. Paller
Source: Africa Today, Vol. 62, No. 1, Special Issue: The Politics of the Nonstate Provision of
Public Goods in Africa (Fall 2015), pp. 31-55
Published by: Indiana University Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.2979/africatoday.62.1.31
Accessed: 28-10-2015 06:53 UTC
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Indiana University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Africa Today.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Africa has been urbanizing at a rate of 3.5 percent per year during the past
two decadesthe highest regional urbanization rate in the world (African
Development Bank 2012). An estimated 200 million people (Vidal 2010), or
62 percent of the urban population in sub-Saharan Africa, reside in slums
(Arimah 2010; UN-HABITAT 2010).1 The housing challenge is notably severe
in Accra, Ghana, where the urban population has grown by 19.5 percent since
2000 (World Bank 2013a, 2013b), requiring 5.7 million new rooms in Ghana
to be built by 2020; this means that a total of 574,000 rooms must be provided every year, 1,840 per working day, and about four every minute (UNHABITAT 2011). This figure is well beyond the capacity of the government
and the formal business sector to accommodate.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
Ghana has faced a housing shortage since independence, which dates back
to the earthquake that hit Accra in 1939 (Acquah 1958). At the earliest years
of independence, the national government recognized the challenge that the
small and insecure land market had on the provision of housing (Republic
of Ghana 1958). In response, the government formed state bodies, including
the State Housing Corporation (SHC), the Tema Development Corporation
(TDC), and the State Construction Corporation, to address housing issues
(Elleh 2002). TDC, for example, purchased sixty-four miles of land seventeen
miles outside of Accra. At the center of this proposal was a Doxiadis plan
that facilitated the development of twenty-four so-called communities that
would make up the city of Tema. State investments in affordable housing
increased in 1972 with the addition of the Low Cost Housing Programme.
In the postindependence urban plans, the Ghanaian government specifically highlighted slums like Nima, Maamobi, and Chorkor as neighborhoods that were underresourced and in need of upgrading (Arn 1996). Nevertheless, the government suggested a piecemeal approach that allowed poor
residents to stay in these areas (Republic of Ghana 1958). In existing slum
communities like Nima, the government recommended lowering building
standards so that residents could build houses within their income; it called
this allowance the relaxation of structural standards (Republic of Ghana
1958:5354). At the earliest stages of independence, the governments plan
was to formalize and regularize land tenure security of these slum areas.
Despite the governments awareness of the problem, the housing
shortage persisted after Nkrumah left office. Ghana faced a housing deficit
33
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
35
Jeffrey W. Paller
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
By the end of the twentieth century, the state and formal private enterprises had failed in their attempts to provide sufficient housing to urban
residents. In response, the Ghana Poverty Reduction Strategy I, implemented
in 2001, focused on attracting foreign capital to fund housing development.
The GPRS II (20062009) focused on poor and marginalized populations and
detailed a special program for upgrading slums (Bank of Ghana 2007). Two
major initiatives are particularly notable: the Cities without Slums action
plan, under the auspices of the Cities Alliance, and the Slum Upgrading
Facility. These programs seek to mobilize foreign capital and to link this
financial assistance with local actors. The projects seek to package the
financial, technical, and political elements of development projects. The
effectiveness of these policies is still not known, but several scholars blame
them for contributing to a housing market that privileges the rich over the
poor, increasing income inequality and undermining an indigenous housing
market that favors the poor (Gruffyd Jones 2012; Obeng-Odoom 2012).
Unsurprisingly, Ghanaians have accessed housing through leveraging
remittances from family members living abroad (Buckley and Mathema
2008; Yeboah 2000). The World Bank estimates that $119 million in remittances were sent to back to the country in 2013 alone (2013). But these remittances drive up the cost of housing in the city, making individuals without
access to remittances much worse off. The online housing marketfueled
by the influx of nonresident Ghanaians and foreignershelps push house
and land prices to all-time highs (Bank of Ghana 2007). This, in turn, contributes to the deteriorating housing conditions for many others across the
city (Buckley and Mathema 2008). In fact, remittances are part of a broader
globalized environment, which increases land and housing prices, privileges
the private sector over the public sector, and leads to inequity in housing
provision across the city (Grant 2009; Grant and Nijman 2002; KonaduAgyemang 2001; Owusu 2008).
This brief history of housing in Ghana demonstrates that the two
major approaches for increasing access to secure and high-quality affordable housingstate-provisioned housing and increasing access to the free
markethave failed. Part of the reason for this is that slum incidence can
be traced back to colonial-era institutions and lack of investment, and
these historical legacies are difficult to overcome (Fox 2014). But another
shortcoming of these plans is their failure to acknowledge the daily political
realities on the ground. They do not consider how housing is governed in
poor neighborhoods and the ways in which informal networks and political entrepreneurs shape the market and capture state services for their own
interests. My approach advocates studying affordable housing from the
ground up by assessing the unique strategies that low-income urbanites
use to solve daily challenges, like finding and securing affordable housing.
