Prasad
Prasad
Prasad
Abstract
In the increasingly turbulent environment facing business the strategic management of the firm has become
more predominate. However to date, the linkage between strategic management and financial management of the
firm has largely not been explored. This research utilizes two different methods of analysis to confirm the linkage
between capital structure and strategic posture of the firm. Specifically, managers were found to structure the
selection of debt and capital intensity in a means consistent with the strategic goal of long-run control of systematic
risk.
INTRODUCTION
For 35 years, since Modigliani and Miller’s (1958) seminal article, researchers have tried to explain how firms
choose their capital structure. This extensive interest exists because if an optimal structure can be identified a firm
could maximize its value by reaching and maintaining that financial mixture. A wide variety of explanations have
been offered to explain why firms pick the capital structure they do. For example, information asymmetries
between firms’ managers and the financial markets (Myers & Majluf, 1984), the tax shield of debt and non-debt
expenses (DeAngelo & Masulis, 1980), and the use of debt to maintain managerial discipline (Grossman & Hart,
1982) have all been offered as explanations. This confusing mixture of answers lead Myers (1984), in his
presidential address to the American Economic Association, to conclude that no clear solution exists as to why
firms make certain choices concerning their debt/equity mix. To date, there still is no consistently accepted answer
to this puzzle (Norton, 1990).
Increasingly, business people are seeking to manage companies in a strategic manner. The strategic model of
the firm argues that improved firm performance occurs when the firm’s managers select strategic goals and all of
the activities of the firm are directed towards meeting those goals (Schendel & Hofer, 1976). A part of the firm’s
overall strategy is the firm’s financial strategy and goals (Andrews, 1980). For greatest success the operating
strategies of the firm should be consistent with one another. Thus, the financial strategy of the firm should be
consistent with the firm’s strategic objectives.
To date, the empirical investigations that sought to examine the impact of the organization’s overall strategic
goals on the firm’s debt/equity mix are limited and inconclusive. One would expect that if the strategic perspective
is correct capital structure should vary as managers attempt to fulfill the firm’s strategic goals. One strategic goal
that is directly impacted by the firm’s debt/equity mix is its systematic risk (Mandelker & Rhee, 1984). Therefore,
the efficacy of a strategic perspective of capital structure will be examined in this paper by investigating the control
of systematic risk in firms over the long term through the adjustment of the firm’s capital structure. The long-run
total systematic is used since strategic events need time to demonstrate their full impact (Lubatkin & Shrieves,
1986). Thus, an additional unique contribution of this study is that it examines the “trade-off” between capital
intensity and financial leverage in the light of the firm’s long term beta. In this study, the long run beta covers an
18 year period; this is in contrast to earlier studies which have calculated beta over shorter periods with a
maximum of 5 years previously being used.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Despite a continuing stream of research on the topic (see John & John, 1993; Bagwell & Zecher, 1993) a full
understanding of capital structure has not yet been achieved. One potential reason for this limited understanding is
the lack of integration of organizational theory into the investigation (Frankfurter & Philippatos, 1992). One
significant aspect of organizational theory which yet to be addressed in the investigation of capital structure is
strategic management.
The strategic view of capital structure argues that managers actively seek to direct the firm’s capital structure to
support the firm’s overall long term strategic goals (Barton & Gordon, 1987). There is partial evidence to support
this analysis of capital structure. For example, Sandberg, Lewellen, and Stanley (1987) supported the idea that the
firm’s level of debt is consciously selected by managers. Similarly, Balakrishnan & Fox (193) found firm specific
effects produced variances in firm leverage. However, while there is evidence that managers consciously select at
least part of the firm’s capital structure, it has yet to be established what parameters direct the selection of the
firm’s total capital structure.
The single attempt that has been made to investigate whether strategic goals direct the firm’s capital choices
examined the capital structure of 279 firms over four years (Barton & Gordon, 1988). This investigation found
only partial support for the strategic perspective of capital structure with less than half of the authors’ nine
hypotheses not being rejected. However, as will be detailed later in the paper this lack of results may have been due
to methodological problems in the research.
Despite these inconclusive results, strategic management researchers have increasingly demonstrated support
for the concept of strategic capital structure. This support for the concept is illustrated by the efforts of strategy
researchers to control for each firm’s long term financial structure in empirical analysis by utilizing systematic risk
as a control variable (Miller & Bromiley, 1990). However, an analysis of systematic risk, and in turn strategic
capital structure, that emphasizes its control by firms challenges some traditional financial viewpoints.
