Inequality is a core feature of American criminal justice, but its causes remain obscure.
Official racism has declined even as the black share of the prison population has risen.
Inequality is a core feature of American criminal justice, but its causes remain obscure.
Official racism has declined even as the black share of the prison population has risen.
Inequality is a core feature of American criminal justice, but its causes remain obscure.
Official racism has declined even as the black share of the prison population has risen.
Inequality is a core feature of American criminal justice, but its causes remain obscure.
Official racism has declined even as the black share of the prison population has risen.
ARTICLE UNEQUAL JUSTICE William J. Stuntz TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION ..........................................................................................................................1970 I. EQUALITY AND LOCAL POLITICS..................................................................................1975 A. Laws Limits, Bureaucracys Bias .................................................................................1975 B. Criminal Justice in the Gilded Age ..............................................................................1982 1. The South...................................................................................................................1983 2. Northern Cities ..........................................................................................................1986 II. THE RISE OF INEQUALITY..............................................................................................1997 A. Local Democracys Decline ............................................................................................1997 B. Lenity and Severity ........................................................................................................2010 C. Violence and Drugs.........................................................................................................2019 D. Federalism........................................................................................................................2025 III. EQUALIZING CRIMINAL JUSTICE ..................................................................................2031 A. Police Funding................................................................................................................2032 B. Jury Trials ........................................................................................................................2034 C. Vague Substantive Law ..................................................................................................2036 IV. CONCLUSION.......................................................................................................................2040
1970 UNEQUAL JUSTICE William J. Stuntz
Inequality is a core feature of American criminal justice, but its causes remain obscure. Official racism has declined even as the black share of the prison population has risen. The generation that saw the rise of enormous, racially skewed punishment for drug crime followed the generation that saw the rise of civil rights for black Americans and racially integrated police forces. What explains these trends? One answer the decline of local democracy has received too little attention in the growing literature on this subject. A century ago outside the South, high-crime city neighborhoods were largely self- governing; residents of those neighborhoods decided how much criminal punishment to impose, and on whom. Those locally democratic justice systems were both remarkably effective and surprisingly egalitarian. During the latter half of the twentieth century, local democratic control over criminal justice unraveled. Residents of high-crime cities grew less powerful; suburban voters, legislators, and appellate judges grew more so. Prison populations fell sharply, then rose massively. The effects of both the fall of criminal punishment and its subsequent rise were disproportionately felt in urban black neighborhoods. The justice system grew less equal, and less just. Parts I and II of the Article explore these trends. Part III turns to the future, and asks what steps might be taken to reverse them. I suggest three changes: better-funded local police forces, more trials to locally selected juries, and more vaguely defined crimes (to give those juries opportunities to exercise judgment). Those changes would make urban criminal justice more democratic, more lenient and more egalitarian. INTRODUCTION merican criminal justice is rife with inequality. African Ameri- cans constitute 13% of the general population, 1 but nearly half of a record-high prison population. 2 The imprisonment rate for Latino
Henry J. Friendly Professor, Harvard Law School. I thank Dan Epps, Mike Klarman, Adriaan Lanni, Dan Richman, David Sklansky, Carol Steiker, Jim Whitman, and participants in the Harvard Criminal Justice Colloquium for exceptionally helpful comments on earlier drafts. Jessee Alexander-Hoeppner, Josh Goodbaum, Saritha K. Tice, Tara Ramchandani, and Andy Stuntz provided excellent research assistance. Remaining errors are my responsibility.
1 BUREAU OF THE CENSUS, U.S. DEPT OF COMMERCE, STATISTICAL ABSTRACT OF THE UNITED STATES: 2007, at 14 tbl.13 (2007) (showing total population of 296,410,000 and a black population of 37,909,000). The 2007 Statistical Abstract is available online at http://www. census.gov/compendia/statab/2007/2007edition.html (last visited May 12, 2008); previous editions are available online at http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/past_years.html (last visited May 12, 2008). Henceforth, annual volumes of the Abstract will be cited as [year] STATISTICAL ABSTRACT.
2 See Michael Tonry, Obsolescence and Immanence in Penal Theory and Policy, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 1233, 1255 tbl.3 (2005). On the prison populations size, see BUREAU OF JUSTICE STA- TISTICS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, SOURCEBOOK OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE STATISTICS: ONLINE, tbl.6.28.2006 (showing prison population of 1.5 million in 2005, more than seven times the figure in 1970), available online at http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook (last visited May 12,
A
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1971
males is almost triple the rate for white males; black men are locked up at nearly seven times the rate of their white counterparts. 3 The dif- ferentials in drug punishment are even larger: of every 100,000 black Americans, 359 are imprisoned on drug charges; the analogous figure for whites is 28. 4 Drug offenders are far more equally distributed: 9.7% of Americas black population uses illegal drugs; the analogous figure for whites is 8.1%. 5
Those data suggest a justice system hard-wired for punitive racism. The truth is more complex. A mere thirty-five years ago, imprison- ment rates across the Northeast and Midwest were comparable to or below those in Scandinavian countries today; 6 the number of African American prisoners was one-eighth todays figure. 7 Even now, the po- lice clear more violent crimes in small cities than in large ones, more in suburbs than in small cities, and more in small towns and rural ar- eas than in suburbs. 8 In other words, the justice system solves (and hence punishes) violent crimes most often in places with the fewest poor people and black people. 9 One-third of violent felony defendants
2008). The online version of the Sourcebook will henceforth be cited as ONLINE SOURCEBOOK; the Sourcebooks annual volumes will be cited as [year] SOURCEBOOK.
3 ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.33.2005.
4 Among Latinos, the drug imprisonment rate is 127 per 100,000. The figures on drug prison- ers by race appear in ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.0001.2003. The general popu- lation figures used to calculate rates appear in 20042005 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 14 tbl.13.
5 OFFICE OF APPLIED STUDIES, U.S. DEPT OF HEALTH & HUMAN SERVS., RESULTS FROM THE 2005 NATIONAL SURVEY ON DRUG USE AND HEALTH: NATIONAL FINDINGS 22 (2006), available at http://www.oas.samhsa.gov/nsduh/2k5nsduh/2k5results.pdf.
6 In 2001, Denmark, Norway, and Sweden imprisoned 58, 58, and 69 inmates per 100,000 population, respectively. GORDON BARCLAY & CYNTHIA TAVARES, INTERNATIONAL COM- PARISONS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE STATISTICS 2001, at 7 tbl.B (2003), available at http:// www.csdp.org/research/hosb1203.pdf. In 1972, Illinois, Massachusetts, and New York imprisoned 50, 32, and 64 inmates per 100,000 population, respectively. 1975 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 642 tbl.6.17.
7 In 2005, the number of black prisoners was just over 631,000. See ONLINE SOURCE- BOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.33.2005; 2007 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 14 tbl.13. In 1970, that number was fewer than 82,000. See MARGARET WERNER CAHALAN, HISTORICAL CORRECTIONS STATISTICS IN THE UNITED STATES, 18501984, at 65 tbl.3-31 (1986); 1972 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 16 tbl.15.
8 The data appear in FEDERAL BUREAU OF INVESTIGATION, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2005, tbl.25 (2005). From 1995 forward, annual volumes of Crime in the United States are available online at http://www.fbi.gov/ucr/ucr.htm#cius. Earlier volumes in the series, which dates to the 1930s, are titled UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS. Hence- forth, volumes in this series will be cited as CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: [year] or UNI- FORM CRIME REPORTS: [year], depending on which title is used for the relevant volume.
9 As of 2002, 51.5% of Americas black population lived in central cities, while 36% lived in metropolitan areas outside central cities, and a mere 12.5% lived outside metropolitan areas. Among non-Hispanic whites, the comparable figures were 21%, 57%, and 22%. JESSE MCKINNON, U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, U.S. DEPT OF COMMERCE, THE BLACK POPULATION IN THE UNITED STATES: MARCH 2002, at 2 fig.2 (2003). On the link between race and concen- trated poverty, see ALEMAYEHU BISHAW, U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, U.S. DEPT OF COMMERCE,
1972 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
in the seventy-five most populous counties nearly half of whom are black and the large majority of whom are poor 10 have the charges against them dismissed. 11 A mere 8% of federal fraud defendants, a group that is much wealthier and whiter, 12 achieve the same result. 13
In all categories of criminal cases, indigent defendants are more likely to win dismissals than defendants who hire their own lawyers. 14
These are not the hallmarks of an adjudicative system bent on locking up young men in poor black neighborhoods. What accounts for this strange set of patterns? Official racism 15 is an unlikely explanation for a massive rise in black punishment that took hold in the generation after the civil rights movement. The rise of populist politics 16 appears not to fit the relevant trends: populism and the politics of crime were as potent a mix in George Wallaces day as in our own but the prison populations in Wallaces Alabama and in Ronald Reagans California were low and falling, not high and ris- ing. 17 The culture of control and governing through crime, David
AREAS WITH CONCENTRATED POVERTY: 1999, at 8 fig.4 (2005). For evidence that race, but not poverty, is a strong negative predictor of clearance rates, see Janice L. Puckett & Richard J. Lundman, Factors Affecting Homicide Clearances: Multivariate Analysis of a More Complete Conceptual Framework, 40 J. RES. CRIME & DELINQ. 171 (2003).
10 Among defendants charged with violent felonies in large metropolitan counties, 44% are black, and only 28% are white. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.52.2002. 83% of those defendants are poor enough to qualify for court-appointed counsel. CAROLINE WOLF HARLOW, BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS, DEFENSE COUNSEL IN CRIMINAL CASES 5 tbl.7 (2000), available at http://www.ojp.usdoj.gov/bjs/pub/pdf/dccc.pdf.
11 ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.57.2002.
12 Not only in the collar: 65% of federal fraud defendants are white; fewer than 30% are black. Id. tbl.5.18.2003. 43% of such defendants pay for their own lawyers, well over twice the rate for defendants charged with violent felonies. HARLOW, supra note 10, at 3 tbl.3.
13 ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.17.2004.
14 HARLOW, supra note 10, at 6 tbl.10. In nearly all categories of cases, defendants with court-appointed counsel receive shorter prison sentences. Id. at 9 tbl.18.
15 For the classic account of racism as the cause of Americas punitive turn, see MARC MAUER, RACE TO INCARCERATE (1999). Cf. FRANKLIN E. ZIMRING, THE CONTRADIC- TIONS OF AMERICAN CAPITAL PUNISHMENT 89118 (2003) (noting that jurisdictions with a history of lynching carry out executions at much higher rates than other jurisdictions).
16 On the connection between massive, discriminatory punishment and the rise of the populist politics of crime, see SAMUEL WALKER, POPULAR JUSTICE: A HISTORY OF AMERICAN CRIMINAL JUSTICE (2d ed. 1998); FRANKLIN E. ZIMRING ET AL., PUNISHMENT AND DE- MOCRACY: THREE STRIKES AND YOURE OUT IN CALIFORNIA (2001) [hereinafter ZIMRING ET AL., THREE STRIKES].
17 In 1962, the year Wallace was first elected Governor of Alabama, that states imprisonment rate was 166 per 100,000. See 1964 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 11 tbl.8, 159 tbl.216. Fourteen years later, the states imprisonment rate had fallen to 83; Wallace and his wife Lurleen governed the state for eleven of those fourteen years. 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72. Californias imprisonment rate stood at 146 in 1966, the year before Reagans governorship began. See 1968 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 12 tbl.11, 159 tbl.237. That figure fell to 84 in 1972. 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72. By comparison, in 2005, Alabamas and Californias imprisonment rates and the rate for the nation as a whole stood at 591, 466, and 491, respectively. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1973
Garlands and Jonathan Simons apt labels for the growing use of criminal punishment to manage the nations poor, 18 capture the char- acter of contemporary drug enforcement but not the enforcement of laws against criminal violence or white-collar crime: 19 in those areas, rich suspects do badly and poor ones do surprisingly well. Another explanation does better: inequality of all these varying sorts arose, in large measure, because of the decline of local democratic control over criminal justice outcomes. In the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, when local politics governed the amount and distribution of criminal punishment, the justice system was stable, rea- sonably lenient, and surprisingly egalitarian. Prison populations were much smaller than todays, and varied little across place and time. Outside the South, the groups most likely to be the targets of discrimi- natory punishment blacks, women, and poor immigrants achieved results as favorable as native-born white men, or nearly so. No legal rules commanded those results; rather, political equilibrium produced them. In the twentieth centurys second half, that equilib- rium unraveled. Suburban populations mushroomed, diluting poor city neighborhoods electoral power; big-city police forces grew more professionalized, hence more detached from the streets they patrol. Crime became a live issue in state and national elections, shifting po- litical power from high-crime cities to the safer suburbs and country- side. The constitutional law of criminal procedure expanded dramati- cally, shifting legal authority from locally elected trial judges to state and federal appellate courts. As local control faded, variation of all kinds across place, time, and demographic category exploded. In the 1950s, 1960s, and early 1970s, Northern prison populations fell sharply, in the midst of an un- precedented crime wave. The balance of the twentieth century saw an unprecedented punishment wave, while urban crime remained stub- bornly high. 20 Both the lenient turn of the centurys third quarter and the punitive turn of its last quarter struck high-crime cities, and black neighborhoods within those cities, especially hard. So did the rise of massive, racially disparate drug enforcement. And so did the under-
18 See DAVID GARLAND, THE CULTURE OF CONTROL: CRIME AND SOCIAL ORDER IN CONTEMPORARY SOCIETY (2001); JONATHAN SIMON, GOVERNING THROUGH CRIME: HOW THE WAR ON CRIME TRANSFORMED AMERICAN DEMOCRACY AND CREATED A CULTURE OF FEAR (2007).
19 Jim Whitmans theory explains not only the punitive turn in general, but the harsh charac- ter of the law of white-collar crime as well. According to Whitman, American-style harsh jus- tice flows from a decision to level down rather than level up to treat high-status criminals like low-status ones, instead of the other way around as in Europe. See JAMES Q. WHITMAN, HARSH JUSTICE: CRIMINAL PUNISHMENT AND THE WIDENING DIVIDE BETWEEN AMER- ICA AND EUROPE (2003) [hereinafter WHITMAN, HARSH JUSTICE].
20 See infra p. 2011 (Table 5).
1974 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
punishment of urban violence, as police and prosecutors substituted cheap drug cases for more expensive violent crime cases. 21 These var- ied trends are linked: all flow, in large measure, from the decline of lo- cally self-governing justice systems in high-crime cities. Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means would have understood the con- nection. Seventy-five years ago, Berle and Means made famous the separation of ownership from control in the world of business corpora- tions. 22 Thanks in part to their book, reducing the agency cost that inheres in control by non-owner managers and ownership by non- controlling shareholders is corporate laws primary goal. Contempo- rary American criminal justice faces the same governance problem, but in worse form. After all, managers have good reason to see that the corporations they run remain profitable: their jobs depend on it. The detached managers of urban criminal justice systems are in a dif- ferent position. To the suburban voters, state legislators, and state and federal appellate judges whose decisions shape policing and punish- ment on city streets, criminal justice policies are mostly political sym- bols or legal abstractions, not questions the answers to which define neighborhood life. Decisionmakers who neither reap the benefit of good decisions nor bear the cost of bad ones tend to make bad ones. Those sad propositions explain much of the inequality in American criminal justice. How are the relevant trends to be reversed? The core principle is the same as in the law of corporations: reduce agency cost; place more power in the hands of residents of high-crime city neighborhoods for they feel the effects of rising and falling rates of crime and punish- ment, just as shareholders feel the effects of rising and falling corpo- rate profits. Make criminal justice more locally democratic, and jus- tice will be both more moderate and more egalitarian. Three moves are key, and all can be accomplished without radical change in the structure of the system or the legal doctrines that govern it: put more police officers on city streets, try more criminal cases to locally selected juries, and define criminal prohibitions more vaguely so jurors can exercise judgment instead of rubber-stamping prosecutors charging decisions. The federal government can and should advance those goals by changing the character of the federal contribution to state and local law enforcement: less federal law, more federal budget dollars. The balance of the Article is organized as follows. Part I explains the link between criminal justice equality and local politics, both in the abstract and historically. Part II traces the late-twentieth-century col-
21 See infra section II.C, pp. 201925.
22 ADOLF A. BERLE, JR. & GARDINER C. MEANS, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1975
lapse of the egalitarian justice system that once governed Northern cit- ies. Part III turns to the future, exploring some means by which a measure of equality in this crucial sphere of governance might be re- covered. Part IV concludes. I. EQUALITY AND LOCAL POLITICS Localism and democratic politics seem antithetical to egalitarian criminal justice. Localism means difference and variation: tough en- forcement here and lax enforcement there, moralist legal doctrine in one place and libertarian rules in another. A criminal justice system under the thumb of voters and politicians is a system prone to act on majoritarian prejudices. Taken together, local control of criminal jus- tice institutions and political control of those institutions would appear to maximize discrimination, not equality. History suggests the opposite conclusion: when Americas criminal justice system was more localized than it is today, the variation in im- prisonment rates was much smaller than it is today. So was the degree of change over time, and so were racial disparities in criminal punish- ment (based on the limited data available). Outside the South, the Gilded Age the era of Lochner 23 and laissez-faire saw the rise of the most egalitarian criminal justice in American history. That more egalitarian justice system was both more localized and more democ- ratic than our own. Local power over criminal punishment was exer- cised by local jurors, by locally elected government officials, and by voters from the neighborhoods where crime and punishment alike were concentrated. In our time, centralized democratic power seems associated with discrimination and severity. 24 In the past, local de- mocratic control of criminal justice appears to have produced equality and lenity. This Part seeks to explain those surprising truths. I begin with a brief discussion of the limits of the two alternatives to politics as a means of guaranteeing criminal justice equality: legal doctrine and bu- reaucracy. Next comes a discussion of Lochner-era criminal justice: an age of brutal discrimination in the South, but one that produced a sur- prisingly large measure of egalitarianism in Northern cities. A. Laws Limits, Bureaucracys Bias In order to identify and combat inequality, one must first know what the term means. My definition is conventional: an egalitarian
23 The reference, of course, is to Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45 (1905).
24 The leading scholarship on Americas punitive turn has emphasized the role of democratic politics in producing it. See sources cited supra notes 16, 1819. Centralization has not played a large role in that story: an important gap in the literature.
1976 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
justice system treats morally like cases alike. 25 Because race does not alter offenders moral desert, black drug dealers should be as likely as white ones to be arrested and prosecuted, and should receive the same punishments when convicted. Because wealth creates no moral enti- tlement to the laws protection, crimes that victimize the poor should trigger arrest and punishment at the same rate as crimes that victimize the rich. The Fourteenth Amendment, with its promise of the equal protection of the laws, 26 seems to guarantee as much yet the justice system does not fulfill the Constitutions promise. Why not? Why have courts and legal doctrine proved unable to provide even a modest measure of criminal justice equality? There are two answers. First, judges lack the information needed to identify race- and class-based inequalities when they happen. Second, judges lack the remedial tools to rectify those inequalities. The key missing information concerns missing cases: the many crimes that do not yield arrests, prosecutions, and convictions. In or- der to redress the massive discrimination that appears to afflict drug enforcement, judges need to know about the black and (especially) white drug dealers who have escaped arrest. That information does not exist. The data noted in this Articles first paragraph illustrate the point: we know, at least roughly, the number of black and white drug users, but no one knows the numbers and locations of black and white drug dealers and it is dealers, not users, who swell the nations prison population. The problem extends beyond drug cases: demo- graphic information about criminals who commit uncharged crimes of all kinds is sparse, and it is hard to see how any legal system could make it otherwise. Hard as inequality is to identify and prove, remedying it through litigation seems harder still. If a large corporation hires too many white job applicants and too few blacks, a court can order the hiring of more applicants from the victimized group. At worst, a few people who deserve to keep their jobs will lose them (and likely find equiva- lent work elsewhere), while a few qualified-but-not-stellar applicants will get jobs that others might have done slightly better. Error costs are low. Remedying unequal criminal punishment is far more disrup- tive. Imagine a judicial holding that a given states drug punishment
25 There are nearly as many moral theories of equality as there are moral theories. See, e.g., DOUGLAS RAE, EQUALITIES 133 (1981) (finding more than one hundred definitions). As Peter Westen has explained, however, these different theories are merely substantive variations on the common, formal principle that likes should be treated alike. Peter Westen, The Empty Idea of Equality, 95 HARV. L. REV. 537, 539 n.8 (1982); see also Jeremy Waldron, The Substance of Equality, 89 MICH. L. REV. 1350, 135864 (1991) (reviewing PETER WESTEN, SPEAKING OF EQUALITY (1990)) (explaining the relationship between that principle and substantive equality).
26 U.S. CONST. amend. XIV, 1.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1977
practices violate the Equal Protection Clause. What happens next? Courts might order police to arrest and prosecutors to charge more white drug suspects but which ones? What should officials say to the crime victims whose crimes are never investigated because the po- lice were busy rounding up drug suspects whom residents of the rele- vant communities do not want to punish? Prosecutors might not try hard to win convictions in cases they preferred not to bring in the first place. What happens if the additional white defendants win their cases? Such questions have no good answers. The logical alternative is to spare members of the victimized group. But how many, and which ones, and what is to be the mechanism by which they are selected? Those questions likewise have no good an- swers. The criminal justice system is not designed to identify marginal convictions that can be overturned at little cost if the need arises. Even were it otherwise, judges might reasonably fear the consequences of freeing large numbers of drug prisoners from neighborhoods where street-level drug trafficking causes the most damage. 27 And discrimi- natory drug enforcement is an easy matter compared to discriminatory enforcement of violent felonies and felony thefts: imagine the political consequences of a judicial order freeing a large bloc of burglars or ar- sonists, car thieves or rapists. Perhaps because defining and enforcing criminal justice equality seems so difficult, courts have been quick to embrace legal substitutes. Vagueness doctrine requires reasonably specific crime definition, 28
which is supposed to reduce inequality by reducing the range of en- forcement discretion. 29 The Fourth, Fifth, and Sixth Amendments, plus the Fourteenth Amendments Due Process Clause, oblige police officers, prosecutors, and trial judges to follow procedures designed to protect criminal suspects and defendants against abuse and exploita- tion. Those procedures apply to all, regardless of skin color and social class. But their raison dtre is the prevention of class and race dis- crimination the protection of suspects and defendants who lack the
27 A comprehensive remedy for discriminatory drug enforcement would probably require the widespread dismissal of drug charges in poor black neighborhoods, given the high concentrations of poor blacks among drug defendants. See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.52.2002 (showing a three-to-two ratio of black to white drug defendants in metropolitan counties); id. tbl.6.0001.2003 (showing a two-to-one ratio of black to white drug prisoners in state penitentia- ries); HARLOW, supra note 10, at 5 tbl.7 (84% of drug defendants in metropolitan counties are poor enough to receive state-paid counsel).
28 Sufficiently specific to provide the kind of notice that will enable ordinary people to under- stand what conduct [the law] prohibits. City of Chicago v. Morales, 527 U.S. 41, 56 (1999) (plu- rality opinion).
29 For the best explanation of the link between specificity and discrimination, see John Calvin Jeffries, Jr., Legality, Vagueness, and the Construction of Penal Statutes, 71 VA. L. REV. 189, 214 18 (1985).
