Making Credit Safer: The Case For Regulation
Making Credit Safer: The Case For Regulation
Making Credit Safer: The Case For Regulation
O
R
U
M
I
34
I l l u s t ra t i o n s b y D a v i d Pl u n k e r t
feel about their inability to pay their bills? In 2005, the National
Opinion Research Council asked families about negative life
events: the death of a child and being forced to live on the street
or in a shelter topped the list, but ling for bankruptcy ranked
close behind, more serious than the death of a close friend or separating from a spouse. Of those who le for bankruptcy, 85 percent struggle to hide the fact from families, friends, or neighbors.
Why do people get into debt in the rst place? People know
that credit cards are dangerous, all the more so if they carry a balance. Any consumer who signed mortgage papers without reading carefully or seeking legal assistance should not be surprised if
terms come to light later that are unfavorable to the consumer.
Payday lenders have a bad reputation for taking advantage of people; no one should expect to be well treated by them. Car lenders,
check-cashing outlets, overdraft protectionthe point can be repeated again and again: Financial products are dangerous, and
any consumer who is not careful is inviting trouble. And yet, dangerous or not, millions of Americans engage in billions of credit
transactions adding up to trillions of dollars every year.
SETTING THE SNARE
35
those who were sold ruinous subprime mortgages would have qualied
for prime-rate loans. A study by the
Department of Housing and Urban
Development revealed that one in nine
middle-income families (and one in
14 upper-income families) who renanced a mortgage ended up with a
high-fee, high-interest, subprime loan.
Of course, YSPs are not conned to
subprime mortgages. Pushing a family
that qualies for a 6.5 percent loan
into a higher-cost loan and pocketing
the dierence will cost the family tens
of thousands of dollarsbut it will
not show up in anyones statistics on
subprime lending.
Other creditors have their own
techniques for eecing borrowers.
Payday lenders oer consumers a
friendly hand when they are short of
cash. But buried back in a page of disclosures for one lender (rather than on the fee page, where the
customer might expect to see it) was the note that the interest
rate on the loan was 485.450 percent. In transactions recently
documented by the Center on Responsible Lending, a $300 loan
cost one family $2,700, while another borrowed $400, paid back
$3,000, and was being hounded by the payday lender for $1,200
per month when they gave up and led for bankruptcy. In total,
the cost to American families of payday lending is estimated to
be $4.2 billion a year. The Department of Defense identied payday lending as such a serious problem for those in military service that it noted that the industry impaired military readiness. Congress has now banned all companies from charging
military people more than 36 percent interest, while leaving all
other families subject to the same predatory practices.
For some, Shakespeares injunction Neither a borrower nor a
lender be seems to be good policy. But no one advocates that
people who dont want their homes burned down should stay
away from toasters, or that those who dont want their ngers
and toes cut o should give up mowing the lawn. To say that
credit markets should follow a caveat emptor model is to ignore
the success of the consumer-goods marketand the pain inicted by dangerous credit products.
Indeed, the pain imposed by a dangerous credit product is
even more insidious than that inicted by a malfunctioning
kitchen appliance. Wealthy families can ignore the traps associated with credit-card debt: their savings will protect them from
medical expenses that exceed their insurance coverage or the
eects of an unexpected car repair. Working- and middle-class
families are far less insulated. For those closer to the economic
margin, a credit card with an interest rate that unexpectedly escalates to 29.99 percent or misplaced trust in a broker who recommends a high-priced mortgage can trigger a downward economic spiral from which a family may never recover.
INSUFFICIENT REMEDIES
Credit transactions have in fact been regulated by statute
or common law since the founding of the Republic. Traditionally
the most basic eorts are blocked from becoming law. A decade
ago, for example, mortgage-lender abuses were rare. Today, experts estimate that fraud and deception stripped $9.1 billion in
equity from homeowners, particularly from elderly and workingclass families, even before the subprime crisis got into full swing.
A few hardy souls have repeatedly introduced legislation to halt
such practices, but those bills never make it out of committee.
Even after a change in control of Congress in 2006, eorts to rein
in lenders have made little headway.
