S89 PDF
S89 PDF
S89 PDF
THE MICROSTRUCTURE
OF THE FOREIGN-EXCHANGE MARKET:
A SELECTIVE SURVEY OF THE LITERATURE
LUCIO SARNO
AND
MARK P. TAYLOR
PRINCETON STUDIES
IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
THE MICROSTRUCTURE
OF THE FOREIGN-EXCHANGE MARKET:
A SELECTIVE SURVEY OF THE LITERATURE
LUCIO SARNO
AND
MARK P. TAYLOR
2001024516
CIP
Tel: 609-258-4048
Fax: 609-258-1374
E-mail: [email protected]
Url: www.princeton.edu/~ies
CONTENTS
1
INTRODUCTION
3
3
9
EXCHANGE-RATE EXPECTATIONS
Survey-Date Studies
Order-Flow Studies
4
CHARTIST ANALYSIS
11
11
12
14
14
16
17
19
21
21
24
27
33
33
34
40
40
41
CONCLUSION
43
REFERENCES
44
1 INTRODUCTION
Over the last quarter century, exchange rates among the currencies of the
leading industrial countries have shown substantial and often persistent
movements that are largely unexplained by movements in macroeconomic
fundamentals (Frankel and Rose, 1995; Taylor, 1995; Flood and Taylor,
1996). The literature on the microstructure of the foreign-exchange market
in some measure reects researchers attempts to understand the mechanisms generating these deviations from fundamentals (Taylor, 1995; Flood
and Taylor, 1996; Lyons, 2001).1 More broadly, however, this literature is
concerned with other micro aspects of the foreign-exchange market, such
as the transmission of information among market participants, the behavior
of market agents, the importance of order ow, the heterogeneity of agents
expectations, and the implications of such heterogeneity for trading volume
and exchange-rate volatility.
The assumptions and methodology of the microstructure literature often
dier substantially from those of the conventional macroeconomic approach.
Indeed, some authors see the microstructure literature as a radical departure from the traditional modelling strategy of treating foreign exchange
rates as a macroeconomic relative price (Frankel and Rose, 1995. p. 1710).
With respect to assumptions, the foreign-exchange microstructure typically
does not assume that only public information is relevant to exchange rates,
that foreign-exchange-market agents are homogeneous, or that the mechanism used for trading is inconsequential (Lyons, 2001). In fact, these issues
are themselves often the subject of investigation in microstructural analysis. With respect to methodology, instead of starting with a set of macroeconomic relations such as money demand and purchasing-power parity,
which are then used to solve for the exchange rate (Taylor, 1995), the microstructure literature analyzes the behavior and interaction of individual
decisionmaking units in the foreign-exchange market.2 Simply put, the microstructure literature is concerned with the details of the mechanics of
1 One way in which a speculative movement of the exchange rate away from the
level consistent with the macroeconomic fundamentals could begin would be if some
agents were to have destabilizing expectationsif, for example, a 5 percent appreciation
were to lead agents to expect a 10 percent appreciation, which would lead them to
buy the appreciating currency, causing it to appreciate faster in a self-fullling fashion.
Bandwagon eects of this kind have been examined by Frankel and Froot (1986), Allen
and Taylor (1990), and others, using survey data on expectations. The evidence to date
tentatively suggests that expectations may be more destabilizing over relatively short
horizons.
2 The microstructure approach should also be distinguished from the dynamic optimizing approach of the new open-economy macroeconomics (Obstfeld and Rogo,
1995, 1996; Lane, 1999; Sarno, 2001). Although the new open-economy literature explic-
For the convergence process to continue, therefore, the microstructure literature needs to be more widely understood. It is in this spirit that the
present survey is oered.
The remainder of this study is set out as follows. Chapter 2 gives a general overview of the institutional features of the foreign-exchange market.
Chapter 3 discusses studies employing survey data on market participants
exchange-rate expectations and studies using data on foreign-exchange order ow. Chapter 4 reviews the literature on chartist, or technical,
analysis. Chapter 5 summarizes recent work on modeling time-varying
volatility in the foreign-exchange market, on the relation between volatility
and trading volume, and on the nature of information that is relevant to
trading in the foreign-exchange market. Chapter 6 reviews the literature
on bid-ask spread determination in the foreign-exchange market. Chapter
7 discusses the literature on modeling market makers behavior. A nal
chapter summarizes and concludes the study.
itly takes an optimizing approach (usually of representative agents in two economies),
rather than relying on o the peg macroeconomic behavioral relations, it is generally concerned with interactions between whole economies, rather than strictly with the
functioning of the foreign-exchange market.
3 Flood and Taylor (1996, p. 285), for example, write: It is apparent that there
are important inuences, not on the list of standard macro fundamentals, that aect
short-run exchange rate behavior . . . , and it is in this context that new work on the
microstructure of the foreign exchange market seems both warranted and promising.
4 Researchers have, in the past, occasionally employed methods of analysis that eectively synthesize macroeconomic and microeconomic approaches. For example, Taylors
(1987, 1989) studies of covered interest parity may be viewed as early microstructural
analysis, applying high-frequency, high-quality data from the brokered foreign-exchange
market and microstructural tools to resolve an issue (the validity of covered interest
parity) debated up till now only at the macroeconomic level.
The empirical evidence from the current microstructure literature strongly suggests that the dierent degrees of centralization across markets may be
very important in explaining dierences in market performance. A widely
held view is that, by centralizing trading and price information, the brokered market uses time more eciently, eliminates signicant arbitrage opportunities rapidly, and ensures dealers that orders are executed according
to price priority (Garbade, 1978; Garbade, Pomrenze, and Silber, 1979;
Glosten and Milgrom, 1985).4
Flood (1994) investigates the intraday operational eciency of the U.S.
foreign-exchange market by executing simulation experiments calibrated on
a particular market structure for market makers, brokers, and customers.
His results support the traditional view that centralization is a key factor
in achieving operational eciency. In particular, he nds that signicant
operational ineciencies may be explained by temporary inventory imbalances inherent in a decentralized market. He also nds that this ineciency
could be largely alleviated by centralizing price information.
Interesting work on the implications of decentralization in this context
has been done by Perraudin and Vitale (1996), who construct an elegant
theoretical framework for a decentralized dealer market and discuss the
implications for price-information-transmission mechanisms and eciency
in the foreign-exchange market. They model interbank trading so as to show
that market makers sell each other information about their transactions
with outside customers by adjusting the bid and ask prices and the bidask spread in their price quotations (for example, by lowering the bid and
ask prices for a particular currency if the bank has been given a large
amount of that currency). This modeling assumption in turn implies that
market makers can capture, through interdealer trades, the informational
rents associated with receiving outside orders and that they can optimally
adjust bid-ask spreads to maximize those rents and elicit information. The
model also implies that bid-ask spreads are wider in decentralized markets,
because, by using wider spreads, dealers can discourage liquidity traders,
who are strongly reactive to price changes, and can therefore increase the
informativeness of their order ow.5 Perhaps the most important nding
from Perraudin and Vitale, however, is that decentralized markets are much
less subject to crashes than are centralized markets. The intuition behind
this conclusion is that information on order ow is used to update subjective
4 One of the benchmark models in the literature is Glostens and Milgroms (1985)
sequential-trade model, which is designed to capture the way in which bid and ask prices
evolve in a dealership market as orders arrive in sequence. For a comprehensive discussion
of the Glosten-Milgrom model and its subsequent extensions, see Lyons (2001).
5 Liquidity traders can be thought of as agents who need to buy or sell foreign exchange
in response to international trade in goods and services and who do not speculate or hedge
their exposure in any way. Their orders are therefore largely random.
One issue that seems not to have been fully examined in this connection
is the importance of credit and the role of clearing houses.10 In a decentralized market, where trade occurs in private meetings between parties, an
assessment of credit risk (whether the counterparty will deliver the agreed
amount of funds at the agreed time at the agreed location) is presumably
made before a deal is struck. In fact, a bank will usually have a prudential
limit, determined by its senior management, on the credit exposure it is
willing to have with any particular counterparty at any point in time, and
it will not deal with that counterparty once this limit is reached until the
net exposure is diminished.
The existence of such prudential limits may be problematic for a fully
centralized system, in which prices are public information and the counterparty is known only after the deal is struck. In practice, centralized
nancial exchanges often circumvent this problem by having a clearinghouse system. For example, the London Clearing House (LCH) acts as
the central counterparty for trades conducted on several of the London nancial exchanges, including the London International Financial Futures
and Options Exchange. This enables the LCH to guarantee the nancial
performance of every contract registered with it by its members (the clearing members of the exchanges) up to and including delivery, exercise, and
settlement. Both sides of a trade are entered in an electronic registration
system by the exchange members, the exchange itself, or both, where they
are matched and conrmed. At the end of each business day, the trade
is registered in the name of the LCH, and the original contract between
the two agents is canceled and replaced by two new onesone between the
LCH and the clearing member seller, the other between the LCH and the
clearing member buyer. This is known in legal terms as novation.