In doing so, I find that accessing and securing affordable housing requires
political power (Auyero 2001; Nelson 1979). The next sections uncover the
avenues to power across different types of urban neighborhoods.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
37
Aspiring leaders are, in a manner of speaking, political entrepreneurs. . . . They engage in the enterprise of amassing
resources and using them, skillfully, to attract followers. In
Mushin, a first step in this enterprise ... was acquiring real
estate, for it gave people who owned housing an advantage
over those who did not. A second step was to capitalize on
this inequity, by adding political content to the interactions
that grew out of landlordtenant relationships. The owners
who wished to wield power in Mushin typically began a political career by attracting a neighborhood clientele to whom
they acted as patrons, middlemen, and dispute settlers. They
dispensed, among other resources, information, contacts, and
services that were particularly helpful in meeting the needs
of urban life. In return they received support for their political
goals.
Barnes 1986; Cohen 1969; Kobo 2010; Peil 1971; Pellow 2002; Schildkrout
1970, 1978; Skinner 1963, 1972), yet they are especially important for vulnerable communities, particularly migrant and squatter settlements, because
residents rely on patronclient relationships to secure citizenship status
and tenure security, respectively. Peil (1971) describes this phenomenon
in Ghana in the 1960s, when migrants were threatened with expulsion.
Similarly, Schildkrout (1970, 1978) documents this pattern in Ghanaian
zongosstrangers quarters, where migrants to African cities settledwhere
patronclient relationships developed in the context of limited resources.
Residents needed patrons to gain any public services from the state.4 They
also needed strong patrons with powerful links to state administrators and
political parties to protect their land and housingto prevent evictions and
demolitions that were common in these neighborhoods.
Perhaps the most important way that a leader accumulates power is
through the control of land and housing (Gulyani and Talukdar 2008). Barnes
(1986:70) describes this phenomenon in the context of Mushin, a Nigerian
slum:
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
39
Slum Name
City
Settlement Type
Aboabo *+
Abuja CMB *+
Agbogbloshie +
Alajo
Amakom New Town *
Asawase
Ashaiman Zongo *+
Ashanti New Town*
Avenor *+
Chorkor *+
Darkuman
ECOMOC +
Ga Mashie *+^
Gbegbeyise
King Shona (James Town Beach) *+
Kotobabi
Maamobi *
Nima *+
New Fadama
New Town
Nii Boi Town
Old Fadama *+^
Sabon Zongo *
Shiabu *
Sukura
Taabo *+
Tulako *+^
Valco Flat
Zongo Laka +
Kumasi
Accra
Accra
Accra
Kumasi
Kumasi
Ashaiman
Kumasi
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Accra
Ashaiman
Ashaiman
Ashaiman
Ashaiman
Purchased
Extralegal
Extralegal (part indigenous)
Indigenous
Extralegal
Purchased
Purchased
Indigenous
Extralegal (part indigenous)
Indigenous
Purchased
Extralegal
Indigenous
Indigenous
Extralegal
Purchased
Purchased
Purchased
Purchased
Purchased
Indigenous
Extralegal
Purchased
Indigenous
Purchased
Indigenous
Extralegal (part purchased)
Purchased
Purchased
Purchased
Housing as a common good
Indigenous
Housing as a club good
Purchased
Housing as a public good
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
41
Jeffrey W. Paller
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
relationships serve the politicians need to win votes and the leaders desire
to reward loyal followers, many of whom are linked to the hometown. Leaders also control land markets, allowing them to establish bases of power
by providing land to coethnic followers. In this way, affordable housing is
governed as a private good, a valuable resource for political entrepreneurs to
achieve personal empowerment.
For an increasingly large number of residents, particularly migrants
from Ghanas three northern regions and neighboring countries, extralegal
settlements offer the most affordable housing option in Accra, yet housing
characteristics in extralegal settlements are particularly distinct. Seventytwo percent of all respondents who live in shacks or kiosks were in extralegal
settlements, and 38 percent of homes have dirt or wooden floors (in contrast
to 16 percent who indicate this housing feature in indigenous settlements
and 12 percent in purchased settlements). Structures in extralegal settlements tend to be the most susceptible to floods and fires: 31 percent of
residents in extralegal settlements indicate that their structures always
flood; 21 percent indicate that it sometimes floods; and 21 percent indicate
that sometimes water drips. Old Fadama, Avenor, and Abuja CMB residents
indicated that their structures have been burned many times.