1978 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
political and financial power to protect themselves. 30 Both vagueness doctrine and the law of constitutional criminal procedure amount to equal protection doctrine in disguise. Unfortunately, these ersatz equality rules work no better than di- rect legal mandates. Legislators can define broad crimes as specifically as narrow ones, 31 and thereby create as much enforcement discretion as they wish without violating the void-for-vagueness doctrine. Pro- tective procedures make criminal trials more expensive; more expen- sive trials make guilty pleas more valuable to prosecutors and also to poor defendants, whose lawyers cannot afford to take many cases to trial. 32 The consequence is more plea bargaining, and hence (again) more discretionary power for prosecutors. That does not advance the cause of equal justice. Laws fundamental problems in this area the absence of good data on crimes never prosecuted, the judiciarys lim- ited array of remedial tools are not susceptible to doctrinal fixes. If the law cannot command criminal justice equality, perhaps a centralized bureaucracy can do so. Well-run government agencies, one might suppose, are good at handling large numbers of cases without generating disparities like those Americas dysfunctional justice system creates. Most Western justice systems are run by apolitical national or provincial bureaucracies, 33 and those countries do not have massive, racially skewed prison populations. 34 Perhaps institutional design and criminal justice outcomes are linked. It might be so: but it is worth noting that those justice systems did not face the combination of American-style crime rates and serious racial or ethnic divisions before
30 On the link between Warren-era criminal procedure doctrine and class discrimination, see LUCAS A. POWE, JR., THE WARREN COURT AND AMERICAN POLITICS 37986, 44546 (2000); and Michael J. Klarman, Rethinking the Civil Rights and Civil Liberties Revolutions, 82 VA. L. REV. 1, 6266 (1996). On the relationship between that doctrines origins and race discrimination, see Michael J. Klarman, The Racial Origins of Modern Criminal Procedure, 99 MICH. L. REV. 48 (2000) [hereinafter Klarman, Racial Origins].
31 See William J. Stuntz, The Pathological Politics of Criminal Law, 100 MICH. L. REV. 505, 55961 (2001) [hereinafter Stuntz, Pathological Politics].
32 On the docket pressure faced by court-appointed counsel, see STANDING COMM. ON LE- GAL AID & INDIGENT DEFENDANTS, AM. BAR ASSN, GIDEONS BROKEN PROMISE: AMER- ICAS CONTINUING QUEST FOR EQUAL JUSTICE 1011, 16, 1718 (2004), available at http:// www.abanet.org/legalservices/sclaid/defender/brokenpromise/fullreport.pdf; Mary Sue Backus & Paul Marcus, The Right to Counsel in Criminal Cases, A National Crisis, 57 HASTINGS L.J. 1031, 103436, 105359 (2006); and Note, Effectively Ineffective: The Failure of Courts to Address Underfunded Indigent Defense Systems, 118 HARV. L. REV. 1731, 173435 (2005).
33 See Michael Tonry, Determinants of Penal Policies, 36 CRIME & JUST. 1, 3536 (2007); see also WHITMAN, HARSH JUSTICE, supra note 19, at 1315, 199202 (linking strength of state bu- reaucracies with lenity of criminal justice outcomes).
34 Some European prison populations may be racially skewed, but they cannot fairly be called massive. Across the E.U., the average imprisonment rate in 2001 stood at 87 per 100,000. BAR- CLAY & TAVARES, supra note 6, at 7 tbl.B. In the same year, the imprisonment rate in the United States stood at 470. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1979
the last generations wave of North African and Middle Eastern immi- gration. 35 A generation hence, Europes centralized criminal justice bureaucracies might appear as discriminatory as the political agencies that run Americas system. To see why that depressing conclusion is plausible, it helps to com- pare two kinds of centralized power: political and bureaucratic. Na- tional politicians controlling criminal law enforcement face two obvi- ous discriminatory temptations. They might use their power to overpunish minorities, because doing so is popular with the majority of voters. Or, they might devote too much time and energy to a small number of politically salient criminals like O.J. Simpson or Kenneth Lay, and pay too little attention to low-salience crimes against poor or minority victims. These two tendencies, toward racism and populism, are precisely the ones that the literature on the politics of crime identi- fies as the sources of discriminatory criminal justice. 36
Centralized, apolitical bureaucrats probably are less prone to those two forms of discrimination. But the bureaucrats face another tempta- tion: to skew enforcement in favor of the rich say, by ignoring rich criminals offenses, or by policing wealthy neighborhoods more care- fully than poor ones. As generations of political scientists have taught, regulatory capture is common in the realm of bureaucratic governance: when well-funded groups have important interests at stake, they often find it easy to convince allegedly impartial bureaucracies to serve the groups selfish ends. 37 That insight is rarely applied to crime and criminal justice, but it applies as readily to those fields as, say, to envi- ronmental regulation. Despite criminal laws banning the employment of illegal immigrants, a host of businesses continue to rely on off-the- books immigrant labor; prosecution for such behavior is rare. 38 De-
35 Several of the essays in ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION: COMPARATIVE AND CROSS-NATIONAL PERSPECTIVES (Michael Tonry ed., 1997) [hereinafter ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION], play this theme. See Hans-Jrg Albrecht, Ethnic Minorities, Crime, and Criminal Justice in Germany, in ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION, supra, at 31; Josine Junger-Tas, Ethnic Minorities and Criminal Justice in the Netherlands, in ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION, supra, at 257; Martin Killias, Immigrants, Crime, and Criminal Justice in Switzerland, in ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION, supra, at 375; Peter L. Martens, Im- migrants, Crime, and Criminal Justice in Sweden, in ETHNICITY, CRIME, AND IMMIGRATION, supra, at 183; see also SENTENCING AND SANCTIONS IN WESTERN COUNTRIES (Michael Tonry & Richard S. Frase eds., 2001).
36 See sources cited supra notes 1516, 18.
37 See, e.g., Michael E. Levine & Jennifer L. Forrence, Regulatory Capture, Public Interest, and the Public Agenda: Toward a Synthesis, 6 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 167 (1990); Richard A. Posner, Theories of Economic Regulation, 5 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI. 335 (1974).
38 See Spencer S. Hsu & Kari Lydersen, Illegal Hiring is Rarely Penalized, WASH. POST, June 19, 2006, at A1. For a summary of the available enforcement data, see Michael J. Wishnie, Pro- hibiting the Employment of Unauthorized Immigrants: The Experiment Fails, 2007 U. CHI. LE- GAL F. 193, 20911.
1980 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
spite draconian money laundering statutes, the bureaucratized federal justice system almost never prosecutes bankers or those who operate other apparently legitimate businesses. 39 These enforcement patterns are classic examples of capture: the industries that benefit the most from cheap immigrant labor have more clout than the mass of ordi- nary citizens who wish to see immigration laws enforced, just as banks have more influence than voters who want to see drug financing net- works destroyed. Were the justice system centrally controlled by apo- litical agencies like the FBI, 40 such examples would likely multiply. Likewise, bureaucrats tend to minimize effort, and maximize lei- sure. Drug cases in poor city neighborhoods are cheap for police and prosecutors; investigating and prosecuting drug crime in well-off sub- urbs is a good deal more expensive. 41 Were Americas justice system more bureaucratized, the disparities in drug enforcement might grow, not shrink. Of course, Americas justice system already is bureaucratized, but the most important bureaucracies police forces and district attor- neys offices are governed by local politics and politicians. That sounds like bad news if ones goal is a more egalitarian justice system. After all, for much of American history, the exaltation of local elector- ates was the creed of racists. Federal law Brown v. Board of Edu- cation, 42 the Civil Rights Act of 1964, 43 the Voting Rights Act of 1965 44 drove the legal movement for civil rights. State and local power were key sources of resistance to that movement. Surely local politics is the last place to look for egalitarian law enforcement. Yet local politics and politicians have two crucial advantages in this area. First, poor blacks are a larger fraction of urban electorates than of state or national voting populations. 45 Residents of poor, high-
39 That is the central claim of Mariano-Florentino Cullar, The Tenuous Relationship Between the Fight Against Money Laundering and the Disruption of Criminal Finance, 93 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 311 (2003). As Cullar notes, the money laundering statutes are often used to prosecute drug dealers, see, e.g., United States v. Rivera-Rodrguez, 318 F.3d 268 (1st Cir. 2003), and sometimes used to ratchet up the punishment of ordinary frauds, see, e.g., United States v. Trost, 152 F.3d 715 (7th Cir. 1998); United States v. Reynolds, 64 F.3d 292 (7th Cir. 1995). Re- cently, those statutes have been used to attack terrorism, with little success. See David Zaring & Elena Baylis, Sending the Bureaucracy to War, 92 IOWA L. REV. 1359, 140918 (2007). Rarely are money laundering statutes used for their intended purpose.
40 On the FBIs insulation from political oversight, see Daniel C. Richman, Federal Criminal Law, Congressional Delegation, and Enforcement Discretion, 46 UCLA L. REV. 757, 79396 (1999).
41 See William J. Stuntz, The Distribution of Fourth Amendment Privacy, 67 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1265, 128187 (1999) [hereinafter Stuntz, Fourth Amendment Privacy].
42 347 U.S. 483 (1954).
43 Pub. L. No. 88-352, 78 Stat. 241 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 28 and 42 U.S.C.).
44 Pub. L. No. 89-110, 79 Stat. 437 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 42 U.S.C.).
45 See sources cited supra note 9.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1981
crime neighborhoods should find it easy to join the governing coali- tions of their cities; wielding influence in state legislative hallways or on Capitol Hill is bound to be harder. 46 This point is especially impor- tant given the demographics of poverty in the United States. Gener- ally speaking, the white poor are dispersed, not concentrated. Outside the South, the black poor are concentrated, not dispersed, and the largest concentrations are in cities. 47 Giving cities less power over criminal justice, and giving state and national governments more, means shifting power from urban blacks to suburban whites: hardly a recipe for egalitarian criminal justice. The second advantage does not depend on the demographics of poverty or race; it applies as much to rich white suburbs as to poor black neighborhoods in large cities. With respect to crime and crimi- nal punishment, residents of all neighborhoods have two warring in- centives. On the one hand, they want safe streets on which to walk and drive and go about their business; they want to travel to parks and sporting events and grocery stores without fearing for their lives and property. On the other hand, they are loath to incarcerate their sons and brothers, neighbors and friends. The desire for order and the longing for freedom, anger at crime and empathy for the young men whom police officers arrest and prosecutors charge both forces are powerful, and they push in opposite directions. Anyone who has been the victim of a serious crime knows the desire to see perpetrators pun- ished that seems to be part of our nature. 48 At the same time, all those who have seen neighbors sons, or their own, behind bars know the
46 A decade ago, Dan Kahan and Tracey Meares noted this fact and its implications for the portions of constitutional criminal procedure that regulate policing. See Dan M. Kahan & Tracey L. Meares, Foreword: The Coming Crisis of Criminal Procedure, 86 GEO. L.J. 1153 (1998). Ka- han and Meares were right but their point extends farther. Not just Fourth and Fifth Amend- ment law, but constitutional law generally regulates local law enforcement agencies more strin- gently than state and federal ones. Yet the groups whose interests constitutional law allegedly protects minorities and the poor have more political power over local governments than over state and national ones.
47 For news stories noting this pattern in three metropolitan areas, see Kiljoong Kim, Where Do Chicagos Poor White People Live?, BEACHWOOD REP. (Chicago), Sept. 11, 2006, http://www. beachwoodreporter.com/politics/where_chicagos_poor_white_peop.php; Christopher Tidmore, Public Housing Redevelopment Sparks Multi-City Protest and Lawsuit, LA. WKLY. (New Or- leans), July 3, 2006, at 1, available at http://www.louisianaweekly.com/weekly/news/articlegate. pl?20060703b; Margery Austin Turner, Segregation by the Numbers, WASH. POST, May 18, 1997, at C3. For a brief discussion of the more general pattern, see, for example, David R. Williams, Poverty, Racism, and Migration: The Health of the African American Population, in RACE, POV- ERTY, AND DOMESTIC POLICY 311, 32022 (C. Michael Henry ed., 2004). For evidence of the much higher levels of concentrated poverty in the African American population, see BISHAW, su- pra note 9, at 8 fig.4.
48 See, e.g., WENDY KAMINER, ITS ALL THE RAGE: CRIME AND CULTURE (1995) (dis- cussing the link between capital punishment and popular rage at crime and criminals).
1982 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
agony incarceration imposes on local communities. 49 Local political control over criminal justice harnesses both forces, without giving precedence to either. The balance between those warring incentives looks quite different when power over criminal punishment is given to voters and officials outside the communities where crimes happen and punishment is im- posed. Anger and empathy alike are weaker forces when they come from voters who see crime on the evening news than when they flow from voters lived experience. When both forces are weak, small changes in either can produce large systemic consequences: no coun- tervailing force checks the trend toward more or less punishment. Ex- treme variation becomes the norm, stable equilibrium the exception. The system oscillates not between moderate levels of mercy and retri- bution, but between wholesale indifference and unmitigated rage. When that happens, we see what Americans have seen over the past fifty years unfathomable lenity, followed by unimaginable severity. B. Criminal Justice in the Gilded Age If the preceding discussion is right, criminal justice systems gov- erned by local politics should achieve more egalitarian results than jus- tice systems that are more centralized, legalized, and bureaucratized. That hypothesis sounds backward: after all, American criminal justice is governed by local politics unlike the rest of the world, we elect prosecutors and trial judges, and urban police forces are answerable to the elected mayors and council members who govern their cities. The results can hardly be called egalitarian. Yet the hypothesis is probably correct. Notwithstanding the role local politics plays in it, American criminal justice is more centralized, more legalized, and less locally democratic than first appears. The true test of the effect of local de- mocracy on criminal justice equality is not to be found in todays jus- tice system, but in the justice system of the Gilded Age: the half- century between the end of Reconstruction and the beginning of the Great Depression. Those fifty years are not known for their egalitarianism. The Gilded Age was the era of robber barons and sweatshops, a time when the power of the trusts dwarfed the clout of labor unions or govern- ment regulators. 50 In the world of legal doctrine, it was the age of constitutionalized laissez-faire, when any interference with business or
49 See BRUCE WESTERN, PUNISHMENT AND INEQUALITY IN AMERICA 85198 (2006).
50 For the classic view, see JACK BEATTY, AGE OF BETRAYAL: THE TRIUMPH OF MONEY IN AMERICA, 18651900 (2007); MATTHEW JOSEPHSON, THE ROBBER BARONS (1934). For more nuanced views of the era, see SEAN DENNIS CASHMAN, AMERICA IN THE GILDED AGE (3d ed. 1993); REBECCA EDWARDS, NEW SPIRITS: AMERICANS IN THE GILDED AGE, 1865 1905 (2006).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1983
any government effort to improve the lot of the poor risked judicial invalidation. 51 Last but certainly not least, it was an age when Jim Crows strange career began, when black voting in the South all but ceased and the grip of a second slavery grew steadily tighter. 52 Yet criminal justice was egalitarian far more so than in our own time, and probably more so than at any time in American history. These propositions did not hold true in the South, and probably did not hold true everywhere in the North. But in most Northern cities, policing, criminal litigation, and criminal punishment appear to have been both a good deal less discriminatory and a great deal more lenient toward poor and working-class offenders than today. The key to this surpris- ingly egalitarian justice system was local democracy. 1. The South. The justice system of the post-Reconstruction South was neither democratic nor egalitarian. Private terrorism played roles that well-funded law enforcement agencies played in the North; 53 the consequence was a strange mix of anarchy and authori- tarianism. Black crimes against whites were punished brutally, often without the niceties of due process. 54 White offenders who victimized blacks regularly went unpunished 55 and, frequently, so did black criminals who harmed other blacks. As the following table indicates, this anarchic social order was far from orderly. The table lists the policing and homicide rates police officers and murders per 100,000 population in three Northern and three Southern cities in the mid-1930s:
51 The sentence in the text describes the reality a bit too starkly. For a more nuanced discus- sion of Lochner-era doctrine, see HOWARD GILLMAN, THE CONSTITUTION BESIEGED: THE RISE AND DEMISE OF LOCHNER ERA POLICE POWERS JURISPRUDENCE (1993).
52 The classic treatment is the one from which the phrase in the text is borrowed. See C. VANN WOODWARD, THE STRANGE CAREER OF JIM CROW (3d rev. ed. 1974).
53 On the rise of that system of privatized terrorism and its victory over the federal govern- ments efforts to protect newly freed slaves, see ERIC FONER, RECONSTRUCTION: AMERICAS UNFINISHED REVOLUTION, 18631877 (1988); LOU FALKNER WILLIAMS, THE GREAT SOUTH CAROLINA KU KLUX KLAN TRIALS, 18711872 (1996). On the character of Jim Crow law enforcement, see JOHN DITTMER, BLACK GEORGIA IN THE PROGRESSIVE ERA, 1900 1920 (1977); NEIL R. MCMILLEN, DARK JOURNEY: BLACK MISSISSIPPIANS IN THE AGE OF JIM CROW (1990); HORTENSE POWDERMAKER, AFTER FREEDOM: A CULTURAL STUDY IN THE DEEP SOUTH app. D (1939).
54 The white Souths approach to legal process when prosecuting black defendants was com- plicated. The late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries saw lynching the ultimate rejection of legal procedure reach its peak. Later, the decades following World War I saw a marked trend toward adherence to legal forms, as Michael Klarman has noted. See Klarman, Racial Ori- gins, supra note 30, at 5558. Nevertheless, when black defendants were in the dock, white Southerners commitment to following the appropriate formal procedures was, in a word, formal: black defendants were routinely denied the practical benefits of the procedural rights that the Southern justice system pretended to honor. See id.
55 On the different treatment afforded the two different classes of interracial crime, see MI- CHAEL J. KLARMAN, FROM JIM CROW TO CIVIL RIGHTS: THE SUPREME COURT AND THE STRUGGLE FOR RACIAL EQUALITY 11735, 15258, 22532, 26786 (2004).
1984 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
TABLE 1. POLICING AND MURDER RATES IN 1937, SELECTED CITIES 56
City Policing Rate Murder Rate Boston 292 1.6 Detroit 238 4.6 New York 251 4.5 Atlanta 125 39.3 Houston 98 21.3 Memphis 93 12.8
These figures capture a key reality of law enforcement in the pre air conditioning, precivil rights South: the regions poverty. All gov- ernment services were underfunded by comparison to the wealthier Northeast and Midwest. 57 That fact left Southern cities with fewer police officers to contain crime than in the North, and with more crime to contain. 58
Underfunded Southern law enforcement agencies mostly ignored black neighborhoods, which led to racially skewed crime data like those reported in Hortense Powdermakers study of Mississippi homi- cides in the 1930s. 59 Three-fourths of the states murder victims were black, as were two-thirds of the killers. White killers victims were ra- cially mixed: 63% white, 37% black. By comparison, nineteen of every twenty black killers killed black victims. Punishment rates were low by our standards, but aside from black-victim cases, they were very high by comparison with Northern cities in the same period. 60 One-
56 All rates in the Tables are per 100,000 population. The numbers of homicides and urban police officers are taken from UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1937, supra note 8, at 19799 tbl.108; and UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1938, supra note 8, at 71 tbl.51, respectively. For the cities populations, see 1941 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 2728 tbl.30.
57 As long ago as 1855, Bostons policing rate stood at 153 per 100,000. See ROGER LANE, POLICING THE CITY: BOSTON 18221885, at app. III (1967) [hereinafter LANE, POLICING THE CITY]. A century later, Houstons policing rate was less than two-thirds of that figure 96 per 100,000. See 1961 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 16 tbl.10; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1956, supra note 8, at 29 tbl.13. Rates are calculated using city populations extrapo- lated from those of the nearest decades.
58 Today, the wealth gap between North and South has narrowed considerably and so have the gaps in murder and policing rates. In 2005, Atlanta had a higher policing rate than either Boston or Detroit, and a significantly lower homicide rate than Detroit. See CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2005, supra note 8, tbls.8, 78.
59 The data cited in the text appear in POWDERMAKER, supra note 53, at app. D.
60 In late-nineteenth- and early-twentieth-century Chicago, a mere 22% of homicide cases ended in conviction. JEFFREY S. ADLER, FIRST IN VIOLENCE, DEEPEST IN DIRT: HOMI- CIDE IN CHICAGO, 18751920, at 11516 (2006). Given the large number of black-victim cases and the low levels of law enforcement in black neighborhoods, it seems likely that well over half of Mississippis white-victim cases led to conviction and punishment.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1985
third of the murders Powdermaker studied led to criminal convictions, and that figure undoubtedly differed depending on the races of killers and, especially, victims. Killers of whites could expect a serious effort at arrest, prosecution, and punishment. Killers of blacks white ones to be sure, but many black killers as well were more likely to escape detection. That is why prison populations in the Jim Crow South were almost certainly whiter than the offender population, and sometimes whiter than the general population. 61
Poverty fed inequality. Egalitarian law enforcement requires the money needed to pay for it, and Southern governments found it harder to raise revenue than their Northern counterparts. Crime rates were much higher in the South than in the North partly because Southern criminals faced lower odds of detection than Northern ones which in turn was partly due to small budgets for Southern law enforcement agencies. The undemocratic character of Southern government rein- forced these tendencies. Not only were blacks barred from voting throughout the Jim Crow South; in many places, so were poor whites. 62 Thus, the portions of the population that suffered the most from both crime and criminal punishment were frozen out of political power. 63 Naturally, equal justice was in short supply. The Gilded Age South more nearly resembled a weak authoritarian state, able to do lit- tle save for oppressing blacks, than any form of democracy we know today. Jim Crows history does not support the proposition that local democracy promotes egalitarian criminal justice, but neither does it negate that proposition.
61 In 1950, South Carolinas population was nearly 40% black, 1953 STATISTICAL AB- STRACT, supra note 1, at 36 tbl.25, yet more than two-thirds of the states imprisoned felons were white. See FED. BUREAU OF PRISONS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, NATIONAL PRISONER STA- TISTICS: PRISONERS IN STATE AND FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS: 1950, at 55 tbl.21. According to the same sources, in the eleven states of the old Confederacy except Georgia (for which data are missing), 44% of imprisoned felons were black, compared to 24% of the general population. By comparison, in the Northeast, 29% of prisoners were black, compared to only 5% of the general population. The conclusion is inescapable: Jim Crow held the black imprisonment rate down.
62 The poll tax, common in most of the South during the first half of the twentieth century, was the most obvious means of biracial disenfranchisement but not the only one. For the classic discussion, see V.O. KEY, JR., SOUTHERN POLITICS IN STATE AND NATION 578618 (1949). The effect of those restrictions on white turnout rates was dramatic. See J. MORGAN KOUSSER, THE SHAPING OF SOUTHERN POLITICS: SUFFRAGE RESTRICTION AND THE ESTABLISH- MENT OF THE ONE-PARTY SOUTH 18801910, at 22431 (1974).
63 Since the 1930s, the Southern state with the highest ratio of police officers to population has been Louisiana which, thanks to Huey Long, is also the state with the strongest political tradi- tion of government officials competing for the votes of the poor. In 1937, New Orleans had 175 police employees per 100,000 population, see UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1938, supra note 8, at 71 tbl.51; 1942 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 27 tbl.25 far higher than the rate in other Southern cities, see supra p. 1984 (Table 1). Today, Louisiana has the highest policing rate in the nation. Its neighbors Mississippi, Arkansas, and Texas are all in the bottom half of state policing rates. See CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2006, supra note 8, tbls.77, 78.
1986 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
2. Northern Cities. Northern cities were far less discriminatory, as three pieces of evidence suggest. First, criminal defendants in the demographic groups most likely to suffer discrimination women, blacks, and poor immigrants seem to have achieved litigation out- comes nearly as good as the outcomes native-born white men achieved. Second, imprisonment rates were stable: in an age of great social and political change, prison populations neither exploded nor collapsed. Third, those populations varied remarkably little across jurisdictional boundaries; differences in population-adjusted imprisonment rates were much smaller than in the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. Begin with the treatment of what would now be called suspect classes. In the early 1900s, no one had heard of battered womans syndrome; east of the Mississippi River, women could not yet vote. 64
Even so, more than 80% of Chicago women who killed their husbands escaped punishment among white women, the figure topped 90% thanks to the new unwritten law permitting women to defend themselves on the same terms as men. 65 This law consisted mostly of jury preferences, but the preferences were clear enough to lead the local States Attorney to opine that a wife may murder her husband in Cook County with impunity. 66 A half-century before the womens movement transformed the law of self-defense, female defendants were achieving the results the movement sought without the help of the le- gal and medical arguments on which their late-twentieth-century sis- ters relied. 67
As historian Jeffrey Adler notes, black women who killed their husbands fared worse, probably due to a combination of race and sex biases. 68 The existence of such biases is no surprise. What is surpris- ing is the weakness of the racial bias in Northern cities in the Gilded Age. After an exhaustive study of early-twentieth-century Philadel- phia homicides, Roger Lane concluded that black murder defendants did about as well as white ones:
64 See ANNE F. SCOTT & ANDREW M. SCOTT, ONE HALF THE PEOPLE: THE FIGHT FOR WOMAN SUFFRAGE 16668 (1975). Illinois granted women a limited right to vote in 1913. See SHERNA BERGER GLUCK, FROM PARLOR TO PRISON: FIVE AMERICAN SUFFRAGISTS TALK ABOUT THEIR LIVES 297 (1985); SCOTT & SCOTT, supra, at 166.
