The Ottoman Monetary Crisis of 1585 Revisited
The Ottoman Monetary Crisis of 1585 Revisited
The Ottoman Monetary Crisis of 1585 Revisited
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
BRILL is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of the Economic and
Social History of the Orient.
http://www.jstor.org
(it) |7eSHo|
*
'<
WiPw
Journal of theEconomic and
BRILLSocial History of the Orient 52 (2009) 460-504
brill.nl/jesh
Abstract
In 1585-8,
44%.
the Ottoman
theVenetian
Some
others have
whereas
to face in
itswar
financing
that the unification of a number
study suggests
that the
state had
Ottoman
must
interregional imperial economy by the second half of the sixteenth century
as an
to the monetary
crisis
of
that
factor
contributed
1585.
important
be regarded
lamonnaie
1585-88,I'akge,
d'argent ottomane, fut devaluee officiellement de 100% par
et le pourcentage
d'ar
rapport au ducat d'or venitien et lesmonnaies
d'argent etrangeres,
et cette
cette
en
devaluation
Certains
chercheurs
fut
reduit
de
44%.
interpretent
gent
En
les Safavides
de zones monetaires
dans
interregionale
Empire,
contribution
ayant contribue
important
Keywords
Ottoman
d'Iran. Cette
de
de
a la crise monetaire
devaluation,
debasement,
tan
l'influx d'argent venant des Ameriques,
au financement
des guerres
l'etat ottoman
economic
integration, monetarization
dynamics
Although
*) Baki
Tezcan,
Assistant
Professor
Studies
of History,
Program,
and Religious
Studies,
of California, Davis,
University
2009
DOI:
Department
USA,
of
btezcan@
10.1163/156852009X458223
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 RevisitedAG1
between the influx of Spanish silver from theAmericas into theOttoman
an abundance of silver should
Empire and the debasement, the reason why
a debasement of the silver currency is not quite clear.
about
such
bring
to Bernard Lewis, "[t]he Ottoman
rulers, accustomed to crises
According
or
to
meet a crisis
were
unable
of shortage,
understand
quite
resulting from
an excess of silver," and thus took the same measures that theywould have
taken if they faced a shortage, hence the debasement.1
Halil Inalcik asserts that the devaluation and debasement were "a conse
which was
sets of data,
inspired by Earl Hamilton's work.2 Using multiple
Omer Lutfi Barkan demonstrates that theOttoman economy experienced
was very similar to the
a
changes in the Euro
general price increase which
to
in
rise
the
Barkan,
pean economy. According
prices and the devaluation
of the akce were parallel developments thatwere brought about by "inter
in precious metals, changes in trade patterns, the
national movements
tremendous expenditures of the Ottoman
government for various wars
undertaken at the time, and a great population increase which took place
inmost of Europe, as well as in the remainder of theMediterranean world,
After Pamuk's correction, the price increases between 1489 and 1573
expressed in grams of silverwere reduced to 31% from 60%. After this
1) Bernard
Islamica
2) Halil
Lewis,
9 (1958):
"Some
Reflections
on
the Decline
of the Ottoman
Empire."
Studia
119-20.
"Notes
on a
and
Study of the Turkish Economy
during the Establishment
Tr.
Howard
translation
of
"Osmanh
[revised
Empire."
Douglas
Impa
kurulus ve inkisafi devrinde Turkiye'nin
iktisadi vaziyeti iizerinde bir tetkik
Inalcik,
on
Inalcik (Bloomington:
Indiana Uni
Empire: Essays
Economy and Society, Halil
Turkish
Earl
"American
Treasure
and
Studies,
241,
Hamilton,
1993):
243-4;
J.
versity
A Study in the
Andalusian
1503-1660:
Prices,
Journal
Spanish Price Revolution."
of
Ottoman
1 (1928):
and Business History
1-35
"The Price Revolution
of the Sixteenth Century: A Turning Point in
the Economic
of
the
Near
East."
Tr.
Justin McCarthy
History
[abridged translation with
revisions of "XVI. asnn ikinci
yansinda Turkiye'de
fiyat hareketleri." Belleten 34 (1970):
Economic
3) Omer
L. Barkan,
Uni
of the Ottoman Empire (Cambridge: Cambridge
also
See
Hareketleri":
569.
Pamuk,
122; compare Barkan, "Fiyat
?evket
versity Press, 2000):
International Journal of
in the Ottoman
"The Price Revolution
Empire Reconsidered."
?evket Pamuk, A Monetary
Middle
East
Studies
33
History
(2001):
69-89;
?evket
Pamuk,
"Prices
in the Ottoman
Empire,
ve
Yilhk Fiyatlar ve Ucretler, 1469-1998
Diger Kentlerde 500
tistik Enstitusu, 2000).
5) Omer L.
ait tereke defterleri
Barkan, "Edirne Askeri Kassami'na
Istanbul
(Ankara: Devlet
(1545-1659)."
Ista
Belgeler
The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century: The East India
Steensgaard,
Press,
Trade (Chicago: The University of Chicago
theDecline
and
of the Caravan
Companies
7) The
donem
(Tanzimat
by Baki (Jakir, "Geleneksel
ve
Kurumlar
In
Osmank
biitce gelirleri."
Butgeler, eds M. Gene
oncesi) Osmanh
Maliyesi:
Bankasi Arsiv ve Arastirma Merkezi,
2006): vol.
and E. Ozvar. 2 vols. (Istanbul: Osmanh
to (fakir's
error, the deficit according
1: 171, is misleading.
First, there is a calculation
not include the treasury's
akces. Second,
numbers should have been 8,841,285
(Jakir did
akces from tefdviit, an income item that is constituted by the difference
profit of 4,912,497
of exchange rates in receiving and expending funds in currencies other than the akce. While
deficit of 12,830,005
akces noted
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited463
a total of 38,207 soldiers,
including auxiliary
more than in 1574.
troops and cadets, received regular salaries?9,000
Moreover,
10,000,000 akces were sent to Ozdemiroglu Osman Pasha in
achieved at a time when
Shirvan for the payment of his troops, numbering at least another 4,000.8
Thus as late as 1583, in themidst of the Safavid wars, while the number of
people who received salaries from the treasury had increased by almost
50% in the previous ten years, the Ottoman central treasurywas able to
deal with the situation, despite the fact thatmore than 11% of the reve
totaled 279,649,967
akces, were transferred to the personal
were
thus not available to cover expenditures.
treasury of the sultan and
nues, which
(2004):
included
ve Biitceler, eds
In Osmanh
tarihli biitce?ceviriyazi."
Kurumlar
(hicri 990)
Maliyesi
and E. Ozvar. 2 vols. (Istanbul: Osmanh
Bankasi Arsiv ve Arastirma Merkezi,
2006):
vol. 2: 33, 46. The surplus of 36,165,890
akces for the same year that is shown in Pamuk,
A Monetary History
carried over to
133, is the amount of money
of the Ottoman Empire:
83
M.
Gene
8)The
soldiers
figuresfor 1583 [and 1574] are: 16,905 [13,599] janissaries,8,346 [5,957] cavalry
(altt boluk), 3,736
[2,124]
auxiliary
troops
fob),
XVTI.
dir deneme."
(Istanbul Universitesi,
Ph.D.
dissertation
asnn
sonlanna
kadar Osmanh
para
1958).
tarihi uzerinde
464
ratiosmoved closer
of arbitrage opportunities as the different gold?silver
to each other.
lands
The first section of the study focuses on the former Mamluk
ratio in the Levant and Egypt
and demonstrates that the gold?silver
was different from the one in the central lands of the Ottoman Empire
was overvalued
the monetary
In the third section, I will point out that the arrival of Spanish silver
from theAmericas intensified the expansion of the sahi's use in the empire
tomint overvalued silver coinage which liter
by providing ample supplies
a
in the gold?sil
ally invaded theOttoman domains, threatening change
ver ratio at the center. Consequently, the value of silver increased above the
level that could support the weight and fineness of the akce. In the last
section Iwill argue that these results proved to be disadvantageous for the
Ottoman center as theOttoman
treasury had a vested interest in keeping
more expensive in relation to silver in the capital. Thus in 1585 the
gold
administration not only acknowledged a situation created by
Ottoman
market forces but also made an effort to intervene by trying to increase the
value of gold against silver.Yet the effortof the administration failed, and
in 1600 theOttoman center finally revalued silver in relation to gold.