Only 20 percent of respondents in extralegal settlements indicate that
they do not have security of tenure. While a community might be under the
threat of eviction by state authorities, my data suggest that residents rely
on alternative means to secure their tenure on a daily basis. The following
anecdote illustrates one important way that Ghanaian slum residents rely
on NSPs to access housing and gain tenure security. The day after the results
from Ghanas 2012 presidential election were announced, an Accra resident
explained, Everybody [in our community] is happy that our peace is preserved. They [the NPP supporters] planned to [attack and seize property] if
they win, but Nana Addo has been retired, so they have to sit back. The
resident explained that the stakes were high for his community, an extralegal settlement. The atmosphere was so intense and laced with uncertainty
before the elections that this resident even sent his wife and daughter to
the Northern Region for safety. Others were warned to sell their property;
otherwise, it might be seized by the sympathizerspolitical party branch
leaders and foot soldiersof the opposing government if they won power.
After the NDC won victory in 2008, the NPP activists were forced out of the
community. NPP strongmen relinquished their power to NDC strongmen;
private toilets were seized; and locally named parks and neighborhoods were
renamed after NDC sympathizers. For example, no longer did the local NPP
foot soldier named Yaw collect property rates from the area around self-titled
Yaws Park: NDC foot soldier Hanaan established control, empowered his
base, and now controlled the newly named Hanaans Park.8
In the absence of strong property-rights institutions and state-provisioned housing, residents rely on informal networks with access to political power to secure housing and tenure security. In the case of extralegal
settlements, residents do not have the legal right to reside and work in the
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
43
Jeffrey W. Paller
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a bank loan, though he has a bank account; he did not access governmentprovided housing (it was not an option); he did not leverage remittances (he
has no family members abroad); he did not align with an internationally
aligned NGO (the few NGOs in the community are mistrusted by residents
and accused of corruption); and he did not purchase a property title (they do
not exist in the community). But what is interesting about his experience,
as well as that of thousands of others in Old Fadama, is that they do invest
in their houses, benefit from their cheap housing, and feel secure in their
tenure. Housing is a private good, but it is still an affordable good.
Most attention given by outsiders to residents in slums emphasizes
poverty, informality, and unemployment, but extralegal settlements provide
young social and political entrepreneurs the opportunity to make money,
develop a fund of followers, and amass power. The development of these
power structures directly affects the housing market because the local leaders control the provision of public and private services to the area, and they
collect rents to deepen their control. Leaders abilities to maintain informality and take advantage of the extralegal environment shape the political terrain and daily governance. The original settlement pattern that helped shape
the development of local authority structures provides a glimpse into how
access to power shapes the governance of affordable housing.
While Old Fadama is typically portrayed as a haven for poor and vulnerable internal refugees, the reality on the ground is that it is a vibrant space
for commercial enterprise. With a population of more than eighty thousand,
business opportunities there are plentiful (Housing the Masses 2010). Men
work in the burgeoning scrap and e-waste business (Grant and Oteng-Obabio
2012); women sell goods at the largest market in Accra just across the street;
and early settlers in the community sell land on the informal market. A
further source of income is the provision of basic services like selling water,
siphoning electricity, and running private showers and toilets. In fact, shower
and toilet operators are some of the wealthiest people in the community,
along with scrap dealers and transport operators. They earn consistent, daily
cash income. Many of the business owners no longer sleep in the community
but continue to do business there.
For most residents of Old Fadama, the slum offers cheap housing and
access to business opportunities. For many, it offers more: the opportunity
to establish political ties and enhance personal power. For example, in the
early 2000s, an NGO called Peoples Dialogue for Human Settlements (PD)
started working in the community; its goal was to ensure that the rights of
the slum dwellers were protected in the case of eviction (Braimah 2011). It
vehemently fought against forced eviction of the community. As part of its
work, it attempted to build a community-based organization of members
who live in the community. The Old Fadama Development Association
(OFADA) was formed, and local leaders who had accumulated power based
on securing political connections, amassing wealth, providing private goods
and services, and having higher education levels stepped into formal positions of power. But these leadership selections were not based on transparent,
free, and fair democratic elections: instead, leaders were publicly appointed
among a small cadre of local leadership. Governance of the community,
including its housing, was a private affair.
The organization was supposed to help improve the services in the
community, but the leaders were not held accountable by the residents. The
most obvious example was in 2009, when the organization instituted a ten
cedi tax (about US$5) to all households, but the money was never used for
its purpose. The allegation was that the chairman and his closest advisers
captured the money and used it for their own businesses. Residents lost trust
in the organization, and many community leaders no longer wanted to be
associated with it, yet it continues to exist as a shadow organization: when
PD, the internationally funded affiliate of Slum Dwellers International,
needs to mobilize people on the ground, it calls the leaders of OFADA. Further, the OFADA leaders have deep ties with the NDC political party, greatly
bolstering their financial power in the community. The chairman of OFADA
is the local special ward chairman for the NDC. This political entrepreneur
maintains strong links to development NGOs, the governing political party,
and his ethnic group traditional authorities.
