The Boom and Bust of U.S. Housing Prices From Various Geographic Perspectives
The Boom and Bust of U.S. Housing Prices From Various Geographic Perspectives
The Boom and Bust of U.S. Housing Prices From Various Geographic Perspectives
This paper summarizes changes in housing prices during the recent U.S. boom and bust from various geographic perspectives. Nationally, the Standard & Poors/Case-Shiller house price index more than doubled in nominal terms during the boom and has fallen by roughly a third subsequently. During the boom, housing prices tended to rise much faster in metropolitan areas in the East and West Coast regions than in the countrys interior. After adjusting for inflation, 7 of 19 metropolitan areas have experienced real declines in housing prices from the start of the boom to the present. Although lower-priced houses showed a larger percentage increase during the boom, higher-priced houses fared relatively better over the boom and bust. Changes in land prices, which are not easily measured, appear to have driven housing prices to a greater extent than changes in the prices of housing structures. Internationally, seven countries experienced housing booms and busts; however, these countries tended to have larger booms and smaller absolute busts than the United States. (JEL R31) Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2012, 94(5), pp. 341-67.
eginning in the late 1990s, U.S. housing prices rose substantially and subsequently fell sharply.1 Because many jobs are related to the value of housing through spending by households and the public sector, especially local governments, the recent swings in housing prices and housing-related employment have had significant macroeconomic and microeconomic consequences.2 Not surprisingly, interest in the movements of housing prices over time and across geographic areas has heightened. This paper is primarily a descriptive review of the recent boom and bust in U.S. housing prices from various geographic perspectives. Our focus is on presenting facts rather than providing explanations for the housing price changes. Thus, we do not present models of house price determination. Nor do we examine the literature assessing the importance of fundamentals (e.g., wages and interest rates) for housing prices changes or the effect of other factors that contribute to bubbles. However, numerous references providing and examining explanations for the housing bubble, as well as housing price changes in its aftermath, are presented throughout the paper.3 Admittedly, the cited references are only a subset of the existing literature.
Jeffrey P. Cohen is an associate professor of economics at the University of Hartford. Cletus C. Coughlin is senior vice president and policy adviser to the president, and David A. Lopez is a senior research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Jeffrey P. Cohen acknowledges support by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the University of Hartford. 2012, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced, published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts, synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
September/October 2012
341
We examine both national and metropolitan area changes in housing prices. Our review of metropolitan areas allows for comparisons across these areas and, more generally, across regions. In addition, we review changes in prices within and across metropolitan areas by housing tiers. For example, housing prices in a metropolitan area are grouped into three categories: low, middle, and high tiers. Then, within a metropolitan area, the behavior of prices across the three categories is compared and, across metropolitan areas, the behavior of prices for each category is compared. To complete our review, we compare the recent U.S. experience with those of numerous advanced foreign economies. A portion of our review of national and metropolitan area housing prices examines the changes in land prices and structure prices separately over the boom and bust periods. As stressed by Davis and Heathcote (2007) and Davis and Palumbo (2008), the price of a house can be separated into its physical structure, which is reproducible, and a plot of land, which is nonreproducible. These components serve different functions. The physical structure is an essential input for housing services as well as for leisure, while land, especially its geographic location, plays a key role in access to employment, public goods, and amenities. These different functions and their varying degrees of reproducibility suggest that physical structures and land are priced differently. As a result, it is not surprising that the prices of structures and land behave differently over time. Especially useful for our analysis are the estimates generated by Davis and his co-authors (2007, 2008) of these prices over time, covering the recent U.S. housing price boom and bust for the nation overall and many individual metropolitan areas. The extent of the boom and bust has varied across metropolitan areas. The Davis datasets and other research allow us to assess how changes in the prices of land and structures have individually contributed to the changes in housing prices.4
Figure 1A
S&P/Case-Shiller House Price Index (1991:Q12012:Q1)
Index (SA), 2000:Q1 = 100 250
200
150
2012:Q1 HPI = 127.32
100
50 S&P/Case-Shiller HPI: U.S. National 0 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
NOTE: The shaded areas indicate U.S. recessions as determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. HPI, house price index; SA, seasonally adjusted.