65 ADLER, supra note 60, at 112. Even if one counts only white women who were arrested for homicide, a mere 11% were convicted. Id. at 329 n.141. On the character and power of the un- written law, see id. at 10817.
66 Id. at 112 (internal quotation mark omitted).
67 Favorable results were not limited to self-defense claims. Women who murdered their chil- dren, a surprisingly common scenario in turn-of-the-century Chicago, were almost never prose- cuted. See id. at 9299.
68 See id. at 15355. Black child-killers either did not exist or were ignored by the authorities. Id. at 15253.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1987
While Philadelphia was . . . the northernmost of southern cities, . . . [the citys justice system] seems to have been largely free of systematic preju- dice in determining guilt or innocence. Elderly black men and women, survivors of The Great Migration north in the era of World War I and after, recall the justice system as essentially fair. . . . [I]n most identifiable measures of discrimination, such as degree of charge and conviction rate, neither blacks nor those with Italian [surnames] seem to have differed sig- nificantly from others brought to the dock. 69
The early twentieth century saw the beginnings of the mass migration of Southern blacks to Northern cities, prompting bloody race riots and a resurgent Ku Klux Klan as strong in parts of the North as in the South. Even so, Northern cities treatment of black defendants ap- pears to have been essentially fair. The famous story of Ossian Sweet captures the phenomenon. Sweet was a black doctor who had the audacity to buy a house in a white Detroit neighborhood in 1925. A white mob surrounded his house and shots were fired from inside, where several of Sweets rela- tives and friends were armed. One of the shots killed a white neighbor. All eleven people in the house, including Sweet and his wife, were charged with murder. 70 Clarence Darrow took the case and ar- gued self-defense, invoking the long history of violence against blacks by white mobs. The case was tried twice, both times to all-white ju- ries; 71 in his closing arguments, Darrow questioned whether white ju- rors could fairly judge black defendants charged with doing violence to a white man. The first jury hung; the second acquitted. 72 The judge in both trials was Frank Murphy, who went on to become Mayor of Detroit and Governor of Michigan before Franklin D. Roo- sevelt appointed him to head the Justice Department, and later to the Supreme Court. 73 Notice: a black man was acquitted of killing a white man by an all-white jury, in a case in which the victim was un- armed and the defense all but admitted the killing. The judge who
69 Roger Lane, On the Social Meaning of Homicide Trends in America, in 1 VIOLENCE IN AMERICA 55, 7071 (Ted Robert Gurr ed., 1989) [hereinafter Lane, Homicide Trends]; see also ROGER LANE, ROOTS OF VIOLENCE IN BLACK PHILADELPHIA, 18601900 (1986) [hereinafter LANE, BLACK PHILADELPHIA].
70 See KEVIN BOYLE, ARC OF JUSTICE: A SAGA OF RACE, CIVIL RIGHTS, AND MURDER IN THE JAZZ AGE 2043, 19394 (2004) (discussing Sweets background and the events surround- ing the house purchase, the shooting, and the filing of criminal charges).
71 Id. at 266, 316.
72 In the first trial, all eleven defendants were tried; in the second trial, Ossian Sweets brother Henry believed to be the shooter was tried alone. Id. at 29299, 33136.
73 One of Murphys biographers reports that the trial was the most intense emotional experi- ence of his life. RICHARD D. LUNT, THE HIGH MINISTRY OF GOVERNMENT: THE POLITI- CAL CAREER OF FRANK MURPHY 26 (1965).
1988 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
presided over the case was rewarded for that outcome, not punished. 74
To anyone familiar with American criminal litigation in the last thirty years, the story sounds wildly implausible. Black defendants like Sweet did not avoid conviction because they lived in racially enlightened times: a Klan rally in nearby Dearborn, Michigan in 1924 drew upwards of fifty thousand. 75 Rather, black defendants benefited from the fact that all defendants fared better than their counterparts today. Adler notes that a mere 22% of turn-of- the-century Chicago homicides led to criminal convictions. 76 In Ala- meda County, California in the same era, fewer than 60% of felony tri- als ended in conviction; in cases in which defendants made bail, the conviction rate fell below 30%. 77 Comparable figures today are much higher. 78 Turn-of-the-century defendants success rates were even bet- ter than appears from the figures just cited, because many fewer criminal defendants pled guilty a century ago than today. In metro- politan counties today, 65% of felony cases end with a guilty plea, and those pleas represent 95% of felony convictions. 79 In turn-of-the- century Alameda County, the analogous figures were 41% and 63%, respectively 80 and the figures in the Northeast and Midwest were probably a good deal lower. 81 In todays justice system, felony trials are rare events, acquittals rarer still. In Northern cities a century ago, both trials and acquittals were common. Women and blacks fared
74 Murphy later lost an election due to his stance on crime, but it was not black crime that prompted his defeat. In 1938, Murphy was running for reelection as Michigans Governor; his lenient treatment of sit-down strikers in automobile factories was a major issue, and Murphy lost in a close race. See id. at 15160. In late 1930s America, being seen as soft on industrial labor unions carried a higher political price tag than acquitting black criminals.
75 BOYLE, supra note 70, at 142. For a discussion of the Klans role in Detroit politics at the time, see id. at 24, 14043.
76 ADLER, supra note 60, at 11516.
77 See LAWRENCE M. FRIEDMAN & ROBERT V. PERCIVAL, THE ROOTS OF JUSTICE: CRIME AND PUNISHMENT IN ALAMEDA COUNTY, CALIFORNIA 18701910, at 166 tbl.5.8 (1981).
78 More than 80% of murder arrests in metropolitan counties lead to conviction. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.57.2002. In felony cases that go to trial, the conviction rate is 75%. Id.
79 Id.
80 See FRIEDMAN & PERCIVAL, supra note 77, at 166 tbl.5.8.
81 Guilty pleas play no part in Adlers account of Chicago homicide cases partly because pleas make less interesting stories, but probably also because pleas were less common in the Northeast and Midwest than on the West Coast. Throughout this period, Californias imprison- ment rate was double that of most states in the Northeast and Midwest. See CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3. Criminal convictions must have been more numerous in California than in the nations Northeastern quadrant, and guilty pleas are an efficient litigation tool for prosecutors who must convict large numbers of criminal defendants.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1989
well in that older justice system because defendants as a whole fared well. 82
A large fraction of the many acquittals in this period were won by defendants from poor or working-class immigrant communities. Adlers book about violence in turn-of-the-century Chicago is a com- pendium of stories of homicides by that citys immigrant poor, who needed no Clarence Darrow to win their cases: vague, generic self- defense arguments . . . nearly always persuaded jurors. 83 Bar fights, disputes over card games, and drunken brawls regularly produced de- fense victories. Those victories rarely flowed from doubts about the killers identity. 84 Rather, Adlers Chicago juries were exercising pow- ers of moral evaluation 85 powers the substantive law of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries vested in fact finders, not just in legislatures and appellate courts. Acquittals of working-class white immigrants may seem less sur- prising than victories by husband-killing white women and homicidal black men. But white immigrants of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries held a lower political status than twenty-first- century Americans might suppose. The bulk of the immigration in this period came from Southern and Eastern Europe; Catholics and Jews were a larger fraction of immigrants than in the past. 86 Both groups were subject to substantial religious prejudice, a major factor in the Klans rise during the 1920s. 87 In context, the success of the poor immigrants Adler discusses is almost as remarkable as the suc- cesses enjoyed by women and blacks.
82 Adler explicitly makes the link with respect to women. ADLER, supra note 60, at 11516. Taken together, his evidence and Roger Lanes analysis suggest the same conclusion with respect to black defendants as well. See supra note 69 and accompanying text.
83 ADLER, supra note 60, at 116.
84 See, e.g., id. at 637 (discussing the many Chicago homicides that arose from drunken brawls in public places in front of dozens of witnesses).
85 Much like the seventeenth- and eighteenth-century English juries that are the subject of JAMES Q. WHITMAN, THE ORIGINS OF REASONABLE DOUBT: THEOLOGICAL ROOTS OF THE CRIMINAL TRIAL (2008) [hereinafter WHITMAN, REASONABLE DOUBT]. Like turn-of- the-century Chicago juries, English juries of centuries past tended to resolve doubts in favor of acquittal; as in old Chicago, those doubts often had more to do with moral desert than with the facts of the case at hand. See id. at 159200; see also ROGER LANE, VIOLENT DEATH IN THE CITY: SUICIDE, ACCIDENT, AND MURDER IN NINETEENTH-CENTURY PHILADELPHIA 66 (2d ed. 1999) [hereinafter LANE, VIOLENT DEATH IN THE CITY] (Philadelphia juries were usually quite tolerant of assaultive behavior and were always greatly influenced by moral or so- cial rather than purely legal considerations.).
86 JOHN HIGHAM, STRANGERS IN THE LAND: PATTERNS OF AMERICAN NATIVISM, 18601925, at 6467 (rev. ed. 2002).
87 Id. at 28586, 29094. Politicians and some scholars argued that Southern and Eastern Europeans belonged to a different race than immigrants of the past; fears of inundation by immi- grants of inferior racial stock were common. Id. at 13157.
1990 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
Nationwide data on litigation outcomes do not exist for this period. Still, what little evidence we have tends to confirm the proposition that, outside the South, Adlers Chicago and Lanes Philadelphia rep- resent the rule, not the exception. The key evidence comes from the combination of imprisonment rates and homicide rates, which suggest that criminal punishment was both stable and moderately lenient throughout the relevant period. Table 2 presents the murder rate, the imprisonment rate, and the number of prisoner-years per murder in 1904, 1910, and at ten-year intervals beginning in 1923. Under each heading, the first figure is the rate for New York, using New York Citys murder rate and New York states imprisonment rate, while the second figure is the rate for the nation as a whole. 88
TABLE 2. CRIME AND PUNISHMENT IN NEW YORK AND IN THE UNITED STATES 89
88 For New York, the figure on prisoner-years per murder is only a rough approximation, be- cause the murder rate is the citys and the imprisonment rate is the states. States, not cities, run Americas penitentiary system, so city-level imprisonment data are, for the most part, nonexistent.
89 Through 1973, both New Yorks homicide rate and the nations are taken from data and estimates collected by the late Eric Monkkonen and used in ERIC H. MONKKONEN, MURDER IN NEW YORK CITY (2001). The data are available through the National Archive of Criminal Justice Data, at http://www.icpsr.umich.edu/cocoon/NACJD/STUDY/03226.xml. After 1973, homicide rates are taken from the relevant volumes of the UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS, supra note 8. Imprisonment rates up to 1923 come from CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3. Subse- quent imprisonment rates for the United States as a whole come from ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006. New Yorks imprisonment rates from 1933 to 1963 are taken from the relevant volumes of the STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1; later rates appear in 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72; and ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006. To calculate prisoner-years per murder, I divided the imprisonment rate by the murder rate.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1991
New Yorks murder rate was lower in the early twentieth century than today, 90 while its prison population was a small fraction of to- days. Moderate punishment coexisted with modest levels of criminal violence. And the punishment was moderate: substantially more se- vere than in the 1970s, far more lenient than today. Neither impris- onment rates nor punishment per unit crime changed dramatically in the early 1900s; levels of criminal punishment were relatively stable. 91
Not so in the centurys last forty years, when murders nearly quadru- pled before falling sharply, imprisonment quintupled, and prisoner- years per murder fell by more than 90%, then multiplied fourteen times. Instability suggests inconsistency the same crimes received very different treatment at different times. Early-twentieth-century criminal punishment appears to have been more consistent. New York was typical. In the last half of the twentieth century, imprisonment rates varied massively throughout the Northeast and Midwest, both over time and between jurisdictions. 92 States in those regions incarcerated similar (and similarly low) percentages of their populations in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, sug- gesting that the patterns Adler and Lane discovered in Chicago and Philadelphia were typical of their regions. Other regions differed: Southern prison populations varied more widely, both over time and across jurisdictional boundaries as Table 3 shows. The table re- cords the imprisonment rates per 100,000 population for two sets of five neighboring states, North and South:
90 Much lower: a large fraction of the homicides of generations past would not be so classified today, because high-quality emergency medical care would save the victims lives. JAMES Q. WILSON, THINKING ABOUT CRIME 16 (rev. ed., Vintage Books 1985) (1975).
91 The era of stable imprisonment rates ended in the 1930s, with the first of Americas two twentieth-century punitive turns. Imprisonment peaked at 137 per 100,000 in 1939, followed by a sharp drop as millions of young men were drafted into the army. See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006.
Notice that the lowest and highest imprisonment rates come from the South along with the largest ranges of variation. Alabamas rate quintupled and North Carolinas fell by almost two-thirds; none of the Northern states imprisonment rates varied by as much as 40% in either direction. Southern criminal justice, which was designed for inequality, produced highly variable prison populations. Inmate popu- lations in the North were far more stable, and what little evidence we have suggests surprisingly low levels of discrimination against vulner- able groups. 94 Variation and discrimination seem to travel together. So do stability and equality, perhaps joined by moderately lenient treatment for criminal defendants. Southern criminal justice systems had the former set of characteristics, Northern systems the latter. Why was Northern criminal justice both stable and relatively leni- ent? There are four related answers. First, Northern cities were well- policed, at least by the standards of the time. The reasons for the link between relatively high levels of policing and relatively low and stable punishment levels are unclear. But it seems increasingly plain that such a link exists. Today, jurisdictions with the most police officers
93 The figures in Table 3 are taken from CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3. Georgias im- prisonment rate in 1880 is unavailable.
94 The evidence goes beyond Adlers and Lanes studies. Data on sentences broken down by demographic group are nearly nonexistent for the early twentieth century, but data from mid- century support the picture painted in the text. Across the Northeast and Midwest, whites were punished more severely than blacks for murder and drug crime; blacks were punished more se- verely than whites for manslaughter, fraud, and rape. Overall, blacks served longer sentences, but not by a large margin. In the South, the median time served by white offenders was 18 months; for blacks, the median was 21 months. See FED. BUREAU OF PRISONS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, NATIONAL PRISONER STATISTICS: PRISONERS RELEASED FROM STATE AND FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS: 1952 AND 1953, at 32 tbl.7A. The chief difference between the re- gions was one that those data do not capture: the selection of cases for prosecution. Many more black-on-black crimes were prosecuted and punished in the North than in the South.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1993
tend to have the lowest imprisonment rates and the smallest rates of increase in imprisonment. 95 The same was true a century ago: cities in the Gilded Age South had much smaller police forces than their Northern counterparts; the South also saw both higher and more vari- able punishment levels than the North. 96 Those propositions are likely connected. Second, then-prevailing procedural rules made criminal trials cheap and therefore common. Because jury trials were more common than today, defense victories were bound to be more common as well. 97
Acquittals were less newsworthy, so prosecutors paid a smaller politi- cal price for them and were less eager to avoid them than today. Note the logic: less elaborate trial procedures helped defendants not the government by making both trials and acquittals more ordinary events. Third, substantive criminal law was both less clearly defined and more favorable to defendants than todays legal doctrine. Defendants rarely have occasion to challenge the application of todays bright-line criminal liability rules, in large part because those rules seem designed to foreclose defense arguments. That was not the case a century ago. Statutory conduct terms, mens rea standards, and affirmative defenses all invited such arguments rather than foreclosing them. When the terms of criminal statutes were insufficiently hospitable to such argu- ments, courts filled the gap through common lawmaking. An example makes the point. Like many of its neighbors, Michigan passed a local- option law banning liquor in counties that approved the ban; to dis- courage evasion, the legislature forbade not only selling alcoholic bev- erages but also giving them away. The Michigan Supreme Court soon established a defense for those who served liquor in their homes as an exercise of a decent hospitality to their guests. 98 Analogous doctrines in todays law of controlled substances (the analogue to early- twentieth-century liquor laws) are unimaginable. Such doctrines were everywhere in the criminal law of the Gilded Age. Another Michigan doctrine held that mutual fights in which both sides were willing participants were not crimes. 99 According to the
95 William J. Stuntz, Accountable Policing 4546 & tbl.3 (2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Harvard Law School Library). The data used are taken from CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2004, supra note 8, tbls.8, 78; and ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2004.
96 See supra p. 1984 (Table 1), p. 1992 (Table 3).
97 See supra notes 7681 and accompanying text.
98 The quoted phrase is from People v. Bedell, 127 N.W. 33, 36 (Mich. 1910) (Ostrander, J., concurring); the leading case for the doctrine in question was People v. Peterson, 120 N.W. 570 (Mich. 1909).
99 See People v. Yund, 128 N.W. 742, 744 (Mich. 1910). For a decision rejecting the doctrine, see People v. Sherman, 166 N.W.2d 22 (Mich. Ct. App. 1968).
1994 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
common law definition used in most states, burglary defendants could prevail if the targeted place was not a dwelling, if the break-in did not happen at night, or if the defendant formed the intent to commit a fel- ony only after going inside. 100 Rape defendants won if their victims failed to resist with all their might. 101 Proof of mens rea meant proof of moral fault, not just the intent to carry out ones physical actions. 102
In the late twentieth century, self-defense doctrine seemed to bar de- fenses for battered women who killed their batterers. 103 The less doc- trinally developed version of the defense that applied in early- twentieth-century Chicago awarded victory not only to abused women, but to virtually any homicide defendant who could offer a better rea- son for his or her crime than greed or hatred. 104 With open- ended doctrines like these, criminal trials were genuine morality plays, with jurors serving as both judge and Greek chorus. Jurors went well beyond determining witnesses credibility: 105 they were moral arbiters, assessing both the propriety of defendants conduct and the propriety of punishing it. As Jim Whitman has shown, in English legal history, that open- ended power to pass judgment and to assign blame was long associ- ated with lenity. 106 Likewise in Gilded Age America: local juries hesi- tated to send their neighbors to prison when the law offered multiple ways to avoid doing so. Surprisingly, lenity and predictability seem to have coincided. The unwritten law excusing wives who killed abu- sive husbands, the pattern of acquittals for bar fights that escalated to homicide, the unofficial defense granted automobile drivers in cases of vehicular homicide 107 because of their consistency, these patterns
100 See, e.g., People v. Sparks, 47 P.3d 289, 293 (Cal. 2002) (describing traditional common law definition).
101 See Susan Estrich, Rape, 95 YALE L.J. 1087, 110521 (1986) (discussing cases).
102 Chief Justice Tafts opinion in United States v. Balint, 258 U.S. 250 (1922) a case in which proof of moral fault was not required makes the point. Balint was charged with violat- ing the Harrison Act; his only possible defense was that he did not know the conditions the Act placed on drug sales. Taft reasoned that Congress weighed the possible injustice of subjecting an innocent seller to a penalty against the evil of exposing innocent purchasers to danger from the drug, and concluded that the latter was the result preferably to be avoided. Id. at 254. His opin- ion makes sense only on the assumption that moral blameworthiness was a prerequisite for crimi- nal liability: that, save for a few unusual cases, the government must prove the defendant knew enough about the relevant facts and law to render his behavior culpable.
103 See, e.g., Kit Kinports, Defending Battered Womens Self-Defense Claims, 67 OR. L. REV. 393 (1988).
104 See ADLER, supra note 60, passim.
105 Cf. George Fisher, The Jurys Rise as Lie Detector, 107 YALE L.J. 575 (1997).
106 So much so that the beyond-a-reasonable-doubt standard of proof was needed to reassure reluctant eighteenth-century English jurors that they could convict plainly guilty defendants without jeopardizing their souls. See WHITMAN, REASONABLE DOUBT, supra note 85, at 125 200.
107 See ADLER, supra note 60, at 21112.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1995
amounted to the functional equivalent of legal doctrine. 108 Perhaps consistency flowed from transparency: these unwritten legal standards emerged from public trials, not behind-closed-doors plea bargains. The fourth answer follows naturally from the first three: political control over policing and prosecution was in the hands of the same groups who were most often victimized by and charged with serious crime. Big-city police forces were governed by big-city political ma- chines that in turn relied on the votes of the working-class immigrants whose streets most needed patrolling. 109 Officers were not so much professional law enforcers as holders of patronage jobs, rewards for the machines supporters. 110 They lived in the same communities as the young men they arrested, attended the same churches, depended on the same networks for help when hardship struck. Urban machines likewise selected the district attorneys who prosecuted criminal cases and the judges who tried those cases. Last but not least, working-class voters exercised power in the jury box as well as the ballot box. The common law vicinage requirement held that the jury was to be se- lected from the community in which the crime happened. 111 The norm today is county-wide selection 112 and because most metropoli- tan counties include vast suburbs, high-crime city neighborhoods have little control over the juries that try crimes committed on their streets. Before the rise of the automobile, more localized selection practices
108 That is one reason why government officials objected to these patterns so strenuously. See id. at 112, 21215.
109 See, e.g., M. Craig Brown & Barbara D. Warner, Immigrants, Urban Politics, and Policing in 1900, 57 AM. SOC. REV. 293 (1992) (showing strong negative correlation between machine con- trol of city politics and the level of arrests for alcohol-related offenses). The one major city with both a high level of machine control and a high level of alcohol arrests was Philadelphia, in which the political machine was Republican and relied on native-born voters for its support. Id. at 301 & tbl.2. Elsewhere, the reigning machines Republican and Democratic alike depended on immigrant votes, and generally avoided strict enforcement of alcohol regulations.
110 See ROBERT M. FOGELSON, BIG-CITY POLICE 1722 (1977); Mark Haller, Historical Roots of Police Behavior: Chicago, 18901925, in 5 CRIME AND JUSTICE IN AMERICAN HIS- TORY: POLICING AND CRIME CONTROL 244 (Eric H. Monkkonen ed., 1992); Eugene J. Watts, The Police in Atlanta, 18901905, in 5 CRIME AND JUSTICE IN AMERICAN HISTORY: POLIC- ING AND CRIME CONTROL, supra, at 908. Cf. LANE, POLICING THE CITY, supra note 57, at 213 (noting the difficulty upper-class Republicans in Boston had in controlling the local police force even when they won local elections).
111 For the standard historical discussion, see William Wirt Blume, The Place of Trial of Crimi- nal Cases: Constitutional Vicinage and Venue, 43 MICH. L. REV. 59 (1944). Custom, not law, de- termined the size of the community. In England, locally selected juries were a functional neces- sity, since local knowledge informed jury decisionmaking. Steven A. Engel, The Publics Vicinage Right: A Constitutional Argument, 75 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1658, 1674 (2000). Local knowl- edge was still an important part of jury decisions in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centu- ries. The limits of urban transportation and the necessities of urban machine politics pushed in the same direction. But these forces shaped the practice of jury selection, not its legal form. Con- sequently, evidence of particular selection practices is hard to come by.