This is not uncommon across Accra, as local leaders capture government or internationally funded resources, exhibiting predatory behavior
politely termed elite capture (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2005; Platteau
2004), and it continues to be one of the most serious problems facing slum
communities. It fosters serious mistrust among residents and their leaders.
But it is unique in extralegal settlements because living and working there
offers local leaders political opportunities that they would not have if the
settlement were formal. Leaders become vocal advocates for seemingly
powerless populations and closely align themselves with international organizations like Amnesty International and PD. They organize protests against
recent forced evictions and claim to be human-rights advocates for the poor.
These informal networks are shielded by formal political actors, particularly their political parties. Informal networks shape access to affordable housing because they have access to the real sources of power in
the countrythe political parties who control the distribution of state
resources. Politicians and state bureaucrats empower these local political
entrepreneurs by protecting the de facto landlordism, despite the extralegal
context, in exchange for political supportvotes, providing foot soldiers, and
making campaign contributions from the proceeds of their public services
(e.g., private toilets and showers). Political parties establish organizational
branches along these already existing informal social networks, with political entrepreneurs acting as branch executives, providing an embedded link
to neighborhoods. Competition over housing, public services, and other
resources occurs between these informal networks and between different
political entrepreneurs. Many of these struggles occur within the same political parties and among the same ethnic group.
The role of the political parties in the situation surrounding Old
Fadama is critical, but is underemphasized in the literature. Existing
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
45
seeding mistrust and resentment. This dates back to colonial times (Quarcoopome 1987; Sackeyfio-Lenoch 2014). Therefore, housing is a club good
that is nonrivalrous and excludable and benefits leaders and members of the
indigenous ethnic group. Being part of the indigenous club is the best way
to secure access to affordable and secure housing.
Because of the customary property rights regime, politicians and government authorities need access to land to implement development projects.
They therefore have the incentive to align with traditional authorities to
pursue their developmental priorities. Traditional authorities connect with
politicians to promote their self-interest, with little incentive to invest in
the interests of the broader city. Politicians offer patronage in exchange for
land, votes, and spiritual support. This is evident at the individual level,
where residents maintain distinct relationships to the metropolitan assembly. These links are substantiated by my data, which show fifty-six respondents in indigenous settlements who have secured a government contract,
compared to only twenty-four in purchased and twenty-eight in extralegal
settlements.9 This evidence suggests that indigeneity is a powerful political resource in local politics (Hilgers 2011). Further, most pockets of highly
educated individuals are in indigenous settlements, perhaps reflecting the
fact that during colonial urban planning, schools and educational facilities
were built closest to the urban center, where indigenous settlements remain
(Mabogunje 1976; Myers 2003). Also, more residents of indigenous settlements are literate than in in extralegal settlements. In these distinct ways,
the political entrepreneurs of NSPs in indigenous settlements tend to have
high-status occupations, like lawyers, judges, and employees of big corporations. These leaders do not necessarily live in the community, but own bigger
houses in faraway neighborhoods.
Consider the example of a community leader and political entrepreneur in one NSP in Ga Mashie, an indigenous neighborhood that comprises
James Town and Ussher Town in Accra. Samuel Ashalley Addey-Ashley
serves as the preeminent landlord on one neighborhood block because he
is the fetish priest for the Ga peoplefor which his name is Nana Odupon
Okomfo Abeka Sikafo II. In April 2013, he celebrated his latest accomplishment: securing the government contract to rebuild the local Salaga Market.
He has no contracting skills and has never been to technical school, but
his close political connections to Member of Parliament Edwin Nii Lantey
Vanderpuye helped secure him the contract. Vanderpuye needed the support
of a traditional elder to build on the land: he needed to offer club goods to a
traditional leader for the state to develop a market there. Ashley sought the
assistance of his son-in-lawan educated businessman living in the United
Statesto help finance the project and provide the contracting skills and
expertise. The contract was the prize outcome of a long political struggle for
the rights to rebuild the marketone that spanned political parties, market
womens associations, and various MPs and assemblymen.