Figure 1B
Core PCE Rate and Year-Over-Year Changes in the S&P/Case-Shiller HPI (1991:Q12012:Q1)
Percent (SA) 20 15 10 5 0 5 10 15 20 1991
1998:Q1 HPI = 4.77 Core PCE = 1.51 2012:Q1 HPI = 1.86 Core PCE = 1.98 2006:Q2 HPI = 7.45 Core PCE = 2.27
S&P/Case-Shiller HPI: U.S. National (year/year) Core PCE (year/year) 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
NOTE: The shaded areas indicate U.S. recessions. HPI, house price index; SA, seasonally adjusted.
September/October 2012
343
S&P/Case-Shiller index since 1991. Figure 1A shows the level, while Figure 1B shows the yearover-year changes in this quarterly index. As Figure 1A shows, the level of this index began to increase at a faster pace beginning in 1998:Q1. It peaked in 2006:Q1 and subsequently has generally declined to its present level (as of 2012:Q1). Meanwhile, Figure 1B highlights the following: (i) the significantly larger increases on a year-over-year basis in housing prices during the boom period and the subsequent general decline in house prices, (ii) the faster pace of housing price increases relative to the core inflation personal consumption expenditure (PCE) index during the boom, and (iii) the faster growth of the core inflation PCE index relative to the pace of housing price changes during the subsequent period. In nominal terms, housing prices more than doubled, with an increase of 119 percent during the boom period and a decline of 33 percent during the bust period. Overall housing prices increased 47 percent during the entire period (1998:Q12012:Q1). The view changes slightly when housing prices are expressed in inflation-adjusted terms. Using the core inflation PCE index (see Figure 1B), housing prices increased 89 percent during the boom period and decreased 39 percent during the bust period.6 The overall housing price increase was 14 percent. Figure 2 shows two views of the FHFA Purchase-Only House Price Index since 1991. Figure 2A shows that the level of this index began to increase at a faster pace beginning in 1998:Q1. It peaked in 2007:Q1 and has subsequently generally declined to its present level (as of 2012:Q1). Figure 2B shows the following: (i) the significantly larger increases in housing prices during the boom period and the general decline in house prices subsequently, (ii) the faster pace of housing price increases relative to the core inflation PCE index during the boom, and (iii) the faster pace of the core inflation PCE index relative to the pace of housing price changes during the subsequent period. In nominal terms, housing prices increased 83 percent during the boom period and declined 18 percent during the bust period. The overall housing price increase was 49 percent. The view changes slightly when housing prices are expressed in inflation-adjusted terms. Using the core inflation PCE index (see Figure 2B), housing prices increased 57 percent during the boom period and decreased 26 percent during the bust period. The overall housing price increase was 16 percent. Thus, despite the fact that the S&P/Case-Shiller index showed a larger boom and a larger bust than the FHFA purchase-only index, the two indexes are remarkably similar when the beginning of the boom is compared with the present.7 To date, the increase in inflation-adjusted housing prices is virtually identical: 14 percent using the S&P/Case-Shiller index and 16 percent using the FHFA Purchase-Only index. The aggregate market values of homes using the two indexes are also roughly similar at the beginning of the boom compared with their most recent values. For example, using the S&P/ Case-Shiller index, Davis and co-authors (2007, 2008) estimate an aggregate market value of homes of $10.9 trillion for 1998:Q1; using the FHFA housing price index, they estimate a value of $11.4 trillion.8 Using the most recent estimates for 2012:Q1, the respective estimates are $19.5 trillion and $20.8 trillion. As suggested above by the differences in percentage changes during the boom period, the estimates for 2006:Q2 differ substantially, with an estimate of $28.4 trillion based on the S&P/Case-Shiller index and $24.9 trillion based on the FHFA index.
344 September/October 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW
Figure 2A
FHFA House Price Index (1991:Q12012:Q1)
Index (SA), 1999:Q1 = 100 250
2006:Q2 HPI = 221.25
200
2012:Q1 HPI = 181.03
150
1998:Q1 HPI = 121.21
100 FHFA HPI: Purchase-Only, U.S. 50 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
NOTE: The shaded areas indicate U.S. recessions. HPI, house price index; SA, seasonally adjusted.