112 See Engel, supra note 111, at 1705 n.242.
1996 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
were probably the norm: 113 would-be jurors could not easily transport themselves across large metropolitan counties. Nowhere was the power of local democracy more evident than in battles over vice. Between 1870 and 1930, Americans fought a series of vice wars: against pornography, 114 gambling, 115 prostitution, 116 nar- cotics 117 and, above all, alcohol. 118 As in the late twentieth centurys drug war, these vice crusades invariably led to state and federal legis- lation seeking to stamp out the relevant markets. The similarity ends there. In todays drug war, offenders face sentences far more severe than anything bootleggers or pimps faced eighty or a hundred years ago. State and federal drug laws have been enforced most aggressively in poor city neighborhoods. 119 Enforcement of late-nineteenth- and early-twentieth-century vice laws in Northern cities was usually lax and often nonexistent. 120 (In the South, such laws were often enforced disproportionately against blacks. 121 ) In the one field in which federal law battled for control over criminal justice, local officials fought back, usually taking the side of the working-class populations that indulged
113 This proposition is surprisingly hard to support, because records of jury selection practices in the past are thin. For a rare discussion of the scope of the community from which urban juries were actually drawn in generations past, see People v. Jones, 510 P.2d 705 (Cal. 1973), which ad- dressed jury selection under the Los Angeles system of judicial districts.
114 See DONNA I. DENNIS, THE RISE OF AMERICAN EROTICA: PRODUCING AND POLIC- ING PORNOGRAPHY IN NINETEENTH-CENTURY NEW YORK (forthcoming 2009) (manuscript at ch. 7, on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
115 See David Skeel & William J. Stuntz, The Puzzling History of the Criminal Law of Gam- bling (2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
116 There were two different battles against prostitution. The first was fought locally, where occasional crusades prompted backlash from the silent army of customers, LAWRENCE M. FRIEDMAN, CRIME AND PUNISHMENT IN AMERICAN HISTORY 331 (1993), leading to a re- turn to quiet tolerance. See Haller, supra note 110, at 257 (describing lax enforcement in turn-of- the-century Chicago). The second battle was the federal drive to stamp out the so-called white slave traffic. See, e.g., Mara L. Keire, The Vice Trust: A Reinterpretation of the White Slavery Scare in the United States, 19071917, 35 J. SOC. HIST. 5 (2001).
117 For the best discussion of the crusade against opium that took hold in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, see GEORGE FISHER, MARRIED TO ALCOHOL: THE DRUG WARS MORAL ROOTS (forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at chs. 78, on file with the Harvard Law School Library) [hereinafter FISHER, MARRIED TO ALCOHOL].
118 See, e.g., EDWARD BEHR, PROHIBITION: THIRTEEN YEARS THAT CHANGED AMER- ICA (1996); FISHER, MARRIED TO ALCOHOL, supra note 117; DAVID E. KYVIG, REPEALING NATIONAL PROHIBITION (2d ed., Kent State Univ. Press 2000) (1979).
119 Proving that the laws have been more aggressively enforced in the poorer sections of cities is difficult, perhaps impossible though the demographics of the drug defendant population sug- gest as much. For evidence that drug defendants are disproportionately poor, see HARLOW, supra note 10, at 5 tbl.7. For evidence that drug defendants are disproportionately black, see supra notes 45 and accompanying text. Finally, for evidence that the black population is both poorer and more urbanized than the white population, see supra note 9.
120 See BEHR, supra note 118, at 17593 (discussing lack of enforcement in Chicago); MICHAEL A. LERNER, DRY MANHATTAN: PROHIBITION IN NEW YORK CITY 16070 (2007) (discussing local opposition to enforcement in New York).
121 See MARTHA BENSLEY BRUERE, DOES PROHIBITION WORK? 11213 (1927).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1997
in the relevant vices. The lenient locals won most of those battles against their more severe federal and state adversaries. In the larger and more important realms of violent felonies and felony thefts, local control was unchallenged. II. THE RISE OF INEQUALITY The power of high-crime city neighborhoods over criminal justice in those neighborhoods fell sharply during the course of the twentieth centurys second half. Rising suburban populations exercised more power over local elections than in the past; city voters exercised less. Entrepreneurial national politicians discovered that they could use ur- ban crime to win votes not in cities, but in suburbs and small towns. The constitutionalization of criminal procedure and the combined ex- pansion and growing specificity of substantive criminal law have, taken together, made prosecutors more powerful and local juries less so. Todays professionalized urban police forces have left officers de- tached from the neighborhoods they serve. The trends just described arose precisely when black neighbor- hoods became the focus of criminal justice in Northern cities. That combination was bound to produce more racial inequality and injus- tice. Other crime and policing trends reinforced that sad result. As urban violence escalated, police clearance rates for violent felonies plummeted and large illegal drug markets arose, in poor city neighborhoods as elsewhere. Beginning in the 1970s, lawmakers, po- lice officers, and prosecutors alike began to use drug prosecutions as an indirect means of attacking urban violence. That misguided substi- tution fed rising inequality. The federal government should have miti- gated that trend but instead aggravated it, by enacting draconian fed- eral sentencing rules that local prosecutors could use to induce favorable (from prosecutors point of view) plea bargains. Had the federal government made less law and spent more money on local po- licing, the trend might have been very different. But federal police spending has been light, while substantive lawmaking has been heavy. The predictable consequence has been more criminal punishment, more unequally distributed. A. Local Democracys Decline Three pairs of trends led to the demise of the locally democratic criminal justice systems of the Gilded Age. The first pair began in the 1930s and 1940s: the rise of the symbolic politics of crime and the con- sequent expansion of state and federal criminal liability. The second pair of trends took hold after World War II: the growing geographic concentration of violent crime in poor black neighborhoods in North- ern cities, and the coincident growth of white suburbs surrounding those cities. The third pair of trends a legal change and the politi-
1998 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
cal response to it arose in the 1960s, and picked up steam in the decades that followed. The legal change was the constitutionalization of criminal procedure. The political response was the bidding war that broke out beginning in the late 1960s between politicians on the right and those on the left, as the two sides sought the votes of blue- collar whites by vying to see who could punish black crime most se- verely. Each of these trends reduced the power of urban voters over crime and punishment close to home. Begin with symbolic politics. Today, politicians seeking state and national office routinely use salient crimes as political symbols. 122
That tactic was all but unknown before the 1930s. When lawmakers debated criminal prohibitions, both sides in the relevant debates as- sumed that the point of the prohibitions was to stamp out the banned conduct not to take a public stand against it while ignoring the conduct in practice. That state of affairs began to change in the wake of Prohibition: a criminal justice disaster for which national politicians and federal officials bore political responsibility. New Dealera politi- cians did not wish to repeat the disaster, but they did want to find ways to capitalize on public concern about crime. How can one claim credit for fighting crime without bearing responsibility if the fight fails? A pair of young men on the rise FBI Director J. Edgar Hoo- ver and Manhattan District Attorney Thomas E. Dewey answered that question in the same manner at about the same time. Thus was born the modern politics of crime. The solution was to go after not crimes but criminals: pick a few high-profile bad guys who can be taken down, then take them down as publicly as possible. Call it the John Dillinger strategy. 123 In the 1950s, Hoovers FBI institutionalized that strategy with its Ten Most Wanted list, which soon became a fixture in American post offices. 124
(Hoover could have made a fortune in advertising.) Dewey was more successful still. An ambitious young lawyer on the make, he became Americas first celebrity prosecutor the Rudy Giuliani of his day,
122 See, e.g., ZIMRING ET AL., THREE STRIKES, supra note 16, at 194223; Sara Sun Beale, Whats Law Got to Do With It? The Political, Social, Psychological and Other Non-Legal Factors Influencing the Development of (Federal) Criminal Law, 1 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 23 (1997). For an argument that American-style symbolic politics has spread beyond our borders, see Tim New- burn & Trevor Jones, Symbolic Politics and Penal Populism: The Long Shadow of Willie Horton, 1 CRIME, MEDIA, CULTURE 72 (2005).
123 Dillingers capture and death in 1934, at the hands of FBI agents, helped to make the Bu- reaus reputation and Hoovers. See BRYAN BURROUGH, PUBLIC ENEMIES: AMERICAS GREATEST CRIME WAVE AND THE BIRTH OF THE FBI, 193334, at 40216 (2004). On Hoo- vers use of battles against high-profile criminals to raise his own political profile, see RICHARD GID POWERS, SECRECY AND POWER: THE LIFE OF J. EDGAR HOOVER 18993, 196209 (1987).
124 On the Ten Most Wanted list, see The FBIs Ten Most Wanted Fugitives: Frequently Asked Questions, http://www.fbi.gov/wanted/topten/tenfaq.htm (last visited May 12, 2008).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 1999
only bigger by charging and convicting Richard Whitney, the dis- graced head of the New York Stock Exchange, and Lucky Luciano, then New Yorks leading Mafia don. 125 Dewey became a national hero: Time magazine put him on its cover in early 1937; 126 by the summer of 1939 (Dewey was then a 37-year-old local prosecutor who had never won an election outside Manhattan), he was the leading candidate to succeed Franklin D. Roosevelt in the White House, more popular than FDR himself. 127 But for Adolf Hitler, Whitneys and Lucianos convictions might have made Dewey President eight years before his upset loss to Harry Truman. Other politicians noticed. SEC Chair William O. Douglass cru- sade against Wall Street in the late 1930s, 128 Estes Kefauvers nation- ally televised Senate hearings on links between the Mafia and big-city Democratic machines in the early 1950s, 129 Robert Kennedy and the 1959 Senate Rackets Committee hearings that exposed Jimmy Hoffa, 130 even Joe McCarthy and his efforts to expose subversion in the State and Defense Departments 131 these exercises in the sym- bolic politics of crime were Deweys descendants, Hoovers heirs. Douglas and McCarthy, Kefauver and Kennedy won fame and power not by fighting crime but by talking about it. The tactic worked: Douglas became the youngest Supreme Court Justice since Joseph
125 See RICHARD NORTON SMITH, THOMAS E. DEWEY AND HIS TIMES 176206, 24950 (1982). Dewey convicted Luciano of multiple counts of conspiracy to commit prostitution. Id. at 20506. The prostitution charges seem an obvious law enforcement tactic now, but the tactic was at least somewhat novel then: most prosecutors probably assumed that voters would attach no value to such convictions. Dewey saw that the political payoff from criminal prosecution depended more on the identity of the defendant than on the law that formed the basis of the conviction.
126 See Fight Against Fear, TIME, Feb. 1, 1937, at 14.
127 SMITH, supra note 125, at 285 (reporting Gallup Poll results showing Dewey as the choice of 50% of Republicans for his partys presidential nomination, and giving Dewey 58% in a head- to-head matchup with FDR). Dewey won most of the primaries in 1940 and led on the first three ballots of the Republican convention, before losing to Wendell Willkie on the sixth ballot. CHARLES PETERS, FIVE DAYS IN PHILADELPHIA 57108 (2005); SMITH, supra note 125, at 294314.
128 See BRUCE ALLEN MURPHY, WILD BILL: THE LEGEND AND LIFE OF WILLIAM O. DOUGLAS 12454 (2003).
129 JOSEPH BRUCE GORMAN, KEFAUVER: A POLITICAL BIOGRAPHY 74102 (1971); WIL- LIAM HOWARD MOORE, THE KEFAUVER COMMITTEE AND THE POLITICS OF CRIME: 19501952 (1974).
130 For a critical view of Kennedys work on the Rackets Committee, see Paul Jacobs, Extra- curricular Activities of the McClellan Committee, 51 CAL. L. REV. 296 (1963).
131 The literature on McCarthyism is massive. For a good general discussion of the Wisconsin Senators work and legacy, see JAMES T. PATTERSON, GRAND EXPECTATIONS: THE UNITED STATES, 19451974, at 196205, 26470 (1996) [hereinafter PATTERSON, GRAND EXPECTATIONS].
2000 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
Story, and was nearly chosen as FDRs running mate in 1944. 132 Ke- fauver eliminated a sitting President from the presidential race in 1952 and was a leading contender for his partys presidential nomination that year and in 1956. 133 Kennedy became Attorney General on the strength of a reputation for doggedness earned in the Hoffa hear- ings. 134 McCarthy, a dissolute drunk, was for a time one of the most powerful men in the United States. These creative politicians changed the governance of Americas justice system. Before Hoover and Dewey, the politics of crime mostly resembled the politics of fixing potholes: local voters governed local of- ficials who administered the relevant government services locally. State legislators and members of Congress were small players; aside from the occasional vice war, substantive criminal law was not the subject of high-profile legislation. Beginning in the 1930s, that ceased to be true. The Lindbergh kidnapping prompted a federal criminal statute, 135 just as the rise of celebrity gangsters led to the National Firearms Act 136 and the Anti-Racketeering Act. 137 These bills were not designed to stamp out kidnapping or to regulate the firearms trade; rather, they were tools used to exploit the publicity surrounding fa- mous crimes like Bruno Hauptmanns 138 and famous criminals like John Dillinger and Pretty Boy Floyd. 139 Over time, state legislators came to embrace the same practice, as shown by the wave of anti- carjacking laws that followed a famous Maryland crime in 1992. 140
132 On Douglass Supreme Court appointment, see MURPHY, supra note 128, at 16575. On the 1944 vice-presidential nomination, see id. at 21130. The man who was chosen to run with FDR, Harry Truman, became President upon Roosevelts death in April 1945. PATTERSON, GRAND EXPECTATIONS, supra note 131, at 137. It could easily have been Douglas.
133 GORMAN, supra note 129, at 10359, 21165. In 1952, crime not only made Kefauvers name, but also served as his key campaign issue. See id. at 142.
134 Of course, the fact that his brother was the President whose campaign he had managed had something to do with the appointment. Still, but for the Rackets Committee hearings, the selec- tion would have been politically impossible. For a good discussion of Kennedys appointment and the reasons for it, see VICTOR S. NAVASKY, KENNEDY JUSTICE xii-xx (1971).
135 Pub. L. No. 72-189, 47 Stat. 326 (1932); see also HOMER CUMMINGS & CARL MCFARLAND, FEDERAL JUSTICE: CHAPTERS IN THE HISTORY OF JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL EXECUTIVE 47879 (1937).
136 Pub. L. No. 73-474, 48 Stat. 1236 (1934) (codified as amended at 18 U.S.C. 922 (2000) and 26 U.S.C. 5861 (2000)).
137 Pub. L. No. 73-376, 48 Stat. 979 (1934) (replaced by the Hobbs Act, which is codified at 18 U.S.C. 1951 (2000)).
138 Hauptmann was convicted of first-degree murder for the kidnapping and killing of the Lindberghs infant son. Russell B. Porter, Hauptmann Guilty, Sentenced to Death for Murder of the Lindbergh Baby, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 14, 1935, at A1.
139 See SIMON, supra note 18, at 4649; see also Staples v. United States, 511 U.S. 600, 626 (1994) (Stevens, J., dissenting) (describing the National Firearms Act as targeting weapons char- acteristically used only by professional gangsters like Al Capone, Pretty Boy Floyd, and their henchmen).
140 See Stuntz, Pathological Politics, supra note 31, at 53132 & nn.10710.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2001
Laws like these give prosecutors more cards to play in plea bargaining sessions, and thereby give jurors fewer opportunities to exercise the discretion that characterized criminal justice in early-twentieth-century Northern cities. Such laws also make the justice system more central- ized, less locally governed. Which leads to the second pair of trends: the rise of black crime in Northern cities and the coincident rise of middle-class white suburbs surrounding those cities. The first half of the twentieth century saw black crime rates in the North rise sharply, becoming a large multiple of white crime rates. 141 As Roger Lane has explained, industrialization provided economic opportunity for young white men who controlled their antisocial impulses, and taught those same young men the disci- pline essential to orderly urban life. Blacks were largely excluded from the markets that offered the best opportunities for upward mobil- ity save for the years immediately before and during World War II, when the gap between black and white crime rates narrowed substan- tially. After the war, economic discrimination took hold again, and black crime returned to its earlier path. 142
Initially, rising black crime did not have dramatic effects on crime rates in Northern cities because those cities black populations were small. 143 After the war, that story changed as Table 4 shows. The Table records the murder rate and the black percentage of city popula- tion for selected Northern cities and for the nation as a whole, at ten- year intervals:
141 See ADLER, supra note 60, at 127 fig.6; Lane, Homicide Trends, supra note 69, at 7072 & tbl.2.2. The size of the racial disparity in Northern prison populations in 1950, see supra note 61, suggests a large disparity in crime rates. Marvin Wolfgangs famous study of juvenile crime in Philadelphia likewise found such a disparity. See MARVIN E. WOLFGANG ET AL., DELIN- QUENCY IN A BIRTH COHORT (1972).
142 For a good, brief exposition of this argument, see Lane, Homicide Trends, supra note 69, at 5664, 7074. William Julius Wilson used a similar argument to explain the high levels of vio- lence and drug crime in urban black neighborhoods of the 1980s and 1990s. See WILLIAM JULIUS WILSON, THE TRULY DISADVANTAGED: THE INNER CITY, THE UNDERCLASS, AND PUBLIC POLICY 2233 (1987); WILLIAM JULIUS WILSON, WHEN WORK DISAPPEARS: THE WORLD OF THE NEW URBAN POOR 2123, 5561 (1996).
143 See ADLER, supra note 60, at 134, 239 (blacks accounted for less than 5% of Chicagos population in 1920); Lane, Homicide Trends, supra note 69, at 72 tbl.2.2 (black Philadelphians were 5% of that citys population in 1900, rising to 10% by 1928).
2002 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
TABLE 4. MURDER RATE AND BLACK SHARE OF GENERAL POPULATION 144
City 1950 1960 1970 1980 Boston 1.4 5% 3.9 9% 17.8 16% 16.4 22% Chicago 7.1 14% 10.3 23% 24.1 33% 28.9 40% Cleveland 6.8 16% 9.6 29% 36.1 38% 46.2 44% Detroit 6.1 16% 9.0 29% 32.7 44% 45.7 63% New York 3.7 9% 5.0 14% 14.1 21% 25.7 38% Philadelphia 5.9 18% 7.5 26% 18.1 34% 25.8 38% United States 5.3 10% 4.7 11% 8.3 11% 10.7 12%
As the black share of the urban Norths population grew, so did the murderousness of Northern city streets. Violent crime became increas- ingly localized in cities with large black communities. Meanwhile, the white suburbs surrounding those cities exploded. Both local district attorneys and trial judges are elected county-wide in the United States; metropolitan counties typically include both cities and close-in suburbs. The suburban share of those counties popula- tions rose in the generation after the war and cities share declined. In 1940, Chicagoans were 70% of the population of the Chicago met- ropolitan area; by 1980, their share had fallen to 42%. 145 Atlantas percentage of its metropolitan population fell from 58 to 21 during those same forty years; Clevelands fell from 69 to 30, Detroits from 68 to 28. 146 Wherever counties included both urban and suburban voters, the mix of those two categories changed: suburban voters grew more numerous, and city voters less so. White suburbanites power over local prosecutors and trial judges grew, even as those officials fo- cused a larger share of their attention on crime in urban black neighborhoods.
144 I use Eric Monkkonens data for the figures on the United States, and for New Yorks mur- der rate in 1950. See MONKKONEN, supra note 89. Homicide data for the other cities are taken from UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1950, supra note 8, at 9599 tbl.35; UNIFORM CRIME RE- PORTS: 1960, supra note 8, at 129 tbl.38; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1970, supra note 8, at 185 tbl.60; and UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1980, supra note 8, at 97127 tbl.6. City population data, including the black percentage of various cities populations, come from CAMPBELL GIB- SON & KAY JUNG, U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, HISTORICAL CENSUS STATISTICS ON POPULA- TION TOTALS BY RACE, 1790 TO 1990, AND BY HISPANIC ORIGIN, 1790 TO 1990, FOR LARGE CITIES AND OTHER URBAN PLACES IN THE UNITED STATES, tbls.5, 14, 22, 23, 33, 36 & 39 (2005), available at http://www.census.gov/population/www/documentation/twps0076.html. The black percentages of the United States population for the relevant years are taken from 1962 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 24 tbl.15; and 1982 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 21 tbl.24.
145 See 1951 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, tbls.55 & 56; 1981 STATISTICAL AB- STRACT, supra note 1, tbls.23 & 24.
146 See sources cited supra note 145.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2003
Of course, white residents of metropolitan areas had always gov- erned their black neighbors, even in the North: recall that Ossian Sweet was freed by a white lawyer, white jurors, and a white judge. Before the mid-twentieth century, though, that fact had smaller ef- fects on Northern criminal justice than one might suppose. Black neighborhoods accounted for a small fraction of Northern cities popu- lations. The neighborhoods that dominated urban crime working- class white neighborhoods, mostly European immigrants and their off- spring also governed urban policing and, to a large degree, urban criminal justice generally. The lenient doctrines and practices used in blue-collar white neighborhoods spilled over to urban blacks. 147 The growth of large, high-crime black neighborhoods in Northern cities, along with the coincident explosion of white suburbs surrounding those cities, made that egalitarian equilibrium hard to maintain. The third pair of trends the rise of constitutional criminal pro- cedure and the consequent rise of bidding-war politics made it harder still. Before 1950, procedural litigation was a small share of criminal litigation. Criminal procedure doctrines were, by contempo- rary standards, simple and spare. The growth of state constitutional law in the 1950s 148 began to change that state of affairs. The criminal procedure revolution of the 1960s obliterated it, and thereby changed the politics of crime. As the risk of pro-defendant constitutional rul- ings grew, so did politicians incentives to find ways to evade those rul- ings. Broader and more specific criminal prohibitions made guilty pleas easier to extract; tougher sentencing rules did the same. Coinci- dentally or not, criminal liability grew both broader and more rule-like after the Warren Court decisions of the 1960s, and severe sentencing rules multiplied. 149 Those changes added to the power of the state and
147 See supra pp. 198789, 199596.
148 See, e.g., Corinna Barrett Lain, Countermajoritarian Hero or Zero? Rethinking the Warren Courts Role in the Criminal Procedure Revolution, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 1361, 137982, 1394, 1411 (2004). Curiously, commentary in the 1950s paid little attention to state-law developments, focus- ing instead on the more modest changes in federal constitutional law. See, e.g., Walter V. Schae- fer, Federalism and State Criminal Procedure, 70 HARV. L. REV. 1 (1956).
149 On the rise of rule-based sentencing in the states, see ZIMRING ET AL., THREE STRIKES, supra note 16; and Symposium, Sentencing: Whats at Stake for the States?, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 933 (2005). On the rise and (apparent) fall of detailed and severe sentencing rules for federal cases, see Frank O. Bowman, III, The Failure of the Federal Sentencing Guidelines: A Structural Analysis, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 1315 (2005). On the breadth of substantive criminal law, see DOUGLAS HUSAK, OVERCRIMINALIZATION: THE LIMITS OF THE CRIMINAL LAW 354 (2008). On the link between breadth and specificity, see Stuntz, Pathological Politics, supra note 31, at 51519, 55961, 57879. For an argument linking substantive laws breadth to the post-1960 expansion of constitutional criminal procedure, see William J. Stuntz, The Political Constitution of Criminal Justice, 119 HARV. L. REV. 780, 80207 (2006) [hereinafter Stuntz, Po- litical Constitution].
2004 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
national electorates who choose legislators, and reduced the power of the local communities from which criminal juries are drawn. Had these trends taken hold in the Gilded Age, big-city police forces would have reduced their impact. That didnt happen. Instead, urban police forces grew more professionalized, hence more distant from the city neighborhoods officers patrolled. Police unions grew more powerful, overturning the patronage hiring practices of the past. Meritocratic hiring and seniority-based protections took hold just when the older style of police hiring would have helped black job applicants. 150
Pro-defendant criminal procedure doctrines were not responsible for white power over urban policing. But those doctrines were at least partly responsible for the rise of the punitive politics of crime at the national level. This point requires a brief detour. Before the 1960s, conservative politicians were either indifferent toward crime or mildly libertarian in their attitudes toward criminal defendants. Conservative Republican President William Howard Taft opposed Prohibition; 151 his son Robert criticized the Nuremberg prosecutions. 152 Save for the fa- thers fondness for trust-busting and the sons late-career flirtation with McCarthyism, 153 neither Taft ever sought to make political hay from crime. For political conservatives, that stance was natural. Criminal punishment is an especially intrusive form of government regulation. Spending on criminal justice including prison spending is redistributive: money spent to warehouse poor criminals comes disproportionately from rich taxpayers pockets. Conservative politi- cians dislike government regulation and redistributive spending. Two conservative governors in the liberal 1960s George Wallace and Ronald Reagan upended that tradition. 154 Before Wallace, Southern politicians chief goal with respect to crime was to keep the
150 On the professionalizing trends in mid-twentieth-century policing, see FOGELSON, supra note 110, at 16792; DAVID ALAN SKLANSKY, DEMOCRACY AND THE POLICE 3438 (2008) [hereinafter SKLANSKY, DEMOCRACY].