The strategic perspective argues that depending on the goals of the firm, and the disposition for risk by the
firm’s managers in meeting those goals, that a firm’s capital structure will vary. However, it has typically been
argued by those using the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) that the relevant measure of profitability is return
adjusted to reflect the systematic risk. Thus, classic financial theory argues: since shareholders can manage
systematic risk present in the financial market they should do so; the firm should not try to manage risk by varying
its long term capital structure. But, Aaker and Jacobson (1987) demonstrated that systematic risk can impact the
profitability of the firm and its strategic business units. They found that the impact of one unit increase in the
systematic and business risk lead to significantly different levels of return. Thus, there is evidence of a potential
benefit to firms from properly managing their systematic risk through their long term financial structure.
It is recognized that investors will try to control the risk present in their own portfolios (Hax & Majluf, 1984).
However, it is not as well recognized that managers also have incentives to seek to control systematic risk of their
firm’s stock. Portfolio theory builds on the assumptions that stockholders can fully diversify and that capital
markets operate without imperfections such as transaction costs and taxes. But the reality is that many investors are
not, or can not afford to be, fully diversified. Additionally, transaction costs can act as an impediment to full
diversification (Constantinides, 1986). Finally, there is evidence that firms can achieve reduction in systematic risk
that the individual could not achieve on their own (Lubatkin & Chatterjee, 1994). Therefore, some investors will
value control of systematic risk in a stock. If the investors do value such control, then managers can increase the
attractiveness of their stock managers by controlling the risk their firm represents to the investors. If the stock is
more attractive to investors it will allow the financial manager to reduce the cost of capital, specifically the cost of
equity due to the increased capital from any new stock issued. Thus, again a benefit to the firm can occur from
properly managing systematic risk.
Agency theory is another widely recognized theory in the finance literature but it is one largely ignored in
regards to the development of a firm’s capital structure. The theory argues that managers will maximize their own
wealth (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). It has been demonstrated that a determinant of a top manager’s compensation
is the stability of the cash flows of the firm (Amihud & Lev, 1981). Thus, a manager may find it is desirable to
have a stable cash flow over time rather than a cash flow which, while totally higher, has greater variability. The
control of systematic risk can provide such stability of the cash flow. Also, it has been shown that the stabilization
of cash flows helps to entrench managers in their positions and to make their removal less likely (Schleifer &
Vishny, 1992); which again should encourage the manager to seek control of the systematic risk of the firm.
Long-Run Strategic Capital Structure 49
Finally, a large portion of a top manager’s personal wealth is typically invested in the stock of their principal
employer (Vancil, 1987). Thus, the control of systematic risk becomes important for the manager since the risk of
the firm impacts his/her personal wealth. Agency theory would argue that in such a situation that managers would
actively seek to control the systematic risk of the firm. Such an alignment between the manager’s disposition for
risk and the firm’s strategy would also be viewed as appropriate by strategic management researchers (Donaldson
& Lorsch, 1983).
In summary, it is reasonable to expect managers to seek to control the firm’s systematic risk. One of the
principal tools through which managers can control systematic risk is the capital structure of the firm.
To further examine the implications discussed above this paper utilizes the Mandelker and Rhee (1984)
decomposition of systematic risk into three elements:
The decomposition of this model suggests that for a given level of total systematic risk there is an inverse
relationship between the amount of debt used and the firm’s asset structure. This inverse relationship leads to the
corporate trade-off hypothesis, as the level of total systematic risk of the firm increases the management will seek
through its functional strategy for capital structure to control that risk. Therefore, the hypotheses for investigation
in this research are:
Hypothesis 1: For a given level of systematic risk, there is a negative relationship between a firm’s capital
intensity (business risk) and its financial leverage (financial risk).
Hypothesis 2: As the level of systematic risk increases, the negative relationship between a firm’s capital
intensity and debt levels will become stronger.