Ashleys story is specific but not unique. Despite Ga Mashies political
and historical importance, family struggles for authority and power divide
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
47
the community and undermine the public interest (Paller 2014b). NSPs in
indigenous settlements serve club interestsfamilies from the indigenous
ethnic group who claim ownership of the land. Political entrepreneurs in
indigenous settlements gain power from their ability to control land and
housingand profit from so-called drink moneyand derive their legitimacy
and authority from customary norms (Tipple et al. 1999). While members
of the nonindigenous group can make alliances with these NSPs, they must
subscribe to these indigenous norms and duties. In this way, affordable housing is not a public good for all members of the community, but a good that
privileges family and indigenous ties. Housing is governed as a club good.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
49
Jeffrey W. Paller
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
housing through a more formalized process. Political entrepreneurs in indigenous settlements like Ga Mashie and Chorkor are likelier to be entrenched
in traditional authority networks, reflecting the role customary authorities
have in controlling the land market. In extralegal settlements, NSPs control
the de facto land market and rule for their private interests. Yet all these
NSPs have important connections to the state and political parties that
require further investigation.
This article set out to answer why some urban residents gain access
to quality, affordable, and secure housing while others do not. The answer I
advance is that residents who align with powerful NSPsthe local informal
network led by a political entrepreneurhave greater opportunities to access
and secure affordable housing. NSPs respond to the incentives shaped by the
settlement pattern in which they govern land and housing. In other words,
the provision of affordable housing depends on more than state policies and
access to the free market; also, it requires paying attention to the informal
norms and duties that shape local governance and collective action.
Urban residents and businessmen in Accra rely on their political leaders to access affordable housing, secure land tenure, protect themselves from
the rule of law, and gain access to state resources. Affordable housing, rather
than being understood or experienced as a public good that helps all Ghanaians, is often a private or club good that benefits a small group of people.
Ghanaians vote their political party into power and support their community
leaders so they can access basic goods and services, like housing. Residents
whose leader is not in power feel a strong sense of insecurity, heightening the
importance of maintaining strong allegiances to their political party. Rather
than unifying the country and supporting a national housing policy, partisan
interests have politicized the provision of affordable housing and created a
political deadlock that is hard to break. This has significant implications for
the democratic process. Democratic government is not benefiting the public
good, but is being used by political parties to distribute state resources to
their followers at the expense of the rest of the population. Poor residents
who are not part of informal networks with access to political power suffer
the most and face the greatest barriers to affordable housing.
Without a strong rule of law and property-rights regime in place, those
who benefit from the private provision of goodsparticularly in extralegal
settlementshave significant power in maintaining the status quo (Fox
2014; Gulyani and Talukdar 2008). Therefore, providing public goods is not
simply about strengthening formal government institutions, but also about
creating incentives for these informal actors to enter a formal and regulated
environment. This involves directly confronting the politico-institutional
context that underlies daily life. The affordable housing shortage is a political
problem, not merely a technical or administrative one.
Finally, the study of housing requires on-the-ground analysis and the
collection of household-level and neighborhood-level original data. My
study demonstrates how ethnography and original survey data uncover the
importance of NSPs and their political effects in a way that relying on census
data and newspaper accounts does not. I can show the mechanisms through
which residents access, afford, and secure housing in poor environments.
I can demonstrate the power that certain local actors have and attempt to
show why some residents overcome institutional and structural challenges
while others do not. In fact, some local residents do have power, and they do
have opportunities to improve their life: the poor are not entirely powerless
or marginal (as Nelson 1979 and Perlman 1975 argued). The type of NSP,
the patronage networks that develop, and the links to political parties and
the state matter when it comes to control of the housing market in urban
Ghanaian communities. These things help explain why the status quo is so
difficult to change and why numerous efforts that focus solely on formal
housing markets and state provision of housing have failed. A continued
investigation of the grassroots political economy and local governance is
necessary to understand the challenges of urban housing in Ghana today.
INFORMAL NE T WORK S AND ACCESS TO POWER TO OBTAIN HOUSING IN URBAN SLUMS IN GHANA
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Special thanks to Sarah Charlton, Peter Lewis, Kate Owens, and Anne Pitcher for helpful comments during the African Studies Association Annual Meeting of 2013. The 2012 APSA Africa
Workshop team provided the inspiration for the paper. Danielle Carter and Lauren MacLean
provided fantastic feedback on many iterations of the paper. The Social Science Research Council
and the National Science Foundation Award Number 1226588 funded the research. Alhassan
Ibn Abdallah, Philip Kumah, Nii Addo Quaynor, and Abubakar Addy provided excellent research
assistance. Emmanuel Gyimah-Boadi and the Ghana Center for Democratic Development served
as great research collaborators. Mohammed Awal and Kakra Duayeden helped manage the
survey team with great skill. All errors are my own.