151 See Robert Post, Federalism in the Taft Court Era: Can It Be Revived?, 51 DUKE L.J. 1513, 1540 n.109 (2002).
152 On then-Senator Tafts criticism of the Nuremberg trials on rule-of-law grounds, see JAMES T. PATTERSON, MR. REPUBLICAN: A BIOGRAPHY OF ROBERT A. TAFT 32629 (1972). Tafts libertarianism ran deep: while serving in the Ohio legislature, he opposed Klan-sponsored legisla- tion banning dancing on Sundays and mandating Bible readings in public schools. See id. at 96 97, 10002.
153 See id. at 44549 (discussing the relationship between Senators Taft and McCarthy).
154 Interestingly, neither Wallace nor Reagan had deep roots in American conservatism. Wal- lace grew to political maturity as a liberal populist and ally of Big Jim Folsom, one of the Souths most liberal mid-century politicians. See STEPHAN LESHER, GEORGE WALLACE: AMERICAN POPULIST 8183, 99101 (1994). Before his ideological conversion, Reagan was a proNew Deal Democrat. MATTHEW DALLEK, THE RIGHT MOMENT 1, 2932 (2000).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2005
federal government away from it. 155 Wallace sought to keep the fed- eral government away from civil rights but when the subject was crime, he focused not on states rights but on black criminals, and (even more) on the liberal white judges who allegedly protected them. His 1968 stump speech included these lines: If you walk out of this [hall] tonight and someone knocks you on the head, hell be out of jail before youre out of the hospital, and on Monday morning theyll try the policeman instead of the criminal. 156 As race riots struck many American cities, Wallace bragged about Alabamas version of social peace: They start a riot down here, first one of em to pick up a brick gets a bullet in the brain. 157 Such racially charged rhetoric won votes: Wallace ran strong races in three Democratic presidential primaries in 1964; four years later, he carried five states and won 13% of the popu- lar vote on a third-party ticket. 158
Reagan was more subtle instead of rhetorical bullets to the head, Reagan noted sadly that [o]ur city streets are jungle paths after dark 159 and also more effective. In his 1966 campaign for Califor- nias governorship, Reagan took Wallaces tough-on-crime rhetoric, made it more respectable, 160 and used it to draw blue-collar Democrats across the partisan aisle in huge numbers: enough to win by a million- vote margin against a seemingly unbeatable opponent. 161 In doing so, Reagan married two political constituencies that his contemporaries
155 Two generations of Southern members of Congress fought to prevent federal anti-lynching legislation. See, e.g., ROBERT A. CARO, THE YEARS OF LYNDON JOHNSON: MASTER OF THE SENATE 187202, 21218 (2002). During his Dixiecrat campaign for the White House, Strom Thurmond told New Yorkers that federal civil rights legislation would be as much an af- front to his state as a federal ban on gangland murders would be to theirs. ZACHARY KARA- BELL, THE LAST CAMPAIGN: HOW HARRY TRUMAN WON THE 1948 ELECTION 224 (2000).
156 POWE, supra note 30, at 410 (quoting Wallace) (internal quotation marks omitted).
157 Dan T. Carter, Legacy of Rage: George Wallace and the Transformation of American Politics, 62 J. S. HIST. 3, 11 (1996) (quoting Wallace) (internal quotation mark omitted).
158 See MICHAEL BARONE, OUR COUNTRY: THE SHAPING OF AMERICA FROM ROOSE- VELT TO REAGAN 43436, 44951 (1990); LESHER, supra note 154, at 28485, 295, 30304.
159 DALLEK, supra note 154, at 195 (quoting Ronald Reagan, Speech Announcing Candidacy for Governor of California (Jan. 4, 1966)) (internal quotation mark omitted). The jungle refer- ence was a clear piece of racial code. Reagan wasnt that subtle.
160 One of Reagans key tactics was to link urban rioting with disorder on college campuses a largely white crime problem. See id. at 18589, 19596. That move helped him appeal to white racists without identifying himself as one of them. Reagans gifts at that enterprise were consid- erable. See, e.g., LOU CANNON, GOVERNOR REAGAN: HIS RISE TO POWER 122, 13233, 139 40 (2003) (discussing Reagans opposition to the Civil Rights Act of 1964); id. at 26368 (detailing Reagans efforts to appeal to Wallace supporters during his 1968 campaign for the Republican presidential nomination).
161 Reagans opponent Pat Brown, the two-term Democratic governor and father of Reagans successor, Jerry Brown was known as the giant killer because of his two previous gubernatorial victories. DALLEK, supra note 154, at 1316, 2023. Brown won the office in 1958 by beating then-Senator William Knowland, a leading presidential contender before his defeat. Four years later, Brown won reelection by beating former Vice President Richard Nixon.
2006 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
thought were incompatible: economic conservatives who had opposed the New Deal and unionized workers who had formed its core base of support. Partisan politics was transformed. To Northern and Western poli- ticians of the 1950s and early 1960s, blacks and procivil rights whites were the swing voters for whose allegiance the two parties competed. Dwight Eisenhower won 40% of the black vote in 1956; Richard Nixon won nearly a third in 1960. 162 While blacks were the object of partisan competition, blue-collar whites were generally seen as a core part of the Democratic base. 163 Reagan intuited that, thanks to the Kennedy and Johnson Administrations support for civil rights, blacks and white liberals were now solidly Democratic; yesterdays swing voters didnt swing anymore. Rising crime, falling punishment, and liberal Supreme Court decisions protecting criminal defendants pro- cedural rights had created a new set of swing voters: blue-collar whites. That changed electoral configuration gave conservative Re- publicans the opportunity to build a national majority, just when that opportunity seemed most distant. The Warren Courts criminal procedure decisions were crucial to that process, in three respects. First, those decisions allowed politi- cians to attack black crime indirectly by condemning the white judges who protected black criminals, not the criminals themselves. That gave conservative politicians a chance to appeal to more than racist whites. Second, the Court made street crime violent felonies and felony thefts: classic state-law crimes a national political issue for the first time in American history. One reason crime played a larger role in national politics in the last decades of the twentieth century than ever before 164 is that national politicians could talk about the kinds of crime that voters most feared: not Mafia corruption or labor racketeering 165 but robbery and burglary, murder and rape. Earlier generations had assumed that only local officials concerned themselves with such crimes. Earl Warren changed that political equation. Third, because the Court was the Court, crime talk was cheap talk: politicians couldnt change the constitutional rulings that prompted so
162 On Eisenhowers vote, see DOUG MCADAM, POLITICAL PROCESS AND THE DEVELOP- MENT OF BLACK INSURGENCY, 19301970, at 158 (1982); on Nixons, see BARONE, supra note 158, at 557.
163 Democrats won the large congressional majority they held throughout the 1960s in the off- year election of 1958, in which Republican candidates throughout the country campaigned for anti-union right-to-work laws. See BARONE, supra note 158, at 30104.
164 For the best discussion to date, see SIMON, supra note 18.
165 The focus of Estes Kefauvers Senate hearings in 19501951 was Mafia influence over big- city Democratic machines. Robert Kennedy first won fame as chief counsel to the Senate commit- tee holding hearings on labor racketeering in the late 1950s the same hearings that made Jimmy Hoffa a household name. See supra pp. 19992000.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2007
much controversy, so their criticisms were unburdened by the need to exercise governing responsibility. Reagan and Wallace exemplified that last point. Californias im- prisonment rate fell by nearly half during Reagans two terms in Sac- ramento. 166 Alabamas imprisonment rate did likewise under Wal- lace. 167 Neither of these tough-on-crime governors did anything to reverse those trends. Their tough rhetoric was just that: rhetoric, with no discernible policy implications. Like Kefauvers hearings and Hoo- vers Ten Most Wanted list, the conservative politics of crime was an exercise in political symbolism that seemed to have no substantive consequences. But symbols do not remain purely symbolic for long; substantive consequences have a way of catching up to them. When conservatives like Reagan, Wallace, and Nixon 168 won blue-collar white votes by at- tacking soft judges and (indirectly) black criminals, liberal politicians were forced to respond. Liberal Democratic President Lyndon John- son supported and signed legislation that funneled money to local po- lice and purported to overrule Miranda v. Arizona: 169 the Omnibus Crime Control and Safe Streets Act of 1968, 170 the first of what be- came a long series of federal crime bills targeting urban street crime. 171
Liberal Democratic presidential candidate Robert Kennedy made tough measures against urban disorder a centerpiece of his campaign for his partys nomination. 172 Jimmy Carter embodiment of the Southern left in the early 1970s presided over a 40% increase in Georgias imprisonment rate as governor, while neighboring Ala- bamas prison population stagnated. 173 Liberal Republican Governor Nelson Rockefeller proposed ramped-up penalties for heroin offenders; the so-called Rockefeller laws became the model for the next wave of
166 Californias imprisonment rate fell from 146 in 1966 to 84 in 1972. See supra note 17.
167 Between 1962 and 1976, Alabamas imprisonment rate fell from 166 to 83. See supra note 17. George and Lurleen Wallace won all four of the gubernatorial elections during those fourteen years.
168 Like Wallace and Reagan before him, Nixon was no life-long conservative. In 1960, he sought the White House by running to the left, seeking and winning Nelson Rockefellers support and angering Barry Goldwater and the Republican right in the process. See BARONE, supra note 158, at 330. In 1968, Nixon switched sides, winning longtime segregationist Strom Thurmonds support at the cost of alienating the procivil rights Rockefeller wing of the party. See id. at 442. The law and order issue played a key role in that right turn, and in Nixons subsequent victory. See MICHAEL W. FLAMM, LAW AND ORDER: STREET CRIME, CIVIL UNREST, AND THE CRISIS OF LIBERALISM IN THE 1960S 16278 (2005).
169 384 U.S. 436 (1966).
170 Pub. L. No. 90-351, 82 Stat. 197. For the story of Johnsons involvement with this legisla- tion, see FLAMM, supra note 168, at 13241.
171 See NANCY E. MARION, A HISTORY OF FEDERAL CRIME CONTROL INITIATIVES, 19601993 (1994).
172 See FLAMM, supra note 168, at 14850.
173 See 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72.
2008 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
tough state drug statutes. 174 The same year Rockefeller signed the laws that bore his name, New Yorks imprisonment rate turned up af- ter fifteen years of decline. 175
For the balance of the 1970s as liberal Democrats controlled Congress, two-thirds of state legislatures, the large majority of gover- norships, and nearly all big-city mayoralties prison populations rose steadily, after falling throughout the country in the preceding dozen years. 176 Americas punitive turn did not come from the political right, at least not initially. Rather, the rise in punishment came from the lefts response to the rights rhetoric. 177 That response soon bred its own response. Once liberal politicians like Johnson and Kennedy em- braced punitive politics, the rights bluff had been called. Conserva- tive politicians had two choices: they could back down, cede the crime issue to their liberal opponents and admit that their tough rhetoric was cheap talk. Or they could follow suit, and ramp up punishment still more. They followed suit. Reagan was once again a key player, the model for his party and for his ideological camp. As Governor, he had spe- cialized in combining tough talk with soft policy, or no policy at all. As President, his walk matched his talk: he signed into law the most draconian piece of drug legislation to date; 178 partly as a consequence, the federal imprisonment rate doubled in the 1980s. 179 In an increas- ingly conservative age, state prison populations saw similar trends. 180
The conservative politics of crime remained symbolic at its core but the symbolism worked only if conservatives were seen as tougher than liberals. What began as a political bluff had become a bidding war.
174 See Alan Chartock, Narcotics Addiction: The Politics of Frustration, PROC. ACAD. POL. SCI., May 1974, at 239, 24248.
175 The Rockefeller laws were signed in 1973. New Yorks imprisonment rate fell in at least ten of the preceding fifteen years (data concerning two of the remaining five years are missing). For the data, see the annual volumes of STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1. 1973 saw the first of twenty-seven consecutive increases in that rate. 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72; 2003 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 501 tbl.6.29.
176 Between 1972 and 1980, the nations imprisonment rate rose by half, after falling by 22% in the preceding eleven years. See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006.
177 Cf. SIMON, supra note 18, at 4952 (discussing Robert Kennedys posture toward crime); id. at 90101 (same, regarding Lyndon Johnson).
178 For the best account, by far, of the passage of the federal legislation that mandated the hun- dred-to-one crack/powder sentencing ratio meaning, possession of one gram of crack cocaine is punished as severely as possession of one hundred grams of cocaine powder see David A. Sklansky, Cocaine, Race, and Equal Protection, 47 STAN. L. REV. 1283 (1995) [hereinafter Sklansky, Cocaine and Race].
179 In 1980, the year before Reagan took office, the federal imprisonment rate was 9 per 100,000. By 1989 the year Reagan left the White House the federal imprisonment rate had risen to 19. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006.
180 From 1980 to 1989, the state imprisonment rate rose from 130 to 253. Id.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2009
The bidding war continued through the 1990s, when liberal De- mocrats faced the same problem that conservative Republicans faced in the 1980s, and embraced the same solution. Ann Richards served as the Democratic Governor of Texas from 1991 to 1995; she followed Republican Bill Clements and was replaced by Republican George W. Bush. Under Clements and Bush, Texass imprisonment rate rose 29% and 5%, respectively; under Richards, it rose 128%. 181 Democrat Mel Carnahan replaced Republican John Ashcroft as Missouris Governor in 1993. In Ashcrofts two terms in office, Missouris prison popula- tion grew more slowly than the nations; in Carnahans two terms, the number of Missouri prison inmates grew almost twice as fast as the national average. 182 Democrat Douglas Wilders four years in the Vir- ginia statehouse saw that states imprisonment rate increase 46%. Under Wilders Republican replacement George Allen, who cam- paigned on a promise of ending parole 183 imprisonment fell 2%. 184
The moment that best captured both liberals dilemma and their response to it came shortly before the New Hampshire primary in 1992. Then-Governor Bill Clinton, falling in the polls, returned to Ar- kansas to supervise the execution of a mentally retarded black inmate named Ricky Ray Rector. 185 It worked: Clinton finished a close sec- ond in New Hampshire, and went on to win the White House. The Rector execution was Clintons gruesome answer to the elder George Bushs use of Willie Horton to defeat Michael Dukakis four years ear- lier. The character of the answer captures the relevant political dy- namic. This was no philosophical argument between opposing sides; rather, it was a war of images in which, strangely, both sides sought to send the same message. As the Horton and Rector incidents illus-
181 See id. The figures in this paragraph were calculated using the imprisonment rates re- ported in the Online Sourcebook as of December 31 of the relevant years. Since governors usually begin their terms in early January, there is a nearly year-long time lag between the beginning of each new governors term and the imprisonment rate which, in the text, I attribute to that gover- nors administration. The time lag is consciously chosen; it ordinarily takes at least a year for state-level policy decisions to have significant effects on the relevant states imprisonment rate.
182 From 1985 to 1993 Ashcrofts term as Missouris governor the states imprisonment rate rose from 194 to 308, an increase of 59%, while the nations imprisonment rate rose from 200 to 350: a 75% increase. Id. In Ashcrofts second term, imprisonment rose a mere 15%; in his last two years in office, the rise was less than 1% compared to a 13% increase in the nation as a whole. Id. From 1993 to 2001 Carnahan died in October 2000; a Democratic successor served the balance of his second term Missouris imprisonment rate rose from 308 to 509, an increase of 65%; the nations imprisonment rate rose 34% during those eight years. See id.
183 Donald P. Baker, Winner Talks Tough, Cites Mandate for Change, WASH. POST, Nov. 4, 1993, at A1.
184 ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006.
185 See Christopher Lydon, Sex, War, and Death: Covering Clinton Became a Test of Character For the Press, COLUM. JOURNALISM REV., MayJune 1992, at 57, 60.
2010 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
trated, the politics of crime had devolved into a game of can-you-top- this. Bush probably found Lee Atwaters Horton ad distasteful, 186 and Clinton may have felt similarly about Rectors execution. If so, the two presidents distaste highlights an important feature of late- twentieth-century politics: right and left alike supported criminal jus- tice policies that, in principle, they found repugnant. The Reaganite right disbelieved in big government, yet helped create a prison system of unprecedented scope and size. The Clintonian left opposed racially discriminatory punishment, yet reinforced and expanded the most ra- cially skewed prison population in American history. The source of this conflict between politics and principle was the same on both sides. Crime policy was not a means of addressing crime and the policys consequences for the poor blacks who were both victimized by crime and punished for it were, politically speaking, irrelevant. Each side supported punitive policies because the other side had done so, and because changing course seemed politically risky. Such political stances worked because the votes that mattered most the votes for which the two parties competed, the ones most likely to switch sides if the other sides crime posture seemed more attractive were not the votes of crime victims and their friends and neighbors, much less of criminal defendants and their friends and neighbors. They were the votes of those for whom crime was at once frightening and distant, those who read about open-air drug markets and the lat- est gang shootings in the morning paper. Neighborhood democracy faded, and was replaced by a democracy of angry neighbors. The con- sequence was much more criminal punishment, distributed much less equally. B. Lenity and Severity The last half of the twentieth century saw two dramatic turns in criminal justice. The second is famous: the generation-long punitive turn that drove American prison populations into the stratosphere. The first is less well known: a generation-long lenient turn that saw criminal punishment collapse in Northern cities, in the midst of an un- precedented crime wave. Table 5 captures the magnitude of these two opposite trends. The Table lists the city homicide rate and state im- prisonment rate for seven cities: two each from the South, Northeast, and Midwest, and one from the West Coast. Notice the difference be- tween the two Southern cities and the rest:
186 Even Atwater appears to have found it distasteful, after the fact. See John Brady, Im Still Lee Atwater, WASH. POST MAG., Dec. 1, 1996, at 16, 45 (discussing Atwaters deathbed apology for his treatment of the Horton issue).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2011
TABLE 5. CITY HOMICIDE RATE AND STATE IMPRISONMENT RATE, SELECTED CITIES, 19502005 187
City 1950 1972 1991 2005 Atlanta 30.5 155 52.8 174 50.9 342 20.9 533 Houston 15.3 77 22.5 136 36.5 297 16.3 691 Boston 1.4 55 16.6 32 19.7 143 12.9 239 New York 3.7 103 21.9 64 29.5 320 6.6 326 Chicago 7.1 91 21.6 50 32.9 247 15.6 351 Detroit 6.1 135 41.5 94 59.3 388 39.3 489 Los Angeles 3.2 98 17.6 84 28.9 318 12.6 466
In Atlanta and Houston, the lenient turn never happened; punish- ment and crime rose in tandem through the 1950s and 1960s. 188 In the following three decades, Southern prison populations kept rising while crime rates plateaued, then fell to something like mid-century levels. In the rest of the country, imprisonment rates fell by one-third or more during the 1950s and 1960s, while criminal violence rose through the roof. In some places, punishment per unit crime appears to have fallen by more than 80%: a stunningly large decline. 189 Then, beginning in the mid-1970s, punishment rose through the roof yet crime kept ris- ing. Just when no one thought it could happen crime fell substantially
187 The left column under each year notes the relevant citys homicide rate; the right column notes the relevant states imprisonment rate. For New Yorks homicide rate in 1950, I use Eric Monkkonens data. See MONKKONEN, supra note 89. For the other listed homicide rates, see UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1950, supra note 8, at 9498 tbl.35; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1972, supra note 8, at 218 tbl.76; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1991, supra note 8, at 11250 tbl.8; and CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2005, supra note 8, tbl.8. City populations for 1972 (used in computing city homicide rates) are extrapolated from the populations for 1970 and 1980, which can be found in GIBSON & JUNG, supra note 144, tbls.5, 11, 14, 22, 23, 33 & 44, as can city populations for 1950. Georgias imprisonment rate in 1950 is taken from CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3. For other states 1950 imprisonment rates, see 1952 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 14 tbl.11, 146 tbl.175. For later imprisonment rates, see 1991 SOURCEBOOK, su- pra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72; and ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006.
188 Georgia did experience a brief period of declining prison populations but it lasted a mere six years and was quickly reversed. In 1964, the states imprisonment rate stood at 168 per 100,000. 1966 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 11 tbl.9, 162 tbl.232. By 1970, that rate had fallen to 111. 1972 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 11 tbl.10, 161 tbl.264. Two years later, the imprisonment rate had risen to 174. 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72.
189 In Boston, Detroit, and New York, prisoner-years per murder fell by 90% or more. The ac- tual drop in punishment per unit crime was no doubt smaller, since imprisonment rates are state- wide while the homicide rates in Table 5 are city-wide. If the drop in imprisonment was felt most where crime rates were lowest, then falling punishment in high-crime cities was less extreme than the figures suggest. Still, it was extreme enough.
2012 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
beginning in 1992. 190 Even after what Frank Zimring calls the great American crime decline 191 of the 1990s, violent crime in Northern cit- ies remains much higher than the pre-1960 historical norm. If a common theme runs through these cross-cutting trends, the theme is instability. The last half of the twentieth century was an age of disequilibrium: rising and falling crime plus steeply rising punish- ment in the South, unprecedented crime increases coupled with equally unprecedented punishment decreases and increases in the North. It was also an age of inequality but this time, the geographic focus of the inequality was the procivil rights North, not the Jim Crow South. In the South, the paradigmatic victim of discriminatory criminal justice in mid-century America was Emmett Till, the black teenager from Chicago who was murdered for whistling at a white woman in the inaptly named town of Money, Mississippi in 1955. 192 Surprisingly, Tills white killers were charged with the crime and brought to trial; less surprisingly, they were swiftly acquitted. 193 The basic story of the Till case the justice system failed to protect a black victim from his white victimizers had long been common in the South. That form of discrimination was declining by mid-century, as the prosecution of Tills killers illustrated. South Carolinas imprisonment rate almost tripled during the 1940s and 1950s; North Carolinas rate doubled, and Virginias nearly did so. 194 The largely privatized system of law en- forcement that had long ignored crimes against black victims the system Hortense Powdermaker described in her study of Depression- era Mississippi 195 was dying, and increasingly populous Southern prisons were a sign of its demise. Less discriminatory law enforcement meant more punishment for crimes victimizing blacks, which in turn meant rising levels of black incarceration: 196 in the mid-twentieth-
190 See generally THE CRIME DROP IN AMERICA (Alfred Blumstein & Joel Wallman eds., 2000).
191 FRANKLIN E. ZIMRING, THE GREAT AMERICAN CRIME DECLINE (2007).
192 STEPHEN J. WHITFIELD, A DEATH IN THE DELTA: THE STORY OF EMMETT TILL 15 23 (1988).
193 Id. at 2224, 3348. Shortly after their acquittal, the killers confessed to the author of an article published in Look magazine; the consequent story detailed how they committed the crime. Id. at 5155.