I
a new region, the Ottoman administra
the Ottomans
conquered
to unify its dominions under a
not
at
endeavor
did
least
tion,
initially,
to
the local traditions of the areas
follow
single law; theymostly continued
matters relating to
that were brought under Ottoman
sovereignty in
When
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited465
or just a
policy,10
matter of necessity in the relative absence of efficient central political
tools of enforcement, is open to debate. Different regional currencies were
among the local practices that theOttoman administration continued to
taxation and land laws.Whether
this was
a conscious
allow in its eastern and southern provinces. Thus the empire was divided
into a number of currency zones inwhich coins of differentweights con
stituted themajor denomination in daily use. As will be shown later in this
zones as
study, the Ottoman center benefited from the existence of these
as
was
was in the
in
it
them
than
comparatively cheaper
capital.
gold
long
of Conquest."
Studia Islamica 2 (1954):
103-29.
Inalcik, "Ottoman Methods
Stephen Album, A Checklist of Islamic Coins, second ed. (Santa Rosa: Stephen Album,
and Mecca,
for instance, are valued
in an
1998): 126. The silver coins of Aleppo
differently
"The Role of
inventory of the Ottoman
imperial treasury from 1518; Halil
Sahillioglu,
n)
International
in Ottoman
and Metal Movements
1300
Monetary
Monetary
History,
1750." Tr. liter Turan and Rhoads Murphey
[translation of "Osmanh para tarihinde diinya
hareketlerinin
Issue (1978):
para ve maden
yeri (1300-1750)."
Geli?me Dergisi
Special
In
in the Later Medieval
Precious
Metals
and
1-38].
Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F. Richards
466
the establishment
among
themselves
in their
respective regions.
In the formerMamluk
Mamluk
denote
dard
to denote
by
introducing
Osmanli
the stan
yet
Sikkeleri
15)On
Sul
the origins of the designation
nisf, see Paul Balog, The Coinage of theMamluk
tans
American Numismatic
The
387.
York:
and
47,
1964):
(New
Society,
Syria
ofEgypt
16)
"Osmanli
Ottoman Empire:
95; Sahillioglu,
Pamuk, A Monetary History
para
of the
ve
Tahlilleri.
Hukuki
Kanunnameleri
Osmanli
tarihi": 96, n. 9; Ahmed Akgiinduz,
ed.,
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited 467
was less than the Otto
gold coin
Although theweight of theMamluk
was
more than theOtto
man one, that of the standardMamluk
silver coin
man akce,
in
late
fifteenth
the
around
1.4-1.5
century, and ca.
g.
weighing
1.1 g. in the early sixteenth century, if one were to rely on theweight of
extant coins.When Selim I conquered the area, the gold coins struck in his
were the most
name followed the standard of the
ghawri ashrafls, which
recent and the least valuable in terms of silver currency.Yet the silver coins
struck in the name of Selim I by the firstOttoman governor of Egypt seem
to have lowered standards even more, and probably continued the trend of
to be worth
one
9 vols.
Arastirmalan
vol. 3: 260, 272;
Vakfi,
(Istanbul: Osmanh
1990-6):
Sahillioglu,
"Ottoman Monetary History":
Osmanh
biit
"1524-1525
297, Table 4a; Halil Sahillioglu,
cesi." Istanbul Universitesi Iktisat Fakiiltesi Mecmuasi
41 (1982-3):
434, 437-8.
17)Norman
D. Nicol,
Raafet El-Nabarawy,
and Jere L. Bacharach,
eds, Catalog
of the
Islamic Coins, Glass Weights, Dies
in the Egyptian National
and Medals
Cairo
Library,
"Osmanh
Publications,
(Malibu, CA: Undena
1982): 95, 98; Sahillioglu,
para tarihi":
96-7,
n. 9, 11; Olcer,
Osmanh
Sikkeleri:
istrative
and Admin
and Development
(Princeton: Princeton
Organization
ofOttoman Egypt, 1517-1798
65.
Press,
1962):
University
18)
"Osmanh
Sultan Suleyman
para tarihi": 97, n. 11; ibrahim Artuk, Kanuni
Sahillioglu,
Adma Basilan Sikkeler (Ankara: Turk Tarih Kurumu,
Osmanh
1972): 64-65; Akgundiiz,
Kanunndmeleri;
vol. 6:
139.
468
Mamluk
a silver
sharp increase in the value of silver against gold hence implying
scarcity, as, according to Ashtor, the ratio in 1497 had been 1:11.1. The
in 1522 and sanctioned in
ratio instituted by the Ottomans
gold?silver
1524-5 was
19)
Akgiindiiz,
20)
Osmanh
Kanunnameleri:
vol. 6: 124.
et la balance
despayements
du proche-orient
a la basse
content of the silver currency with its exchange rate against the gold currency,
ing the silver
= 7.25.
and then dividing the result by the weight of the gold currency: (1.03 x 25): 3.55
21)
Sultans: 43. At that time 420 akces were struck from
The Coinage of theMamluk
Balog,
100 dirhems (307.2 g.) of pure silver, so an akce contained 0.73 g. of silver. 55 akces made
"Osmanh
a ducat. Thus (0.73 x 55): 3.55 = 11.3; Sahillioglu, "1524-1525":
434; Sahillioglu,
64.
tarihi'>:
42,
para
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited 469
verified by the fact that Egypt sent its tribute to the Ottoman
capital in
a
gold coins, point thatwill be revisited below.
It is also interesting to note thatwhile the Egyptian para contained only
1.03 g. of silver, itwas valued at 2 akces in relation to theOttoman akce,
which was supposed to contain 0.73 g. of silver at that time.22 Intrinsically,
the para should have been worth 1.4 akces, or 1.5 akces at themost. Thus
the Egyptian para was definitely overvalued in terms of its silver content.
This only makes sense when the exchange value of the para and the akce
against the gold ducat is taken into consideration. Using the gold ducat as
a measure
towhich 25 paras equaled 55 akces, one would expect
according
the para to be worth 2.2 akces (55/25). This is significantly closer to the
official exchange rate of 2 akces to the para. The respective values of the
para and the akce against the ducat must therefore have been decisive for
a comparison of
establishing their exchange values against each other?not
their silver contents.
The available evidence thus suggests that Egypt and the Levant which
para zone, on the one hand, and Anatolia and
tively independently from each other; due to less developed market rela
tions zones are either not well informed about each other's
respective
22) For
see
the value of the para in terms of the akce in
Osmanli Kanun
Egypt,
Akgiinduz,
area that date from
6; 111. Three financial regulations from the Adana
ca. 1526, 1536, and 1547
rate of the para as 2 akces as well;
give the exchange
Akgunduz,
Osmanli Kanunndmeleri:
vol. 5: 608, 613, vol. 7: 191.
23) K. N.
"The Economic
and Monetary
Problem of European
Trade with
Chaudhuri,
Asia during the Seventeenth and
The Journal
Eighteenth Centuries."
ofEuropean Economic
ndmeleri'. vol.
470
created the arbitrage profits in the first place. Moreover, the exchange rate
of the akce against the para changed to reflect the new value of the ducat
in paras. Whereas
the para was valued at 2 akces in 1525 when 25 paras
a
made
ducat, later rates suggest that 1.5 akces were counted as the equiv
alent of one para, which makes sense since now 40 paras and 60 akces
in terms of the value of the ducat.25
equaled each other
24)
UgoTucci,
1553-1556(Paris:
SEVPEN,
25)Walther
Hinz,
1991): 13,42-3.
Islamische Wahrungen
umgerechnet
in Gold
(Wiesbaden:
Otto Harrassowitz,
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited 471
Even at the new rate of the para against the ducat, silverwas slightly
more valuable in the Levant than itwas in the central lands of the empire
as one needed 2.6 g. less silver to get a ducat inAleppo than one would in
Istanbul. Yet in the 1550s, Egypt was experiencing a silver drainage to an
unknown destination, where silver must have been even more valuable
than itwas in the para zone. As is evident from an imperial order sent to
the governor of Egypt in 1552, among the solutions offeredwas an increase
of the copper content of the para. Although no action was taken at the
time, around 1565 a debasement did take place in Egypt the exact ratio of
which is open to debate. An Arabic source suggests that itwas around
to 0.68
decreasing the silver content of the akce from 0.73 g.
g.27Yet nei
ther in the Levant, nor in the central lands of the empire did an official
devaluation against the ducat take place, which suggests that the govern
ment was trying tomake silvermore valuable in relation to
was
gold. Silver
most probably moving to an unidentified destination where itwas more
valuable
restore
pre-conquest
rates,
as was
the
case
in
Egypt
in
1522-5.