The above hypotheses are also intuitively appealing in the light of finance studies on related topics. Studies
such as Bradley, Jarrell and Kim (1984) have shown a negative relationship between debt and earnings volatility;
additionally, studies such as those by Hill and Stone (1990) have established the relationship between betas,
earnings, and returns. These studies suggest that firms with high betas are likely to have high earnings volatility,
and therefore, are likely to prefer low debt equity ratios. However, the uniqueness of this study lies in its
examination of whether the same holds true from the long term perspective.
METHODOLOGY
In analyzing capital structure a number of methodological problems must be overcome. First, the principal
investigation of strategic capital structure (Barton & Gordon, 1988) has been criticized for the regression model
used for analysis (Ruefli, 1990). It was argued that the introduction of a performance mean and the mean itself into
the same regression equation was inappropriate and resulted in findings that were ungeneralizable. Such a
methodology does not control the shifting of stock and market values over time. Ruefli (1990) cited Barton and
Gordon (1988) as a principle example of research where such an inappropriate methodology had been applied.
In addition to Ruefli’s (1990) criticisms, other criticisms can be made of that principal study. Barton and
Gordon (1988) assumed that the factors introduced into their regression were independent variables. However,
their research showed the variables were interactive. Additionally, the initial research also claimed that the
methodology controlled for financial context. However, it is unclear how they operationalized this.
The methodology used in this investigation builds on the previously cited decomposition of systematic risk by
Mandelker and Rhee (1984). This analysis of systematic risk allows several of the problems faced by the prior
investigation to be overcome. For example, the multiplicative nature of this decomposition considers the
interaction of variables. Also, the absence of considering the financial context can, in part, be overcome through
this methodology since firms with similar risk can be classified together to form homogeneous risk classes. The use
of a capital asset pricing model (CAPM) also overcomes the criticism of Ruefli (1990) that Barton and Gordon
(1988) had used the performance mean and the mean itself into the same regression.1
50 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions
The CAPM postulates that the equilibrium return on any risky security is equal to the sum of the risk-free rate
of return, the risk premium measured by the product of the market price of risk and the security’s systematic risk
(Beta). Mandelker & Rhee (1984) proved that Beta (β) can be expressed as the product of three elements. First, the
risk due to the firm’s asset structure, which can be captured as the firm’s degree of operating leverage (DOL). This
variable represents the firm’s capital intensity. Second, the firm’s risk due to its financial structure which can be
expressed as its degree of financial leverage (DFL). This variable represents the firm’s debt intensity. Finally, the
firm’s intrinsic risk (β*) which is the uncertainty faced by an all-equity and all-variable cost firm. Therefore, β can
be expressed as:
Equation 1
β = (DFL)(DOL)(β*)
Equation (1), demonstrates that the firm’s intrinsic risk β* is magnified by DOL and DFL.2 Additionally, it is
known that DOL will increase as capital intensity increases (Rubenstein, 1973; Hamada, 1972) and that DFL will
increase as the firm’s debt level increases (Percival, 1974).
Examining equation (1), an all equity firm’s systematic risk would be (DOL)( β*) since DFL equals one. The
finance literature defines this type of risk as business risk, βU (Chance, 1982). Therefore, for an all equity firm,
equation (1) becomes:
Equation 2
β = (DOL)(β*) = βU
From equation (2), it is easy to recognize that as DOL increases (due to the asset intensity) the level of business
risk also increases. Thus, the relationship between the firm’s capital intensity and business risk is positive.
Beta should, theoretically, be determined by business risk and financial leverage. Therefore, substituting
equation (2) into (1), we have:
Equation 3
β = (DFL)(βU)
Equation (3), demonstrates that the firm’s systematic risk, β, can be expressed as the product of two elements,
business risk (βU) and the firm’s financial risk (DFL). It also demonstrates that as debt financing for the firm
increases so does the level of systematic risk. However, equation (3) also suggests that there are multiple
combinations of βU and DFL which can be used to generate the same level of β. Finally, using equation (3) we can
express the financial leverage DFL as,
Equation 4
DFL = β/βU
Thus, for a fixed level of β, the equation (4) can be re-written as:
Equation 5
DFL = k/βU
To help visualize the relationship expressed in equations (3) and (5) it is possible to graphically demonstrate the
proposed interactions (see Figure 1). Conceptualize two firms, H and M, with different asset structures and thus
with different levels of unleveraged risk, βU,H and βU,M. It is possible for these firms to obtain the same level of total
systematic risk by consciously selecting their financial leverage (DFL). Therefore, firm H can combine its level of
risk βU,H with the lower level of financial leverage DFLHBetaU for a given level of β. This same level of β is then
also obtained by firm M, with βU,M, by the firm consciously selecting higher debt level DFLLBetaU
Therefore, each firm is associated with two risk-index measures: 1) βU, which is partially determined by the
firm’s asset structure, and 2) β, which is the magnification of the βU due to debt financing. Firms can be classified
together by their βUs to form particular classes of firms that share the same business risk (Chance, 1982).