194 CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3.
195 See supra notes 5961 and accompanying text.
196 Race-specific imprisonment data from the Jim Crow South are hard to come by, but the available evidence supports the claim in the text. Between 1937 and 1964, the annual number of blacks admitted to state prison rose 79% in North Carolina, 43% in South Carolina, 94% in Flor- ida, and 58% in Texas. See BUREAU OF THE CENSUS, U.S. DEPT OF COMMERCE, PRISON- ERS IN STATE AND FEDERAL PRISONS AND REFORMATORIES: 1937, at 28 tbl.22; FED. BU- REAU OF PRISONS, NATIONAL PRISONER STATISTICS: STATE PRISONERS: ADMISSIONS AND RELEASES, 1964, at 23 tbl.A8. Between the 1940 and 1960 censuses, the black population rose 14% in North Carolina, 2% in South Carolina, 71% in Florida, and 28% in Texas. See 1965 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 26 tbl.23.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2013
century South as in the twenty-first-century Northeast, most crime was intraracial. 197
While inequality was falling in the South, it was rising in the North in two distinct ways, serially. First, punishment in high-crime cities all but collapsed, in the midst of the worst crime wave in Ameri- can history. As Table 5 suggests, prison populations fell most in the places where that crime wave crested highest: throughout the urban- ized Northeast and Midwest. 198 Taken together, those trends were revolutionary. After the early 1970s, Americans saw a revolution of a different sort, as imprisonment rates soared. The number of white inmates shattered records. The number of black inmates shattered communities. 199
The consequences of these two turns were disproportionately felt in black neighborhoods. During the 1960s, imprisonment fell more among whites (26%) than among blacks (19%) 200 but that fact may be due chiefly to Southern trends, 201 and the massive crime wave that coincided with falling punishment was focused on mostly black inner cities, not on the white suburbs. In the five non-Southern cities listed in Table 5, the murder rate rose an average of 562% between 1950 and 1972. In the nation as a whole, murders rose 77% during those years. 202 The combination of skyrocketing crime and falling punish- ment hit Northern cities, and black neighborhoods within them, hardest. The second trend is more familiar: after abandoning black neighborhoods in the 1950s and 1960s, Northern law enforcement agencies punished young men in those neighborhoods in numbers never before seen reinforcing a trend that was already underway in the South. Strangely, the same political and legal changes that helped cause the lenient turn of the twentieth centurys third quarter also re- inforced the punitive turn of its last quarter. With respect to politics, the preceding section tells the story. Sub- urban voters cared less about urban crime than did the residents of city neighborhoods; falling punishment in an era of rising crime was
197 See, e.g., POWDERMAKER, supra note 53, at 39596.
198 See CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3, 38 tbl.3-10. Cahalans figures show that the big- gest imprisonment drops came in the Midwest and West, as well as in New York the largest state in the Northeast.
199 For the best discussion to date, see WESTERN, supra note 49.
200 See CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 65 tbl.3-31.
201 Black imprisonment was rising in the South during Jim Crows last days. See sources cited supra note 196. State-level demographic data on prison populations during these years are sparse, but it could well be that, in the Northeast and Midwest, the decline in black imprisonment out- stripped the decline in white imprisonment.
202 In 1950, the murder rate for the United States as a whole stood at 5.3 per 100,000; by 1972, that rate had risen to 9.4. See sources cited supra note 89.
2014 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
the natural consequence of suburban indifference. Both the number of urban police officers per unit population and the urban arrest rate rose during the 1960s, 203 even as prison populations fell. Those facts sug- gest that prosecutors and judges, not police officers, were the chief rea- sons for declining punishment. Then as now, urban police forces worked for city governments; prosecutors and trial judges were usually elected county-wide. The officials who cared most about suburban voters preferences drove punishment levels down. 204
After the early 1970s, indifference gave way to anger; voters sought something more tangible than tough rhetoric about urban crime. Lo- cal district attorneys responded. 205 Voters in poor city neighborhoods might have limited the turn toward more punishment, but they were outvoted by the suburbs. Local juries might have made the punitive turn less punitive by acquitting large numbers of defendants, as Chi- cago juries had done two generations before. But changes in substan- tive law made acquittals harder to win, and the rising number of guilty pleas left few trials in which to win them. Fiscal cost might have signaled that the punishment wave had gone too far, but thanks to nineteenth-century institutional arrangements, state taxpayers paid for prison beds while local voters chose the prosecutors who filled them. 206 To the suburban voters who chose big-city district attorneys, criminal punishment was nearly a free good. Naturally, they bought too much of it. While states paid the tab for growing prison populations, no com- parable subsidy swelled the ranks of urban police forces. Local gov- ernments pay 90% of the cost of policing in their jurisdictions, and
203 According to FBI data, the number of police employees per 100,000 urban population stood at 189 in 1960; the city arrest rate stood at 4762 per 100,000. UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1960, supra note 8, at 95 tbl.20, 105 tbl.31. By 1969, the former number had risen to 216, and the latter to 4876. UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1969, supra note 8, at 127 tbl.37, 148 tbl.49.
204 To some degree, falling criminal punishment was due to liberal prosecutors and judges ideological aversion to incarcerating criminals. For a good account of this skeptical ideology, see GARLAND, supra note 18, at 4651. But suburban voters indifference was crucial: without it, those liberal prosecutors and judges would have lacked the freedom to indulge their lenient preferences.
205 Between 1974 and 1990, the number of local prosecutors in the United States rose from 17,000 to 20,000 an increase of 18%. Between 1978 and 1991, the number of felony charges filed in state court more than doubled. See William J. Stuntz, The Uneasy Relationship Between Criminal Procedure and Criminal Justice, 107 YALE L.J. 1, 9 n.19, 25 (1997) [hereinafter Stuntz, Uneasy Relationship], and sources cited therein.
206 This crucial fact was ignored in the legal literature until Robert Misners brilliant article highlighted it. See Robert L. Misner, Recasting Prosecutorial Discretion, 86 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 717 (1996). For an interesting discussion of the interjurisdictional competition that these institutional arrangements foster, see Doron Teichman, The Market for Criminal Jus- tice: Federalism, Crime Control, and Jurisdictional Competition, 103 MICH. L. REV. 1831 (2005).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2015
that percentage has been stable over time. 207 Predictably, police budg- ets have grown much more slowly than prison budgets. The number of prison inmates per unit population more than tripled in the 1970s and 1980s; the number of urban police officers per capita held steady. 208 Police officers and prison cells are substitutes: alternative means by which governments spend money to battle crime. In the last thirty-five years, the mix of those two alternatives has changed radi- cally: in 1970, there were more than twice as many local cops as in- mates; today, there are more than twice as many inmates as local cops. 209 Local governments largely determine the character of the mix cities and counties hire and pay for the police officers who patrol their streets, and local district attorneys decide whom to prosecute and for what charges. But those same local governments pay for only one of the two alternatives. Notice: The decline of local democracy did not inevitably produce more punishment, nor did it inevitably produce less. As in the early- twentieth-century South, it produced both: first much less punishment, then vastly more. The crucial regulating mechanisms that governed Northern cities justice systems in the Gilded Age juries selected from the local population, prosecutors elected by city voters (because suburban populations were small), police forces ruled by urban ma- chines that depended on working-class immigrant votes for their sur- vival faded or disappeared. Bureaucratic detachment, legal proce- dure, and symbolic politics took their place. The consequences were poor crime control, rapidly changing punishment practices, and mas- sive inequality. Far from checking political excess, constitutional law encouraged it in both directions. The key mechanism was price. Protective pro- cedures adopted in the 1960s raised the price law enforcers paid for ar- rests and convictions when urban violence was already rising, and when punishment for it was falling. Urban arrests fell sharply in the
207 For the current figures, see ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.1.4.2003. For budget data from the early 1970s, see 1974 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 33 tbl.1.2.
208 On the imprisonment data, see 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72. Accord- ing to FBI data, the number of urban police officers per 100,000 population rose from 204 in 1970 to 211 in 1974; in 1989 it stood at 210. See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1970, supra note 8, at 163 tbl.51; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1974, supra note 8, at 236 tbl.57; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1989, supra note 8, at 238 tbl.66.
209 The numbers of prison inmates and police officers per 100,000 population in 1970 were 96 and 204, respectively. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1970, supra note 8, at 163 tbl.51. In 2005, the analogous numbers were 491 and 230. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006; CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2005, supra note 8, tbl.71.
2016 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
decades first half, 210 after Mapp v. Ohio 211 imposed the Fourth Amendments exclusionary rule on state courts. The drop in impris- onment accelerated in the decades second half, 212 when most of the key Court decisions regulating criminal trials took hold. After 1970, when political pressures began pushing punishment levels up, proce- dural doctrine changed again: this time, making both arrests and con- victions cheaper for the government. The law made punishment more costly when there was too little of it, and cheaper when there was far too much. The first step in that progression is straightforward. The level of procedural regulation, both of policing and prosecution, was already on the rise when the 1960s began: state appellate courts were rapidly adopting protective procedures like the exclusionary rule and state- appointed lawyers before the Supreme Court required them to do so. 213 The Court accelerated that process, beginning in 1961 with Mapp. Later in the decade, the Justices constitutionalized the right to counsel (on appeal as well as at trial), 214 the right to discovery, 215 the law of self-incrimination, 216 the right of compulsory process, 217 the right to a jury trial, 218 and the right to be free from double jeopardy. 219
These decisions did not transform state-court criminal processes: all the procedural elements just mentioned already existed; indeed, most had existed for centuries, which explains their inclusion in the Bill of Rights. The chief effect of Warren-era criminal procedure decisions was to raise the level of legal uncertainty. The boundaries of rights that had been long settled became hotly contested. Contested doctrine attracts litigation. Procedural claims mushroomed. 220
210 In 1961, the FBIs city arrests data showed 4776 arrests per 100,000 urban population; by 1964, that figure had fallen to 4325. See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1961, supra note 8, at 97 tbl.23; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1964, supra note 8, at 123 tbl.30.
211 367 U.S. 643 (1961).
212 Illinoiss imprisonment rate stood at 90 per 100,000 in 1960, falling to 78 in 1965, then dropping to 57 in 1970. New Yorks imprisonment rate fell from 109 in 1957 to 97 in 1965, then fell to 66 in 1970. Georgias rate was 178 in 1959 Southern prison populations were larger than Northern ones declined to 170 in 1964, then fell sharply to 111 in 1970. Californias imprison- ment rate rose in the early 1960s, from 137 in 1960 to 146 in 1966, before dropping to 87 in 1971. These data are taken from the relevant volumes of the STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, and from 1992 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 609 tbl.6.59.
213 See Lain, supra note 148, at 137982, 138999.
214 Gideon v. Wainwright, 372 U.S. 335 (1963) (trials); Douglas v. California, 372 U.S. 353 (1963) (appeals).
215 Brady v. Maryland, 373 U.S. 83 (1963).
216 Malloy v. Hogan, 378 U.S. 1 (1964).
217 Washington v. Texas, 388 U.S. 14 (1967).
218 Duncan v. Louisiana, 391 U.S. 145 (1968).
219 Benton v. Maryland, 395 U.S. 784 (1969).
220 I have explained this dynamic elsewhere. See Stuntz, Uneasy Relationship, supra note 205, at 3552.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2017
These destabilizing court decisions arose from egalitarian motives: the Justices saw the Bill of Rights as a procedural Equal Protection Clause, a means of assisting poor black suspects and defendants as they battled a criminal justice system run by and for wealthier whites. 221 To a surprising degree, the Justices egalitarian goals were fulfilled. Not only did arrests fall in the 1960s arrests of black sus- pects fell more, and in a time of rising black crime. 222 Imprisonment rates fell too, at a time when rich criminal defendants were a rare breed. And the trial process grew friendlier to poor defendants, at least as a relative matter. A large number of studies across a wide range of jurisdictions over a period of several decades show that indi- gent criminal defendants defendants poor enough to receive state- paid lawyers achieve as good or better outcomes as defendants who hire their own lawyers. 223 The criminal procedure decisions of the 1960s explain that surprising result. But pendulums that swing in one direction tend to swing back. The very doctrines that raised the cost of policing and prosecution cre- ated political pressure to reduce those costs. The consequence was a more streamlined process than the one that existed before Earl Warren and his fellow Justices crafted their constitutional revolution. The character of the relevant procedural rules offered a ready means of reducing the legal tax Warren and his colleagues had im- posed on law enforcers. That tax consisted almost entirely of proce- dural rights exercised by individual suspects and defendants. In American law, individuals who hold legal rights may use them as they wish: rights are like alienable property interests, waivable at will by rightholders. Cutting Warrens procedural taxes was easy: one need only establish generous waiver rules, and help police and prosecutors to induce as many waivers as possible. After 1970, the Supreme Court took the first step, while legislators took the second. Police officers
221 Race is the familiar subtext of Warren-era criminal procedure doctrine. See sources cited supra note 30. David Sklansky persuasively argues that a less familiar subtext police oppres- sion of gay Americans likewise influenced the criminal procedure decisions of the 1960s. See David Alan Sklansky, One Train May Hide Another: Katz, Stonewall, and the Secret Subtext of Criminal Procedure, 41 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 875 (2008). Notice that both subtexts concern ine- quality: the central theme of the law of criminal procedure.
222 According to the FBIs city arrest data, the arrest rate fell 9% from 1961 to 1964; the rate of black arrests fell 12%. See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1961, supra note 8, at 97 tbl.23; UNI- FORM CRIME REPORTS: 1964, supra note 8, at 123 tbl.30. As a percentage of the urban black population, black arrests fell 18%. See 1976 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 18 tbl.19. By 1969, the overall arrest rate was slightly higher than in 1961 but the black arrest rate was 6% lower. UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1969, supra note 8, at 127 tbl.37.
223 For a recent example, see HARLOW, supra note 10. Older studies to the same effect are dis- cussed in Floyd Feeney & Patrick G. Jackson, Public Defenders, Assigned Counsel, Retained Counsel: Does the Type of Criminal Defense Counsel Matter?, 22 RUTGERS L.J. 361, 36578 (1991).
2018 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
and prosecutors reaped the benefit: dramatic rises in rates of arrest, prosecution, conviction, and imprisonment. Fourth Amendment law bars intrusive searches without probable cause and, sometimes, a warrant. If the target of the search consents to it, however, the warrant and probable cause requirement go by the boards. Post-1970 Supreme Court decisions make obtaining consent easy: police need only ask; if the circumstances suggest that police re- quests are the functional equivalent of commands, 224 so much the bet- ter. 225 Fifth Amendment law bars the interrogation of arrested sus- pects without a voluntary, knowing, and intelligent waiver of the suspects rights to remain silent and to the assistance of counsel. 226
Such waivers are easily induced, given the generous Miranda waiver doctrines the post-Miranda Court has crafted. 227 The various trial rights the Constitution guarantees apply only to defendants who take their cases to trial. Guilty pleas waive those rights, and the state is free to use even extortionate threats to induce pleas. 228
In all these areas, constitutional law establishes procedural hurdles the state must clear but also creates cheap alternatives if clearing those hurdles seems too costly. The net result is to make searches, in- terrogations, and criminal prosecutions cheaper, not more expensive. Mike Seidman captured the dynamic in a brilliant article about Miranda doctrine in the early 1990s. 229 Before Miranda, courts re- viewed police interrogation under a voluntariness standard. Since that decision, judges have relied on Mirandas warnings and invocation rules to ensure that confessions are the product of suspects free choice. Consequently, Seidman notes, confessions that might have been sup- pressed before Miranda are routinely admitted today. 230 Before Mapp v. Ohio, the probable cause requirement applied to local police searches but was not rigorously enforced, because of the absence of a binding exclusionary rule. In the age of consent searches, probable
224 For a study showing that most people do think that even people who are unusually well- informed about their legal rights see David K. Kessler, Free to Leave? An Empirical Look at the Fourth Amendments Seizure Standard, 98 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY (forthcoming Jan. 2009).
225 See Ohio v. Robinette, 519 U.S. 33 (1996); Schneckloth v. Bustamonte, 412 U.S. 218 (1973); Janice Nadler, No Need to Shout: Bus Sweeps and the Psychology of Coercion, 2002 SUP. CT. REV. 153.
226 E.g., Moran v. Burbine, 475 U.S. 412, 42028 (1986) (explaining the meaning of these terms).
227 See William J. Stuntz, Mirandas Mistake, 99 MICH. L. REV. 975, 98286 (2001) (summariz- ing Miranda waiver doctrines).
228 See, e.g., Miles v. Dorsey, 61 F.3d 1459 (10th Cir. 1995) (prosecutors threatened to imprison defendants parents if defendant refused to plead guilty; plea was held voluntary); United States v. Pollard, 959 F.2d 1011 (D.C. Cir. 1992) (prosecutors threatened to imprison defendants wife if defendant refused to plead guilty; plea was held voluntary).
229 Louis Michael Seidman, Brown and Miranda, 80 CAL. L. REV. 673 (1992).
230 Id. at 74247.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2019
cause rarely applies police need no cause once they have consent: and today, they nearly always have consent. 231 Before the 1960s, criminal trials were more casual than today, but still common. Todays more elaborate trials are rare events. 232 Fourth Amendment searches, police station confessions, and criminal convictions alike are probably cheaper now than before Warren and his colleagues crafted their pro- cedural code. The law of criminal procedure raised the cost of policing and prosecution when that cost was already too high, and lowered it when the cost was already too low. The consequence was to make both the punishment drop of the 1960s and the punishment rise of the following three decades larger and more destructive. C. Violence and Drugs Consider a recent story about a Boston gang bust:
Authorities said yesterday they are keeping a promise to prosecute 25 members of a violent street gang they hold responsible for 57 shootings and six slayings in Dorchester and Mattapan in two years. The Lucerne Street Doggz, who authorities said have about 40 mem- bers ranging in age from 18 to 28, now face federal and state gun and drug trafficking charges that could keep some jailed for up to 40 years. We told them we wanted them to put their guns down, Police Com- missioner Edward F. Davis said at a press conference . . . . The ones that continued are being prosecuted today, Davis said. We are following through on the warning that was issued. . . . Seeking to break the gangs grip and improve the quality of life for residents, authorities said, they held two meetings last year involving gang members, police, job training groups, members of the 10 Point Coalition, and law enforcement. During the meetings, dubbed Operation Ceasefire, authorities detailed the prison sentences that courts can impose for crimes involving guns and drugs, according to an affidavit by Boston police Sergeant John J. Ford. 233
231 See Nadler, supra note 225, at 20810.
232 In a 1962 study of criminal litigation in twenty-eight counties, the author found a plea rate of 74% for defendants with court-appointed lawyers and 48% for defendants with retained coun- sel. See 1 LEE SILVERSTEIN, DEFENSE OF THE POOR IN CRIMINAL CASES IN AMERICAN STATE COURTS: A FIELD STUDY AND REPORT 2223 tbls.3, 4 (1965). (The latter category was a good deal larger then than it is now. See infra note 266.) Forty years later, a study of criminal litigation in seventy-five metropolitan counties found that 95% of felony convictions were ob- tained by guilty plea. ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.57.2002.
233 John R. Ellement, Officials Say Vow Kept with Arrests, BOSTON GLOBE, May 25, 2007, at B4.
2020 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
The reason for the bust was the spate of shootings for which the Lu- cerne gang is responsible. But the crimes charged are selling drugs, and buying and selling unregistered guns. That story is not unusual, and not limited to Boston. For the past generation, drug and gun crime (by gun crime, I mean offenses in- volving gun registration and licensing, not the use of guns to commit violent felonies) have been used as means of battling violent crime. As Tracey Meares, Neal Katyal, and Dan Kahan have noted, prosecutors regularly justify drug prosecutions as surrogates for violent crime charges even when the drug in question is marijuana. 234 The pattern is especially clear in the federal system. Bill Clinton instructed the FBI to treat gangs like the Lucerne Street Doggz as it had treated the Mafia, 235 and charging proxy crimes was a key means of taking down Mafia families, dating back to Robert Kennedys tenure in the Justice Department. 236 The Lucerne story illustrates the degree to which the pattern has taken hold in local prosecutors offices as well. The historical norm was very different. During Prohibition, unre- lated charges like the tax charge that sent Al Capone to prison were sometimes used to target bootleggers, 237 but alcohol charges were not used to target more traditional crimes. The other vices that federal and state law have forbidden over the years were used strategically against high-profile mobsters, like Lucky Luciano or the various Mafia defendants who faced federal gambling charges but Mob cases were rare, and nearly all of them were federal. With few exceptions, violent felonies were enforced straight-up, as is proved by the high acquittal rates in homicide cases that were common a century ago. Charges like those in the Lucerne case were unknown. Why did that state of affairs change? There are three answers: coincidence, a changed political structure, and law enforcement necessity. Mass markets for illegal drugs arose just after the wave of violence that swamped Northern cities, and just when political pressure was forcing big-city prosecutors to ramp up criminal punishment. For urban police looking to increase their arrest numbers and urban prosecutors seeking higher conviction rates, drug
234 Tracey L. Meares et al., Updating the Study of Punishment, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1171, 1178 & n.22 (2004).
235 Nancy E. Marion, Symbolic Policies in Clintons Crime Control Agenda, 1 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 67, 97 (1997).
236 See Daniel C. Richman & William J. Stuntz, Essay, Al Capones Revenge: An Essay on the Political Economy of Pretextual Prosecution, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 583, 59899 (2005) (quoting Attorney General John Ashcroft, Prepared Remarks for the U.S. Mayors Conference (Oct. 25, 2001) (noting and endorsing this policy)). This approach has made the federal law of gun registra- tion and possession a de facto federal law of violent crime. See Daniel Richman, The Past, Pre- sent, and Future of Violent Crime Federalism, 34 CRIME & JUST. 277 (2006).
237 Including Capones brother Ralph. See Richman & Stuntz, supra note 236, at 584 n.2.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2021
cases were a godsend. As for political structure: local electorates seem to like transparent charging practices meaning, the crimes charged are the reasons for criminal punishment. That is probably why drug sentences are so much more severe in urban black neighborhoods than in wealthier and whiter suburbs. 238 Suburban drug cases are prose- cuted directly, not as a substitute for other crimes. In the suburbs, criminal justice remains a locally democratic enterprise. Not so in high-crime cities. The third reason law enforcement necessity requires explana- tion. Police clearance rates in violent crime cases were high in the past 239 because the cases were easy. Killings tended to follow a few simple fact patterns; identifying the killer was not hard. As Roger Lane has noted, that state of affairs changed beginning in the mid- twentieth century: both stranger killings and robbery-murders rose, and the friends-and-family killings that had dominated homicide sta- tistics in the past declined sharply. 240 Clearance rates fell. 241
As evidence-gathering in violent crime cases grew more difficult, the law of criminal procedure placed more restrictions on it. Confes- sions and eyewitness testimony are crucial to the prosecution of many violent felonies. Thanks to changes in the relevant bodies of constitu- tional law, confessions became a good deal harder for the police to ob- tain in the 1960s. 242 As for eyewitness testimony, criminal violence is frightening, not only to its victims but to those who see and hear it as well; witnesses fear becoming victims themselves if they testify. The rise of violent urban gangs in the last generation is partly attributable to gangs skill at silencing would-be witnesses. 243 Both the rise of po-
238 More whites than blacks are convicted of drug felonies in state courts. See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.5.45.2004. Yet the ratio of black to white drug prisoners in state penitentiaries is more than three to two. See id. tbl.6.0001.2004.
239 See, e.g., LANE, VIOLENT DEATH IN THE CITY, supra note 85, at 81 (noting that 91% of homicides were cleared in mid-twentieth-century Philadelphia, a figure very close to that re- ported for other cities in the same period).
240 See Roger Lane, Murder in America: A Historians Perspective, 25 CRIME & JUST. 191, 20810 (1999).
241 See Paul G. Cassell & Richard Fowles, Handcuffing the Cops? A Thirty-Year Perspective on Mirandas Harmful Effects on Law Enforcement, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1055, 106670 & figs.12 (1998).
242 See Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436 (1966); Massiah v. United States, 377 U.S. 201 (1964). At the same time, silence became a more viable litigation strategy. See Griffin v. California, 380 U.S. 609 (1965).