Moreover,
Sahillioglu, "Osmanli para tarihi": 85-7, 98 (n. 18); compare Pamuk, A Monetary History
the
Ottoman Empire: 96 (n. 18); Muhammad
Ibn Abi al-Surur, Al-Minah
of
al-rahmaniyya
al-dawlat
ed.
Dar al-Bashair,
172,
(Damascus:
1995):
Layla
ft
al-uthmaniyya,
al-Sabbagh
ca.
however, supports Sahillioglu's
argument and suggests that the para was debased
by
8.7%. For different interpretations of the relevant statement in this text, see Baki Tezcan,
A Reassessment
of the Deposition
of the Ottoman
Sultan Osman
"Searching for Osman:
II (1618-1622)."
Ph.D. dissertation
314-5, n. 44.
(Princeton University, 2001):
27) The exact
is not known, but itwas in effect
date of this debasement
by 1572; Sahillioglu,
"Osmanli para tarihi": 64, 74 (n. 7).
of the sixteenth century this area had become far better integrated
into themarkets of the central Ottoman
lands as indicated by the change
in its gold?silver
ratio, which came quite close to the one prevalent in
Istanbul. Thus it seems justified to claim that the forces of themarket oper
ated against the will of the administration by bringing the different cur
rency zones closer to each other, a point to be discussed further below.
one
ca. 1565 and the Ottoman
Finally, the Egyptian debasement of
middle
Persia.
II
akce. Around
28) In order to
the Persian from the Ottoman
coin, the former will be referred
distinguish
to hereafter as shahi, the latter as sahi.
29)H. L. Rabino
and Seals of the Shdhs of Iran, 1500-1941
di Borgomale,
Coins, Medals
"Search
II (following p. 8); see Tezcan,
Table
and
Austin
Sons,
1945):
(Hertford: Stephen
315-6
(n. 46), for a discussion on the accuracy of this weight.
ing for Osman":
Crisis of1585
Revisited
473
was
5.25 g. Around
1547,
if
conclusions are correct, between 1501 and 1550, the
Album's
Thus,
Safavid shahi lost half of its silver content. The Ottoman akce, however,
did not go through any debasements between 1491 and the reign of
Selim II (1566-74). Consequently, one could claim that the Safavid debase
ments of the firsthalf of the sixteenth century did not have an impact on
theOttoman akce.
This picture, however, changes in the second half of the sixteenth cen
tury. Berengo, our Venetian merchant inAleppo, provides some valuable
30)
Album,
on Rabino
A Checklist
59-61, relying
of Islamic Coins: 126-7; Hinz, Islamische Wahrungen:
di Borgomale,
and Seals of the Shahs of Iran, 1500-1941:
Coins, Medals
28, 30,
coins
the
denomination
of
these
he
does
that
the
shahi
lost a
yet
agree
regards
differently,
lot of its silver content during the reign of Tahmasp.
I took Albums western Safavid stan
into consideration
Khorasan
November 15, 1555), 101 (#93,November 17), 113 (#100,November 17), 126 (#109,
18); see also letters #87, 88, 91, 96, pp. 93, 95, 98, 106. 20 soldi made a lira,
in 1533 a Venetian
ducat was valued at 7 lire and 18 soldi; in 1562, its value is
gold
recorded as 8 lire;W. A. Shaw, The History of Currency, 1252 to 1894, third ed. (New York:
November
and
G.
P. Putnam's
Sons
1896):
317.
Ifwe
474
uation
devaluation
in Persia,...
at
king of theTurkes [Murad III (1574-95)], who receauing theCitty ofCairo the
he put it out againe in Constantinople,
of gold [sequin] for xliii. Maidini,
that it should
lxxxv.Maidini,
and Ianissaries, withall
commanding
pay his Capigi
of that value ouer all the Citty, and countryes subiect vnto it.35
Cechino
to
be
33)FernandBraudel,TheMediterraneanand the
MediterraneanWorld in the
Age ofPhilip II,
Hartwell
(London:
Iohn Wolfe,
1595):
inEuropa.
7 vols. (Gotha:
F. A. Perthes,
76.
tr.
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisis of1585 Revisited 475
account of the Persian devaluation
Minadoi's
dinars.36What
100 dinars and struck smaller coins of ca. 2.3 g. that he valued at 50 dinars.
The numismatic evidence supports this hypothesis to a large extent.
Album, whose work represents the latest research on Safavid coinage,
argues that the 2.3 g. coins were worth half a shahi, i.e. 25 dinars, in the
period 1547-52, while the shahis of 50 dinars weighed ca. 4.7 g. Around
1553, the denominational value of the former shahi was increased to 80
dinars, and that of the former half shahi to 40 dinars. In 976 / 1568-9, the
Hinz,
"The Value
eds Mojtaba
Minovi
I. Afshar
1969): 90-5.
37)
Album,
in theMiddle
of the Toman
and
of 1553,
(Tehran:
In
Ages."
Ydd-ndme-ye Irdni-ye
of Tehran University,
Publications
A Checklist
standards within
the Ottomans.
38) E.
Delmar
discussion
of the eastern
127-8; I omit Albums
of Islamic Coins:
the Safavid Empire, which would not have had much of an influence on
Morgan
and C. H.
Coote,
and Persia.
2 vols.
476
dence, these coins originally seem to have weighed 4.4 g., which is quite
close to theweight of the Persian shahi prior to itsdebasement.41 Although
there is no evidence to establish the officialweight or the exchange rate of
these initial Ottoman
sahis, these coins most probably had a value of 7
or
the Persian shahi before the debasement. Then in
like
5
akces,
paras,
(London:Hakluyt Society,1885-6): vol. 2: 387-9, 391-2. Other letterspublished in the
60
=) 6.75
of the shahi
Ottoman
value of thePersianshahi in 1566 as 66 2/3 Pf., and thatof theakce in 1564 as 16 2/3 Pf.,
the Persian shahi after its devaluation was valued at 4 akces;
supporting the argument that
Islamische Wdhrungen: viii, 43, 60.
41)
Sultan Suleyman Adina Basilan Sikkeler. 68, no. 173;
See, for instance, Artuk, Kanuni
the weight of this coin might have been more than 4.4 g. since the extant coins may have
been subject to clipping. On the other hand, there are also coins of this sort that are much
or may represent a different
have been struck after a debasement,
lighter, and which may
see Artuk, Kanuni
Sultan Suleyman Adina Basilan Sikkeler. 23, no. 61.
denomination;
Crisis of1585
Revisited
477
50 dinars in terms
1555, after the debasement of the Persian shahi?worth
half itsweight, the Ottomans had two alterna
of money of account?to
tives. If theywere to follow the Safavids, they could strike coins of half the
same value in terms ofmoney of account, for instance
weight and keep the
same
a
or
2.2 g. for 7 akces,
they could have kept the
weight and assign
value of 14 akces to it. In this case the akce would have been effectively
to half its silver value, which did indeed eventually happen at
the end of the sixteenth century.42Alternatively, they could have kept
the same weight as well as the exchange value of the coin in terms of the
devalued
akce, but effectivelydevalue the Persian money of account in the sense that
two new Persian shahis worth 100 dinars (instead of one former Persian
sahi of 7 akces. In this
shahi of 50 dinars) would be worth 1 Ottoman
case the Ottoman
silver coins would have had a tremendous advantage
in Persian markets
would
follow.
25% more
to
we do
that the Ottoman
sahi was supposed
weigh 3.84 g. in 1566,
were struck
the official weight of the
coins
that
I
the
earlier,
larger
by Suleyman
heaviest extant example of which from the
mint is 4.4 g.; Artuk, Kanuni
Sultan
Baghdad
Suleyman Adina Basilan Sikkeler. 23.