Similarly, firms can be classified together by their β to form classes of firms with the same systematic risk. Thus,
using equations (3) and (5), by holding systematic risk constant through the use of different β classes, the
relationship between business risk, which is partially determined by the capital intensity (asset structure) and debt
can be examined.
DEVELOPMENT OF DATA
Once the βs are controlled, the hypothesis can be tested by evaluating the relationship of βU and debt levels. To
conduct such an analysis data on debt, β, and βU must be generated for a sample of firms.
To measure debt it has been argued that the annual debt to equity ratio is too unstable (Hamada, 1972).
Therefore, the mean debt to equity ratio (MDR) for the period examined; i.e., the average of the annual book value
of long term debt to equity ratios was used as a proxy for the financial leverage variable. Financial data for various
firms were drawn from the Standard and Poor’s 1990 Compustat Tapes (Annual) for the years 1969-1987. Data for
1988 and 1989 was not used since there was missing data for many firms. To develop the MDR variable
consistently for all firms, those companies whose fiscal year did not end on December 31 were eliminated from the
sample following the methodology of (Chance, 1982). There were 810 firms which met this criteria.
The development of the βU values for each firm required two stages of data development. As per the
methodology of Chance (1982), first a time series of unleveraged returns had to be developed. It was assumed that
in the development of such a time series that the interest paid on the firm’s debt and the average tax rate from the
firm’s financial statements may be applied for each period, and that the Modigliani and Miller model of firm
evaluation (Modigliani & Miller, 1958; 1963) holds as an approximation (Chance, 1982). These assumptions allow
the estimation of the firm’s unleveraged cash flow. However, we use annual data to avoid the problems faced by
Chance (1982) who used quarterly data. We follow the relatively newer Chance (1982) methodology in preference
to the older Hamada (1972) method (i.e., first calculating the leveraged beat and then unleveraging the ß using
Hamada’s adjustment to obtain βU).
With this information it was then possible to develop the βU values for all firms in the sample from the market
model relationship:
Equation 6
where:
The eut were assumed to be homoscedastic, serially uncorrelated and uncorrelated with RMt. Residual analysis
revealed these assumptions to be reasonable. The market rate of returns were obtained by using the Standard and
52 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions
Poor’s 500 stock composite index as a proxy for the market. This data was drawn from the Standard and Poor’s
Daily Stock Price Index and Daily Stock Price Record. RUt and RMt were calculated for each firm for each year
from 1969-1986. Thus, βU s are obtained for each firm using time-series data. The same data is used to calculate
the total returns.
Finally, the betas (βs) for each firm in the sample were estimated from the market model relationship in
equation (7).
Equation 7
RTt = a + (β)(RMt) + et
where:
In the second stage, the βs and βUs calculated above, are used cross-sectionally using the MDR data to study the
relationship between βU and capital intensity.
ANALYSIS
As previously stated, the researchers identified 810 firms which had a fiscal year end of December 31st and
which possessed all the necessary information for analysis. These firms reflected a wide range of two and four digit
SIC codes and firm sizes. This wide distribution of firms should control for confounding variables. For the
calculation of each firms βs and βUs, a regression has to be made using the specific firm’s data over the 1969 -
1986 time period. Thus, before the cross sectional analysis to study the relationship between βUs and capital
intensity could be performed, 1620 regressions needed to be performed to develop the firms’ βs and βUs.
To make the study meaningful, it is necessary that firms have similar systematic risk. Thus, those firm with
negative or very high βs, or βUs, or MDRs were eliminated from the sample. The result was a final sample of 592
firms with βs between 0 and 1.50.