A clearing-house system thus serves two functions in a centralized market. First, it obviates the need to assess the credit rating of the counterparty
or, indeed the need to identify the counterparty at allbefore a trade
is made. Second, because all trades are eectively made with the clearing
house, only the net position at the end of the day is important for settlement purposes. In a decentralized system, trades may be made with a
great many counterparties, so that, even though the end-of-day net position may be close to zero, the trader may have lled a number of credit
limits and will still have to complete all of the agreed-upon trades (with the
consequent transactions costs). In the brokered foreign-exchange market,
although dealers trading on a price quoted by a broker will not know the
identity of the counterparty until after the trade has been made, trades
occasionally have to be canceled once the identities are revealed and one
1 0 We
party nds that its credit limit with the counterparty is full.11 The need
to assess creditworthiness prior to trading may thus explain why the bulk
of foreign-exchange trading (63 percent in April 1998) is between dealers
(BIS, 1998). Moreover, in the absence of an international clearing-house
system, market makers in the foreign-exchange market may fulll many of
the functions of a clearing house. This may explain why the market allows
them to earn signicant prots on the bid-ask spread. The issue of credit
and creditworthiness may thus explain many of the institutional features
of the foreign-exchange market, including the predominant system of communication of prices (open-order-book and interdealer) and the importance
of established market makers. This is clearly an issue that would repay
further research.
Another important feature of the foreign-exchange market is the development, since 1992, of proprietary screen-based electronic foreign-exchangedealing and brokering systems such as the Reuters 2000-2 Dealing System
(Reuters) and the Electronic Broking System Spot Dealing System (EBS).
These systems may also be seen to perform many of the functions of a
clearing house and are an important driving force toward the virtual centralization of the global foreign-exchange market. The Reuters and EBS
are anonymous interactive brokering and dealing systems delivered over
proprietary networks and combining standard closed-order-book brokering
services with the opportunities for electronic trading. Deals are completed
by keystroke or automatic deal-matching within the system. An important
feature of these systems is their prescreened credit facility, so that although
the closed-order-book prices on the dealers screen seem to be anonymous,
the system has automatically checked that the bank to which the price is
being fed has a sucient open credit limit with the originator of the price.
This feature eliminates the potential for failed trades by assuring traders
that they can deal on the prices they see. Credit limits are set and maintained by the designated bank sta and can be modied at any time during
the trading day. Access to the credit le is password driven and condential.
An automated electronic interface between the system and a banks internal banking system, moreover, allows for net, rather than gross, transaction
processing between counterparties and eliminates duplicate trade-entry activity. Although this is not quite the same as dealing with a clearing house,
it substantially reduces transactions costs. These electronic dealing and
brokering systems appear to be growing rapidly in use. Reuters currently
oers its 2000-2 service in forty countries, and the EBS has 800 subscriber
1 1 In practice, where a limit order is placed with a broker by a small or exotic bank,
the broker may try to circumvent this problem by quoting the inside spread, ignoring
the limit order, adding that a better bid or oer is available for a certain amount from
an exotic, and allowing dealers to ask the identity of the potential counterparty before
the trade is made.
The U.S. dollar was, as one would expect, the most actively traded
currency in 1998, being involved in 87 percent of all transactions worldwide.
The deutsche mark followed, with almost 33 percent of all currency trades
(although the mark was also increasingly used as a proxy for the euro in
the run-up to the euros launch in January 1999). The yen was the third
most used currency, accounting for about 21 percent of all currency trades.
The British pound was the fourth, with 11 percent of trades.
Foreign-exchange-market turnover showed an increasing concentration
in four centers: the United Kingdom (32 percent), the United States (18
percent), Japan (8 percent), and Singapore (7 percent). Although some
smaller countries experienced low or negative growth during the 1990s (for
example, Austria, Finland, and Sweden), a number of others realized quite
spectacular gains, especially in the second half of the 1990s (for example,
Greece, Ireland, the Netherlands, Portugal, and South Africa).15
The replacement of a number of European currencies by the euro, on
January 1, 1999, has considerably modied the conguration of markets
and related trading strategies, as well as the evolution of risk exposure and
management. Indeed, information about the relative importance of the
euro as a traded currency during its early years of operation will be one of
the most widely awaited features of the 2001 BIS survey.
Overall, however, the information available suggests that foreign-exchange-market activity is continuing to grow, largely in response to the
rapid growth of derivatives products. Understanding the future evolution
of the foreign-exchange market, as well as the eects of the emerging euro
market, poses new challenges as well as new opportunities for both practitioners and academics.
in microstructure. Although the literature covered in this study has focused largely on
the spot market, extending the analysis to derivatives markets would open an important
avenue of research. Our interpretation of volume shares from dierent instruments is
essentially literal. It is arguable, however, that swaps, for example, do not involve net
demand in one direction or the other. Rather, a currency swap can be replicated by
buying a bond in one currency and selling a bond in another; the arbitrage does not
involve a net foreign-exchange transaction. Currency swaps, therefore, with their large
notional values, might lead us to underestimate the importance of the spot market in
terms of net order ow (that is, in terms of market-clearing net demand). We are grateful
to Richard Lyons for pointing this out.
1 5 Although the advent of the euro may appear to have caused the decline in some
European centers, the strong growth rates experienced by Ireland, Portugal, and the
Netherlands suggest that other factors are in play. Portugals growth, in particular, might
be attributed to the positive eects of the liberalization of the foreign-exchange market
in 1992. The Netherlands also saw strong growth in its local market as institutional
investors expanded their international portfolios.
10
3 EXCHANGE-RATE EXPECTATIONS
Survey-Data Studies
The process by which agents form expectations about future exchange rates
is the subject of much of the early literature on foreign-exchange-market
microstructure. The simplifying assumption that underlies virtually all
the traditional asset-based exchange-rate models is that expectations are
rational. Thus, the expected exchange rate has usually been measured
in empirical studies using either the forward discount or the interest-rate
dierential, with uncovered interest-rate parity or uncovered and covered
interest-rate parity being implicitly assumed (Taylor, 1995). The strategy
followed by much of the microstructure literature has been to employ direct
measures of expectationsthat is, data on exchange-rate expectations from
surveys of market participants conducted by nancial-services companies
(see Takagi, 1991, or Frankel and Rose, 1995, for an overview of surveydata studies).
Although the various studies using these data dier in their specic
strategies and results, some general qualitative results are discernible. All
foreign-exchange-survey data sets, for example, suggest a strong heterogeneity of expectations and an increasing dispersion of expectations at
longer forecast horizons. They also show a twist in expectations, in
that long-run expectations tend to reverse the direction of short-run expectations. In other words, although a depreciation is usually followed by
expectations of further depreciations in the short run, it is usually followed
by expectations of a moderate appreciation in the long run.1
Survey data have mainly been used to study the existence of foreignexchange-market risk premia in spot-forward regressions and the validity of
the rational-expectations hypothesis (Taylor, 1995). The main conclusions
of these studies are that (1) survey data generally suggest the presence of
1 The discrepancy between the mechanisms for the short- and long-run exchange-rate
expectations formation used by agents in the foreign-exchange market suggests that
short-run expectations generally respond to lagged exchange-rate changes by moving in
the same direction (away from the long-run equilibrium exchange rate), whereas longrun exchange-rate expectations respond to lagged exchange-rate changes by moving in
the opposite direction (toward the long-run equilibrium exchange rate). This behavioral
discrepancy has been rationalized by Froot and Ito (1989) using the concept of consistency, which may be considered a weaker condition than full rationality. Nevertheless,
Froot and Ito (1989, p. 506) nd that expectations generally do not satisfy the consistency condition: In every one of twenty sets of time-series estimates encompassing four
surveys, ve forecast horizons and ve currencies, shorter-term expectations overreact
relative to longer-term expectations when the exchange rate changes. See also Pesaran
(1989) for an alternative derivation of the consistency condition.
11
13
4 CHARTIST ANALYSIS
An alternative explanation of the discrepancy between short- and longrun exchange-rate expectations is that the participants in foreign-exchange
markets may use dierent forecasting techniques for dierent expectations
horizons. The predominant technique used for short-run exchange-rate forecasting may be chartist analysis, for example, whereas the technique used
for long-run exchange-rate forecasting may be based on fundamental analysis or on conventional exchange-rate models.
Chartist, or technical, analysis uses charts of nancial-asset price
movementsoften with the aid of additional descriptive statisticsto infer
the likely course of future prices and thus to derive forecasts and trading
strategies. The trends and patterns that chartists consider are generally
inferred through loose inductive reasoning. Perhaps the most famous example of a chartist technique (indicating a trend reversal) is the head and
shoulders pattern presented by Allen and Taylor, (1990; Taylor and Allen,
1992). Chartists often use trends and patterns to identify broad ranges
within which exchange rates or asset prices are expected to trade, attempting to set the parameters for price movements. They may also employ
one or more mechanical indicators when forming a general view, which may
be trend-following (for example, based on moving averages) or non-trendfollowing (for example, rate-of-change indicators or oscillators used on
the assumption that the markets tend to correct when an asset has been
overbought or oversold). In practice, chartist analysis includes both
pattern and trend recognition, as well as information from basic statistical
indicators.