Although
not know
478
empire in the 1560s. First of all, 8 sahis would include 30.72 g. of silver,
which is quite close to the estimated weight of silver exchanged for a ducat
in Persia. Second, the sources that cite the value of the ducat against the
sahi later in the century either quote 8 sahis for a ducat, or, after the rise in
the value of the ducat, 8 sahis for a "ducat of account."45 Thus an exchange
rate of 8 sahis per ducat in the 1560s would not have been unreasonable.
sahi against
If one takes this estimated exchange value of theOttoman
the ducat as a starting point, its value against the akce becomes under
standable. As pointed out above, although the para contained only asmuch
44) Laurence
an
in a letter from Qazvin
dated April 28, 1569,
Chapman,
English merchant,
asserts that "twelve duckets...
sixe and fiftie shawghs" i.e. 13 shahis
[make] one hundred
and Coote, Early Voyages to Russia and Persia: vol. 2: 413. The very
for a ducat; Morgan
Discov
same letter in Richard Hakluyt,
ed., The Principal Navigations
Voyages Traffiques &
vol. 3:
12 vols. (Glasgow: James MacLehose
and Sons, 1903-05):
of theEnglish Nation.
"The
in rendering 156. Hinz,
is probably a mistake
reads "... 165. shaughs," which
in theMiddle Ages": 92, relies on the latter edition of the letter, thus
Value of the Toman
eries
142,
ducats
takes these ducats to be Hungarian
his figure needs to be corrected. Moreover Hinz
in the letter. The context, which is the price of kersey
is no such qualification
there
although
ducats. For the weight of the
rather suggests that it should be Venetian
clothes inAleppo,
shahi, see above, p. 475. In the Istanbul of the late 1560s, a gold ducat was worth 60 akces
=
see
while 450 akces were struck from 307.2 g. of silver, thus (307.2: 450) x 60
40.96;
n. 27 above.
William
Barret
in 1584
that in Baghdad
and Basra
8 sahis make
& Discoveriesofthe
ducat of account;Hakluyt, The PrincipalNavigationsVoyages
Traffiques
Levant
in late sixteenth-century
Nation:
vol. 6: 10, 12. The ducat of account
English
included 40 paras (8 sahis) which was the value of the real ducat between the 1550s and the
354, and
late 1570s; seeTucci, Lettres dun marchand venitien Andrea Berengo, 1553-1556:
the quotes
inHinz,
Islamische Wahrungen:
12-4.
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited479
silver as was used for 1.4 akces
in theOttoman records is very close to this and must therefore have been
calculated according to this principle.46 Had the center been motivated by
the intrinsic silver content of the sahi, a sahi that contained 3.84 g. silver,
which equaled 5.6 akces, would have been valued at 5.5, or at most
6 akces. The official value of 7-7.5 akces assigned to the sahi makes it clear
that the center determined the exchange rate of this regional currency in
The assumption of the administration must have been that the trade
with Safavid Persia had a certain monetary impact on the eastern and
southeastern provinces. A devaluation in the Safavid Empire could at best
have had an influence on those areas but not really on western Anatolia, let
alone the Balkans. The fact that previous Safavid debasements had not had
an
on theOttoman akce shows that this
impact
assumption was not neces
sarilywrong.47 The Ottoman administration thus responded to the ques
tion at hand with the experience of the past, which was an
experience
based on more limited trade zones with multiple local economies inwhich
different gold?silver
ratios could operate, creating
arbitrage profits for the
were
fewwho
inmany zones.
well-connected
The Ottoman
46)
this was
to the
treasury. In 1582, the
as 7.5 akces when
were
they
44.
480
was.
quite difficult to account for Sokollus own trade in grain with Venice, or
the various violations of the prohibition by less exalted people.49 As will be
shown below, thingswere changing in the currency market as well.
use of theOttoman ?ahi
Although the
might have prevented silver losses
thatwould
is fasci
theywere, because the ?ahi had quickly invaded the Levant. What
was welcomed
use
it
is
of
the
about
the
the
of
that
?ahi
expansion
nating
by the public despite the fact that itwas an overvalued piece of silver. In
1572, its going rate inAleppo seems to have been 5 paras, which must
have been the result of its independent value against the ducat in the east
ently this is exactly what happened. The finance director of Aleppo drew
theOttoman capital's attention to the fact that the sahi was overvalued in
terms of its silver content, and that itsvalue had to be reduced to 4 paras.
48) Liitfi
ticareti
Gii^er, "XVI. yiizyil sonlannda Osmanli
Imparatoriugu dahilinde hububat
Mecmuasi
nin tabi
13 (1951-2): 79-98.
oldugu kayitlar." Istanbul Universitesi tktisat Fakultesi
49)
ticaretinin
dahilinde hububat
"XVI. yiizyil sonlannda Osmanli
Gucer,
Imparatoriugu
tabi oldugu
Dair
Kaynaklar:
Hirzii'l-Muluk,
"Hirzii'l-Muluk."
Mesalihil
(Ankara: TurkTarih
In Osmanli
Miislimin
Kurumu,
Devlet
Teskildtina
ve
MendfiTl-Muminin?
178.
1988):
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited 481
to
coins or
coming fromAnatolia, who used
bring either gold
to barter with, now brought silver, converted it to sahis in themint
goods
of Diyarbekir, and used the sahis for their purchases.50
Merchants
Since around this time 450 akces were struck from 100 dirhems of sil
ver, one may suppose that the price of silver could not have been any
inAnatolia. Most probably, itwas
higher than 450 akces per 100 dirhems
one had to pay certain fees for the
a
since
that
little
than
actually
cheaper
mint. Ifone took 100 dirhems of silver to the southern mints of the empire,
one could get 80 sahis.51 These sahis were worth at least 560 akces at
7 akces a sahi. Thus 450 akces worth of silver produced an extra 110 akces
worth of purchasing power in the Levant, which amounts to a profit of
24.4%.
After the finance director of Aleppo had explained this situation to the
center
to his request
capital in 1572, the Ottoman
responded favorably
and ordered the exchange rate of the sahi to be reduced to 4 paras. Although
at 4 paras the sahi would make 6 akces and would still be overvalued, the
to 6.7%. Yet it seems that the order was
arbitrage profitwould be reduced
of no avail. European travelers noted the value of the sahi at 4.5 paras in
1574, and at 5 paras in 1577 and 1579.52
Thus the sahi started to be used in the greater Syria area at the latest by
the early 1570s. Minting
sahis soon became quite popular in the region
and spread from themint of Baghdad to themints ofAleppo and Diyarbe
kir. By the late 1570s investors had raised their bids for the tax-farms of the
mints that struck sahis by almost 25,000 ducats.53 In 1582, the provincial
50)
Sahillioglu,
51)When
420
"Osmanli
akces were
in the balance
mail yilina
19 (1957-8):
276. The
value
seem to have
of the mid
changed after the debasement
Devlet Arsivleri Osmanli
by Celil Ender, Basbakanlik
Belgeler Katalogu
a sahi included
Dernegi
100 dirhems
Arsivindeki
Yayinlan,
Niimismatik
1996):
10, no.
ile ilgili
104. Since
at a face value thatwas far above the value of its actual silver content.
Pamuk assumes that the sahi's overvaluation resulted from a policy pur
center
sued by the government, and speculates as to why the Ottoman
a
to adopt such
policy.55 Although the government
might have chosen
a "policy" in determining the weight and
have
indeed
adopted
might
in the eastern provinces, in the Levant things do
exchange value of the sahi
not seem to have been under its control. The orders of the center to the
in 1572, and to the authorities inDamascus
in 1582, suggest that the government actually tried to intervene in order
to reduce the exchange rate of the sahi yet their endeavor turned out to be
unsuccessful. Thus one cannot assume that the overvaluation of the sahi in
increasing, and
silver currency in circulation was not sufficient to finance
this higher volume. By valuing the sahi at 5 paras instead of 3.5 paras, the
Evidently
the available
54) See
the document
Pamuk, A Monetary
History
of the Ottoman
Empire:
103.
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited483
Levantine market increased the amount ofmoney in circulation by almost
43% without changing the amount of silver thatwas available. The accept
a
ance by the
public of the sahi, larger coin than either theOttoman akce
or the Levantine para, at a
higher face value than its silver content consti
tuted a way of increasing the total amount of money in circulation while
stayingwithin the limits set by the scarcity of silver to strike coins with.