These 592 firms were then subdivided into groups which had similar levels of β (Chance, 1982). The sample
was initially divided into 3 groups of firms with the groups being approximately equal in size (Method 1). The use
of this grouping method was chosen since it adequately addressed the tradeoff between having sufficient numbers
of firms in each interval for statistical analysis while ensuring the firms had similar enough levels of β to be
considered comparable. The division of the sample into equal groups produced unequal β categories in each cell.
To ensure that this inequality in β intervals did not impact the results, the analysis was repeated (Method 2) using
groups with equal β intervals of 0.50 (Chance, 1982) though unequal in group size.
Once the risk was controlled through the establishment of β classes, the inverse relationship (or, the corporate
trade-off hypothesis) between the firm’s asset structure (capital intensity) and level of debt (financial structure)
could be investigated. This was done by examining the βU and corresponding MDR values for each β class using
the least squares regression equation:
Equation 8
βU = A + C (MDRi ) + eei
where: βUi = Beta unleveraged, and, MDRi = mean debt to equity ratio for the ith firm, and eei is an error term.
If C is a negative value, a negative relationship between capital intensity and debt is indicated but the causality
may be in either direction. The regression is used to verify the trade-off between unleveraged Betas and debt. Thus
the regression of MDR on βU could be just as appropriate. Therefore, the following equation is also investigated:
Long-Run Strategic Capital Structure 53
Equation 9
where ee*i is the error term and MDRi , βUi are defined in equation (8).
Again a negative coefficient C* would indicate that debt and capital intensity are inversely related.
RESULTS
The results of the regressions, within each β group, using Methods 1 and 2 are summarized in Tables 1 and 2
respectively. The third column contains the estimated value for C for βU regressed on MDR. The fourth and fifth
columns respectively, represent the R2and the probability for the entire regression equation. The higher the R2
value the greater the variance in risk explained by the debt/asset structure. The t-values are given in the brackets.
Note that for the least squares regressions βU regressed on MDR and MDR regressed on βU produce the same t-
values, R2and probability for regressions using either equations (8) or (9). Column six contains the estimated value
for C* for MDR regressed on βU.
TABLE 1
Regression Results (Method 1)
Group Regression
β Group Estimate C R² Estimate C*
Size F Values
A review of the results in Table 1 and 2 indicates strong support for the theoretical proposition that
management influences and controls the level of systematic risk through its selection of assets and debt structure;
thus, hypothesis 1 is supported. A closer review of the results in these Tables indicates a strong negative
relationship between debt and capital intensity for all three β groups based on a 2-tail test of significance.
It is interesting to note that the adjusted R2 is the highest for the group of firms with the greatest risk. For
example, the finding in Table 1 for the β group 1.08-1.50 that 54 percent of the variance in risk was explained by
the debt/capital interaction is extremely strong. Such a finding is consistent with theory. If firms seek to control the
risk presented to the investor in order to make their stock more attractive, that control of risk should become more
critical as the risk faced by the firm increases. Thus, hypothesis 2 is supported, firms with high levels of systematic
risk do engage in trade-off more actively than do firms with low levels of risk.
There are some limitations to this study which should be recognized. First, this research limited the impact of
any given industry or environment by obtaining a large sample representing a wide range of industries. However,
the use of strategic capital structure may be acute in particular environments. For example, it is argued that some
firms, frequently referred to as turnaround firms, quickly gain control of their costs including their debt expense
(Bibeault, 1982). It may be that firms in decline will pursue the use of strategic capital structure more actively
54 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions
since such firms must manage their funds more actively through such means as the capital structure to survive.
Therefore, future research may seek to expand the examination of strategic capital structure to different
environments.
TABLE 2
Regression Results (Method 2)
Group Regression
β Group Estimate C R² Estimate C*
Size F Values
Second, this study does not examine the interaction between strategic capital structure and firm performance.
The evidence presented here demonstrates that as a strategic goal strategic capital structure is relevant. Future
research should expand this investigation to examine how such strategic goals impact and interact with resulting
firm performance.
This study demonstrates the relevance of the concept of long run strategic capital structure. The evidence
presented illustrated that there is a relationship between the strategic long-term goals of the firm and its capital
structure decisions. Specifically, there is a joint impact of both asset structure and capital structure on systematic
risk. Our empirical findings suggest that, the interaction between asset and financial structure explain a large
portion of the variation in beta. The proposed hypotheses received strong support. Managers do engage in trade-
offs to control and maintain the strategically selected level of systematic risk and that trade-off is stronger the
higher the level of systematic risk.