Chartist Analysis in the Foreign-Exchange Market
Although casual observation suggests that the use of chartist analysis is
widespread in leading nancial markets, evidence about its use has been
largely anecdotal (Malkiel, 1996). A survey conducted by the Group of
Thirty (1985), however, reported that 97 percent of banks and 87 percent of
securities houses believed that the use of technical analysis has a signicant
impact on the foreign-exchange market.
Applied work on the use of technical analysis includes that by Allen
and Taylor (1990; Taylor and Allen, 1992), who carried out a study of the
London foreign-exchange market on behalf of the Bank of England. Their
questionnaire, sent to over 400 chief foreign-exchange dealers in the London market in November 1988, achieved a response rate of over 60 percent
and suggested a broad consensus regarding the weight given to chartist
14
15
this study suggest that only about 30 percent of traders can be characterized as technical traders, although this proportion has been increasing
over the last ve years. Incorporation of news about fundamentals into
exchange-rate expectations occurs very rapidly, and news about interest
rates appears to be relatively more important in these markets. As one
would expect, macroeconomic fundamentals appear to be particularly important for long-run exchange-rate expectations.3
At the very least, therefore, the empirical evidence suggests that the
attitude of many nancial economists toward chartist analysisthat technical strategies are usually amusing, often comforting, but of no real value
(Malkiel, 1996, p. 154)should not be held with 100 percent condence,
at least in the foreign-exchange market.
The Impact of Chartist Analysis
The widespread academic skepticism of nonfundamental inuences in nancial markets has begun to give way to active investigation of the many
phenomena not captured by traditional economic models. Although analyses of the stock market have begun to consider the inuence of nonfundamental factors in general (Shiller, 1984; De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and
Waldmann, 1989), studies of the specic role of chartism have so far been
largely conned to the foreign-exchange market.
Goodhart (1988) discusses the way in which exchange-rate misalignment might occur by considering that the rate might be determined by
a balance of chartist and fundamentalist predictions. This surmise is, in
some ways, similar to the simple model of the stock market suggested by
Shiller (1984), in which the equilibrium price depends on the balance between fundamentalists (smart money) and ordinary investors who subscribe
to popular models. A comparable approach is developed more formally by
Frankel and Froot (1990b), who explain the sharp rise in the demand for
the U.S. dollar over the 1981-85 period as a shift in the weight of market
opinion away from fundamentalists and toward chartists. This shift is modeled as a Bayesian response to the inferior forecasting performance of the
economic fundamentalists.
3 Cheung and Chinn (1999) also report that speculation and ocial intervention, although thought to increase market volatility, are likely to restore equilibrium by moving
exchange rates toward their long-run values. Finally, traders do not value purchasingpower parity highly as a long-run equilibrium concept, although they seem to believe
that it might be useful for horizons of at least six months. Cheung, Chinn, and Marsh
(1999) use U.K. survey data and conrm that nonfundamental factors are thought to
dominate short-run movements in exchange rates, although fundamentals are deemed
important over much shorter horizons than is suggested by the mainstream empirical
literature.
16
17
other nancial markets. Their model, designed to explain the demand for
the U.S. dollar during the 1980s, functions as though there are actually
two models of the dollar operating, one at each end of the spectrum, and
a blend in between (Frankel and Froot, 1986, p. 36). The two models
they use are a fundamentalist model, for which they assume a Dornbusch
overshooting model (long-run), and a chartist model, for which they use
a simple autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) forecasting
equation (short-run).
The value of a currency can then be driven by the decisions of portfolio
managers who consider a weighted average of the expectations of fundamentalists and chartists of the following form:
f
c
sm
t+1 = t st+1 + (1 t ) st+1 ,
(1)
f
c
where sm
t+1 , st+1 and st+1 denote the rate of change in the spot rate expected by portfolio managers (the market), fundamentalists, and chartists,
respectively, and t is the weight given to the fundamentalist view by portfolio managers. Assuming, for simplicity, that sct+1 = 0, equation (1)
becomes
f
(2)
sm
t+1 = t st+1 ,
and thus
f
t = sm
t+1 /st+1 .
(3)
(4)
18
The results of the simulations suggest that a bubble in the exchange rate
is generated by portfolio managers attempts to learn the model. When the
bubble takes o, as well as when it collapses, portfolio managers learn the
model more slowly than when they are changing it by revising the weight
given to fundamentalist and chartist views. When the weight given to the
fundamentalist view leans toward any of its extreme values (zero and unity),
however, the portfolio managers exchange-rate-determination model leans
toward the correct model. In addition, the revisions of the weight become
smaller until the portfolio managers model corresponds perfectly to the
correct one, implying that portfolio managers change the model more slowly
than they learn it.
Following the seminal article by Frankel and Froot (1987), a number
of researchers constructed models to illustrate the role of nonfundamentalist traders in generating bubbles in the foreign-exchange and other nancial markets. These models are generally alike in considering at least two
types of traders who dier in their forecasts or beliefs, and in predicting
an outcome that shows the nonstationary dynamics typical of many nancial markets. Among them, those by De Long et al. (1989, 1990a, 1990b),
Kirman (1991), and Goldberg and Frydman (1993) are worth citing. The
models predict that periods of steady evolution are interrupted by bubbles
and crashes, with noise around the turning point when one regime shifts
to another. Opinions in the market are usually modied endogenously as
a result of the interactions among agents. Agents make mistakes at the
turning points when the opinion of the majority is not clear, but these
episodes are not long enough for learning or for the generation of protable
arbitrage opportunities (Kirman, 1991). De Grauwe and Dewachter (1993)
use a combined chartist-fundamentalist model to show the way in which
chaotic behavior of the exchange rate may be generated; the exchange rate
produced by such a process would be essentially unpredictable, regardless
of whether the underlying model is deterministic or stochastic (Goodhart,
1988). If these models accurately describe the foreign-exchange market, the
discrepancy between short- and long-run expectations of the exchange rate
may no longer be considered a puzzle for the profession.
Summing Up
Although it seems inexorable that economic fundamentals will win in
the long term, it is likely that short-term price movements may be dominated by popular models and theories, one of which is chartist analysis. Clearly, simple reliance on the extrapolation and inductive reasoning
found in chartist analysis is ultimately unsatisfactory. It may be, however,
that chartists (and foreign-exchange dealers in general), by working with
the minutiae of market-price movements, are able to get a feel for lo19
20
(5)
(6)
t = yt xt ,
(7)
22
Nason examine this issue by estimating nonparametrically the conditionalmean functions of ten nominal dollar spot rates for the sample period 1973
to 1987, used to generate in-sample and out-of-sample nonparametric forecasts. Interestingly, their ndings do not support the idea that nonlinearities in exchange rates can be exploited for prediction purposes. Their
results are also consistent with the ndings of other similar studies, such
as that by Meese and Rose (1991).
Another nding, suggested by both Diebold (1988) and Baillie and
Bollerslev (1989), is that although ARCH eects are found to be strongly
statistically signicant on daily and weekly exchange-rate data, they weaken
and eventually disappear with less frequently sampled data, that is to say,
ARCH eects aggregate out over time. In addition, the assumption of
normality appears to be a good approximation over four-week or, perhaps,
two-week frequencies, but not at higher frequencies. Baillie and Bollerslev
(1989) also estimate a GARCH(1,1) model and report a value of 1 + 1 very
close to unity, suggesting an IGARCH process (see also Diebold, 1988).2
Andersen and Bollerslev (1998) have recently raised the level of analysis
well beyond the standard GARCH approach. Using an annual sample of
ve-minute returns, their empirical model captures the intraday activity
patterns in the deutsche mark-dollar exchange market, the macroeconomic
announcements in the market, and the volatility persistence (ARCH) known
from daily returns. The authors quantify the dierent features and show
that they account for a substantial fraction of return variability, both at
the intraday and daily level (see also DeGennaro and Shrieves, 1995, and
Melvin and Yin, 1999).
ARCH models of the exchange rate also have important implications
for foreign-exchange-market eciency. The relevant empirical literature
systematically nds that the forward rate is not an unbiased predictor of
the corresponding future spot rate. Under the rational-expectations hypothesis, however, the existence of a risk premium can still reconcile this
fact with eciency in the foreign-exchange market (Hakkio, 1981; Hodrick
and Srivastava, 1984; Domowitz and Hakkio, 1985; Baillie, 1989). The empirical literature has attempted several dierent specications that make
the risk premium a function of the time-varying conditional variance of the
spot exchange rate. In particular, a number of authors have used ARCH2 A nice theoretical contribution in this context has been made by Hodrick (1989),
who studies the failure of log-linear exchange-rate models of the 1970s and the observed
variability of the risk premium in the foreign-exchange market. Rational, maximizing
models predict that changes in conditional variances of monetary policy, government
spending, and income growth aect risk premia, generating conditional volatility of exchange rates. Hodrick examines theoretically the eects these exogenous conditional
variances have on the level of the current exchange rate and quanties the extent to
which this channel explains exchange-rate volatility using ARCH models.