This market operation would not have worked out had the public been
reluctant to participate in it. Itwere after all the people who used the sahi
in the Levant, and they could verywell have refused to accept it at such an
unrealistic value. But they did not. They actually declined to accept it at a
lower value, which would have been more realistic in terms of its silver
content.
gold currency.56 These figures also indicate that in the Levant gold had
become comparatively cheaper in relation to silver, as 8 ?ahis included less
silver than 40 paras yet theywere accepted as the
a
equivalent of ducat.
One could also argue that silver had become more expensive in relation
to
gold, which may be ascribed to the Persian devaluation. The gold?
silver ratio prevalent in the Safavid Empire was
adopted in the eastern
provinces of theOttoman Empire as these areas were in close contact with
Persia. Yet as the eastern provinces came to be
integrated into the larger
to thewest, cance
the
ratio
of
Persia
moved
market,
imperial
gold?silver
out
that
in
context
could
be
realized
the
of the rela
ling
arbitrage profits
tively isolated existence of two different economic zones. Although in the
first half of the sixteenth century a similar
development had taken place
between Egypt and the Levant, on the one hand, and the central lands of
the empire, on the other, that
integration had occurred at the gold?silver
56)
Hinz,
Islamische
Wahrungen:
14.
484
ratio of the center. This time, however, the ratio of the periphery was per
meating the center.
Ill
in ever
Starting in themid 1570s Spanish silver reals entered the Levant
to the expansion of the use of the sahi
which
contributed
larger quantities,
as the main currency of payment in the area and beyond.57 Before their
arrival in such large quantities, the realswere valued at 40 akces per piastre,
or a piece of eight reals,which theOttomans called gurus.58However, after
came to be valued
they flooded the Ottoman market, the Spanish reals
in terms of theirweight. The unit with which the market operated was
90 reals,which weighed 100 dirhems.59 In 1555, 100 dirhems ofVenetian
silver coins were valued at 300 paras. A quotation from a document from
57)
Bau
The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century: 78; Micheline
Steensgaard,
les Freres Hermite,
1570-1612
(Paris: A. Colin,
lant, ed., Lettres de negociants marseillais,
58)
Ottoman
Although
coins until
large silver
would
Crisis of1585
Revisited
485
of silver available in themarket would increase, and thus the price of silver
decrease. However, not only do we have no idea about the exact
would
was
at
a rioall [a
not a rial of
single rial,
eight] of Spaigne
for 4 medins.
Mony atAllepo. A duckett is 40 medins corant. A chekins is48 medins. A saye is 5medins.
Two aspers isV2 is [sic] one medin. 90 realls of platt is a peso, and a peso iswourth 9 ducketts
or else not). A doller
10 medins
is 32 medins.61
(beinge wayght,
(being weyght)
Nation:
vol. 6:
in Baulant,
Lettres de negociants
lesFreres Hermite,
60.
1570-1612:
marseillais,
60)
Tucci, Lettres dun marchand venitien Andrea
486
While
80 sahis that are worth 400 paras. Buying 90 reals for 370 paras?
which must have been paid either in goods, or sahis, since 370 paras actu
ally included more than 100 dirhems of silver?and then converting them
make
During
from these provinces reached the treasury in the form of sahis, which is
quite unlikely, at least 8.5 million akces worth of ?ahismust have been paid
into the treasury from sources of income located in the central lands of the
empire.
s
is not dated, yet the price quoted
apprentice John Hanger,
is 100 dirhems of silver, seems to be the same as the one
compare
Baulant,
in Tripoli
ordered
tarihli biitce":
on a local
initiative
it to be closed down;
Sahillioglu,
35, 38-9.
"Osmanli
Crisis of1585
Revisited
487
There is both archival and literary evidence to suggest that the sahi
circulated not only inAnatolia, but also in the Balkans. Selaniki, an Otto
man chronicler of the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries, states
that the overvalued sahi came from the borderland between theOttomans
and the Safavids and reached the farthest points of Rumelia during the
III (r. 1574-95). Selaniki is not exaggerating, as the sahi
reign ofMurad
even reached beyond Rumelia and was recorded in the
principalities of
Wallachia
and Moldavia.64
The dynamics of the expansion of the sahi beyond the zone where itwas
to circulate is of great
our
significance for
understanding of the
devaluation of theOttoman akce against the ducat and the piastre in 1585
6, aswell as itsdebasement. The actual debasement of the akce was directly
meant
related to the expansion of the sahi intoAnatolia and the Balkans. Sahilli
as the government did not take steps to
oglu argues that
adjust the exchange
akce."65 Since
ernment
offered overvalued
There
Selaniki,
Tarih-i Selaniki,
ed. M.
and Bal
Ipsirli.
2 vols.
(Istanbul:
in the
Istanbul Universitesi
EdebiyatFakiiltesi
Yayinlan, 1989): vol. 1:427; Pamuk,AMonetaryHistoryoftheOttoman
Empire: 93.
65)
"Ottoman Monetary
Sahillioglu,
66) See n.
50 above.
History":
286.
488
Levant,67 and there are also indications that the silver brought by the Euro
pean merchants could find itsway to these mints. InMay 1583, G. Her
mite, a French merchant inAleppo, recorded the price of [90] reals as 9.25
ducats of account at themint and 9.5 in the contraband market.68 Debased
akces in their turn could increase the value of the sahi in terms of the akce,
or make the Levantine mints feel free to produce debased sahis. And there
is indeed evidence which
See,
for instance,
the orders
10 (#96-7).
68)
Baulant,
Selaniki,
Tarih-i Selaniki:
lesFreres Hermite,
(#50),
51.
vol.
1: 427;
Sinan Pasha,
Telhisdt
(originally
1570-1612:
untitled),
63.
Siiley
Crisis of1585
Revisited
489
reached 11 ducats of
1585, fivemonths prior to the official deval
Apparently things got out of control in 1584 when the price of silver
exceeded itspossible ceiling. The rising trend in the price of silver between
1582 and 1584 was a byproduct of the sahi; had the sahi not already been
an overvalued silver coin thatwas widely
accepted in the Levant, the prof
itsofmelting Spanish reals and converting them into local currency would
not have been that
one were to strike akces from 90
high. If
Spanish reals
thatweighed 100 dirhems, one would get 450 akces, equating a Spanish
real with 5 akces, and the gurus as a piece of eight reals with 40 akces,
which was the official exchange rate. Thus one could not make a profit by
melting Spanish silver and converting it into akces and therewould not
imperial
in the
zone.
it seems that just as the use of the overvalued sahi had not
Moreover,
an
made
impact on the value of the gold ducat in the late 1570s, the
de facto debasement of the akce does not seem to have had an immediate
influence on the exchange rate of the ducat. As late as 1577, theOttoman
gold coin was quoted as being worth 60 akces.73More importantly, a con
temporary Ottoman author, writing in 1581 while working at the provin
cial finance department ofAleppo, notes that the de
facto debasement did
not have an impact on the value of the ducat in terms of the akce: "The
have divided the 'osmani [i.e. the akce] coins into three
money-changers...
the
Of
small ones they spend 60 on one florin, of the
categories.
large ones
72)
73)
Baulant,
Hinz,
lesFreres Hermite,
1570-1612:
490
50 and 45, and of the drachms of medium grade 55."74 This observation
suggests that the old exchange rate of 60 akces to the ducat was still valid
even
though the akces in question included much less silver than pre
scribed. It seems that gold had become cheaper in relation to silver, follow
ing the developments in the eastern provinces and the Levant. Itwas this
itfinally devalued
IV
So far I have shown that theOttoman
that of the central lands of the empire, and the example of the sahi,which
was meant to be used as a
rest
regional currency but practically invaded the
of the empire in the 1570s and early 1580s, suggest that the Ottoman
domains were developing into one big imperial economic market. In this
section I argue that the rise in the value of silver in relation to gold as a
result of the spread of the sahi had an important impact on the govern
ment s decision
Crisis of1585
Revisited
491
60 akces respectively in 1584 and early 1585. Although their prices may
have risen somewhat further prior to September, the ratio of the value of
the ducat to that of the gurus in the freemarket seems to have been quite
different from the new ratio instituted by the government. The actual
in Istanbul, or 47 and
figures for 1584 and early 1585, 85 and 60 akces
as
as
in
well
available
for
33 paras
1582, around 70 and
figures
Baghdad,
50 akces in Istanbul for the ducat and the gurus respectively,76 suggest that
the gold ducat was worth around 1.4 gurus. On the other hand, the former
official exchange rates for the ducat and the gurus were 60 and 40 akces
at 1.5 gurus. In
respectively,which implies that the ducat had been valued
1585, however, the government valued the ducat around 1.7 gurus.