For the practitioner manager the study has the benefit of demonstrating that the control of systematic risk is a
strategic goal pursued by most firms. The study also has provided one more potential answer to the capital
structure puzzle. This research demonstrates that new means of examining the problem are justified.
This study uses a different perspective to address a problem that has plagued finance researchers for many
years. The results confirm that there is an integration of the various business facets. This research used the
literature from strategic management and finance to gain a better understanding of what laymen might consider to
be a traditional finance topic, capital structure. There are other areas where integration of finance and strategic
management research may allow a greater understanding of the behavior of business firms. For example, how
finance tools can be used by firms to gain a competitive advantage over other firms remains largely unexamined.
Future research should continue to expand our understanding of capital structure. However, it is clear that the
strategic perspective is important to the potential answers to the capital structure puzzle. This research also
supports the need for greater investigation of the commonalities and differences in the fields of strategic
management and finance since both of these fields are an integral part of any firm’s success.
Long-Run Strategic Capital Structure 55
ENDNOTES
1. It has been suggested that a CAPM may not be appropriate for the study of all strategic issues (Bettis, 1983;
Oviatt, 1989). This criticism of CAPM is based on the argument that a wider range of stakeholders, such as
employees and other member of the community, should be considered in evaluating strategic issues.
Notwithstanding this argument, the examination of capital structure is most concerned with the providers of
the debt and equity, the stockholders and creditors. The analysis of other stakeholders is not of a central
concern here. Thus, the CAPM is acceptable for this investigation.
2. In this paper, for the purpose of analysis, the decomposition of beta as suggested by equation (1) is followed.
This equation relies on the decomposition suggested by Mandelker and Rhee (1984) rather than the more
widely recognized decomposition suggested by Huffman (1983). Mandelker and Rhee (1984) was selected due
to its ability to provide fresh insights to the problem of interest.
where:
where:
where:
REFERENCES
[1] Aaker, D.A. and R. Jacobson, “The Role of Risk in Explaining Differences in Profitability,” Academy of
Management Journal, 1987, Vol. 30, pp. 277-296.
[2] Amihud, Y. and B. Lev, “Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers,” Bell Journal of
Economics, 1987, Vol. 12, pp. 605-616.
[3] Andrews, K.R., The Concept Of Corporate Strategy, Irwin, Homewood, Illinois, 1987.
[4] Bagwell, L. and Z. Zecher, “Influence Costs and Capital Structure,” Journal of Finance, 1993, Vol. 48, pp.
975-1008.
[5] Balakrishnan, S. and I. Fox, “Asset Specify, Firm Heterogeneity and Capital Structure,” Strategic
Management Journal, 1993, Vol. 14, pp. 3-16.
[6] Barton, S.L. and P.J. Gordon, “Corporate Strategy: Useful Perspective for the Study of Capital Structure?”
Academy of Management Review, 1987, Vol. 12) pp. 67-75.
[7] Barton, S.L. and P.J. Gordon, “Corporate Strategy and Capital Structure,” Strategic Management Journal,
1988, Vol. 9, pp. 623-632.
[8] Bettis, R., “Modern Financial Theory, Corporate Strategy and Public Policy: Three Conundrums,” Academy
of Management Review, 1983, Vol.8, pp. 406-414.
[9] Bibeault, D.G., Corporate Turnaround: How Managers Turn Losers Into Winners, MaGraw-Hill, New York,
1983.
[10] Bradley, M., Jarrell, G.A., and E.H. Kim, “On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and
Evidence,” Journal of Finance, 1984, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 857-858.
[11] Chance, D.M., “Evidence on a Simplified Model of Systemic Risk,” Financial Management, 1982, Vol.11,
No. 3, pp. 53-63.
[12] Constantinides, G.M., “Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs,” Journal of Political Economy,
1986, Vol. 94, pp. 842-862.
[13] DeAngelo, H. and R. Masulis, “Optimal Capital Structure Under Corporation and Personal Taxation,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 1980, Vol. 9, pp. 3-30.
[14] Donaldson, G. and J.W. Lorsch, Decision Making At The Top: The Shaping Of Strategic Direction, Basic
Books Inc, New York, 1983.