23
style models for the risk premium, with largely unsatisfactory results. Several researchers argue, however, that these weak results may simply be
attributable to the fact that the conditional variances are poor proxies for
risk. In principle, therefore, a risk premium may be modeled more satisfactorily by making it a function of time-varying cross-currency conditional
covariances rather than of just its own conditional variance. Following this
argument, several researchers have estimated multivariate ARCH models
as a test of the foreign-exchange-market eciency hypothesis (Lee, 1988;
Baillie and Bollerslev, 1990). Tests of the conditional capital-asset-pricing
model (CAPM) that allow for a time-varying conditional covariance matrix
have been made, for example, by Mark (1988) and Giovannini and Jorion
(1989) and perform much better than the traditional CAPM (Kaminsky
and Peruga, 1990).
Multivariate ARCH models have also been used to investigate various
policy issues associated with the foreign-exchange market. Examples are
models by Diebold and Pauly (1988) and Bollerslev (1990), who analyze
the short-run volatility of the exchange rate immediately after the inception of the European Monetary System (EMS). Their studies conclude that
an increase after 1979 in the conditional variances and covariances among
the member countries of the EMS occurred as a result of increased policy
coordination.
Volatility and Market Location
What are the implications of time-varying volatility in the foreign-exchange
market? Engle, Ito, and Lin (1990) argue that in an ecient foreignexchange market, the ARCH eects characterizing high-frequency data may
be attributed to the amount, or quality, of information reaching the market,
or else to the time necessary for market agents to process the new information fully. This argument seems consistent with the observation rst
made by Fama (1970, p. 396) about volatility clusters, that large daily
price changes tend to be followed by large daily changes. The signs of the
successive changes are apparently random, however, which indicates that
the phenomenon represents a denial of the random walk model but not of
the market eciency hypothesis. Nevertheless, it is interesting to speculate
why the phenomenon might arise. Baillie and Bollerslev (1991) use fourhourly exchange-rate series for a six-month period in 1986 and develop a
seasonal GARCH model to describe the time-dependent volatility of each
exchange-rate series. Their empirical results suggest that hourly patterns
of volatility are remarkably similar across countries and are strongly associated with the opening and closing of the leading world markets. In
addition, they nd that the U.S. foreign-exchange market displays more
volatility than the European market shows.
24
Engle, Ito, and Lin (1990, p. 526; Ito, Engle, Lin, 1992) use meteorological analogies to explain their viewpoint: news follow[s] a process like
a heat wave so that a hot day in New York is likely to be followed by another hot day in New York but not typically by a hot day in Tokyo. The
alternative analogy is a meteor shower which rains down on the earth as it
turns. A meteor shower in New York will almost surely be followed by one
in Tokyo. To anticipate our conclusion, volatility appears to be a meteor
shower rather a heat wave.3
Engle, Ito, and Lin use intradaily data on the yen-dollar exchange rate
from October 3, 1985, to September 26, 1986, and dene four separate
market locations: Europe, New York, the Pacic, and Tokyo. They then
consider a nonoverlapping market for a day, with market 1 being open
rst. Volatility generated into a previously open market can be considered
exogenous and part of the information set for market 2 on the subsequent
day. The Engle-Ito-Lin model is a GARCH-based vector autoregression
model for per-hour volatility of the form
i,t
hi,t
(11)
25
(12)
where is a vector of constants, ht = (h1,t , . . . , hn,t ) , t = 21,t , . . . , 2n,t ,
and
0
0
0
... 0
11 0
0 ... 0
21 0
0
0
... 0
22 0 . . . 0
A = .
,
B
=
,
..
..
..
..
.
.
.
n1
n2
11
0
..
.
12
22
...
... ... 0
. . . 1n
. . . 2n
.
..
. . . nn
(13)
. . . nn
Dening ht+s/nt E ht+s | n,t and taking the iterated expectation of
ht+s , Engle, Ito, and Lin prove that the vector of conditional heteroskedasticity of all the markets follows a process of the form
(I A) ht+s/kt = + (B + C) ht+s1/kt .
(14)
Thus, if Rik (s) hi,t+s/kt /2k,t (for i, k = 1, . . . , n) is the impulse response function of per-hour volatility of market i to the squared innovation
of market k, taking the derivative of (14) allows us to obtain Rik (s) by
solving recursively the equation
(I A) Rk (s) = (B + C) Rk (s 1)
s 2,
(15)
where Rk (s) = [Rik (s)]nx1 . Using simulation methods, Engle, Ito, and
Lin could derive per-hour volatility in each market segment in response
to per-hour volatility of the other market segments and calculate impulse
responses.
Applying their model to yen-dollar intradaily exchange-rate data, the
authors strongly reject the heat-wave hypothesis and interpret this rejection
as consistent either with market dynamics exhibiting volatility persistence
(caused, for example, by private information or heterogenous beliefs) or
with stochastic policy coordination or competition. Thus, they investigate
the dynamic eect of country-specic innovations on conditional volatility
in the subsequent markets. Their ndings suggest that Tokyo news has
the largest impact on volatility spillovers of the yen-dollar exchange rate.
Finally, they compute the impulse response curves to examine the reaction
26
of one markets volatility to news coming from another market. The empirical results suggest a cross-country dynamic eect in the short run, which
gradually dies out. Overall, therefore, the authors nd a case for volatility
clustering of the meteor-shower type, rather than of the heat-wave type.5
Public Information or Private Information?
A common feature of empirical and theoretical studies is the crucial role of
information, especially macroeconomic news, in determining price volatility (Oldeld and Rogalski, 1980; French and Roll, 1986; Harris, 1986).
It is widely thought (and implicitly assumed in conventional macroeconomic models of exchange-rate determination) that all agents in the foreignexchange market base projections on the same public-information set, implying that private information is irrelevant. Some recent studies, however,
challenge this view.
Harvey and Huang (1991) study the volatility implications of foreignexchange trading, using transaction data on futures contracts from the
Chicago Mercantile Exchange and the London International Financial Futures Exchange. To be precise, they analyze the role of public news announcements in determining volatility patterns. Harvey and Huang compute the hourly variance rates for exchange-trading and non-exchangetrading intervals and compute the ratios of both these and the total variance rates.6 The rationale underlying the computation is the so-called
public-information hypothesis, which suggests that even if trading outside exchange-trading time is important, the exchange-trading variance rate
may exceed the non-exchange-trading variance rate, because individual exchange rates are aected by public information available both to the countries concerned and to other countries as well. The availability of this public
information, released during trading hours in both countries, may thus be
expected to aect the volatility of the exchange rate; volatility may increase
when important macroeconomic news is made available.
This view contrasts with that of French and Roll (1986), who suggest
that trading based on private information induces higher volatility when
the market is open than when the market is closed (see also the theoretical
framework of Admati and Peiderer, 1988, and Foster and Viswanathan,
5 See also the closely related study by Hogan and Melvin (1994), who examine the
role that news and heterogeneous expectations play in the meteor-shower eects. Hogan
and Melvin focus on the U.S. trade-balance news, which is shown to have a signicant
and persistent eect on the exchange rate and its conditional variance. In addition, the
impact of U.S. trade-balance news is not isolated to the U.S. foreign-exchange market.
The degree to which this news aects other market locations appears to be functionally
related to heterogeneous priors.
6 The variance-rate ratios are computed under the assumption that returns are serially
uncorrelated.
27
28
29
that, although very appealing, present high computational costs and require
estimation of a large number of parameters (Hull and White, 1987; Scott,
1987; Wiggins, 1987; Chesney and Scott, 1989). An alternative approach,
followed by Jorion (1996), derives ISDs using Fischer Blacks (1976) optionpricing model. Jorion (1996) provides strong evidence for the superiority
of ISDs over time-series models and shows a positive correlation between
volume and volatility that is consistent with the mixture-distribution hypothesis.8
The recent empirical contribution by Ito, Lyons, and Melvin (1998) is,
however, crucial to this literature. Ito, Lyons, and Melvin provide evidence
in favor of the private-information hypothesis, using data for the Tokyo
foreign-exchange market, which from 1972 until 1994 was restricted from
trading over the lunch break (12:00 to 13:30). Following the related study
by French and Roll (1986) for the New York Stock Exchange, Ito, Lyons,
and Melvin start by noting that the three candidate explanations of the
importance of trading for price determination are that (1) public information arrives mainly during trading hours, (2) private information induces
trades that aect prices during trading hours, and (3) errors in pricing are
more likely to occur during trading hours. The authors discriminate among
these explanations by using the following strategy. First, comparing volatility across regimes with an unchanged ow of public information, they nd
that lunch return variance doubles when trading opens. Given that the
foreign-exchange market is largely skewed toward public information, the
fact that public information explains very little is an important nding in
itself.9
Having eliminated public information as the cause of higher volatility,
Ito, Lyons, and Melvin (1998) discriminate between private information
and pricing errors by showing that the volatility U-shape attens over the
full day, because lunch-hour trading induces greater revelation during that
period, leaving smaller shares of information for the morning and afternoon.