Figure 2B
Core PCE Rate and Year-Over-Year Changes in the FHFA HPI (1991:Q12012:Q1)
Percent (SA) 15
2006:Q2 HPI = 7.26 Core PCE = 2.27 1998:Q1 HPI = 3.94 Core PCE = 1.51
10
2012:Q1 HPI = 0.48 Core PCE = 1.98
5 FHFA HPI: Purchase-Only, U.S. (year/year) Core PCE (year/year) 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
10
15 1991
NOTE: The shaded areas indicate U.S. recessions. HPI, house price index; SA, seasonally adjusted.
September/October 2012
345
Figure 3
CoreLogic House Price Indexes (1991:Q12012:Q1)
Index (SA), Jan. 2000 = 100 250
2006:Q2 CoreLogic = 200.25 CoreLogic (excl. distressed) = 193.50
200
150
1998:Q1 CoreLogic = 87.34 CoreLogic (excl. distressed) = 87.66 2012:Q1 CoreLogic = 137.29 CoreLogic (excl. distressed) = 145.32
100
50
0 1991
CoreLogic HPI: National CoreLogic HPI: National, Distressed Excluded 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
NOTE: The shaded areas indicate U.S. recessions. HPI, house price index; SA, seasonally adjusted.
sented a relatively much larger share of sales than during the boom period, the decline in housing prices including distressed sales was relatively much largerfalling 31 percentthan the 25 percent decline in housing prices excluding distressed sales.
A METROPOLITAN VIEW
Next we focus on the changes in housing prices in specific real estate markets during the national boom and bust. Our examination of housing prices at the level of metropolitan areas relies on two data sources: S&P/Case-Shiller indexes and Davis and co-authors (2007, 2008).
Figure 4A
Aggregate U.S. Home, Land, and Structure Values (S&P/Case-Shiller Index, 1975:Q12012:Q1)
USD Billions (Nominal) 30,000 Homes Residential Land Structures
2006:Q2 Homes = $28,372 Res. Land = $13,414 Structures = $14,958
25,000
20,000
2012:Q1 Homes = $19,520 Res. Land = $4,151 Structures = $15,369 1998:Q1 Homes = $10,910 Res. Land = $3,308 Structures = $7,602 2007:Q4 (Peak) Structures = $15,584
15,000
10,000
5,000
0 1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Figure 4B
U.S. Land and Structure Shares (S&P/Case-Shiller Index, 1975:Q12012:Q1)
Percent 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1975 Land Share Structure Share 1980 1985 1990 1995
2005:Q4 (Peak) Land Share = 48.5% Struct. Share = 51.5% 1998:Q1 Land Share = 30.3% Struct. Share = 69.7% 2006:Q2 Land Share = 47.3% Struct. Share = 52.7% 2012:Q1 Land Share = 21.3% Struct. Share = 78.7%
2000
2005
2010
348
September/October 2012
Figure 5A
Aggregate U.S. Home, Land, and Structure Values (FHFA Index, 1975:Q12012:Q1)
USD Billions (Nominal) 30,000 Homes Residential Land Structures
2006:Q2 Homes = $24,857 Res. Land = $9,899 Structures = $14,958
25,000
2007:Q1 (Peak) Homes = $25,477 2012:Q1 Homes = $20,843 Res. Land = $5,474 Structures = $15,369
20,000
15,000
10,000
2007:Q4 (Peak) Structures = $15,584
5,000
2007:Q2 (Peak) Res. Land = $10,005