NOTES
1. UN-HABITAT (2003) defines slums by their physical conditions. Slum conditions lack durable
housing of a permanent nature that protects against extreme climate conditions; sufficient
living space, which means not more than three people sharing the same room; easy access
to safe water in sufficient amounts at an affordable price; access to adequate sanitation in
the form of a private or public toilet shared by a reasonable number of people; and security
of tenure that prevents forced evictions. I define slums as neighborhoods that have these
observable conditions.
2. The precise definition of informal institutions is the socially shared rules that are created,
communicated, and enforced outside of officially sanctioned channels (Helmke and Levitsky
2004). The networks I describe act in these broader, informal institutional environments.
3. The survey, entitled Public Service Provision in Urban Ghana, was conducted in April 2013 in
tandem with the Ghana Center for Democratic Development. It was funded by the National
Science Foundation Award Number 1226588. It is the first comprehensive survey that I know
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
of that considers many different types of slum communities in Accra, particularly the extralegal ones. The survey sampled residents in sixteen slum communities, varying the settlement
type of the slum. Boundaries of slums are determined by a rich assessment of how residents
and officials designate certain neighborhoods based on insights acquired after qualitative
research. The survey asks about political conditions in the slums. The questions are tailored to
fit local contexts and consider dynamics specific to slum life. The survey provides public service
in Accra, Ashaiman, and Kumasi (1183 total respondents). Slums are selected to vary the initial
settlement pattern of the slum (Paller 2014a). To make up for a lack of adequate baseline data
in these communities, the survey utilizes a spatial sampling technique (Landry and Shen 2005).
Using Google Earth, the research team constructed maps of all sixteen communities. It then
constructed a spatial grid of equal geographical units called clusters. Clusters were randomly
sampled in each slum (150 clusters total). The cluster is the enumeration area. A starting point
enumerators conducted a random walk protocol from each starting point.
inhabitants of these communities were Muslims from the north. Today, they are generally
understood to contain a strong Muslim identity, and members speak the Hausa language,
though not all members are of the Hausa ethnic group.
5. The question asked: Do you or the head of the household have property title for the structure?
6. The question asked: I will now read you several statements about your feelings of security of stay.
Please let me know which statement best represents your view. Answers: (1)I do not have security
of stay because the government or my landlord threatens to evict us; (2)I do not have security
of stay because I am in the midst of a property dispute with another family or ethnic group or
landlord; (3)I have security of stay because my political party is in power; (4)I have security
of stay because I am an indigene and this is a family house; (5)I have security of stay because
I or my family purchased this land legally; (6)I have security of stay because my ethnic group
controls this territory; (9)I dont know.
7. I thank Catherine Lena Kelly for emphasizing this point.
8. Ghana has had multiparty elections since 1992 and is hailed as the model democracy on the
continent. The political arena is dominated by two major political parties, the National Democratic Congress (NDC) and the National Patriotic Party (NPP). Since 2008, the NDC has been
the governing party; previously, the NPP ruled from 2000 to 2008. The parties have regional
and ethnic core areas, and most slums in the Greater Accra Region, including my study sites,
are NDC strongholds.
9. The question asked: How many contracts have you received from the government?
REFERENCES CITED
Accra Metropolitan Assembly. 2011. Participatory Slum Upgrading and Prevention: Millennium City of
Accra, Ghana. UN-HABITAT.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Matthew O. Jackson. 2012. History, Expectations, and Leadership in the
Evolution of Social Norms. Working Paper.
Acquah, Ione. 1958. Accra Survey. London: London University Press.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
4. In Nigeria, the term zongo is used to refer to a cattle market (Cohen 1969). In Ghana, the early
51
was randomly selected using GPS; public service data was collected at each starting point. The
data at the household and the community level. It includes sixteen distinct slum communities
Afenah, Afia. 2010. (Re)claiming Citizenship Rights in Accra: Community Mobilization Against the Illegal
Forced Eviction of Residents in the Old Fadama Settlement. In Cities for All: Experiences and
Proposals for the Right to the City, edited by A. Sugranyes and C. Mathivet. Santiago: Habitat
International Coalition.
African Development Bank Group. 2012. Urbanization in Africa, 13 December. www.afdb.org/en/blogs
/afdb-championing-inclusive-growth-across-africa/post/urbanization-in-africa-10143.
Agyei-Mensah, Samuel, and George Owusu. 2012. Ethnic Residential Clusters in Nima, Ghana. Urban
Forum 23:13349.
Allman, Jean Marie. 1991. Hewers of Wood, Carriers of Water: Islam, Class, and Politics on the Eve of
Ghanas Independence. African Studies Review 34(2):126.
Arhin, Kwame. 1971. Strangers and Hosts: A Study in the Political Organisation and History of Atebubu
Town. Transactions of the Historical Society of Ghana 12:6382.