The authors also show that the U-shape tilts upward for the day, a trend
suggesting that the private value of the information is temporary, that is,
an open lunch hour reduces the incentive to trade early, because it reduces
the likelihood that prices will reect information before a position can be
opened.10 Further, there appears to be a clear U-shape in the morning
8 Note that the use of ISDs on stock-market data produces less interesting results. The
predictive power of ISDs is, in general, very low and is never higher than the predictive
power of time-series models (Canina and Figlewski, 1993; Lamourex and Lastrapes,
1993).
9 Ito, Lyons, and Melvin (1998) also provide a number of tests to ensure that the ow
of public information was unchanged.
1 0 This is clear, given the denition of private information used by Ito, Lyons, and
Melvin (1998), which includes information that is not common knowledge and that is
30
when Tokyo closes over lunch, but this U-shape disappears after the lunch
opening, as predicted by private-information models. Finally, Ito, Lyons,
and Melvin also nd that the contribution of mispricing to price volatility
is reduced after the lunch hour, a conclusion that coincides with the view
that the increase in lunch variance is caused wholly by mispricing. Overall,
Ito, Lyons, and Melvin (1998) provide the strongest empirical evidence in
the literature in favor of the private-information hypothesis, even though
their studies conclude that private information is expected to predict prices
mainly over relatively short horizons and, thus, may not be fundamental
(see also DeGennaro and Shrieves, 1995, Andersen and Bollerslev, 1998,
and Melvin and Yin, 1999).
Covrig and Melvin (1999) have also tested some implications of marketmicrostructure theory along the lines of Ito, Lyons, and Melvin (1998).
In particular, Covrig and Melvin identify a period in the foreign-exchange
market when there is a high concentration of informed yen-dollar traders
active in Tokyo. Comparing the period of informed-trader clustering to
a similar period without informed traders, they show that exchange-rate
quotes adjust to full-information levels much more quickly when informed
traders are active in the market than when they are not. Covrig and Melvin
also nd that Japanese quotes lead the rest of the market when the informed
traders are active but show a two-way causality when the informed traders
are not active. In addition, the contribution of yen-dollar price discovery
relative to quotes of the rest of the world is 5 to 12 percentage points higher
when the informed traders are active than when they are not. Covrig
and Melvin suggest that their results are consistent with the view that
private information is at times quite important, but that normal times
seem to be those periods during which public information implies a high
contemporaneous correlation across quotes, regardless of the informations
origin. The important implication of this conclusion is that the results
reported earlier by Ito, Lyons, and Melvin are attributable, not to inventory
rebalancing prior to the close, but to private information. This line of
analysis is an important avenue for future research.
Friedmans (1953) classic argument in favor of oating exchange rates
is that rational speculators will, in addition to imparting valuable information to the market, smooth exchange-rate movements, that is, reduce
exchange-rate volatility. In a recent theoretical microstructural analysis
of the connection between rational speculative activity and exchange-rate
volatility, Carlson and Osler (2000) argue that Friedmans analysis implicitly and crucially excludes interest-rate dierentials from his interpretation
price relevant. This denition is less stringent than that used in previous studies (for
example, French and Roll, 1986), which typically require that the price changes induced
by information be permanent.
31
32
33
34
that measures of exchange-rate dispersion (measuring exchange-rate volatility) are followed closely by exchange-rate spreads (Fieleke, 1975; Overturf,
1982).
Glassman (1987) makes a signicant contribution to the literature with
a model that includes variables representing transactions frequency and
considers the nonnormal distribution of exchange-rate change.3 Her model
not only provides additional evidence for the proportional relation between
exchange-rate volatility and bid-ask spreads, it also suggests that market
makers consider a level higher than the second moment of the exchange
rate in order to evaluate the probability of large exchange-rate changes.
Moreover, exchange-rate volatility is predicted by market makers on the
basis of the information provided by both long-run trends (some sixty-ve
days), and very recent experience (one day or one week). Glassman also
nds that spreads widen just before weekends and holidays. Finally, she
shows that transactions costs vary signicantly over time in response to
regime changes on capital controls.
Admati and Peiderer (1988) provide a model that includes three kinds
of agents: informed traders, who have relatively superior information and
only trade on terms favorable to themselves; discretionary liquidity traders,
who must trade sometime during the day but can choose when during the
day to trade in order to minimize costs; and nondiscretionary liquidity
traders, who must trade at a precise time during the day regardless of the
cost. Trading volume is explained by a concentration of trade by informed
traders and discretionary liquidity traders at specic points in time. The
concentrations occur because it is protable for informed traders to trade
when there are many liquidity traders who do not have the same information
they have; discretionary liquidity traders are attracted, because the larger
the number of traders, the lower the cost of trading. The Admati-Peiderer
model also predicts the increase in both volume and volatility that is typical
at the open and close of a trading day, so that trading activity displays a
U-shaped pattern from open to close.
The assumption of traders risk neutrality is, however, crucial in generating the key results of the Admati-Peiderer model. This is rigorously
shown by Subrahmanyam (1991), who models a noncompetitive speculative market in which informed traders, as well as market makers, are risk
averse. His main nding is that market liquidity is nonmonotonic in the
number of informed traders, their degree of risk aversion, and the accuracy
3 The evidence for a nonnormal distribution of exchange-rate change has grown since
the late 1970s and early 1980s (Westereld, 1977; McFarland, Pettit, and Sung, 1982;
Boothe and Glassman, 1987). The distribution appears to be quite close to a leptokurtic
pattern, with higher peaks and fatter tails than the normal distribution. Because nonnormal distributions are not described completely by the rst two moments, Glassman
(1987) includes the rst through fourth moments in her model.
35
of their information. His model also predicts that price eciency is reduced
by increased concentration of liquidity traders, and that market liquidity
may also be nonmonotonic in the variance of liquidity traders.
Bollerslev and Domowitz (1993) use intradaily data to investigate the
behavior of quote arrivals and bid-ask spreads over the trading day, across
geographical locations, and across market participants. Their ndings are
useful for discriminating among theoretical models of trading activity. In
particular, they determine that trading activity and the bid-ask spreads for
traders whose activity is restricted to regional markets can be described
by a U-shaped distribution consistent with the Admati-Peiderer (1988)
predictions. The patterns of trading activity and spreads during the day,
however, also strongly suggest a degree of risk aversion by traders, a nding
that is consistent with Subrahmanyams model: given a measure of risk
aversion, the more trading that is executed by informed participants, the
higher will be its cost.
Goodhart and Figliuoli (1991) study minute-by-minute spot rates (bidask Reuters quotes) on three days in 1987 (September 14, and 15, October
21) at the Reuters screen in London. They nd evidence that leptokurtosis
and heteroskedasticity are less pronounced at minute-by-minute frequencies
than at lower frequencies. In addition, leptokurtosis, skewness, and heteroskedasticity are time-varying. Trading volume is also time-varying and
is higher at the European and North American market openings and lower
at the European lunch hour. The series also exhibit a rst-order negative
serial correlation that is especially pronounced immediately after jumps in
the exchange rate. Time aggregation appears to reduce, but not eliminate,
the rst-order autocorrelation. Finally, multivariate analysis suggests that
there is a signicant link between lagged exchange rates (both the domestic
rate and the deutsche mark-dollar exchange rate) and the current spot rate
(see also Goodhart, Ito, and Payne, 1996).
Bollerslev and Melvin (1994), using an asymmetric-information model
with informed traders and liquidity traders in the tradition of Glosten
and Milgrom (1985) and Admati and Peiderer (1988), show that bidask spreads are proportionally related to exchange-rate uncertainty. Their
studys innovation is that they employ an ordered probit analysis in order
to capture the discreteness in the spread distribution, with the uncertainty
of the spot exchange rate modeled as a GARCH process (see also Melvin
and Ramirez, 2000).
Overall, the main ndings of the literature on the behavior of bid-ask
spreads in the foreign-exchange market during the 1980s and early 1990s
may be summarized by stating that spreads are directly proportional to
the volatility of exchange rates and trading volume, and that they are
higher on Fridays. In a more recent study, Bessembinder (1994) nds that
36
(16)
(19)
In estimating equation (19), Bessembinder (1994) includes in Xt a Monday indicator variable and the excess of thirty-day eurodollar interest rates
over thirty-day local-currency euro rates; he considers in Zt a Friday indicator, a preholiday indicator, the change since the preceding day in the
thirty-day eurodollar deposit rate, and the change since the preceding day
in the local-currency euro interest rate. The results strongly suggest that
currency market makers reduce quotes in relation to the underlying dol4 Bessembinder uses forecasts of price risk, interest-rate-based measures of liquidity
costs, and a nontrading indicator as proxies for inventory carrying costs. He uses the
forecastable and unexpected components of futures trading volume as proxies for trading
volume.