0 1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Figure 5B
U.S. Land and Structure Shares (FHFA Index, 1975:Q12012:Q1)
Percent 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1975 Land Share Structure Share 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
2005:Q2 (Peak) Land Share = 40.8% Struct. Share = 59.2% 1998:Q1 Land Share = 33.3% Struct. Share = 66.7% 2006:Q2 Land Share = 39.8% Struct. Share = 60.2% 2012:Q1 Land Share = 26.3% Struct. Share = 73.7%
September/October 2012
349
Table 1
Percent Change in House Prices across Metropolitan Areas
Percent Change, Nominal House Price Index Values Area Atlanta Boston Charlotte Chicago Cleveland Denver Detroit Las Vegas Los Angeles Miami New York Phoenix Portland San Diego Seattle Tampa Wash., D.C. Percent Change, Real House Price Index Values
Boom Bust Overall Boom Bust Overall (1998:Q12006:Q2) (2006:Q22012:Q1) (1998:Q12012:Q1) (1998:Q12006:Q2) (2006:Q22012:Q1) (1998:Q12012:Q1)
51.0 121.1 34.2 85.1 33.3 71.3 45.9 150.3 231.5 206.8 156.5 160.8 86.1 212.2 104.5 161.7 178.1
(16) (10) (18) (14) (19) (15) (17) (9) (1) (3) (11) (8) (7) (13) (2) (4) (12) (6) (5)
35.4 15.9 11.4 35.3 20.1 9.2 43.8 61.5 40.6 49.7 34.2 25.6 53.6 24.6 39.4 40.7 24.0 46.9 28.3
(9) (17) (18) (10) (16) (19) (5) (1) (7) (3) (11) (13) (2) (14) (8) (6) (15) (4) (12)
2.4 85.9 18.9 19.8 6.5 55.5 18.0 3.7 96.9 54.4 36.3 90.7 21.1 40.2 89.3 66.2 55.5 38.9 99.4
(17) (5) (15) (14) (16) (7) (19) (18) (2) (9) (12) (3) (13) (10) (4) (6) (8) (11) (1)
29.9 90.2 15.5 59.3 14.7 47.4 25.5 115.4 185.2 164.0 78.3 120.7 124.4 60.1 168.6 141.1 76.0 125.2 139.3
(16) (10) (18) (14) (19) (15) (17) (9) (1) (3) (11) (8) (7) (13) (2) (4) (12) (6) (5)
41.7
(9)
24.3 44.2 7.8 7.1 17.4 20.7 36.4 25.3 52.8 19.7 5.8 48.0 6.0 8.8 46.9 28.9 20.6 7.8 54.7
(17) (5) (15) (14) (16) (7) (19) (18) (2) (9) (12) (3) (13) (10) (4) (6) (8) (11) (1)
24.2 (17) 20.1 (18) 41.7 (10) 27.9 (16) 18.1 (19) 49.3 65.3 46.4 54.6 (5) (1) (7) (3)
Minneapolis 107.2
40.7 (11) 32.9 (13) 58.1 45.3 46.5 52.1 (2) (8) (6) (4) 32.0 (14)
NOTE: Nominal values of the S&P/Case-Shiller house price index series were deflated using the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA)s core PCE price index. These real values were obtained by first reindexing Haver Analytics core PCE and nominal S&P/Case-Shiller series for each metropolitan area to 100 at 2000:Q1, and then dividing the reindexed S&P Case-Shiller series with the reindexed core PCE series. The numbers in parentheses indicate the rank within the 19 metropolitan areas. During both the boom period and the entire period, the metropolitan area with the largest increase is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest increase is ranked 19. During the bust period, the metropolitan area with the largest (absolute) decrease is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest (absolute) decrease is ranked 19.
