Three-Equation Model, IS - PC - MR
Three-Equation Model, IS - PC - MR
Three-Equation Model, IS - PC - MR
THREE-EQUATION MODEL: IS –
PC - MR
THE PHILLIPS CURVES
Three Basic Phillips Curves (PC):
Expectations-Augmented Phillips Curve (EAPC);
π = πe + α(y – ȳ)
Inertia Augmented Phillips Curve (IAPC);
πt = πt-1 + α(yt – ye)
Lucas ‘Surprise’ Supply function;
y = ȳ + β(π – πe)
The difference between the EAPC and IAPC is that, as we assume
adaptive expectations (see appendix), πe is a function of πt-1 and πt-2 etc.
Hence, the IAPC gives a weighting of ‘1’ to πt-1 and 0 to all the other
past inflation values.
The difference between EAPC/IAPC and the Lucas function, is the
direction of causation (in the former, the output gap drives inflation, in
the latter, the inflation gap drives the output).
In addition, the equilibrium output is different in the EAPC/Lucas from
the IAPC because the IAPC assumes an imperfectly competitive.
THE PHILLIPS CURVES
Phillips curve analysis can show Inflation
how costly disinflation policies are. LRPC
We start at A, and want inflation
down to 2.
Pursue a disinflationary policy,
which moves us down SRPC(4) to SRPC (4)
B.
Inflation is now at 3, thus the SRPC SRPC (3)
shifts to SRPC (3) and move from B
to C. A
4
Continue disinflationary policy, SRPC (2)
moving down SRPC(3) to D. 3 B C
Inflation is at 2, so SRPC shifts to
SRPC (2) and we arrive at Z. E D Z
2
Note that we have to induce
unemployment (go below Ye) in
order to lower inflation.
Could have just gone from A to E,
but has a massive cost.
Ye Y
RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
Rational Expectations means that there’s a perfect market for
information, such that everyone has access to (and utilises)
knowledge about EVERYTHING already known at the time.
Hence, the only deviation from what is expected to happen is
through random shocks (mu and xi).
Hence, we can adapt the Lucas model under rational expectations: If
πe = π, then y = ye + ξ
One can justify the Lucas function: If each firm can ONLY observe
the price of it’s own goods, and sees the price of it’s good rise, it can
attribute this to either:
A general rise in prices (which he can’t verify), OR a rise in demand
for his good.
We assume he already has formed expectations of inflation. Thus, if
the price rise is BEYOND his expectations, he will increase output
as he has (mistakenly) attributed it to a rise in the demand for his
good. This describes the Lucas function.
THE MONETARY RULE
Here is a graphical interpretation of the LRPC
MR, a mathematical derivation will
follow in the monetary policy slides.
In order to understand what point along
the SRPC the Government/Central Bank
will choose, we have to model them with
PREFERENCES. SRPC (4)
These preferences can be modelled as a
preference function which are shown by
the ovals.
A
Both Ovals have a centre of Z; this is the 4
bliss point, where the Government wants SRPC (2)
to be. B
3
However, one Government puts a higher
weight on the potential costs of
disinflation than the other, so one will go E Z
to B and the other E, from point A.
2
Ye Y
THE MONETARY RULE
It is possible to plot the locus Inflation
of all the points of tangency LRPC
between the SRPC (the
constraints) and the preference
functions (the objective).
The resulting locus is the SRPC (4)
MONETARY RULE.
MR 1 is the MR for a
Government which has a 4
weight to the consideration of SRPC (2)
the costs involved with
disinflationary policy. MR2,
however, is a ‘cold’ turkey 2 MR2
approach, which just wants to
cut inflation.
MR1
Ye Y
r
Ye Y
r
MR
Ye Y
THE IS-PC-MR MODEL: MATHS
The IS curve equation can be simplified to Y = A – ar,
where A is the sum of the exogenous constants
(including exogenous demand, investment, Gov
expenditure). We will also note that at the stabilising rate
of interest (rs ), output is at it’s equilibrium level (Ye ).
Hence Ye = A – ars
Thus, Y – Ye = -a(r – re ): IS curve in output gap form.
This isn’t needed to calculate the MR, BUT is important.
To calculate the MR, we need to minimise th
Government’s loss function vis-a-vis the SRPC.
THE MR DERIVATION
Government has a loss function of the form:
V = (y – ye)2 + β(πt – πT)2