Arimah, Ben C. 2010. The Face of Urban Poverty: Explaining the Prevalence of Slums in Developing
52
INFORMAL NE T WORK S AND ACCESS TO POWER TO OBTAIN HOUSING IN URBAN SLUMS IN GHANA
Arn, Jack. 1996. Third World Urbanization and the Creation of a Relative Surplus Population: A History
of Accra, Ghana, to 1980. Review 19(4):413444.
Auyero, Javier. 2001. Poor Peoples Politics: Peronist Survival Networks and the Legacy of Evita. Durham,
N.C.: Duke University Press.
Awuvafoge, Samson Abapale. 2013. Affordable Housing in Urban Areas of Ghana: Issues and Recommendations. Masters thesis, Department of Urban Planning, Ball State University.
Bank of Ghana. 2007. The Housing Market in Ghana. http://www.bog.gov.gh/privatecontent/Research
/Research%20Papers/bog%20housing.pdf.
Bardhan, Pranab, and Dilip Mookherjee. 2005. Decentralization, Corruption, and Government Accountability: An Overview. In International Handbook on the Economics of Corruption, edited by Susan
Rose-Ackerman and Edward Elgar. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Barnes, Sandra T. 1986. Patrons and Power: Creating a Political Community in Metropolitan Lagos. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Bates, Robert. 1983. Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Besley, Timothy. 1995. Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana.
Journal of Political Economy 103:90337.
Blocher, Joseph. 2006. Building on Custom: Land Tenure Policy and Economic Development in Ghana.
Yale Human Rights and Development Law Journal 9:166202.
Bob-Milliar, George M. 2012. Political Party Activism in Ghana: Factors Influencing the Decision of the
Politically Active to Join a Political Party. Democratization 19(4):66889.
Braimah, Farouk. 2011. A Decade of Struggles and Lessons at Old Fadama. SDI.net Blog. www.sdinet
.org/blog/2011/11/8/old-fadama-decade-struggles-and-lessons.
Buckley, Robert M., and Ashna Singh Mathema. 2008. Real Estate Regulations in Accra: Some Macroeconomic Consequences? Urban Studies 45(11):224971.
Cammett, Melani, and Lauren M. MacLean, eds. 2014. The Politics of Nonstate Social Welfare. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
Cohen, Abner. 1969. Custom and Politics in Urban Africa: A Study of Hausa Migrants in Yoruba Towns.
London: Routledge.
De Soto, Hernando. 2000. The Other Path. New York: Basic Books.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Du Plessis, Jean. 2005. The Growing Problem of Forced Evictions and the Crucial Importance of Community-Based, Locally Appropriate Alternatives. Environment and Urbanization 17(1):12334.
Elleh, Nnamdi. 2002. Architecture and Power in Africa. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
Fox, Sean. 2014. The Political Economy of Slums: Theory and Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. World
Development 54 (February):191203.
Goldstein, Markus, and Christopher Udry. 2008. The Profits of Power: Land Rights and Agricultural
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
, and Martin Oteng-Obabio. 2012. Mapping the Invisible and Real African Economy: Urban
53
, and J. Nijman. 2002. Globalization and the Corporate Geography of Cities in the Less Developed
Nelson, Joan M. 1979. Access to Power: Politics and the Urban Poor in Developing Nations. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Ntewusu, Samuel A. 2012. Settling In and Holding On: A Socio-Historical Study of Northerners in Accras
Tudu: 19082008. Leiden: African Studies Centre.
Obeng-Odoom, Franklin. 2011. Ill-Health Unleashed? Cities and Municipal Services in Ghana. Review
of African Political Economy 38(127):4360.
. 2012. Neoliberalism and the Urban Economy in Ghana: Urban Employment, Inequality, and
Poverty. Growth and Change 43(1):85109.
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Onoma, Ato Kwamena. 2010. The Politics of Property Rights Institutions in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Owusu, George. 2008. Indigenes and Migrants Access to Land in Peri-Urban Areas of Ghanas Largest
54
INFORMAL NE T WORK S AND ACCESS TO POWER TO OBTAIN HOUSING IN URBAN SLUMS IN GHANA
18(1):6876.
Paller, Jeffrey W. 2014a. African Slums: Constructing Democracy in Unexpected Places. PhD diss.,
University of Wisconsin-Madison.
. 2014b. Friend, Entrepreneur, Parent, Preacher: Informal Institutions and Personal Rule in Urban
Ghana. African Studies Review 57(3):12342.
Peil, Margaret. 1971. The Expulsion of West African Aliens. Journal of Modern African Studies 9(2):20529.
. 1976. African Squatter Settlements: A Comparative Study. Urban Studies 13:155.
Pellow, Deborah. 1985. Muslim Segmentation: Cohesion and Divisiveness in Accra. Journal of Modern
African Studies 23(3):41944.