The metropolitan areas vary greatly in terms of the percentage changes in housing prices. For example, during the boom period, nominal housing prices more than tripled (i.e., increased more than 200 percent) in three areas: Los Angeles (232 percent), San Diego (212 percent), and Miami (207 percent). Meanwhile, housing prices increased by less than 50 percent in Cleveland (33 percent), Charlotte (34 percent), and Detroit (46 percent).14 To provide some perspective, assume two houses, each valued at $100,000, in Cleveland and Los Angeles at the beginning of the housing boom.15 At the end of the national boom, the value of the house in Cleveland would be $133,000, while the value of the house in Los Angeles would be $332,000, roughly a $200,000 difference.16 Similarly, the declines in housing prices during the bust period vary greatly. For example, the three cities with the largest percentage declinesLas Vegas (62 percent), Phoenix (54 percent), and Miami (50 percent)experienced housing price declines of at least 50 percent,
350 September/October 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW
while the four cities with the smallest declinesDenver (9 percent), Charlotte (11 percent), Boston (16 percent), and Cleveland (20 percent)experienced declines of 20 percent or less. To provide some perspective, assume two houses, each valued at $200,000, in Las Vegas and Denver at the beginning of the national bust. At the end of the period, the value of the house in Las Vegas would be $76,000, while the value of the house in Denver would be $182,000, roughly a $100,000 difference. The variation carries over to the changes over the entire period for the metropolitan areas. For example, three areasDetroit (18 percent), Las Vegas (4 percent), and Atlanta (2 percent)experienced overall declines for the entire period, while in three other areasWashington, D.C. (99 percent), Los Angeles (97 percent), and New York (91 percent)housing prices nearly doubled over the period. As a result, the hypothetical $100,000 house at the beginning of the boom would be valued at $82,000 in Detroit and $199,000 in Washington, D.C. The disparity across metropolitan areas remains when adjusted for inflation, but the increases during the boom are much smaller and the decreases during the bust are much larger in absolute terms. For example, during the boom, the real increases in Los Angeles, San Diego, and Miami are 185 percent, 169 percent, and 164 percent, respectively, compared with the nominal increases of 232 percent, 212 percent, and 207 percent. During the bust, the real decreases in Las Vegas, Phoenix, and Miami are 65 percent, 58 percent, and 55 percent, respectively, rather than the nominal decreases of 62 percent, 54 percent, and 50 percent. After adjusting for inflation, seven metropolitan areas have experienced housing price declines for the entire period. In addition to Detroit (36 percent) and Las Vegas (25 percent), Atlanta (24 percent), Cleveland (17 percent), Charlotte (8 percent), Chicago (7 percent), and Phoenix (6 percent) also experienced declines in real housing prices. Overall, two metropolitan areas experienced real housing price increases of more than 50 percent: Washington, D.C. (55 percent) and Los Angeles (53 percent). To explore potential relationships across the periods for the metropolitan areas, we calculated simple rank correlation coefficients. The range of this statistic is from 1 to +1. When comparing two sets of ranks, values close to 1 (+1) indicate that metropolitan areas ranked higher in one period tend to be ranked lower (higher) in the second period, while a value near 0 indicates little or no association. First, we find that the rank correlation between the boom and bust periods is 0.53.17 Thus, metropolitan areas with the larger booms tended to have larger busts. Second, we find a rank correlation of 0.68 between the boom period and overall. This result suggests that metropolitan areas with the largest booms tended to maintain their rank for the period overall. Third, we find a rank correlation of 0.22 between the bust period and overall. This suggests that metropolitan areas with the largest busts tended to have smaller overall changes; however, in contrast to the two other rank correlations, this rank correlation is not statistically significant.