Berthier, a French diplomat in Istanbul, wrote on February 5, 1586, five
months after the official devaluation, that the value of the ducat had been
raised "higher than itwas [in themarket] ."77
It seems that themarket forces had made gold ducats somewhat cheaper
in relation to silver (1.4 piastre as opposed to 1.5), or silver had gained in
value against gold, developments that had been observed earlier in the
Levant and the eastern provinces as a result of the spread of the sahi. Istan
bul was thus about to join the rest of the empire in a different gold?silver
ratio. The Ottoman government aimed at reversing this trend. In order to
some overview of the role of
comprehend themotives of the government,
gold inOttoman finances in the sixteenth century is in order.
a
Although the lands that made up the Ottoman Empire had quite
number of different currencies, some ofwhich have been referred to above,
the currency used for fiscal transactions between these lands as well as
at least up to the 1570s, had been the
large-scale commercial transactions,
either
Ottoman
the
sultani, or theVenetian ducat, which were
gold coin,
more or less of the same
weight. The balance sheet of theOttoman central
treasury for the fiscal year 1582-3 suggests that the relative absence of gold
in the revenues might have been a more important issue than silver scarcity
in the decision of theOttoman administration to devalue the akce.
The Ottomans
had started to strike gold coins during the reign of
II
Mehmed
(1451-81), yet the available evidence from various inventories
76) For
74 n.
see
see
Sahillioglu,
Hakluyt,
"Osmanh
para tarihi":
The Principal
Navigations
77) Cited
Robbers
492
suggests that the share of gold in the pool of currencies in circulation was
not great before the
reign of Suleyman I.78The extant balance sheet of the
for
the fiscal year 1524-5 includes a list of currencies,
treasury
imperial
the previous fiscal year 1523-4, suggest that theArab provinces were then
unable to send any surplus at all,which is probably why the treasury closed
the yearwith a deficit of almost 2,000,000 akces.82 In 1547-8, however, the
78)
Sahillioglu,
"Ottoman
Monetary
"1524-1525":
434,
History":
Tables
the number
was
n. 23.
Aleppo
tional commerce.
sury of Aleppo
coins by distributing
called
to the merchants
gold
tehdil-i hasene.
82)
Sahillioglu, "1524-1525": 437 n.; the deficit is 1,895,464 akces, p. 423. In 1523,
Pasha was appointed governor of Egypt where he is said to have declared his inde
in his own name; Ibn Abi al-Surur, Al-Minah:
139-41. Although
pendence and struck coins
his rebellion was suppressed and he was executed in Egypt, the aftermath of the crisis might
Ahmed
The Ottoman
MonetaryCrisisof1585 Revisited493
Arab provinces and Diyarbekir made a contribution of 28,211,339
akces
in
this
worth, almost exclusively
gold coinage. Without
large contribution,
central treasurywould have been ca. 12,000,000 akces in
the Ottoman
deficit for 1547-8. One must note, however, that the tribute of Egypt is
not included anywhere in this balance sheet.83Thus one may assume that,
the addition of the tribute of Egypt, the total contribution of the
with
Ottoman
of specie, 58% ofwhich consisted of gold coinage.84 This 58% share of the
akce value of gold coinage in the akce value of all the currencies held in the
treasury at the end of the fiscal year seems to have been much larger than
the share of the same in the akce value of all the coins entering the treasury
to
as
during the year.85The Ottomans thus apparently tried hoard the gold
a reserve, and to pay their
with
akces.
expenditures mainly
The next extant balance sheet of the imperial treasury is from the fiscal
year 1567-8. Unfortunately, it neither includes a list of the different cur
up the income, nor an inventory of the holdings of the
treasury at the end of the fiscal year. Yet again, some of the entries indicate
that income items related to those entrieswere paid into the imperial treas
rencies making
ury in gold coinage. These entries record that in the fiscal year of 1567-8
at least 26.5% of the total income was received in
gold coinage. Not sur
prisingly, these income items in gold came exclusively from theArab prov
inces,without which the treasurywould have closed the year with a deficit
ofmore than 50,000,000 akces.86
These balance sheets underline two important points. First,without the
Arab provinces theOttoman administrative-military apparatus could not
have financed
its expenditures
have postponed
the dispatch of the Egyptian
affected the finances of Aleppo.
83)
Omer L. Barkan, "H. 974-975
Compare
(M.
1567-1568)
mali
events may
yihna
also have
biitcesi."IstanbulUniversitesi
Mecmuasi 19 (1957-8): 302, 307; Sahillioglu,
tktisat
Fakultesi
tarihli biitce": 38, 46.
"1582-83
84)
275.
Barkan, "954-955
(1547-1548)":
85) See n.
78-80 above.
86)
Barkan, "H. 974-975
299, 302-4. There are a number of inconsis
(M. 1567-1568)":
tencies in the
to go
the
of
I
tried
document;
figures
by the totals whenever possible.
494
both financed themselves and provided surplus revenues for the expendi
tures of the center elsewhere. Itwould probably not be an exaggeration to
claim that the westward and eastward expansion of the empire during
the reign of Suleyman I was financed by the center at the expense of the
Arab provinces.
finances benefited greatly from arbitrage profits.
Second, Ottoman
revenues in
a
its
Collecting
gold coins from theArab lands where
slightly
different gold?silver
ratio was
teenth century made these revenues more valuable in Istanbul than they
were, for example, in Egypt. To give an example, let us assume that the
tribute of Egypt, 500,000 ducats, thatwas supposed to enter the personal
treasury of the sultan every year, was sent in silver currency. Up to 1585,
500,000 ducats were worth 30 million akces in Istanbul according to the
official exchange rate. The silver currency equivalent of the Egyptian trib
ute was 20 million paras, again
to the official exchange rate
according
of 40 paras a ducat. After the Egyptian debasement of 1565, at themost
was
optimistic estimate, 328 paras contained 100 dirhems of silver,which
sent
in
to
strike 450 akces. Thus had the Egyptian tribute been
necessary
paras to be melted
received 27,439,024
and converted
akces, which
ute had been sent in gold. Hence
center was
Arab
Crisis of1585
Revisited
495
went
straight into the personal treasury of the sultan.87
gold coins, which
Once the value of this tribute is deducted from the total value of all gold
coins that entered the treasury as part of the revenues for 1582-3, the
remainder is 10,316,728 akces worth of gold coins.
The reason for the relative lack of gold coins is not that theArab prov
inces failed to support the central treasurywith their usual contributions.
seem to have sent
On the contrary, the provinces ofAleppo and Damascus
their largest contributions everwhen one compares this balance sheetwith
must have been in sahis. Let us suppose that all of this contribution was
sent in
as
gold coins
opposed to sahis. 37 million akces worth of sahis
Sahillioglu,
tarihli biitce":
"1582-83
31-5,
38-46.
88)
Compare Sahillioglu, "1524-1525": 437-8; Barkan, "954-955 (1547-1548)": 247-8;
Barkan,
The
"H. 974-975
balance
(M.
are lower than those for 1582-3; Omer L. Barkan, "H. 933-934
its
(M.
figures
mali yilina ait bir biitce
ornegi." Istanbul Universitesi Iktisat Fakiiltesi Mecmuasi
4): 294-5.
1527-1528)
15 (1953
496
the imperial palace. Even in the most dire straits that Ottoman
finances
went
wars
in
the
the
and
the
and
1590s
1600s,
through during
Habsburg
accessions
the
four
took
that
between
and
which
1617
1623,
during
place
created an immense burden on the treasury because of the accession ben
efits paid to the soldiers, the private treasury of the sultan was still able to
cover the deficits of the central treasury.Thus the amount of
gold that had
been accumulated during the sixteenth century must have been immense.
one would be
was quite
Consequently,
justified in claiming that it
impor
tant for theOttoman center to protect the value of its
reserves.
gold
In sum, theOttoman center had several reasons not to accept the new
ratio, which had been carried by the sahi, the child of the
of
theOttoman economic zones into a big imperial market in
integration
a
economic
of
expansion, from the Safavid borders to theOttoman
period
gold?silver
capital. It is this observation rather than the fiscal difficulties which the
treasury faced in financing thewar effort,which did not really exist at this
as far as the balance sheet of 1582-3 is concerned, thatmay
point
help to
in
intervention
the
Ottoman
the
of
administration
explain
September 1585.