243 For a telling example, see SUDHIR ALLADI VENKATESH, OFF THE BOOKS: THE UN- DERGROUND ECONOMY OF THE URBAN POOR 30218 (2006). In these pages, Venkatesh tells the story of a gang murder; the victims brother witnessed the killing and was left alive. Never- theless, no one was ever prosecuted for the homicide. Not long afterward, Venkatesh asked a lo- cal minister whether Big Cat, leader of the local gang, was responsible. The ministers answer was telling: If I say yes, youll ask me how do I know. . . . I know, we know, the community knows. Id. at 318 (internal quotation marks omitted).
2022 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
lice interrogation doctrine and the rise of urban gangs made violent crime cases harder to build, and harder to win especially in high- crime city neighborhoods. In earlier generations, these problems might have produced proce- dural reforms designed to make policing and prosecution of violent of- fenses easier. But constitutional law bars the most obvious reforms. Miranda grants savvy suspects the right to be free from all police questioning, not merely the coercive kind and that right cannot be undone by mere politicians. 244 The same is true of the right to con- front the states witnesses, 245 which forces American prosecutors to build cases on live testimony rather than the written case files Euro- pean prosecutors use. 246 Drug law seemed to offer a ready solution to these problems. Physical evidence the drugs themselves, the para- phernalia used to consume them, the cash used to buy them is om- nipresent in drug cases, making eyewitness testimony unnecessary. Po- lice investigation is cheap: a single street stop or buy-and-bust might produce multiple arrests, with many fewer man-hours than in a rob- bery or homicide investigation. And drug markets in poor city neighborhoods were and are associated with the high rates of violence in those neighborhoods. 247 For all these reasons, the substitution of drug prosecutions for violent felony cases was natural. Drug laws passed in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s facilitated that substitution. Draconian sentences far beyond anything attached to vice crimes in the past were attached to possession of even small quan- tities of selected drugs and the drugs selected for such severe treat- ment were those used and sold in poor black neighborhoods. 248 The definitions of the relevant crimes were mechanical; no open-ended de- fenses or mens rea arguments were made available to the unlucky de- fendants charged with drug offenses. 249 For the first time in American history, state criminal statutes carrying severe criminal punishments
244 See Dickerson v. United States, 530 U.S. 428 (2000).
245 See Davis v. Washington, 126 S. Ct. 2266 (2006); Crawford v. Washington, 541 U.S. 36 (2004).
246 The confrontation right exacerbates class-based inequality by raising the cost of prosecuting violent offenders in poor neighborhoods. See William J. Stuntz, Comment, Inequality and Adver- sarial Criminal Procedure, 164 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 47, 50 (2008).
247 See, for example, William J. Stuntz, Essay, Race, Class, and Drugs, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1795, 181315 (1998) [hereinafter Stuntz, Race and Drugs], and sources cited therein. See also Richard H. Blum, Drugs, Behavior, and Crime, ANNALS AM. ACAD. POL. & SOC. SCI., Nov. 1967, at 135, 145 (concluding that drug use by big-city slum-dwelling males was associated with violence and other forms of criminality, but that drug use in the population at large was not asso- ciated with non-drug crime).
248 For the legal side of this equation, see Sklansky, Cocaine and Race, supra note 178. On the character of the relevant drug markets, see Stuntz, Race and Drugs, supra note 247, at 180415.
249 See infra section III.C, pp. 203639.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2023
were designed not to define the prohibited conduct, but to make pun- ishment for other conduct easier. That proposition makes sense of several otherwise puzzling features of drug enforcement and drug politics. Both the timing and demo- graphics of drug punishment track violent crime, not drug crime. The thirty years after 1960 saw an unprecedented explosion in criminal vio- lence. The thirty years after 1970 saw an unprecedented explosion in drug punishment. 250 As for demographics, blacks are imprisoned for drug crime at thirteen times the rate of whites. 251 Rates of illegal drug use vary little across the races. 252 Rates of criminal violence vary much more: in 2006, the murder rate among whites stood at 3.1 per 100,000; among blacks, the analogous figure was 23.7. 253 Clearance rates by race of the offender are unavailable, but clearance rates for violent crimes vary by population density: rates are lowest in large cit- ies and highest in small towns, with suburbs in between. 254 That tracks, inversely, the distribution of the black population: in the places where the most blacks live, clearance rates for violent crimes are low- est; in the whitest areas, clearance rates are highest. 255
The link between drug enforcement and violent crime also explains the absence of large-scale political opposition to contemporary drug laws, despite the draconian punishments those laws impose on drug offenders. Much milder punishments for other vices prompted much more political opposition in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. That earlier age was more moralist than ours: early- twentieth-century Americans criminalized all forms of extramarital sex; 256 twenty-first-century Americans make adult consensual sex a constitutional right. 257 Yet Prohibition proved politically unsustain- able, while the drug war is politically untouchable. During Prohibi- tion, leading politicians like New Yorks Al Smith and Marylands Al- bert Ritchie (each of whom won his states governorship four times)
250 In 1970, there were roughly ten prisoners incarcerated for drug crimes per 100,000 popula- tion. See CAHALAN, supra note 7, at 30 tbl.3-3, 45 tbl.3-17. In 2002, that figure stood at 102. See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbls.6.0001.2002, 6.29.2006.
251 See supra note 4 and accompanying text.
252 See supra note 5 and accompanying text.
253 The number of murders, by race of offender, appears in CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2006, supra note 8, Expanded Homicide Data tbl.3. The general population for 2006, by race, ap- pears in 2008 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at tbl.6. The rates stated in the text assume that murders by offenders of unknown race were committed by whites and blacks in the same proportion as murders by offenders whose race is known.
254 See CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2006, supra note 8, tbl.25.
255 See MCKINNON, supra note 9, at 2 fig.2.
256 See Caminetti v. United States, 242 U.S. 470, 483 (1917) (upholding Mann Act conviction for transporting a young woman across state lines for the purpose of debauchery . . . to wit, that the aforesaid woman should be and become his mistress and concubine).
257 See Lawrence v. Texas, 539 U.S. 558 (2003).
2024 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
publicly criticized the nationwide ban on alcohol sales; 258 aside from former Baltimore Mayor Kurt Schmoke, 259 no major American politi- cian has made opposition to drug criminalization an important part of his or her political profile. Local resistance to the vice wars of a cen- tury ago was common. Not so with respect to the drug war. If drug enforcement isnt a response to criminal violence, these political facts seem inexplicable. There is more. Politicians and judges alike worried obsessively about the chronically inconsistent enforcement of the Eighteenth Amendment, and about what those enforcement patterns said about the rule of law in America. 260 Voters worried too: Prohibition fell not because of the opposition of the wet Northeast, but with the conniv- ance of the dry farm belt. 261 A critical mass of Prohibitions support- ers evidently concluded that repeal was preferable to uneven enforce- ment. Drug enforcement has been plagued by inconsistency and discrimination far worse than anything Prohibition produced. Yet the drug wars supporters still refuse to abandon their cause. Everything about the war on drugs and the politics associated with it makes sense only on the assumption that drugs were not the wars primary target. Violence was. So, in the many cases in which direct punishment for violence was impossible, drug laws made indirect punishment easy. That increased both the size and the racially disproportionate character of state prison populations in two mutually reinforcing ways. First, the use of drug charges as a substitute for violent felony charges increased sentences for non-violent drug crimes. Drugs were not solely proxy crimes; a large fraction of incarcerated drug offenders were suspected of drug crimes and nothing else. But the laws authorizing their punishment were designed with violent offenders in mind. So nonviolent drug of- fenders were, in effect, punished both for the crimes they committed and for the violence of the drug markets in which they participated.
258 Concerning Smith, see LERNER, supra note 120, at 22754. Concerning Ritchie, see, for example, Effects of a Groundswell, TIME, Sept. 29, 1930, at 16, 17; From Anne Arundel Town, TIME, May 24, 1926, at 8.
259 See Baltimore Mayor Supports Legalization of Illicit Drugs, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 30, 1988, at B4.
260 See Robert Post, Federalism, Positive Law, and the Emergence of the American Administra- tive State: Prohibition in the Taft Court Era, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1, 83137 (2006).
261 Franklin D. Roosevelt, the wet candidate in the 1932 presidential election, was both nomi- nated and elected by the dry parts of the country. For an account of Roosevelts nomination and the role Prohibition played in it, see STEVE NEAL, HAPPY DAYS ARE HERE AGAIN 23649 (2004). In the general election, Herbert Hoover, a dry Republican, ran nearly even with Roosevelt in the wet Northeast. Roosevelt, a (newly) wet Democrat, carried the dry West by a two-to-one margin. See OFFICE OF THE CLERK, U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, STATISTICS OF THE CONGRESSIONAL AND PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION OF NOVEMBER 8, 1932 (1933), avail- able at http://clerk.house.gov/member_info/electionInfo/1932election.pdf.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2025
Since poor city neighborhoods had the most violent drug markets, 262
residents of those neighborhoods received the most severe drug sen- tences. The use of drug crime as a (partial) proxy for violence amounted to a sentencing enhancement for black drug crime. Second, because drug punishment was and is a poor tool for deter- ring violence, violence levels remained high even as drug punishment escalated which reinforced political support for tough drug punish- ment: a vicious circle. Recall the Lucerne Street bust. The gun and drug charges filed in that case may track gang members history of criminal violence, but only in the aggregate. The gang was targeted because of the many acts of violence its members committed, and (at least in part) because of the many acts of violence members of other Boston gangs committed. But no gang member knows which particu- lar acts of violence prompt such targeting. From the point of view of any individual offender, the odds that any particular shooting will lead to a later drug trafficking prosecution must be very low. Meanwhile, the gains from the shooting, or at least a large share of them venge- ance, status within the gang, a reputation for toughness are cap- tured by the perpetrator. One reason why violence by drug-dealing gangs remains high is that, from the point of view of the perpetrators, it pays. The upshot is massive drug punishment that deters neither violence nor drug crime. Its dominant incentive effect has more to do with politics than with crime. From its inception, the drug war has been fueled by violence in urban black neighborhoods. Continued violence means a continuing supply of the symbols on which the symbolic poli- tics of crime feeds. Politically speaking, the drug war is self-sustaining as long as it continues to create casualties. Tragically, those are never in short supply. D. Federalism For most of American history, the federal government played a mi- nor role in American criminal justice. It plays a large role now, and the wrong one. In todays justice system, the federal government is a key source of law both procedural and substantive in state criminal cases. It should be a key source of money, especially for cash- strapped urban police forces. Begin with the law of constitutional criminal procedure. That law makes it easier for criminal defendants to threaten expensive, drawn- out litigation. Defendants with the money to pay for high-priced law- yers can make that threat credibly. 263 Poor defendants cannot: their
262 See Stuntz, Race and Drugs, supra note 247, at 181315.
263 Stuntz, Uneasy Relationship, supra note 205, at 2731.
2026 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
lawyers face unimaginably severe docket pressure, and so must plead out the vast majority of cases. 264 Thanks to the crime wave of the 1960s and after, local district attorneys likewise face heightened docket pressure. 265 That fact raises the value of rich defendants ability to draw out criminal litigation. These propositions guarantee rising ine- quality. The generation after the constitutional revolution in criminal procedure saw a sharp rise in the percentage of criminal defendants poor enough to qualify for state-paid lawyers. 266 As criminal trials grew both more expensive and rarer, the pool of criminal defendants grew poorer, and guilty pleas grew more common: a recipe for the massive, class-biased prison populations Americans know today. The Fourth and Fifth Amendment doctrines that the Supreme Court imposed on local police after 1960 have similar distributive ef- fects. Under the governing Fourth Amendment law, inhabitants of de- tached houses receive more protection than apartment dwellers, driv- ers of cars more than passengers on city buses or subways, office workers more than factory workers. 267 Miranda doctrine gives defen- dants the right to opt out of police questioning but only if they know enough to say the right words at the right time. Poor and poorly educated suspects do badly under that regime. Those who do best are recidivists and rich suspects: the former disproportionately invoke their Miranda rights; 268 the police do not bother to question the latter. Those are strange results for bodies of law designed to promote equality as criminal procedure doctrine is, according to the conven- tional understanding. 269 The strangeness has more to do with the de- signers than with the design. Supreme Court Justices have no particu- lar expertise at the enterprise of crafting rules for policing and criminal litigation. Few have extensive criminal litigation experience, fewer still in state cases. The Justices have no means of gathering evidence about the effects of the procedural rules they craft. And constitutional law is easy to make but hard to change, which means that legal errors tend to be uncorrectable. That would be no bad thing if the relevant doc-
264 See sources cited supra note 32.
265 See supra note 205.
266 Entering the 1980s, fewer than half of felony defendants were poor enough to qualify for state-appointed counsel; by 1992, the indigency rate had risen to 80%. See STEVEN K. SMITH & CAROL J. DEFRANCES, BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, INDI- GENT DEFENSE 1, 4 (1996); ROBERT L. SPANGENBERG ET AL., BUREAU OF JUSTICE STA- TISTICS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, NATIONAL CRIMINAL DEFENSE SYSTEMS STUDY 33 (1986).
267 For an explanation, see Stuntz, Fourth Amendment Privacy, supra note 41, at 126774.
268 According to Richard Leo, a suspect with a felony record is nearly four times more likely to invoke his Miranda rights than a suspect with no criminal record, and nearly three times more likely than a suspect with only misdemeanor convictions. Richard A. Leo, Inside the Interroga- tion Room, 86 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 266, 28687 (1996).
269 See supra note 30 and accompanying text.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2027
trines rested on timeless truths. But criminal procedure is filled with rules that rest on changeable and contested empirical assumptions. The rise of new surveillance technologies alters the balance between law enforcement need and individual privacy. Because of the rise of violent urban gangs, the Confrontation Clauses emphasis on live wit- ness testimony has become a barrier to prosecuting ordinary homi- cides. Technological and social change is a constant which means that legal flexibility is essential. Constitutional law is anything but flexible. Federal substantive law should not suffer from these failings. Members of Congress are much better positioned than Supreme Court Justices to gather useful information, to experiment and innovate, and to correct the inevitable mistakes. And their mistakes appear to have smaller consequences, since the statutes that define federal crimes and sentences do not apply in state courts, where most crimes are prose- cuted. Yet federal substantive law may have worse consequences than the law of criminal procedure. The federal share of the prison popula- tion is about 11%; the federal government prosecutes roughly 7% of all felony cases and a fraction of 1% of misdemeanors. 270 The punitive character of federal substantive law accounts for the difference. That is why white-collar defendants achieve worse outcomes than defen- dants charged with thefts and violent felonies. 271 The white-collar de- fendants are charged federally; theft and violent crime defendants are overwhelmingly charged in state court. More important, the federal criminal code increases state prison populations: broad federal liability rules and severe federal sentences allow local prosecutors to induce guilty pleas more easily, with harsher sentences than defendants would otherwise accept. These effects are strongest where the gap between federal and state sentences is most substantial: gun and drug cases. 272 That gap should surprise. Federal criminal law is far more severe than that of most states, as the per- centages cited in the preceding paragraph show but it should be about average in terms of sentencing severity. That is the natural consequence of blending electorates with different preferences: the national electorate is more moderate than the most extreme state elec-
270 See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbls. 6.29.2006, 5.44.2004, 5.17.2004; Stuntz, Po- litical Constitution, supra note 149, at 782 n.5, and sources cited therein.
271 See supra notes 1013 and accompanying text.
272 In 2000, the average federal sentence for drug trafficking was seventy-five months; the av- erage state sentence was thirty-five months. MATTHEW R. DUROSE & PATRICK A. LANGAN, BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS, U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, FELONY SENTENCES IN STATE COURT, 2000, at 3 (2003). Severe federal sentences for gun crimes are the cause of programs like Project Exile that use federal gun charges as a tool for combating urban violence. See Daniel C. Richman, Project Exile and the Allocation of Federal Law Enforcement Authority, 43 ARIZ. L. REV. 369 (2001).
2028 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
torates. Instead of moderation, federal criminal law produces immod- erate severity. Why? The answer stems from two facts. First, federal criminal law is mostly optional: it criminalizes conduct that state law already covers fraud, extortion, robbery, racketeering, drug crime. 273 Second, the law enforcement bureaucracy that enforces federal crimes is small: the number of local prosecutors is five times the number of Assistant U.S. Attorneys. 274 The ratio of state to federal cases is even larger: the number of state-court felony convictions is fifteen times the number of federal felony convictions. 275 The bureaucracys small size means that federal criminal prohibitions have small fiscal consequences. The op- tional nature of federal criminal prohibitions makes them useful vehi- cles for sending symbolic messages. Both facts push toward greater severity. Ironically, so does federal law enforcers restraint. Because federal agents and prosecutors tend to reserve tough federal statutes for seri- ous misconduct recall the Lucerne Street bust, which led to federal gun and drug charges as well as state drug charges Congress faces little pressure to make those statutes less tough. That reinforces the congressional tendency to err on the side of severity when drafting criminal prohibitions and sentencing rules. One more characteristic of federal criminal lawmaking contributes to that tendency. Over the past forty years, as budget pressure on local law enforcement agencies has increased, federal criminal law has become increasingly focused on crimes committed by groups: conspiracy, enterprise crime and racket- eering, terrorism, and so on. Such crimes are more costly to investi- gate and prosecute than one-on-one criminal transactions; it seems natural that the part of the justice system that enjoys the most gener- ous funding has taken over responsibility for the most expensive cases. 276
Criminal organizations, even small ones, are usually good at hiding information. In order to penetrate them, prosecutors need the coopera- tion of some of their members: especially the marginal members, the ones who are least culpable (since prosecutors want to punish the most culpable). To win that cooperation, prosecutors must be able to threaten those marginal members of the organization with serious
273 See 18 U.S.C. 1341, 1343 (2000) (mail and wire fraud); id. 1951 (extortion and robbery); id. 1962 (racketeering); 21 U.S.C. 841 (2000) (drug possession).
274 The number of U.S. Attorneys and AUSAs stands at roughly 5700. ONLINE SOURCE- BOOK, supra note 2, tbl.1.79.2006. The number of district attorneys and assistants is approxi- mately 27,000. Id. tbl.1.86.2006.
275 There are roughly 73,000 federal felony convictions each year, id. tbl.5.17.2004, compared to 1.1 million state-court felony convictions each year, id. tbl.5.44.2004.
276 Cf. Stuntz, Uneasy Relationship, supra note 205, at 2931 (explaining the federalization of white-collar criminal litigation on this ground).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2029
criminal punishment. Which explains the otherwise puzzling character of the federal law of organized crime even by the standards that apply elsewhere in federal criminal law, the offenses used to prosecute criminal organizations are stunningly broad. 277 Federal statutes tar- geting group crimes are designed to overpunish the defendants who fall within their terms, because threats of excessive punishment are the chief means by which federal law enforcers extract information about their targets. The laws are written for their threat value. Severe laws make for more effective threats. Another kind of federal law influenced state criminal punishment in the opposite direction: toward lenity and equality, not severity and discrimination. In 1968, Congress created the Law Enforcement Assis- tance Administration (LEAA), a federal agency designed to funnel money to urban police forces. LEAA money soon dried up; local gov- ernments were left to fend for themselves. 278 A quarter-century later, Congress tried again, passing the Violent Crime Control and Law En- forcement Act of 1994, 279 one portion of which was prompted by then- President Clintons pledge to put another 100,000 police officers on city streets. 280 Both times, the infusion of federal money was short- lived. 281 Both times, it was modest: the vast majority of police spend- ing remained with local governments. 282 Both times, more federal aid led to a short-term increase in the number of police officers per unit population in the nations cities. And both times, higher policing rates appear to have pushed punishment rates down. Figure 1 tracks the annual rate of change in the nations imprisonment rate and in its ur- ban policing rate. The latter figure is shown with a one-year delay: the change in the rate of policing in any given year appears together with the change in the next years imprisonment rate.
277 For a celebratory survey, see John C. Jeffries, Jr. & John Gleeson, The Federalization of Or- ganized Crime: Advantages of Federal Prosecution, 46 HASTINGS L.J. 1095 (1995). The law of terrorism fits the pattern. See Robert M. Chesney, Anticipatory Prosecution in Terrorism-Related Cases, in THE CHANGING ROLE OF THE AMERICAN PROSECUTOR (John L. Worrall & M. Elaine Nugent eds., forthcoming 2008).
278 For the LEAAs origins and history, see MALCOLM M. FEELEY & AUSTIN D. SARAT, THE POLICY DILEMMA: FEDERAL CRIME POLICY AND THE LAW ENFORCEMENT ASSISTANCE ADMINISTRATION, 19681978 (1980). On the agencys demise due to Carter Administration budget cuts, see Charles R. Babcock, By Bits and Pieces, a Crime-Fighting Program Nears Ex- tinction, WASH. POST, Nov. 29, 1980, at A3.
279 Pub. L. No. 103-322, 108 Stat. 1796 (1994).
280 Title I of the Act appropriated $8.8 billion over six years to help local police forces hire more officers. For a good discussion and analysis of the Act, see Harry A. Chernoff et al., Essay, The Politics of Crime, 33 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 527 (1996).
281 On the LEAAs demise, see sources cited supra note 278. On the drying up of Clintons 100,000 cops money, see Daniel Richman, The Right Fight, BOSTON REV., Dec. 2004Jan. 2005, at 6.
282 See 1974 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 33 tbl.1.2; 2003 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 4 tbl.1.3.
2030 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
FIGURE 1. 283
The two curves appear to move in opposite directions: more police officers are correlated with fewer prisoners. This is not simply a by- product of crime trends. The effect appears to hold both in the late 1960s and 1970s when crime was rising steeply and in the 1990s and this decade, when crime rates have fallen substantially. Police of- ficers and prison cells are substitutes, alternative means by which gov- ernments spend money to battle crime. In the last thirty-five years, the mix of those two alternatives has changed radically. The size of
283 Annual imprisonment rates for the period covered by Figure 1 appear in ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.28.2006. The data used to calculate annual policing rates ap- pear in the relevant volumes of UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS, supra note 8, each of which con- tains a table identifying the number of full-time law enforcement officers in the set of reporting cities, along with those cities total population. I calculated the year-by-year percentage changes in imprisonment and policing rates. -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 1 9 6 5 1 9 7 0 1 9 7 5 1 9 8 0 1 9 8 5 1 9 9 0 1 9 9 5 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 5 P e r c e n t
C h a n g e Change in U.S. Imprisonment Rate Change in Urban Policing Rate, One Year Delay
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2031
local police budgets is one reason for that radical change, and those budgets are strained in part because of the dearth of federal aid. Fed- eral and state governments pay a majority of local school budgets; 284
local governments pay 90% of the cost of local police. 285 Had there been more federal legislation like the 1968 and 1994 Acts, those data would differ. Imprisonment rates might differ as well. Those two bursts of federal aid for local police not only helped to reduce criminal punishment; they appear to have reduced the level of police discrimination as well. In the late 1960s, discrimination chiefly took the form of underenforcement in urban black neighborhoods. In the four years after the 1968 Act was passed, urban black arrests rose 16%. 286 By the mid-1990s, the prison population had topped one mil- lion; the chief problem was overenforcement. In the balance of the Clinton Administration, black arrests in cities fell 26%. 287 If federal law makes the justice system more discriminatory, federal budget dol- lars appear to make it less so. III. EQUALIZING CRIMINAL JUSTICE No one chose the unequal justice system Americans know today. Rather, that system arose from a great many shortsighted choices and more than a few well-intentioned ones, made by a wide range of actors over a long period of time. Retracing those path-dependent steps is impossible. Undoing the damage may be impossible as well, at least in the near term. Thankfully, more modest goals are also more achiev- able: stop the downward slide toward ever more inequality; avoid making a bad situation worse and look for ways to make it margin- ally better. The bodies of law that define crime and the institutional arrangements through which those laws are enforced may be unable to guarantee genuinely equal justice. But laws and institutional design can guarantee a measure of moderation. History suggests that mod- eration and equality travel together, reinforce one another. So how does one induce moderation? Place more power in the hands of residents of those neighborhoods where the most criminals
284 See CRECILLA COHEN & FRANK JOHNSON, NATL CTR. FOR EDUC. STATISTICS, U.S. DEPT OF EDUC., REVENUES AND EXPENDITURES FOR PUBLIC ELEMENTARY AND SEC- ONDARY EDUCATION: SCHOOL YEAR 200102, at 1 (2004).