Table 2
Percent Change in Nominal House Prices across Tiers within Metropolitan Areas
Percent change Area Atlanta Low tier Middle tier High tier Boston Low tier Middle tier High tier Chicago Low tier Middle tier High tier Denver Low tier Middle tier High tier Las Vegas Low tier Middle tier High tier Los Angeles Low tier Middle tier High tier Miami Low tier Middle tier High tier Minneapolis Low tier Middle tier High tier 144.3 (1) 103.5 (2) 93.6 (3) 48.0 (1) 35.2 (2) 29.0 (3) 27.0 (3) 31.8 (2) 37.5 (1) 264.9 (1) 215.4 (2) 184.0 (3) 65.2 (1) 53.8 (2) 43.2 (3) 27.0 (3) 45.9 (2) 61.4 (1) 316.9 (1) 248.1 (2) 188.0 (3) 53.5 (1) 41.6 (2) 31.6 (3) 94.0 (3) 103.4 (1) 97.1 (2) 164.2 (1) 148.4 (2) 142.7 (3) 70.0 (1) 63.0 (2) 57.5 (3) 20.6 (3) 8.1 (2) 3.3 (1) 76.9 (1) 67.6 (3) 70.2 (2) 15.2 (1) 7.3 (3) 8.9 (2) 50.0 (3) 55.3 (1) 55.0 (2) 96.1 (1) 90.3 (2) 76.5 (3) 53.6 (1) 40.7 (2) 28.8 (3) 9.1 (3) 12.9 (2) 25.7 (1) 184.6 (1) 129.2 (2) 98.3 (3) 28.2 (1) 19.4 (2) 9.7 (3) 104.3 (1) 84.8 (2) 79.0 (3) 61.0 (1) 46.0 (3) 51.2 (2) 63.9 (1) 41.6 (2) 26.3 (3) 41.9 (3) 14.7 (2) 11.4 (1)
Boom (1998:Q12006:Q2) Bust (2006:Q22012:Q1) Overall (1998:Q12012:Q1)
352
September/October 2012
Table 2, contd
Percent Change in Nominal House Prices across Tiers within Metropolitan Areas
Percent change Area New York Low tier Middle tier High tier Phoenix Low tier Middle tier High tier Portland Low tier Middle tier High tier San Diego Low tier Middle tier High tier San Francisco Low tier Middle tier High tier Seattle Low tier Middle tier High tier Tampa Low tier Middle tier High tier Washington, D.C. Low tier Middle tier High tier 214.6 (1) 182.7 (2) 151.5 (3) 42.8 (1) 31.6 (2) 18.6 (3) 80.0 (3) 93.4 (2) 104.8 (1) 212.5 (1) 172.6 (2) 142.6 (3) 60.9 (1) 51.9 (2) 41.6 (3) 22.2 (3) 31.2 (2) 41.7 (1) 118.2 (1) 107.4 (2) 96.7 (3) 36.2 (1) 27.4 (2) 18.8 (3) 39.2 (3) 50.6 (2) 59.7 (1) 268.3 (1) 187.1 (2) 138.2 (3) 59.9 (1) 41.3 (2) 24.2 (3) 47.5 (3) 68.7 (2) 80.6 (1) 281.5 (1) 216.0 (2) 177.4 (3) 48.5 (1) 39.7 (2) 33.1 (3) 96.6 (1) 90.5 (2) 85.7 (3) 98.8 (1) 87.3 (2) 79.9 (3) 27.9 (1) 24.9 (2) 23.2 (3) 43.3 (1) 40.7 (2) 38.1 (3) 182.5 (1) 150.9 (3) 157.3 (2) 65.0 (1) 56.3 (2) 48.2 (3) 1.2 (3) 9.6 (2) 33.3 (1) 206.5 (1) 168.2 (2) 128.9 (3) 34.2 (1) 27.8 (2) 19.7 (3) 101.5 (1) 93.6 (2) 83.8 (3)
Boom (1998:Q12006:Q2) Bust (2006:Q22012:Q1) Overall (1998:Q12012:Q1)
NOTE: The numbers in parentheses indicate the rank within each metropolitan area. During both the boom period and the entire period, the metropolitan area with the largest increase is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest increase is ranked 3. During the bust period, the metropolitan area with the largest (absolute) decrease is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest (absolute) decrease is ranked 3.
September/October 2012
353
Table 3
Percent Change in Nominal House Prices across Metropolitan Areas within Tiers
Percent change Tier Low tier Atlanta Boston Chicago Denver Las Vegas Los Angeles Miami Minneapolis New York Phoenix Portland San Diego San Francisco Seattle Tampa Washington, D.C. Middle tier Atlanta Boston Chicago Denver Las Vegas Los Angeles Miami Minneapolis New York Phoenix Portland San Diego San Francisco Seattle Tampa Washington, D.C. 46.0 (16) 129.2 (10) 90.3 (13) 67.6 (15) 148.4 248.1 215.4 168.2 150.9 216.0 187.1 172.6 182.7 (9) (1) (3) (7) (8) (2) (4) (6) (5) 41.6 40.7 63.0 41.6 53.8 (5) (8) (1) (6) (3) 14.7 (16) 84.8 55.3 103.4 45.9 93.6 9.6 90.5 68.7 50.6 93.4 (5) (7) (1) (9) (2) (14) (4) (6) (8) (3) 12.9 (13) 8.1 (15) 19.4 (15) 7.3 (16) 61.0 (16) 184.6 (8) 96.1 (14) 76.9 (15) 164.2 (10) 316.9 264.9 206.5 182.5 281.5 268.3 212.5 214.6 (1) (4) (7) (9) (2) (3) (6) (5) 63.9 53.6 70.0 53.5 65.2 (4) (7) (1) (8) (2) 41.9 (16) 104.3 50.0 94.0 (1) (6) (4) 9.1 (14) 20.6 (15) 27.0 (10) 27.0 (11) 101.5 43.3 96.6 47.5 39.2 80.0 (2) (8) (3) (7) (9) (5) 1.2 (13) 28.2 (14) 15.2 (16)
Boom (1998:Q12006:Q2) Bust (2006:Q22012:Q1) Overall (1998:Q12012:Q1)
144.3 (11)
48.0 (10) 34.2 (13) 65.0 48.5 59.9 60.9 (3) (9) (6) (5) 27.9 (15)
98.8 (13)
118.2 (12)
22.2 (12)
103.5 (12)
35.2 (10) 27.8 (12) 56.3 39.7 41.3 51.9 (2) (9) (7) (4) 24.9 (14)