[15] Frankfurter, G. and G. Philippatos, “Financial Theory and Growth of Scientific Knowledge: From Modigliani
and Miller to ‘Organizational Theory of Capital Structure’,” International Review of Financial Analysis,
1992, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 1-15.
[16] Grossman, S. and O. Hart, “Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives,” in J. McCall ed.: The
Economics of Information and Uncertainty, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1982.
[17] Hamada, R.S., “The Effect of the Firm’s Capital Structure on the Systematic Risk of Common Stock,” Journal
of Finance, 1972, Vol. 27, pp. 435-452.
[18] Hax, A.C. and N.S. Majluf, Strategic Management: An Integrative Approach, Prentice Hall, New Jersey,
1984.
Long-Run Strategic Capital Structure 57
[19] Hill, N.C. and B.K. Stone, “Accounting Betas, Systematic Operating Risk, and Financial Leverage: A Risk-
Composition Approach to the Determinants of Systematic Risk,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, 1980, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 595-637.
[20] Huffman, L., “Operating Leverage, Financial Leverage, and Equity Risk,” Journal of Banking and Finance,
1983, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 197-212.
[21] Jensen, M. and W. Meckling, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership
Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, 1976, Vol.4, pp. 305-360.
[22] John, T. and K. John, “Top Management Compensation and Capital Structure,” Journal of Finance, 1993,
Vol. 48, pp. 949-974.
[23] Lubatkin, M. and S. Chatterjee, “Extending Modern Portfolio Theory into the Domain of Corporate
Diversification: Does it Apply?” Academy of Management Journal, 1994, Vol. 37, pp. 109-136.
[24] Lubatkin, M. and R.E. Shrieves, “Towards Reconciliation of Market Performance Measures to Strategic
Management Research,” Academy of Management Journal, 1986, Vol. 11, pp. 497-512.
[25] Mandelker, G.N. and S.G. Rhee, “The Impact of Degrees of Operating and Financial Leverage on Systematic
Risk of Common Stock,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1984, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 45-57.
[26] Miller, K.D. and P. Bromiley, “Strategic Risk and Corporate Performance: An Analysis of Alternative Risk
Measures,” Academy of Management Journal, 1990, Vol. 33, pp. 756-779.
[27] Modigliani, F. and M.H. Miller, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment,”
American Economic Review, 1958, Vol. 48, pp. 261-929.
[28] Modigliani, F. and M.H. Miller, “Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital,” American Economic
Review, 1963, Vol. 53, pp. 433-443.
[29] Myers, S., “The Capital Structure Puzzle,” Journal of Finance, 1984, Vol. 39, pp. 575-592.
[30] Myers S. and N. Majluf, “Corporation Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information
That Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics, 1984, Vol. 13, pp. 187-221.
[31] Norton, E., “Similarities and Differences in Small and Large Corporation Beliefs About Capital Structure
Policy,” Small Business Economics, 1990, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 229-246.
[32] Percival, J.R., “Operating Leverage and Risk,” Journal of Business Research, 1974, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 223-
227.
[33] Oviatt, B.M., “Caveats Concerning Application of the Capital Asset Pricing Model in the Strategic
Management Concept,” Best Paper Proceedings: Academy of Management, 1989, pp. 37-41.
[34] Rubenstein, M.E., “A Mean-Variance Synthesis of Corporate Financial Theory,” Journal of Finance, 1973,
Vol. 28, pp. 167-181.
[35] Ruefli, T.W., “Mean-Variance Approaches to Risk Return Relationships in Strategy: Paradox Lost,”
Management Science, 1990, Vol. 36, No. 3, pp. 368-380.
[36] Sandberg, C.M., W.G. Lewellen, and K.L. Stanley, “Financial Strategy: Planning and Managing the
Corporate Leverage Position,” Strategic Management Journal, 1987, Vol. 8, pp. 15-24.
58 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions
[37] Schendel, D. and C.W. Hofer, Strategic Management: A View of Business Policy and Planning Little Brown,
Boston, MA, 1979.
[38] Schleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny, “Takeovers in the 60’s and the 80’s: Evidence and Implications,” Strategic
Management Journal, 1992, Vol. 12 (Special Issue), pp. 51-60.
[39] Vancil, R.F., Passing the Baton: Managing the Process of CEO Succession, Boston: Harvard Business School
Press, 1987.