As noted above, the Ottoman
than themarket had done. While
devaluation were 85 akces for the ducat and 60 akces for the gurus, the
official rateswere announced at 110 and 65 akces respectively. The deci
sion was thus clearly aimed at making gold more valuable in relation to
In 1591, when Sinan Pasha reminded Murad III that he had accomplished
more than two years
a great deal since
assuming the grand vizierate little
earlier, he noted that he had succeeded in eliminating the sahi from
89) That was
monetaires
de
Crisis of1585
Revisited
497
circulation.90 Itwas Sinan Pasha who had taken over and completed the
debasement operation started byMehmed Pasha in 1588, three years after
the devaluation.91
economic market had started to operate with
Although the Ottoman
the de facto debased akces, the government did not make extensive use of
in salary payments. Even after the devaluation of the akce
at least some
the
against
gold ducat and the gurus in September 1585,
of the soldiers of the central army continued to receive their salaries in
a
good akces for few years. As noted by Reinhold Lubenau around 1587,
rate of the gurus, which used to be 40 akces, had
although the exchange
these akces
were
90) Sinan
Pasha,
to his former
inDamascus
in its aftermath, as well as
grand vizierate and his governorship
that it had been almost two and a half years since he had assumed his
post for
his statement
Imagination
in the summer
at the End
of the
In addition
to the
46.
tarihi": 66,
233-4
224-5,
see also Ender, Niimismatik
(n. 27-34).
18, no.
174,
498
dirhem]?"94 Although it is not clear whether the akces inwhich the cavalry
troops received their salaries were the officially debased ones, the context
of this remark aswell as the timing of the incident right after the
beginning
of the debasement operation suggest that thiswas the case.95
It seems that the imperial army had a strong
leverage against the admin
the expansion of the use of the sahi, the piastres that entered the country
were converted into ?ahis in order to take
advantage of the overvaluation
of the coin. As for the ducat, the southern provinces, its principal source,
now sent their
yearly contributions in overvalued sahis and probably kept
the ducats for themselves.
by minting ?ahis. As for the quite high value of the ducat at 110 akces,
25 akces more than itsmost recentmarket value, this overvaluation of the
ducat suggests that the administration was trying to reverse the trend that
made silvermore valuable than gold. At a higher exchange rate, the center
thought, the southern provinces would again send their tributes in gold
coins as opposed to overvalued ?ahis. Yet the overvaluation of the ducat led
to yet another round of
practical debasement for the akce, pushing the
rates yet further up. Although the government tried to keep the
exchange
value of gold relatively high, eventually the ducat and the gurus were val
ued at 120 and 80 akces respectively,which meant a return to the old ratio
of 1.5 guru? per ducat through a devaluation of 100% in comparison with
the pre-1585 rates of 60 and 40 akces.
94)
Tarih-i Seldnikr: vol. 1: 211. Selaniki was not present in the capital at this
see p. 209.
point;
95)
to Ali,
it was
the more
than 1,000,000
akces, which were delivered by
According
"Kartakoz, the tax-farmer of the levy on wine sales," and were initially refused by the finance
of Otto
"The Boundaries
minister Mahmud
Efendi, which caused the trouble; Kafadar,
Selaniki,
man
Economic
was
not
Crisis of1585
Revisited
499
new akces contained 0.38 g., which indicates a debasement of 44% from
ratio was changed from 1:11.5 to
0.68 g. Thus the official gold?silver
1:13.1, making gold relativelymore expensive than silver.
The Ottoman central government was clearly aiming to reverse the trend
toward a unification of the Ottoman
currency zones with a gold?silver
cies accordingly,96 the debasement operation took the empire back into the
earlier part of the sixteenth century, when separate currency zones with
ratios co-existed. Over the next ten years, during
different gold?silver
which the defacto debasement and devaluation of the akce continued, the
situation proved impossible to sustain.
96)
"Osmanh para tarihi": 223-4.
Selaniki, Tarih-i Seldniki: vol. 1: 430; Sahillioglu,
97) Katib
vol. 1:
1286-7 AH):
Qelebi, Fezleke. 2 vols. (Istanbul: Ceride-i Havadis Matbaasi,
"Osmanh para tarihi": 225.
142-3; Sahillioglu,
98)
in the Levant 1584-1602:
Foster, The Travels ofJohn Sanderson
202; in 1610, George
an
a
see A Relation
still
120
traveler
in
for
akces
ducat
Istanbul;
Sandys,
English
quoted
of
a
1610 (London: W. Barrett, 1615): 73, 77.
Iourney begun An: Dom:
99)Muhammad
Ibn Jum'a, "Al-bashat wa al-qudat."
InWuldt
dimashqfi al- 'ahdal- uthmdni,
kuru? thatwas meant to be used all over the empire. This new
was
as
imperial large silver coin
accompanied by the adoption of the para
an
was
as
as
in
well
minted in Istanbul
imperial small silver currency that
Ottoman
Egypt. Although the akce eventually disappeared, the para survived through
to the end of the Ottoman Empire and was even used
during the early
as
a
of
the
Turkish
unit
that
1/40 of
denoted
monetary
period
Republic
a kurus. The kurus survives to this
as
as
in Egypt
well
day in Turkey
to denote a penny.
(pronounced [qjirsh)
Thus itwas in the sixteenth century that the foundations of the early
modern monetary system of theMiddle East were laid through the unifi
cation of different zones of regional currencies into a unified imperial zone.
the ?ahi, the coin that played a significant role in this process,
eventually disappeared together with the differences in the gold?silver
ratios of the Ottoman provinces, the Egyptian para came to replace the
akce. The fact that para came to mean money in modern Turkish is a
reminder of themarket forces that unified a number of differentmonetary
zones in the sixteenth-centuryMiddle East.
Although
A final question Iwould like to address iswhether one can talk about a
"monetarization" of theOttoman economy parallel to all of these develop
ments. This article does not prove that a monetary economy emerged in
the Ottoman domains during the sixteenth century. After all, the emer
a
gence of a monetary economy based on the idea of production targeting
market where goods are bought and sold, and not bartered, is not some
one can
to a certain moment in the
precisely date
gradual devel
thing that
non-monetary
ed. S. al-Munajjid
[s.n.], 1949): 26. Yet the fineness of the new para is not indi
(Dimashq,
ratios.
there
still
have
been a discrepancy between the gold?silver
thus
cated,
might
ioo)
in the
Pamuk, "In theAbsence of Domestic Currency: Debased
European Coinage
Seventeenth-Century
Ottoman
57 (1997):
345-66.
to test
the
"monetariness,"
or
Crisis of1585
the
Revisited
501
"market-orientedness,"
of an
econ
as great
profitswould stillhave been possible but theywould not have been
as 30 years before. I have also shown that in the 1560s, great
arbitrage
was much more valuable in
profits could be realized since silver
Baghdad
than itwas inAleppo and in Istanbul. But Aleppo soon started to use the
sahi and forced an increase in themarket value of silver,which soon affected
Anatolia and even the Balkans, somuch so that by 1584 gold?silver
ratios
in Baghdad and Istanbul had come to be the same.
I have also argued that the devaluation of 1585 and the debasement of
ratio
1588 were both aimed at the establishment of a different gold?silver
502
even
one cannot assert that theOttoman economy
Consequently,
though
of the late sixteenth and the early seventeenth centuries was a fully-fledged
market economy, it is justified to claim that theOttoman economy of this
was much more market oriented and much more monetary than it
period
had been a century before.101
Bibliography
Ahmed.
Akgiindiiz,
Osmanh
1990-6.
Arastirmalan
veHukuki
Osmanh Kanunndmeleri
Tahlilleri.
9 vols.
Istanbul:
Vakfi.
Album, Stephen. 1998. A Checklist ofIslamic Coins. Second edition. Santa Rosa: Stephen Album.
All's Counsel for Sultans of 1581. Ed., tr.Andreas Tietze.
1979-82. Mustafd
Ali, Mustafa.
2 vols. Vienna:
derWissenschaften.
Verlag der osterreichischen Akademie
In Osmanh Devlet Te?kildtma Dair
1988. HirziiT-Muluk.
Anonymous.
Kaynaklar:
Mesdlihi'l Muslimin
Miistetdb?Kitabu
veMenafi'i'l-Muminin?Hirzu'l-Muluk,
Turk Tarih Kurumu:
Yiicel. Ankara:
Artuk,
1972. Kanuni
Ibrahim.
Kitdb-i
ed. Yasar
171 -201.
Basilan
Sikkeler. Ankara:
Turk Tarih
Kurumu.
1971. Les metaux precieux
Eliyahu.
basse epoque. Paris: SEVPEN.
Ashtor,
a la
Numismatic
Barkan, Omer
L.
Society.
1953-4. H. 933-934
Istanbul Universitesi
-.
1957-8.
954-955
(1547-1548)
1957-8. H.
Universitesi
1527-1528)
(M.
974-975
Mali
Mali
Yihna
15: 251-329.
Yihna
Butcesi.
Istanbul Univer
19: 219-76.
(M.
1567-1568)
-.
-.
Mali
Yihna
Butcesi.
Istanbul
19: 277-332.
(1970):
lesFreres Hermite,
557-607].
1570-1612.
Paris: A. Colin.
Braudel,
Fernand.
1972.
The Mediterranean
2 vols. New
and
theMediterranean
York: Harper
&
World
in the
Age
of
Gelirleri.
In
Row.
Biitce
Osmanh
Donem
(Tanzimat Oncesi)
ve Butgeler, eds Mehmet
Gene and Erol Ozvar.
Osmanh Maliyesi: Kurumlar
vol. 1: 167-95.
Bankasi Ar?iv ve Arastirma Merkezi:
bul: Osmanh
2 vols. Istan
101) Iwill
of the sixteenth-century monetariza
explore the social and political repercussions
in
The
Second
Ottoman
tion of theOttoman
economy
Empire: Political and Social Transforma
tion in theEarly Modern
World,
forthcoming
from Cambridge
University
Press in 2010.
Chaudhuri,
Crisis of1585
and Monetary
Centuries.
Revisited
Problem
503
of European
The Journal
and Eighteenth
Trade
ofEuropean
with
Economic
ile
1996. Ba?bakankk Devlet Arsivleri Osmanli Arsivi'ndeki Niimismatik
ilgili
Turk
Niimismatik
Istanbul:
Dernegi Yayinlan.
Belgeler Katalogu.
Sinan pasa an Sultan Murad
(telhise) des Grosswesirs
Faroqhi, Suraiya. 1967. Die Vorlagen
III. Ph.D. dissertation. Universitat Hamburg.
Ender, Celil.
With his
1931. The Travels ofJohn Sanderson in the Levant 1584-1602.
his
and
London:
Selections
Hakluyt
Society.
from
Correspondence.
Autobiography
dahilinde
hububat
Giicer, Liitfi. 1951-2. XVI. yiizyil sonlannda Osmanli
Imparatoriugu
ticaretinin tabi oldugu kayitlar. Istanbul Universitesi Iktisat Fakiiltesi Mecmuasi
13: 79-98.
ed.
Foster, William,
in
in theMiddle
ed. Layla
al-Sabbagh.
Ibn Juma, Muhammad.
'uthmdni, ed. Salah
-.
of the Toman
of
Minovi
Damascus:
Dar
ir.
al-Basha
1949. Al-bashat
wa
In Wuldt
al-qudat.
Dimashq
l-ahd
fi
[s.n.]: 1-69.
al-Munajjid.
Dimashq:
of Conquest.
Studia Islamica 2: 103-29.
1954. Ottoman Methods
Inalcik, Halil.
1993. Notes on a Study of theTurkish Economy
during the Establishment
of the Ottoman
Howard
[revised translation of "Osmanli
Empire. Tr. Douglas
torlugunun
al
al-Din
kurulus
ve inkisafi devrinde
Turkiye
nin
iktisadi vaziyeti
and Rise
Impara
iizerinde bir tetkik
on
Empire: Essays
Economy
Turkish Studies: 205-63.
University
Kafadar, Cemal.
1986. When
bers of Shadows:
-.
Coins
The Boundaries
of Ottoman
Inalcik. Bloomington:
of Dew
Economic
and Bankers
became
at the End
Imagination
mane
du declin. Annales:
Indi
Rob
of the
otto
46: 381-400.
Katib
Koci
Islamica
Minadoi,
Iohn.-Thomas.
1595.
Hartwell.
and C. H.
The History
of theWarres
London:
Iohn Wolfe.
Coote,
Coins,
betweene
Society.
Raafet el-Nabarawy,
Olcer,
Studia
9: 111-27.
the Per
2 vols.
and Medals
Selim ?ah
Donemi
Osmanli
Sikkeleri.
504
of Domestic
?evket. 1997. In the Absence
Currency: Debased
European Coinage
in the Seventeenth-Century
Ottoman
Empire. Journal ofEconomic History 57: 345-66.
ve Ucretler, 1469-1998.
2000. Istanbul ve
Ankara:
Diger Kentlerde 500 Ytllik Fiyatlar
Devlet
Istatistik Enstitiisii.
Pamuk,
-.
-.
2000.
-.
sity Press.
2001.
-.
Monetary
History
of the Ottoman
Price Revolution
The
Empire.
in the Ottoman
in the Ottoman
Prices
International
1469-1914.
Empire,
Univer
Cambridge
International
Reconsidered.
Empire
Cambridge:
Journal
ofMiddle
di Borgomale,
Hertford:
H.
Sahillioglu,
rinde bir deneme.
-.
L.
1982-3.
Ph.D.
dissertation.
Osmanh
1524-1525
asnn
sonlanna
kadar Osmanh
tarihi iize
para
Istanbul Universitesi.
Butcesi.
Istanbul Universitesi
41:415-52.
-.
in Ottoman
and Metal Movements
Role of International Monetary
Tr. liter Turan
and Rhoads Murphey
1300-1750.
[translation of
History,
Gelisme
para tarihinde diinya para ve maden hareketlerinin yeri (1300-1750)."
In
in
Later
Issue
Precious
the
Medieval
and
Metals
1-38].
(1978):
Special
Early
1983. The
Monetary
"Osmanh
Dergisi
Modern
-.
ed. J. F. Richards.
III. Murad
donemine
Worlds,
2006.
Carolina
Durham:
ait 1582-83
Academic
Press: 269-304.
In
tarihli biitce?ceviriyazi.
2 vols. Istanbul:
and E. Ozvar.
(hicri 990)
Osmanh
1610. London: W.
1615. A Relation of a Iourney begun An: Dom:
Sandys, George.
2 vols. Istanbul:
1989. Tarih-i Seldniki, ed. Mehmed
Selaniki, Mustafa.
lp?irli.
Universitesi Edebiyat Fakultesi Yayinlan.
and Administrative Organization
Shaw, Stanford J. 1962. The Financial
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Ottoman Egypt, 1517-1798.
to 1894. Third
1896. The History
Shaw, W. A.
of Currency, 1252
G.P.
Sinan
Putnam's
Pasha,
Barrett.
Istanbul
and Development
edition.
New
of
York:
[n.d.] Telhisat
[originally untitled].
Siileymaniye
Kiitiiphanesi.
Esad
Efendi
ff.30b-72b.
2236:
Steensgaard, Niels.
India Companies
The Asian
1974.
and
theDecline
East
of the Seventeenth Century: The
Trade. Chicago:
University of Chicago
Trade Revolution
of the Caravan
Press.
Tezcan,
man
-.
-.
Baki.
2001.
Sultan Osman
2004. Tefaviit.
of the Otto
of the Deposition
Princeton University.
24: 333-44.
ofOttoman Studies
A Reassessment
Searching for Osman:
II (1618-1622).
Ph.D. dissertation.
Osmanh
2010.
Arasttrmalan
IJournal
SEVPEN.
Zinkeisen,
J.W.
1840-63.
inEuropa.
7 vols. Gotha:
Perthes.
F. A.