31.8 (11)
87.3 (14)
40.7 (10)
107.4 (11)
31.2 (12)
354
September/October 2012
Table 3, contd
Percent Change in Nominal House Prices across Metropolitan Areas within Tiers
Percent change Tier High tier Atlanta Boston Chicago Denver Las Vegas Los Angeles Miami Minneapolis New York Phoenix Portland San Diego San Francisco Seattle Tampa Washington, D.C. 51.2 (16) 98.3 (10) 76.5 (14) 70.2 (15) 142.7 188.0 184.0 128.9 157.3 177.4 138.2 142.6 151.5 (6) (1) (2) (9) (4) (3) (8) (7) (5) 26.3 28.8 57.5 31.6 43.2 29.0 48.2 33.1 (9) (8) (1) (6) (3) (7) (2) (5) 11.4 (15) 79.0 55.0 3.3 97.1 61.4 83.8 (6) (9) (16) (2) (7) (4) 25.7 (14) 9.7 (15) 8.9 (16)
Boom (1998:Q12006:Q2) Bust (2006:Q22012:Q1) Overall (1998:Q12012:Q1)
93.6 (12)
37.5 (12) 33.3 (13) 38.1 (11) 85.7 80.6 59.7 104.8 (3) (5) (8) (1)
19.7 (12) 23.2 (11) 24.2 (10) 18.8 (13) 41.6 (4) 18.6 (14)
79.9 (13)
96.7 (11)
41.7 (10)
NOTE: The numbers in parentheses indicate the rank within each tier group. During both the boom period and the entire period, the metropolitan area with the largest increase is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest increase is ranked 16. During the bust period, the metropolitan area with the largest (absolute) decrease is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest (absolute) decrease is ranked 16.
In some cases, individual properties may fall into a tier on the first sale that differs from the tier on their repeat sale; however, the tier of the first sale determines the treatment of the paired sale.18 A few regularities can be identified across these 16 metropolitan areas. Without exception during the boom, the low tier showed the largest percentage increase in house prices.19 Meanwhile, the smallest percentage increase nearly always (in 13 of 16 areas) occurred in the high tier. Without exception during the bust, the low tier experienced the largest (absolute) percentage decrease.20 Meanwhile, the high tier nearly always (in 15 of 16 areas) showed the smallest (absolute) percentage decrease in house prices. Combining the two periods, the most favorable percentage price changes (in 10 of 16 areas) were generally found in the high tier. On net, in each of these 10 areas the overall change was positive. Meanwhile, the least favorable percentage price changes (in 12 of 16 areas) were generally found in the low tier, with 4 of these 12 cases revealing a decline in nominal housing prices. We now turn to a comparison across metropolitan areas within tiers, beginning with the low tier during the boom period. This information is summarized in Table 3, which is a reformatting of the data in Table 2. For the low tier, during the boom the percentage increase in housing prices ranged from 61 percent in Atlanta to 317 percent in Los Angeles. San Diego and
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW September/October 2012 355
San Francisco have the next-largest changes with increases of 281 percent and 268 percent, respectively. During the bust, the percentage changes (i.e., declines) in housing prices ranged from 15 percent in Denver to 70 percent in Las Vegas. Given these changes during the boom and bust periods, is there any association between them? For example, did areas experiencing the largest percentage increases in low-tier housing prices during the boom experience the largest (absolute) percentage decreases during the bust? To answer this question, we calculate a simple rank correlation coefficient. In the present case, the rank correlation coefficient is 0.21, which indicates a small, but not statistically significant, association across the two periods. During the entire period under consideration, large percentage differences occurred in the changes in low-tier housing prices across metropolitan areas. Housing prices more than doubled in Boston (104 percent) and New York (102 percent), while housing prices declined in four cities: Atlanta (42 percent), Las Vegas (21 percent), Chicago (9 percent), and Phoenix (1 percent). For the middle tier, identical to the low tier, housing prices during the boom rose the most in percentage terms in Los Angeles (248 percent) and San Diego (216 percent). Miami was a close third with an increase