37
lar value when U.S. interest rates are rising and also, less signicantly, on
Fridays. The results also suggest a Monday eect on currency values, but
shifts in the placement of quotes relative to value as weekends approach
make it dicult to detect. In addition, Bessembinders (1994, p. 344) evidence illustrates that inference regarding asset value can be altered by
allowing for variation in the placement of quotes in relation to value.
Lee (1994) provides an alternative modeling strategy for the conditional
heteroskedasticity of the prediction error of foreign-exchange rates. Under
the assumption of cointegration between spot and forward rates, Lee uses
a system of error-correction models for GARCH-type models as a function of the spread. Estimating the system using daily series for seven exchange rates, he nds a strong correlation between spreads and exchangerate volatility.5
Jorion (1996) uses an option-implied volatility in his model specication
of bid-ask spreads. His results are generally consistent with the implications
of conventional spread theory. He (1996) also shows that ISDs dominate
all other risk measures in explaining bid-ask spreads.
Bessembinder, Chan, and Seguin (1996) investigate the relation between
trading volume and some proxies for information ows (ratio of volatility of
returns to a diversied equity portfolio) and for divergencies in opinion (the
open interest of the Standard & Poors 500 Index futures contract). They
nd that, in both spot and futures markets, trading volume varies positively
with the proxies for information ows. The choice of the trading venue
largely depends, as one would expect, on the nature of information ows:
traders informed about rm-specic matters trade primarily in the spot equity market, whereas traders with more general, market-wide information
choose to trade in the spot market. Bessembinder, Chan, and Seguin (1996)
also nd that trading volumes in both spot and futures markets are positively related to the proxy for divergencies of opinion when these volumes
rise but are unrelated to the proxies when they fall. The day-of-the-week
eects appear to be asymmetric across markets, with lower futures volume
relative to spot volume occurring late in the week (Foster and Viswanathan,
1990, develop a theoretical model that predicts this asymmetry). Bessembinder, Chan, and Seguin (1996, p. 132) conclude that additional research
is warranted on identifying those circumstances under which price forma5 Another paper relating global foreign-exchange markets to spreads is that by Hartmann (1998b), who estimates the long-run impact of trading activity on bid-ask spreads
by using a short panel containing around-the-clock Reuters quotes and global transactions volumes; allowance is made for individual and time eects in an unbalanced
random-eects model. Hartmann nds that the volume parameter has a (weakly) statistically signicant negative sign, in line with liquidity-eect explanations, and that the
volatility parameter is positive. He nds that structural parameters are stable over time
and that residuals are, as a group, heteroskedastic.
38
6 Brock and Kleidon (1992) examine the eect of periodic stock-market closures on
transactions demand and volume of trade and, consequently, bid and ask prices. They
nd that transactions demand is greater and less elastic at market open and close than at
other times during the trading day. A market maker such as a New York Stock Exchange
specialist may thus eectively discriminate by charging a higher transaction price during
these periods of peak demand. The predictions of periodic demand with high volume and
concurrent wide spreads are consistent with empirical evidence, whereas the predictions
of current information-based models are not.
39
40
private beliefs, volume, and volatility. This interactive process leads, however, to a sort of information externality caused by the dual role of traders
as speculators, on the one hand, and as information clearinghouse (intermediating customer orders that contain information), on the other hand.1
Prot maximization induces traders to underestimate important information in making their trading decisions, thereby reducing the information
content of prices at any given time. A crucial implication of this model is
that the greater the market power and the degree of traders risk aversion,
the less the information that will be revealed by market prices.
Lyons (1995) executes a number of tests on standard microstructure
hypothesis in the foreign-exchange market. In order to make these tests, he
builds a model based on realistic assumptions of the institutional features of
the foreign-exchange market. Lyons records the transactions of one dealer
and one broker in the U.S. market for ve days during August 1992. The
data set includes three interlocking components: the direct quotes and
trades of a market maker from a leading New York bank, the position
cards of the same market maker, and the prices and quantities for thirdparty transactions intermediated by a leading New York dealer. The main
focus of the study is to test for eects of trading volume on quoted prices
through the two channels emphasized by the literature: the information
channel and the inventory-control channel. The results suggest that trading
volume aects quoted prices through both channels, therefore giving some
support to both strands of the microstructure literature.2
Event Uncertainty versus Hot Potato
Lyons (1996) extends his 1995 model and uses the same data set to shed
light on the statistical relation between the intensity of trading and the informativeness of trades. In particular, he attempts to discriminate between
the two polar views of trading intensity that he describes as (1) the eventuncertainty view (trades are more informative when trading intensity is
high) and (2) the hot potato view (trades are more informative when
trading intensity is low). The event-uncertainty hypothesis can be traced
back to Easley and OHara (1992), who build a model in which new information may not exist (in contrast to most of the asymmetric-information
models in this literature). In such a framework, there is a probability p
of new information and (1 p) of no new information; also, the new information is good news with probability q and bad news with probability
1 Information externalities are predicted by earlier theoretical models under dierent
mechanisms (Stein, 1987).
2 In modeling the price-expectation formation process, Lyons uses a Bayesian model
in the tradition of Amihud and Mendelson (1980), Cohen et al. (1981), Conroy and
Winkler (1981), Glosten and Milgrom (1985), and Madhavan and Smidt (1991). For a
nontechnical exposition of these models, see Flood (1991).
41
(1 q). Easley and OHara (1992) show that trades occurring when intensity is high should induce a larger updating of beliefs than when trading
intensity is low, implying that trades are more informative when trading
intensity is high. The opposite view, the hot potato view, is rationalized on
the basis of asymmetric-information models in the tradition of Admati and
Peiderer (1988), in which liquidity traders clump together in their trading
in order to minimize their losses to informed traders. Because of this clumping of liquidity traders, trades are more informative when trading intensity
is low.3 The main goal of Lyons (1996) is to examine whether currencytrading volume is informative and under what circumstances. Specically,
he uses transactions data to test whether trades occurring when trading intensity is high are more informative, dollar for dollar, than trades occurring
when intensity is low. Lyons empirical results in estimating his model are
supportive of the one or the other hypothesis depending upon the measure
of trading intensity used in estimation, implying that taken together, the
results highlight the potential complementarity between these seemingly
polar views (Lyons, 1996, p. 20).
Lyons (1998) also examines foreign-exchange trading at the dealer level.
The dealer Lyons tracks averages U.S. $100,000 in prots per day on a volume of U.S. $1 billion per day. The half-life of the dealers position is about
ten minutes, which may be interpreted as evidence supporting inventory
models. The author also identies the dealers speculative position over
time and nds that this position determines the share of prots deriving
from speculation, rather than intermediation, and that intermediation has
a relatively more important role.
3 See
also Lyons (1997), who develops a simultaneous-trade model of the spot foreignexchange market that produces hot-potato trading. At the outset, risk-averse dealers
receive customer orders that are not generally observable. Dealers then trade among
themselves. Thus, each dealer intermediates both his or her customers trades and any
information contained therein. This information is subsequently revealed in price, depending on the information in interdealer trades. Lyons shows that hot-potato trading
reduces the information in interdealer trades, making price less informative.
42
8 CONCLUSION
We began this study by noting that the failure of fundamentals-based
exchange-rate models to explain or predict exchange-rate movements reliably has, at least in part, motivated the development of the microstructure literature (Flood and Taylor, 1996). To date, however, the foreignexchange-market microstructure seems to shed light most strongly on related issues, such as the transmission of information among market participants, the heterogeneity of agents expectations, and the implications of
agents heterogeneity for trading volume and exchange-rate volatility.1
There appears to be an emerging consensus in the literature, moreover,
that macroeconomic fundamentals are a reasonable guide to very long-run
exchange-rate movements (Flood and Taylor, 1996; Lothian and Taylor,
1996), and there is increasing interest in exchange-rate models with rigorous, stochastic, general-equilibrium microeconomic foundations (Obstfeld
and Rogo, 1995, 1996; Lane, 1999; Sarno, 2001). For the foreseeable future, therefore, it seems that research in foreign-exchange markets is likely
to be dominated by three strands: long-run empirical exchange-rate modeling, the new open-economy macroeconomics, and analyses of the foreignexchange-market microstructure. Synthesizing these three approaches into
a unied treatment would seem to be a worthwhile challenge for the economics profession.
1 An important exception is the recent paper by Evans and Lyons (1999), which
demonstrates that order ow may empirically explain a large portion of nominal
exchange-rate movements over periods of four months or less; this nding clearly suggests the need for further research on the relation between order ow and exchange-rate
movements.