. 2002. Landlords and Lodgers: Socio-Spatial Organization in an Accra Community. Chicago, Ill.:
University of Chicago Press.
Perlman, Janice. 1975. Rios Favelas and the Myth of Marginality. Politics and Society 5(2):13160.
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2004. Monitoring Elite Capture in Community-Driven Development. Development and Change 35(2):22346.
Price, Robert M. 1971. Politics and Culture in Contemporary Ghana: The Big-Man Small-Boy Syndrome.
Journal of African Studies 1(2):173204.
Quarcoopome, Samuel. 1987. The Rejection of the Municipal Corporations Ordinance of 1924 at Accra:
A Review of the Causes. Research Review 3(1):2429.
Razzu, Giovanni. 2005. Urban Redevelopment, Cultural Heritage, Poverty, and Redistribution: The Case
of Old Accra and Adawso House. Habitat International 29:399419.
Republic of Ghana. 1958. Accra: A Plan for the Town: The Report for the Minister of Housing. mci.ei
.columbia.edu/mci/files/2013/03/Accra-Town-Plan-1958.pdf.
. 1991. Strategic Plan for the Greater Accra Metropolitan Area. Volume 1: Context Report. http://mci
.ei.columbia.edu/files/2013/03/AMA-Strategic-Plan-vol-1.pdf.
Sackeyfio-Lenoch, Naaborko. 2014. The Politics of Chieftaincy: Authority and Property in Colonial Ghana,
19201950. Rochester, N.Y.: University of Rochester Press.
Sahlins, Marshall D. 1963. Poor Man, Rich Man, Big-Man, Chief: Political Types in Melanesia and Polynesia. Comparative Studies in Society and History 5(3):285303.
Sanjek, Roger. 1972. Ghanaian Networks: An Analysis of Interethnic Relations in Urban Situations. PhD
diss. Columbia University.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Schatz, Ed, ed. 2009. Political Ethnography: What Immersion Contributes to the Study of Power. Chicago:
University Chicago Press.
Schildkrout, Enid. 1970. Strangers and Local Government in Kumasi. Journal of Modern African Studies
8(2):25169.
. 1978. People of the Zongo: The Transformation of Ethnic Identities in Ghana. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Duke University Press.
Skinner, Elliot P. 1963. Strangers in West African Societies. Africa 33(4):30720.
. 1972. Political Conflict and Revolution in an African Town. American Anthropologist 74(5):
120817.
Stokes, Susan C. 2005. Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from
Argentina. American Political Science Review 99(3):31526.
Routledge.
Study of Accra, Kumasi, and Berekum. Progress in Planning 51(4):255324.
Tostensen, Arne, Inge Tvedten, and Mariken Vaa, eds. 2001. Associational Life in African Cities: Popular
Responses to the Urban Crisis. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordic Africa Institute.
UN-HABITAT. 2003. The Challenge of Slums: Global Report on Human Settlements.
. 2010. State of the Worlds Cities 2010/11: Cities for All: Bridging the Urban Divide. www.unhabitat
.org/content.asp?cid=8051&catid=7&typeid=46.
. 2011. Ghana Housing Profile. mirror.unhabitat.org/pmss/listItemDetails.aspx?publicationID
=3258&AspxAutoDetectCookieSupport=1.
Vidal, John. 2010. 227 Million People Escape Worlds Slums, UN Report Finds. Guardian, 22 March.
Wedeen, Lisa. 2010. Reflections on Ethnographic Work in Political Science. Annual Review of Political
Science 13:25572.
Weeks, John R., Allan G. Hill, Justin Stoler, eds. 2013. Spatial Inequalities: Health, Poverty and Place in
Accra, Ghana. GeoJournal Library 110.
World Bank. 2013a. Personal Remittances, Received. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/bx.trf.pwkr
.cd.dt.
. 2013b. Project Performance Assessment Report Ghana: Land Administration Project. www-wds
.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2013/06/19/000445729
_20130619150703/Rendered/PDF/750840PPAR0p0711570Box377346B00OUO090.pdf.
Yeboah, Ian E.A. 2000. Structural Adjustment and Emerging Urban Form in Accra, Ghana. Africa Today
47(2): 6089.
This content downloaded from 183.82.103.12 on Wed, 28 Oct 2015 06:53:47 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Jeffrey W. Paller
Tipple, Graham, David Korboe, Guy Garrod, and Kenneth Willis. 1999. Housing Supply in Ghana: A Case
55
Tibaijuka, Anna Kajimulo. 2009. Building Prosperity: Housing and Economic Development. New York:
Simone, AbdouMaliq. 2004. For the City Yet to Come: Changing African Life in Four Cities. Durham, N.C.: