Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition
• Many individual buyers, none of whom has any control over the market
price – i.e. there is no monopsony power
• Perfect freedom of entry and exit from the industry. Firms face no
sunk costs - entry and exit from the market is feasible in the long run. This
assumption ensures all firms make normal profits in the long run
We can come fairly close to a world of perfect competition but in practice there
are nearly always barriers to pure competition.
It is often said that the most competitive market possible is at best rare and
probably does not exist at all in its purest form. Perhaps the vast market in
global currencies takes us as close as we might reasonably get to a world of
perfect competition?
The foreign exchange market is where all buying and selling of world currencies
takes place.
There is 24-hour trading, 5 days a week (about 9pm London Sunday to 10pm
London Friday.
Trade volume in the Forex market is around $1.2 trillion per day. This compares
with to the New York Stock Exchange which trades ‘only’ $25 billion per day.
31% of global currency trading takes place in London.
Well over ninety per cent of trading in currencies around the world is speculative
rather than the buying and selling of currencies to enable people and firms to
conduct business in the real economy.
Banks both as “market makers” dealing in currencies and also as end users
demanding currency for their own operations). These banks include investment
banks and commercial “high street” banks
Hedge funds and other institutions (e.g. funds invested by asset managers,
pension funds)
Central Banks (including occasional currency intervention in the market)
Corporations (mostly defensive hedging of exposures to risk)
Private investors / market speculators / tourists
Homogenous output: The "goods" traded in the foreign exchange markets are
homogenous - a US dollar is a dollar whether someone is trading it in London,
New York or Tokyo.
Many buyers and sellers meet openly to determine prices: There are large
numbers of buyers and sellers - each of the major banks has a foreign exchange
trading floor which helps to "make the market". Indeed there are so many sellers
operating around the world that the global currency exchanges are open for
business twenty-four hours a day. No one agent in the currency market can
influence the price on a persistent basis - all are ‘price takers’.
Seeking the best price: The buyers and sellers in foreign exchange only deal with
those who offer the best prices.
Firstly the market can be influenced by official intervention via buying and
selling of currencies by governments or central banks operating on their behalf.
There is a huge debate about the actual impact of intervention by policy-makers
in the currency markets.
Those who are sceptical about the effects of intervention buying and selling to
move currencies in anything other than the short term talk of governments not
being able to "buck the market". Others conceded that intervention does change
the ruling price for a currency especially if there is concerted and coordinated
intervention by a number of countries acting in unison.
Secondly there are costs involved in a bank or other financial institution when
establishing a new trading platform for currencies. They need the capital
equipment to trade effectively; the skilled labour to employ as currency traders
and researchers.
Despite these limitations, the foreign currency markets take us close to a world
of perfect competition. Much the same can be said for trading in the equities and
bond markets and also the ever expanding range of future markets for financial
investments and internationally traded commodities.
For the firm, the profit maximising output is at Q2 where MC=MR. This output
generates a total revenue (P1 x Q2). The total cost of producing this output can
be calculated by multiplying the average cost of a unit of output (AC1) and the
output produced. Since total revenue exceeds total cost, the firm in this example
is making abnormal (economic) profits. This is not necessarily the case for all
firms. It depends on their short run cost curves. Some firms may be experiencing
sub-normal profits if average costs exceed the market price. For these firms,
total costs will be greater than total revenue.
If most firms are making abnormal (or supernormal) profits, this encourages
the entry of new firms into the industry, which if it happens will cause an
outward shift in market supply forcing down the ruling market price.
The increase in supply will eventually reduce the market price until price =
long run average cost. At this point, each firm in the industry is making
normal profit. Other things remaining the same, there is no further incentive for
movement of firms in and out of the industry and a long-run equilibrium has
been established. This is shown in the next diagram.
We are assuming in the diagram above that there has been no shift in market
demand, i.e. we are considering an outward shift in market supply brought about
by the entry of new competing firms each of whom is supplying a homogeneous
product to the market. The effect of increased supply is to force down the
market price and cause an expansion along the market demand curve. But for
each supplier, the price they “take” is now lower and it is this that drives down
the level of profit made towards the normal profit equilibrium.
In an exam you may be asked to trace and analyse what might happen if
In the long run, because of freedom of entry and exit into and out of the
industry, we expect the market supply curve to be more elastic in response to a
change in demand. The diagram below shows an outward shift of demand with
short run market supply deemed to be relatively inelastic (in which case the
short run adjustment in the market drives prices higher) but where long run
market supply is elastic, putting downward pressure on price as market output
increases.
The next diagram shows how when price and output is not at the competitive
equilibrium, the result is a deadweight loss of economic welfare. The competitive
price and output is P1 and Q1 respectively.