43
REFERENCES
Admati, Anat R., and Paul Pfleiderer, A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume
and Price Variability, Review of Financial Studies, 1 (No. 1, 1988), pp. 340.
Aliber, Robert Z., Monetary Independence under Floating Exchange Rates,
Journal of Finance, 30 (No. 2, 1975), pp. 365376.
Allen, Helen, and Mark P. Taylor, Charts, Noise and Fundamentals in the
London Foreign Exchange Market, Economic Journal, 100, Supplement (No.
400, 1990), pp. 4959.
Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson, Dealership Market: MarketMaking
with Inventory, Journal of Financial Economics, 8 (No. 1, 1980), pp. 3153.
Andersen, Torben G., and Tim Bollerslev, DM-Volatility: Intraday Activity
Patterns, Macroeconomic Announcements, and Longer Run Dependencies,
Journal of Finance, 53 (No. 1, 1998), pp. 219265.
Bagehot, Walter, The Only Game in Town, Financial Analysts Journal, 22
(No. 1, 1971), pp. 1214.
Baillie, Richard T., Econometric Tests of Rationality and Market Efficiency,
Econometric Reviews, 8 (No. 2, 1989), pp. 151186.
Baillie, Richard T., and Tim Bollerslev, The Message in Daily Exchange Rates:
A Conditional-Variance Tale, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,
7 (No. 3, 1989), pp. 297305.
, A Multivariate Generalized ARCH Approach to Modeling Risk Premia
in Forward Foreign Exchange Rate Markets, Journal of International Money
and Finance, 9 (No. 3, 1990), pp. 309324.
, Intraday and Inter-Market Volatility in Foreign Exchange Rates,
Review of Economic Studies, 58 (No. 3, 1991), pp. 565585.
Bank for International Settlements (BIS), Central Bank Survey of Foreign
Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity, Basle, Bank for International
Settlements, 1998.
Barnea, Amir, and Dennis E. Logue, The Effect of Risk on the Market
Makers Spread, Financial Analysts Journal, 26 (No. 1, 1975), pp. 4549.
Bessembinder, Hendrik, Bid-Ask Spreads in the Interbank Foreign Exchange
Markets, Journal of Financial Economics, 35 (No. 3, 1994), pp. 317348.
Bessembinder, Hendrik, Kalok Chan, and Paul J. Seguin, An Empirical
Examination of Information, Differences of Opinion, and Trading Activity,
Journal of Financial Economics, 40 (No. 1, 1996), pp. 105134.
Bilson, John F. O., Technical Currency Trading, in Lee R. Thomas, ed., The
Currency-Hedging Debate, London, IFR Publishing, 1990, pp. 257275.
Black, Fischer, The Pricing of Commodity Contracts, Journal of Financial
Economics, 3 (No. 1/2, 1976), pp. 167179.
44
45
46
47
Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins, Estimating Time
Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure: The Arch-M Model, Econometrica, 55 (No. 2, 1987), pp. 391407.
Epps, Thomas W., and Mary Lee Epps, The Stochastic Dependence of
Security Price Changes and Transaction Volumes: Implications for the
Mixture-of-Distributions Hypothesis, Econometrica, 44 (No. 2, 1976), pp.
305321.
Evans, Martin D. D., and Richard K. Lyons, Order Flow and Exchange Rate
Dynamics, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7317,
Cambridge, Mass., National Bureau of Economic Research, 1999.
Fama, Eugene, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical
Work, Journal of Finance, 25 (No. 2, 1970), pp. 383417.
Fieleke, Norman S., Exchange-Rate Flexibility and the Efficiency of the
Foreign-Exchange Markets, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
10 (No. 3, 1975), pp. 409428.
Flood, Mark D., Microstructure Theory and the Foreign Exchange Market,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 73 (No. 6, 1991), pp. 5270.
, Market Structure and Inefficiency in the Foreign Exchange Market,
Journal of International Money and Finance, 13 (No., 2, 1994), pp. 131158.
Flood, Robert P., and Mark P. Taylor, Exchange Rate Economics: Whats
Wrong with the Conventional Macro Approach? in Frankel, Galli, and
Giovannini, eds., The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, 1996, pp.
261301.
Foster, F. Douglas, and S. Viswanathan, A Theory of the Interday Variations
in Volume, Variance, and Trading Costs in Securities Markets, Review of
Financial Studies, 3 (No. 4, 1990), pp. 593624.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Kenneth A. Froot, Understanding the U.S. Dollar in
the Eighties: The Expectations of Chartists and Fundamentalists, Economic
Record, 0, Supplement (No. 0, 1986), pp. 2438.
, Using Survey Data to Test Standard Propositions Regarding Exchange
Rate Expectations, American Economic Review, 77 (No. 1, 1987), pp.
133153.
, Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange
Market, American Economic Review, 80 (No. 2, 1990a), pp. 181185.
, Chartists, Fundamentalists and the Demand for Dollars, in Anthony
Courakis and Mark P. Taylor, eds., Private Behaviour and Government Policy
in Interdependent Economies, Oxford, Clarendon, 1990b, pp. 73126.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., Giampaolo Galli, and Alberto Giovannini, eds., The
Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, Chicago, Ill., Chicago University Press for National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Andrew K. Rose, Empirical Research on Nominal
Exchange Rates, in Gene M. Grossman, and Kenneth Rogoff, eds., Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3, Amsterdam and New York, NorthHolland, Elsevier, 1995, pp. 16891729.
48
49
Goodhart, Charles A. E., Takatoshi Ito, and Richard Payne, One Day in June
1993: A Study of the Working of the Reuters 20002 Electronic Foreign
Exchange Trading System, in Frankel, Galli, and Giovannini, eds., The
Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, 1996, pp. 107179.
Grammatikos, Theoharry, and Anthony Saunders, Futures Price Variability: A
Test of Maturity and Volume Effects, Journal of Business, 59 (No. 2, 1986),
pp. 319330.
Group of Thirty, The Foreign Exchange Market in the 1980s, Group of Thirty,
New York, 1985.
Hakkio, Craig S., Expectations and the Forward Exchange Rate, International
Economic Review, 22 (No. 3, 1981), pp. 663678.
Harris, Lawrence, A Transaction Data Study of Weekly and Intradaily Patterns
in Stock Returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 16 (No. 1, 1986), pp.
99117.
Hartmann, Philipp, Currency Competition and Foreign Exchange Markets: The
Dollar, the Yen and the Euro, Cambridge, New York, and Melbourne,
Cambridge University Press, 1998a.
, Do Reuters Spreads Reflect Currencies Differences in Global Trading
Activity? Journal of International Money and Finance, 17 (No. 5, 1998b),
pp. 757784.
, Trading Volumes and Transaction Costs in the Foreign Exchange
Market: Evidence from Daily Dollar-Yen Spot Data, Journal of Banking and
Finance, 23 (No. 5, 1999), pp. 801824.
Harvey, Campbell R., and Roger D. Huang, Volatility in the Foreign Currency
Futures Market, Review of Financial Studies, 4 (No. 3, 1991), pp. 543569.
Ho, Thomas, and Hans R. Stoll, Optimal Dealer Pricing under Transactions
and Return Uncertainty, Journal of Financial Economics, 9 (No. 1, 1981),
pp. 4773.
Hodrick, Robert J., Risk, Uncertainty, and Exchange Rates, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 23 (No. 3, 1989), pp. 433459.
Hodrick, Robert J., and Sanjay Srivastava, An Investigation of Risk and Return
in Forward Foreign Exchange, Journal of International Money and Finance,
3 (No. 1, 1984), pp. 529.
Hogan, Kedreth C., Jr., and Michael T. Melvin, Sources of Meteor Showers
and Heat Waves in the Foreign Exchange Market, Journal of International
Economics, 37 (No. 34, 1994), pp. 239247.
Hsieh, David A., The Statistical Properties of Daily Foreign Exchange Rates:
19741983, Journal of International Economics, 24 (No. 12, 1988), pp.
129145.
, Testing for Nonlinear Dependence in Daily Foreign Exchange Rates,
Journal of Business, 62 (No. 3, 1989a), pp. 339368.
, Modeling Heteroscedasticity in Daily Foreign-Exchange Rates, Journal
of Business and Economic Statistics, 7 (No. 3, 1989b), pp. 307317.
Hsieh, David A., and Allan W. Kleidon, Bid-Ask Spreads in Foreign Exchange
Markets: Implications for Models of Asymmetric Information, in Frankel,
50
51
Lui, Yu-Hon, and David Mole, The Use of Fundamental and Technical
Analyses by Foreign Exchange Dealers: Hong Kong Evidence, Journal of
International Money and Finance, 17 (No. 3, 1998), pp. 535545.
Lyons, Richard K., Private Beliefs and Information Externalities in the Foreign
Exchange Market, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 3889, Cambridge, Mass., National Bureau of Economic Research, 1991.
, Tests of Microstructural Hypotheses in the Foreign Exchange Market,
Journal of Financial Economics, 39 (No. 23, 1995), pp. 321351.