285 See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.1.4.2003.
286 Arrests of white suspects rose 13% during the same years. See UNIFORM CRIME RE- PORTS: 1968, supra note 8, at 129 tbl.36; UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1972, supra note 8, at 140 tbl.42. Both that figure and the figure in the text are based on the numbers of arrests per 100,000 urban population. Changes in the rates of white and black arrests as a percentage of white and black urban populations, respectively, probably differ slightly from the figures just cited.
287 See CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 1995, supra note 8, at 235 tbl.49; CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2001, supra note 8, tbl.49. The same sources show that the white arrest rate fell only 16% in those six years.
2032 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
and crime victims live. Because residents of those neighborhoods suf- fer so much from crime, they are unlikely to support abandonment of the sort that Northern cities experienced in the 1950s, 1960s, and early 1970s. Because those same residents suffer so much from mass incar- ceration, they are also unlikely to support the mindless severity of the 1980s, 1990s, and this decade. Those propositions fit the historical track record: when high-crime cities have exercised the most control over criminal justice within their borders, punishment levels have been more moderate and discrimination less pervasive than today. There are (at least) three ways to make high-crime city neighbor- hoods self-governing without radical changes in legal doctrine or po- litical structure. First, give more state and federal money to urban po- lice forces. Second, increase the number of criminal cases tried by locally selected juries. Third, define frequently prosecuted crimes to include open-ended culpability terms, so that jurors might have room to exercise judgment in the cases they hear. These reforms are emi- nently achievable; none requires large-scale revision of existing law. Taken together, they would make American criminal justice more de- mocratic, and more equal. A. Police Funding According to FBI data, Americas policing rate rose 17% between 1989 and 1999. 288 Based on the Bureaus city arrest data, the black arrest rate fell 17% during those ten years; white arrests fell a mere 6%. 289 Between 1995 the year after Congress passed a watered- down version of Clintons 100,000 cops proposal and 2005, black arrests dropped 30%, compared to a 17% fall in the white arrest rate. 290 Raising the level of urban policing apparently makes the pool of arrestees less racially tilted. Better still, more cops on city streets correlates with fewer young men in prison cells. Early-twentieth- century Southern cities had much smaller police forces than their Northern counterparts; Southern prisons incarcerated a much larger share of their states populations than their Northern counterparts. 291
288 See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1989, supra note 8, at 238 tbl.66; CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 1999, supra note 8, at 293 tbl.71.
289 In 1989, white arrests per 100,000 urban population stood at 4074; the analogous figure for black arrests was 2164. See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1989, supra note 8, at 199 tbl.44. By 1999, white arrests per 100,000 urban population had fallen to 3821, while the analogous rate for black arrests had fallen to 1790. See CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 1999, supra note 8, at 239 tbl.49.
290 In 1995, the FBIs city arrest figures reported 4187 white arrests and 2195 black arrests per 100,000 urban population. CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 1995, supra note 8, at 235 tbl.49. In 2005, the analogous table reported 3467 white arrests and 1544 black arrests per 100,000 urban population. CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2005, supra note 8, tbl.49.
291 See supra pp. 1984 (Table 1), 1992 (Table 3).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2033
When the size of urban police forces rose sharply in the late 1960s and early 1970s, the decline in Americas prison population accelerated. When policing rates kicked up again in the 1990s, the growth in im- prisonment slowed dramatically. 292
Increasing the number of police officers would have another egali- tarian result: it would redistribute police attention across crimes. Vio- lent felonies are underenforced in poor neighborhoods; drug crimes in those same neighborhoods are punished too harshly. Increasing the police-to-population ratio would address both problems. New Yorks experience in the 1990s tends to support that hypothesis: the citys po- licing rate rose by more than a third, clearance rates for non-drug felo- nies also rose sharply, and felony drug arrests fell. 293 That combina- tion is natural: massive levels of drug punishment exist in part as a substitute for direct enforcement of violent crimes. More personnel help to correct the latter problem, and thereby also reduce the size of the former. There is one more reason why more money for urban police would tend to reduce the level of criminal justice inequality. The community policing movement has made urban police forces more attentive to lo- cal needs and preferences than a generation ago, 294 and far more atten- tive than urban prosecutors are today. Spending more on urban polic- ing means more funds for the government entity that pays the most attention to residents of high-crime neighborhoods. That would make criminal law enforcement more locally democratic. In this sphere of governance, equality and local democracy go hand in hand. The Violent Crime Control and Law Enforcement Act of 1994 took a helpful step in that direction by tying federal aid to community po- licing initiatives. The response was promising: the late 1990s saw both the biggest crime reductions and the smallest imprisonment increases in a generation. 295 But the federal subsidies were too modest. Bill
292 See supra p. 2030 (Figure 1).
293 New Yorks policing rate rose from 367 officers per 100,000 population in 1990 to 508 in 1997. See UNIFORM CRIME REPORTS: 1990, supra note 8, at 101 tbl.6, 278 tbl.72; CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 1997, supra note 8, at 146 tbl.8, 347 tbl.78. During those same years, the ratio of non-drug felony arrests to index crimes (violent felonies plus felony thefts) improved dra- matically from 14% to 25% and felony drug arrests fell 13%. See Jeffrey Fagan et al., Neighborhood, Crime, and Incarceration in New York City, 36 COLUM. HUM. RTS. L. REV. 71, 76 tbl.1 (2004).
294 The literature on community policing is massive; even a fair sampling would be too much for a single footnote. For insightful discussions from two different perspectives, the first celebra- tory and the second mildly skeptical, see Tracey L. Meares, Praying for Community Policing, 90 CAL. L. REV. 1593 (2002); and SKLANSKY, DEMOCRACY, supra note 150, at 82105, 11424.
295 In 1994, when the legislation was enacted, the nations homicide rate stood at 9 per 100,000. By 2000, that rate had fallen to 5.5, CRIME IN THE UNITED STATES: 2001, supra note 8, tbl.1 the steepest decline in homicides in sixty years, according to Eric Monkkonens data. See sources cited supra note 89. The late 1990s also saw the nations imprisonment rate rise 21%, see
2034 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
Clinton promised to put another 100,000 cops on city streets; in the end, the federal government paid for something in the vicinity of one- sixth that number, and only for a few years. 296 Clintons original number is a reasonable goal: were it achieved, Americans would have roughly 310 police officers per 100,000 population; 297 by comparison, the analogous figure in EU countries is 337. 298 The cost of an addi- tional 100,000 police officers is not trivial, but neither is it prohibitive. Total spending for local police stands at $58 billion per year; 299 a one- sixth increase in the number of officers (that is what 100,000 more po- lice officers represent) 300 might be expected to cost as much as $15 bil- lion per year. By comparison, total government spending on criminal justice stood at $185 billion in 2003, of which $61 billion was spent on corrections. 301 If, as appears to be the case, hiring more police officers would reduce the number of prison inmates, the net spending increase would be smaller than first appears and a small price to pay for a more equal justice system. B. Jury Trials Jury trials ruled the justice system of Americas past; plea bargain- ing took place in the shadow of substantive law as defined by trial verdicts. In todays justice system, pleas are an autonomous adjudica- tive process. 302 Prosecutors not juries and trial judges govern the content of plea bargains, and suburban voters govern local prose- cutors. Empowering voters in high-crime cities requires fewer pleas and more jury trials. The surest road to fewer pleas and more trials is
ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.6.29.2006: the smallest six-year increase since prison populations began their upward climb in 1973. See 1991 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 637 tbl.6.72.
296 The 1994 legislation appropriated $8.8 billion over six years for aid to local police forces. See supra note 280. Using 2000 budget figures, that amount paid for just under 18,000 local po- lice officers per year during those six years. See 2003 SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, at 4 tbl.1.3, 37 tbl.1.26.
297 As of 2004, there were 731,903 full-time state and local police officers in the United States, plus an additional 86,627 federal officers (not counting federal prison guards). See ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbls.1.27.2004, 1.72.2004. That total amounted to 279 officers per 100,000 population. See 2007 STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 1, at 7 tbl.2. Adding 100,000 officers would have increased the nations policing rate to 313. See id.
298 BARCLAY & TAVARES, supra note 6, at 18 tbl.3.
299 ONLINE SOURCEBOOK, supra note 2, tbl.1.4.2003.
300 See id. tbl.1.29.2004.
301 See id. tbl.1.2.2003.
302 For an explanation of criminal trials limited effect on guilty pleas in a justice system like ours, see William J. Stuntz, Plea Bargaining and Criminal Laws Disappearing Shadow, 117 HARV. L. REV. 2548 (2004). For the classic discussion of (federal) plea bargaining as an autono- mous system of adjudication, see Gerard E. Lynch, Our Administrative System of Criminal Jus- tice, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 2117 (1998).
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2035
to make trials cheaper and pleas more expensive, from prosecutors point of view. Reducing the cost of criminal trials would require radical change in both the quantity and content of criminal procedure doctrine. Raising the cost of guilty pleas, by contrast, is a simple matter. Military courts (along with a few state appellate courts) offer a useful model: they re- view the factual basis of guilty pleas with great care, and with little deference to the pleas themselves. 303 That should be the norm every- where. 304 Stringent appellate review, with reversal in cases of what the military calls improvident pleas, 305 would amount to a procedural tax on pleas. Tax anything and one is likely to see less of it. Plus, military-style review of guilty pleas would make the pleas that remain more accurate a large social gain. Fewer pleas would mean both fewer prosecutions and more trials. More trials could reduce the incidence of discriminatory punishment, but that happy state of affairs is likely to come to pass only if changes are made in the law of jury selection. Current Equal Protection and fair cross-section doctrine encourages juries that represent the jurisdic- tion from which jurors are drawn: 306 usually, the relevant county. If the goal is to protect the interests of residents of high-crime city neighborhoods, that is the wrong pool. Jury selection in large cities should be neighborhood-based, and the number of peremptory chal- lenges should be substantially reduced. 307 The latter change would remove the need for the expensive, elaborate, and largely ineffective body of law barring the discriminatory use of peremptory challenges; eliminating that body of law would make criminal trials cheaper: a large collateral benefit. Fewer peremptories and more localized jury selection might make convictions harder to obtain. That is no bad thing in a system as
303 For representative examples, see United States v. Coffman, 62 M.J. 676 (N-M. Ct. Crim. App. 2006); United States v. Oglivie, 29 M.J. 1069 (A.C.M.R. 1990). For a state court case apply- ing a similar standard to the review of a guilty plea, see State v. Schminkey, 597 N.W.2d 785 (Iowa 1999).
304 The Supreme Court took a step in this direction with its decision in Halbert v. Michigan, 125 S. Ct. 2582 (2005). Halbert held that indigent defendants who plead guilty are constitution- ally entitled to state-paid counsel on direct appeal, id. at 259094 a necessary condition of the kind of review the military employs.
305 See, e.g., Coffman, 62 M.J. 676.
306 Fair cross-section doctrine requires that jury venires represent the general population of the relevant jurisdiction. See Duren v. Missouri, 439 U.S. 357 (1979). Batson doctrine forbids the use of peremptory strikes against potential jurors because of their race or sex. See Snyder v. Louisi- ana, 128 S. Ct. 1203 (2008); J.E.B. v. Alabama ex rel. T.B., 511 U.S. 127 (1994); Batson v. Ken- tucky, 476 U.S. 79 (1986).
307 More radical changes in jury selection might be needed. If jurors are chosen based on voter rolls and drivers licenses and if the urban poor appear more rarely on those lists, different means of selection might be a useful means of increasing jury representation among the urban poor.
2036 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
stacked in the governments favor as ours is. If a prosecutor cannot convince a dozen residents of a high-crime neighborhood that one of their neighbors should be punished, punishment is probably unwise and could well be unjust. Current jury selection rules facilitate con- viction in such cases, instead of obstructing it. C. Vague Substantive Law In 1995, Paul Butler famously some would say infamously argued for the subversion of American criminal justice 308 through jury nullification. 309 Butler maintained that far too many young black men were being sent to prison for nonviolent drug offenses, and urged black jurors to respond by refusing to convict black defendants in drug cases, regardless of the governing law and the evidence. The first of Butlers two claims is a truism. Yet even the liberal New York Times, 310 not to mention a bevy of academic opponents, 311 criticized the second. Butlers own words explain why: jury nullification is subversion; it undermines the rule of law. 312 If black jurors will not convict black drug defendants, the law of controlled substances will differ for blacks and whites. Race-based substantive law seems a poor response to criminal justice racism. But all is not as it seems. For most of American history, white ju- rors exercised the power that Butler suggests black jurors exercise to- day: the power to acquit despite proof of intentional criminal conduct. The label nullification did not attach to that power. On the contrary, substantive criminal law invited the kinds of discretionary judgment that Butlers critics would call lawless. Extralegal mercy was not ex- tralegal; it was part and parcel of crime definition. 313 Butlers critics ignore that fact, and also this one: the mens rea standards and conduct lines that invited jurors to exercise mercy in the past have all but dis- appeared. Nowhere is that more true than in the criminal law of con- trolled substances. Once prosecutors file charges and the defense loses
308 Paul Butler, Essay, Racially Based Jury Nullification: Black Power in the Criminal Justice System, 105 YALE L.J. 677, 680 (1995).
309 See id.; Paul Butler, Black Jurors: Right to Acquit?, HARPERS MAG., Dec. 1995, at 11.
310 See Editorial, When Jurors Ignore the Law, N.Y. TIMES, May 27, 1997, at A16.
311 For a sample of the academic criticism, see Jeffrey Abramson, Two Ideals of Jury Delibera- tion, 1998 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 125, 14552; Andrew D. Leipold, Essay, The Dangers of Race-Based Jury Nullification: A Response to Professor Butler, 44 UCLA L. REV. 109 (1996); Nancy S. Marder, The Myth of the Nullifying Jury, 93 NW. U. L. REV. 877, 93648 (1999); Frank I. Michelman, Foreword: Racialism and Reason, 95 MICH. L. REV. 723, 73334 (1997).
312 As Darryl Brown has explained, those propositions are (to say the least) debatable. See Darryl K. Brown, Jury Nullification Within the Rule of Law, 81 MINN. L. REV. 1149 (1997). But they remain the conventional wisdom. For an aggressive, smart defense of that conventional wis- dom, see Andrew D. Leipold, Rethinking Jury Nullification, 82 VA. L. REV. 253 (1996).
313 See supra notes 98105 and accompanying text.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2037
the inevitable motion to suppress, jury nullification is the only means of avoiding disproportionate or otherwise undeserved criminal pun- ishment. Nullification became a much-debated topic during the last generation not because jurors grew less respectful of the law, but be- cause the law grew less respectful of arguments that might prompt the exercise of mercy. The older state of affairs, the one Butlers proposal seeks to repli- cate, is nicely captured by Justice Robert Jacksons famous opinion in Morissette v. United States. 314 The defendant took spent bomb cas- ings metal tubes used by military pilots in practice bombing runs from government land and sold them for scrap, realizing some eighty dollars in the transaction. Because these events happened in 1948, when military bases filled with unused equipment dotted the country- side, Joe Morissette was charged with theft of government property. 315
Morissette evidently knew what the casings were and clearly knew they were found on government land. Save for the fact that anyone might care to prosecute him, there was no pertinent fact about which he could plausibly claim mistake. Nor could he raise a claim-of-right defense, since he had no preexisting contractual or property interest in the bomb casings. Jackson nevertheless overturned Morissettes con- viction, reasoning that no jury had found criminal intent . . . wrongfully to deprive another of possession of property. 316 The words criminal and wrongfully (neither of which appear in the relevant statute) do all the work in that phrase: the kind of intent Morissette lacked was not cognitive or motive-based; it was moral. In Morissette, proof of criminal intent meant, roughly, proof of the kind and level of moral fault that one ordinarily associates with theft. Compare Morissette with United States v. Hunte. 317 Cheryl Hunte had the poor judgment to have a boyfriend, Joseph Richards, who was a known drug dealer. 318 Hunte joined Richards and one of his col- leagues for a road trip during which Richards picked up several thou- sand dollars worth of marijuana. Hunte made none of the plans, par- ticipated in neither the relevant negotiations nor the drugs packaging and, save for smoking one joint, did not handle the drugs. Most im- portant of all, Hunte neither funded the drugs purchase nor stood to gain from their sale. She was simply along for the ride. 319 Even so, a Seventh Circuit panel affirmed her conviction for possession of mari- juana with intent to distribute and conspiracy to do the same, on the
314 342 U.S. 246 (1952).
315 Id. at 24748.
316 Id. at 276.
317 196 F.3d 687 (7th Cir. 1999).
318 Id. at 689.
319 See id. at 68990.
2038 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
ground that there was some nexus between the defendant and the drugs. 320
Hunte captures the mechanical nature of contemporary drug law. Distribution is proved by proving possession of more than user quan- tity, and (as Cheryl Hunte learned to her dismay) possession may be constructive only. Worse, drug law state and federal alike as- signs punishment based on the weight of the drugs found in the defen- dants possession. That principle leads to decisions like Whitaker v. People, 321 in which the Colorado Supreme Court affirmed the twenty- year prison sentence of a mule carrying a suitcase full of metham- phetamine on a Greyhound bus. David Whitaker was charged with importing methamphetamine into the state and with possession with intent to distribute the drug. 322 The government was not required to prove that Whitaker knew how much methamphetamine he carried, nor that he knowingly crossed a state border, 323 nor that he stood to make a large profit from his errand. (Major dealers rarely travel on Greyhound buses.) As in Hunte, both liability and punishment rested on the drugs, and on the defendants proximity to them. Drug laws like those at issue in Hunte and Whitaker make both convictions and draconian prison sentences nearly automatic. All plausible mitigating arguments I was traveling with my boyfriend; I had no idea how much I was carrying; at worst, Im a small player in a large criminal enterprise are deemed out of bounds. Claims like the one that carried the day in Morissette are unheard of. Butler had it right: nullification is the only means of limiting unjust punishment in such cases. Drug law is more extreme than criminal law as a whole, but the trend in the field runs in the same direction: toward more specifically defined offenses, broader criminal liability, and more severe punish- ments. The second and third trends are old news. The first is at once poorly understood and terribly important. The premise of vagueness doctrine is that uncertain criminal liability promotes unmerited and discriminatory criminal punishment: that vaguely defined crimes are the governments friend and defendants enemy. The criminal law of drugs teaches the opposite lesson. That law is filled with bright lines; even its few standards function like rules: the seemingly vague some nexus requirement in Hunte means that everyone in the vicinity of the drugs loses. Not coincidentally, no other class of criminal cases has seen such grossly excessive punishments, or such discriminatory enforcement.
320 Id. at 692.
321 48 P.3d 555 (Colo. 2002).
322 Id. at 557 & n.1.
323 See id. at 55859.
2008] UNEQUAL JUSTICE 2039
Reintroducing a measure of vagueness to American criminal law would change that state of affairs, by inviting the kinds of jury ver- dicts Butler encouraged without the stigma of nullification. Any of three less-than-radical changes would advance that goal. First, courts could reestablish the older concept of mens rea: save when legislators expressly impose strict liability, proof of a guilty mind or criminal intent the kind of intent that Justice Jackson found lacking in Morissette is required in every case. 324 Second, judges might apply generally a legal principle at the core of racketeering doctrine: when the culpability of defendants charged with a given offense varies widely, the least culpable members of the group should be excused. 325
Third, courts might import into American law the German legal doc- trine that permits any defendant to claim that, though his conduct fits the definition of the relevant offense, it was not sufficiently wrongful to merit punishment. 326
Any of those changes would make criminal liability more legally uncertain yet also, paradoxically, more predictable. A century ago, American criminal law was filled with standards of the sort described in the preceding paragraph. Prison populations were more stable and punishment less discriminatory than in our own time. The explana- tion for that surprising truth is simple: when prosecutors have enor- mous discretionary power, giving other decisionmakers discretion pro- motes consistency, not arbitrariness. Discretion limits discretion; institutional competition curbs excess and abuse. Vague liability rules once were, and might be again, part of a well-functioning system of checks and balances. 327
324 No doubt legislators would impose strict liability more often. But expressly legislated strict liability would be more transparent than the current regime, which has the functional character of strict liability but retains formal mens rea standards. Plus, at least sometimes, legislators would permit the older mens rea standard to stand which would be a large gain for the cause of equal justice.
325 The leading case is United States v. Viola, 35 F.3d 37 (2d Cir. 1994), in which the court held that an errand boy for a Mob boss could not be found to have participate[d], directly or indi- rectly, in the conduct of [the] affairs of the bosss criminal enterprise under 18 U.S.C. 1962(c). Id. at 43.
326 See GEORGE P. FLETCHER, RETHINKING CRIMINAL LAW 77998 (2d ed. 2000).
327 That proposition probably applies as well to sentencing rules as it does to liability rules. Especially federal sentencing rules: bright-line, severe sentencing rules make for more effective threats in plea negotiations and, over the past generation, federal sentencing law has been fa- mously rule-like and severe. See, e.g., KATE STITH & JOS A. CABRANES, FEAR OF JUDGING: SENTENCING GUIDELINES IN THE FEDERAL COURTS (1998). Recent changes in federal sen- tencing doctrine increase district judges power over federal sentences. See Gall v. United States, 128 S. Ct. 586 (2007); Kimbrough v. United States, 128 S. Ct. 558 (2007); United States v. Booker, 543 U.S. 220 (2005). Over time, that should reduce federal laws effect on state-court plea bar- gains: a step toward both lenity and equality.
2040 HARVARD LAW REVIEW [Vol. 121:1969
IV. CONCLUSION Equal justice under law the phrase resonates because of its seeming redundancy. Unequal justice is an oxymoron; law makes jus- tice both equal and just. Those four words are really a long-winded substitute for one: justice. Or so the familiar line goes. That familiar line misleads, because it misperceives the relationship between equality and law. Legal doctrine is not the only means, and in a criminal justice system like ours not the best means, of ensuring rough equivalence in the treatment doled out to black and white of- fenders, or to rich and poor ones. On the contrary: as Americas criminal justice system has grown more law-bound, both the quality and equality of criminal justice have declined. Law is a centralizing force in criminal justice; the key to a more egalitarian justice system is greater local control. The rise of broader and more specific criminal offenses shifted power over punishment from local jurors to state and national voters. The rise of an elaborate constitutional law of criminal procedure shifted power from local politicians to state and federal ap- pellate judges. Changes in the politics of crime reinforced those centralizing trends. Thanks in part to Warren Court criminal procedure decisions, state and national politicians came to use rising urban crime as a po- litical wedge to win the votes of non-urban voters. Liberal Democ- rats and conservative Republicans alike played that game; because they did so, poor urban neighborhoods power over the fate of their young men declined. From the perspective of those who pay for the never-ending battle against crime in the coin of safety and freedom, criminal justice is no longer an exercise in self-government not something residents of high-crime neighborhoods do for themselves, but something people who live elsewhere do to them. If we are ever to see a greater measure of equality in Americas unsystematic criminal justice system, that must change. More law more carefully defined crimes, more elaborately pro- tective procedures is not the answer. Rather, the need is for more politics: not the kind in which images of furloughed prisoners swing national elections, but the kind that happens locally, where crime and punishment alike cut deepest. When police chiefs and (especially) prosecutors listen to those who live in the places we call war zones and heed their wishes, American criminal justice may, at long last, grow more equal. And more just.
Cuz I'm Young & I'm Black & My Hat's Real Low: Constitutional Rights To The Political Franchise For Parolees Under Equal Protection by Shaylen Roberts, Esq.
Rioting by a Different Name- The Voice of the Unheard in the Age of George Floyd, and the History of the Laws, Policies, and Legislation of Systemic Racism