Beyond Congress, some regulation of nancial products occurs indirectly through the Federal Reserve Board, the Oce of
the Comptroller of the Currency, and the Oce of Thrift Supervisioneach of which has some power to control certain forms
of predatory lending. But their main misToday, experts estimate that fraud and sion is to protect the stability of banks
and other nancial institutions, not to
deception stripped $9.1 billion in equity protect consumers. As a result, they focus
intently on bank protability, and far less
from homeowners even before the subprime on the nancial impact on customers of
many of the products the banks sell.
crisis got into full swing. The regulatory jumble creates another
problem: consumer nancial products are
regulated based principally on the identity of the issuer, not on the
ing federal regulators the power to shut down state eorts to
nature of the product. The subprime-mortgage market provides a
regulate mortgage lenderswithout providing eective federal
stunning example of the resulting fractured oversight. In 2006,
regulation in turn.
for example, 23 percent of such mortgages were issued by reguLocal laws suer from another problem. As lenders have conlated thrifts and banks, and another 25 percent by bank holding
solidated and credit markets have become national, a plethora of
companies (subject to dierent federal oversight)but 52 perstate regulations drives up costs for lenders, forcing them to incent originated with companies with no federal supervision at
clude repetitive disclosures and meaningless exceptions even as it
all, primarily stand-alone mortgage brokers and nance compaalso leaves regulatory gaps. During the 1970s and early 1980s, for
nies. This division also triggers a kind of regulatory arbitrage.
example, Congress moved the regulation of some aspects of conRegulators are acutely aware that if they push nancial institusumer credit from the state to the federal level through a series of
tions too hard, those rms will simply reincorporate in another
landmark bills that included Truth-in-Lending (TIL), Fair Credit
form under the umbrella of a dierent regulatory agencyor
Reporting, and anti-discrimination regulations. These statutes
none at all. Indeed, in recent years a number of credit unions
tend to be highly specic: TIL species the information that must
have dissolved and reincorporated as state or national banks,
be revealed in a credit transaction, including the size of the typeprecisely to t under a regulatory
face that must be used and how interest rates must be stated. But
(please turn to page 94)
the specicity of these laws works
against their eectiveness, inhibiting some benecial innovations (e.g., new ways of informing
consumers) while failing to regulate dangerous innovations (e.g.,
no discussion of negative amortization). Whats more, these generation-old regulations completely miss most of the new
features of credit products such as
universal default (increasing interest rates even when customers
are meeting all the terms of their
credit agreements) and doublecycle billing (charging interest on
money that was repaid).
Any eort to increase or reform
regulation of nancial products is
met by a powerful industry lobby
that is not balanced by an equally
eective consumer lobby, so even
states bore the primary responsibility for protecting their citizens from unscrupulous lenders, imposing usury caps and other
credit regulations on all companies doing business locally. Although states still play some role, particularly in the regulation
of real-estate transactions, their primary toolinterest-rate regulationhas been eectively destroyed by federal legislation.
Today, any lender that gets a federal bank charter can locate its
operations in a state with high usury rates (e.g., South Dakota or
Delaware) and then export that states interest-rate caps (or no
caps at all) to customers located all over the country. As a result,
and with no public debate, interest rates have been eectively
deregulated across the country. In April 2007, the Supreme Court
took another step in the same direction in Watters v. Wachovia, giv-
view of nancial products in a single location, with a focus on the safety of the
products as consumers use them. Companies
that oer good products would have little to fear. Indeed, if they could conduct
business without competing with companies whose business model is to mislead the customer, then the vendors
oering safer products would be more
likely to ourish. Moreover, with an
FPSC, consumer-credit suppliers would
be free to innovate on a level playing
eld within the boundaries of clearly
disclosed terms and open competitionnot hidden terms designed to
mislead consumers.
The consumer nancial services industry has grown to more than $3 trillion in
annual business. Lenders employ thousands of lawyers, marketing agencies,
statisticians, and business strategists to
help them increase prots. In a rapidly
changing market, customers need someone on their side to help make certain
that the products they buy meet minimum safety standards. Personal responsibility will always play a critical role in
dealing with credit cards or other loans,
just as personal responsibility remains a
central feature in the safe use of any other
product, but a Financial Product Safety
Commission would be the consumers
ally. And for every family that avoids a
trap or doesnt get caught by a trick
thats regulation that works.
Elizabeth Warren, RF 02, is Gottlieb professor of
law and faculty director of the Program of Judicial
Education at Harvard Law School. An earlier version of this article appeared in Democracy: A
Journal of Ideas (democracyjournal.org/article.php?ID=6528).