, Foreign Exchange Volume: Sound and Fury Signifying Nothing? in
Frankel, Galli, and Giovannini, eds., The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange
Markets, 1996, pp. 183201.
, A Simultaneous Trade Model of the Foreign Exchange Hot Potato,
Journal of International Economics, 42 (No. 34, 1997), pp. 275298.
, Profits and Position Control: A Week of FX Dealing, Journal of
International Money and Finance, 17 (No. 1, 1998), pp. 97115.
, The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates, Cambridge, Mass.,
MIT Press, forthcoming 2001.
Madhavan, Ananth, and Seymour Smidt, A Bayesian Model of Intraday
Specialist Pricing, Journal of Financial Economics, 30 (No. 1, 1991), pp.
99134.
Malkiel, Burton G., A Random Walk Down Wall Street: Including a Life-Cycle
Guide to Personal Investing, 6th ed., New York and London, Norton, 1996.
McCurdy, Thomas H., and Ieuan G. Morgan, Testing the Martingale Hypothesis in Deutsche Mark Futures with Models Specifying the Form of Heteroscedasticity, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 3 (No. 3, 1988), pp. 187202.
McFarland, James W., R. Richardon Pettit, and Sam K. Sung, The Distribution
of Foreign Exchange Price Changes: Trading Day Effects and Risk Measurement, Journal of Finance, 37 (No. 3, 1982), pp. 693715.
Meese, Richard A., and Andrew K. Rose, An Empirical Assessment of
Nonlinearities in Models of Exchange Rate Determination, Review of
Economic Studies, 58 (No. 3, 1991), pp. 603619.
Melvin, Michael T., and Xixi Yin, Public Information Arrival, Exchange Rate
Volatility, and Quote Frequency, Department of Economics, Arizona State
University, Tempe, Ariz., 1999, processed.
Melvin, Michael T., and Patricia Ramirez, FOMC Days and Exchange Rate
Dynamics, Department of Economics, Arizona State University, Tempe,
Ariz., 2000, processed.
Menkhoff, Lukas, Examining the Use of Technical Currency Analysis,
International Journal of Finance and Economics, 2 (No. 4, 1997), pp. 307318.
, The Noise Trading ApproachQuestionnaire Evidence from Foreign
Exchange, Journal of International Money and Finance, 17 (No. 3, 1998),
pp. 547564.
Milhoj, Anders, A Conditional Variance Model for Daily Deviations of an
Exchange Rate, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 5 (No. 1,
1987), pp. 99103.
52
53
Tauchen, George E., and Mark Pitts, The Price Variability-Volume Relationship on Speculative Markets, Econometrica, 51 (No. 2, 1983), pp. 485505.
Taylor, Mark P., Covered Interest Parity: A High-Frequency, High-Quality
Data Study, Economica, 54 (No. 216, 1987), pp. 429438.
, Covered Interest Arbitrage and Market Turbulence, Economic Journal,
99 (No. 396, 1989), pp. 376391.
, The Economics of Exchange Rates, Journal of Economic Literature,
83 (No. 1, 1995), pp. 1347.
Taylor, Mark P., and Helen Allen, The Use of Technical Analysis in the
Foreign Exchange Market, Journal of International Money and Finance, 11
(No. 3, 1992), pp. 304314.
Wasserfallen, Walter, and Heinz Zimmermann, The Behavior of Intra-Daily
Exchange Rates, Journal of Banking and Finance, 9 (No. 1, 1985), pp.
5572.
Wei, Shang-Jin, and Jeffrey A. Frankel, Are Option-Implied Forecasts of
Exchange Rate Volatility Excessively Variable? National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 3910, Cambridge, Mass., National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1991.
Westerfield, Randolph, The Distribution of Common Stock Price Changes: An
Application of Transactions Time and Subordinated Stochastic Models,
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 12 (No. 5, 1977), pp.
743765.
Wiggins, James B., Option Values under Stochastic Volatility: Theory and
Empirical Estimates, Journal of Financial Economics, 19 (No. 2, 1987), pp.
351372.
Wolinsky, Asher, Information Revelation in a Market with Pairwise Meetings,
Econometrica, 58 (No. 1, 1990), pp. 123.
54
PUBLICATIONS OF THE
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS SECTION
Notice to Contributors
The International Economics Section publishes papers in two series. ESSAYS IN
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS and PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS. Two earlier series, REPRINTS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE and SPECIAL
PAPERS IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, have been discontinued, with the SPECIAL
PAPERS being absorbed into the STUDIES series.
The Section welcomes the submission of manuscripts focused on topics in international trade, international macroeconomics, or international finance. Submissions
should address systemic issues for the global economy or, if concentrating on
particular economies, should adopt a comparative perspective.
ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS are meant to disseminate new views about
international economic events and policy issues. They should be accessible to a broad
audience of professional economists.
PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS are devoted to new research
in international economics or to synthetic treatments of a body of literature. They
should be comparable in originality and technical proficiency to papers published in
leading economic journals. Papers that are longer and more complete than those
publishable in the professional journals are welcome.
Manuscripts should be submitted in triplicate, typed single sided and double
spaced throughout on 8 by 11 white bond paper. Publication can be expedited if
manuscripts are computer keyboarded in WordPerfect or a compatible program.
Additional instructions and a style guide are available from the Section or on the
website at www.princeton.edu/~ies.
How to Obtain Publications
The Sections publications are distributed free of charge to college, university, and
public libraries and to nongovernmental, nonprofit research institutions. Eligible
institutions may ask to be placed on the Sections permanent mailing list.
Individuals and institutions not qualifying for free distribution may receive all
publications for the calendar year for a subscription fee of $45.00. Late subscribers
will receive all back issues for the year during which they subscribe.
Publications may be ordered individually, with payment made in advance. All
publications (ESSAYS, STUDIES, SPECIAL PAPERS, and REPRINTS) cost $10.00 each;
an additional $1.50 should be sent for postage and handling within the United States,
Canada, and Mexico; $4 should be added for surface delivery outside the region.
All payments must be made in U.S. dollars. Subscription fees and charges for
single issues will be waived for organizations and individuals in countries where
foreign-exchange regulations prohibit dollar payments.
Information about the Section and its publishing program is available on the
Sections website at www.princeton.edu/~ies. A subscription and order form is
printed at the end of this volume. Correspondence should be addressed to:
International Economics Section
Department of Economics, Fisher Hall
Princeton University
Princeton, New Jersey 08544-1021
Tel: 609-258-4048 Fax: 609-258-1374
E-mail: [email protected]
55
56
57
73. Ishac Diwan and Dani Rodrik, External Debt, Adjustment, and Burden Sharing:
A Unified Framework. (November 1992)
74. Barry Eichengreen, Should the Maastricht Treaty Be Saved? (December 1992)
75. Adam Klug, The German Buybacks, 1932-1939: A Cure for Overhang?
(November 1993)
76. Tamim Bayoumi and Barry Eichengreen, One Money or Many? Analyzing the
Prospects for Monetary Unification in Various Parts of the World. (September 1994)
77. Edward E. Leamer, The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice.
(February 1995)
78. Thorvaldur Gylfason, The Macroeconomics of European Agriculture. (May 1995)
79. Angus S. Deaton and Ronald I. Miller, International Commodity Prices, Macroeconomic Performance, and Politics in Sub-Saharan Africa. (December 1995)
80. Chander Kant, Foreign Direct Investment and Capital Flight. (April 1996)
81. Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti and Assaf Razin, Current-Account Sustainability.
(October 1996)
82. Pierre-Richard Agnor, Capital-Market Imperfections and the Macroeconomic
Dynamics of Small Indebted Economies. (June 1997)
83. Michael Bowe and James W. Dean, Has the Market Solved the Sovereign-Debt
Crisis? (August 1997)
84. Willem H. Buiter, Giancarlo M. Corsetti, and Paolo A. Pesenti, Interpreting the
ERM Crisis: Country-Specific and Systemic Issues. (March 1998)
85. Holger C. Wolf, Transition Strategies: Choices and Outcomes. (June 1999)
86. Alessandro Prati and Garry J. Schinasi, Financial Stability in European Economic
and Monetary Union. (August 1999)
87. Peter Hooper, Karen Johnson, and Jaime Marquez, Trade Elasticities for the
G-7 Countries. (August 2000)
88. Ramkishen S. Rajan, (Ir)relevance of Currency-Crisis Theory to the Devaluation
and Collapse of the Thai Baht. (February 2001)
89. Lucio Sarno and Mark P. Taylor, The Microstructure of the Foreign-Exchange
Market: A Selective Survey of the Literature. (May 2001)
SPECIAL PAPERS IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
29. Peter B. Kenen, Sorting Out Some EMU Issues; reprinted from Jean Monnet
Chair Paper 38, Robert Schuman Centre, European University Institute, 1996.
(December 1996)
58
ISBN 0-88165-261-X
Recycled Paper