of 215 percent. Also identical to the low tier, housing prices rose the least in Atlanta (46 percent) and Denver (68 percent). In fact, the rank correlation coefficient using the low and middle tiers during the boom period is 0.98, indicating a high degree of association. In other words, the ranking of areas from the largest to the smallest in terms of housing price percentage changes is virtually identical for the low and middle tiers. During the bust period, Denver experienced the smallest decline (7 percent), while Las Vegas experienced the largest decline (63 percent). In fact, the rank correlation coefficient using the low and middle tiers for the bust period is also 0.98, indicating that the ranking of housing price percentage changes is virtually identical for the low and middle tiers. Meanwhile, the simple rank correlation coefficient using the boom and bust periods for the middle tier is 0.37, suggesting a positive but statistically insignificant association. During the entire period under consideration, similar to the low tier, Los Angeles (103 percent) and New York (94 percent) were among the areas with the largest increases for the middle tier. Atlanta (15 percent) and Las Vegas (8 percent) were the only two middle tier areas with overall declines in housing prices. Comparing the overall changes for the middle tier with those for the low tier yields a rank correlation coefficient of 0.94, suggesting little difference across tiers in terms of the ranking of housing price changes. Turning to the high tier, as occurred in the other tiers during the boom period, Los Angeles experienced the largest percentage increase (188 percent). In light of the preceding results, it is not surprising that Miami (184 percent) and San Diego (177 percent) also showed large increases. It is also not surprising that Atlanta (51 percent) and Denver (70 percent) showed the smallest increases. The similarity across tiers during the boom period is reflected in the rank correlation coefficients. For the high and low tiers the rank correlation coefficient is 0.88, while for the high and middle tiers the rank correlation coefficient is 0.93. During the bust period for the high tier, Denver experienced the smallest decline (9 percent), while Las Vegas experienced the largest decline (57 percent). Using the boom and bust periods for the high tier, the rank correlation coefficient is 0.55, indicating that areas with the largest percentage increases during the boom period tended to have the largest (absolute) per356 September/October 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW
Table 4
Components of Home Value by Geographic Region
Component value ($) Region 1998:Q1 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 2006:Q2 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 2012:Q1 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 138,425 132,780 155,990 286,100 388,773 224,564 130,930 119,843 133,846 166,311 168,691 145,427 7,495 12,936 22,145 119,789 220,082 79,138 5 9 13 39 48 23 195,896 204,030 205,476 434,659 706,972 356,472 135,656 126,733 122,345 148,119 145,988 136,766 60,240 77,297 83,130 286,541 560,984 219,706 27 35 34 64 76 47 148,169 147,047 140,778 207,709 294,145 189,984 109,388 93,539 95,458 113,200 108,705 105,537 38,781 53,508 45,320 94,509 185,440 84,447 25 35 29 44 58 38
Home Structure Land Lands share of value (%)
NOTE: Nominal values for home, structure, and land values are deflated with the BEAs core PCE index (2004 = 100). Unweighted averages are taken across sample cities in each region. A total of 46 MSAs are included in the full sample (see the appendix). The land share percentages for each geographic region were obtained by averaging the individual land share percentages for all the MSAs within each geographic region.
centage decreases during the bust. Is there any similarity across tiers during the bust period? Using the high and low tiers, the rank correlation coefficient is 0.85, while using the high and middle tiers the rank correlation coefficient is 0.90. Thus, it appears that across areas the tiers behaved similarly.
Table 5
Change in Components of Home Value by Geographic Region
Cumulative change in value (%) Region 1998:Q12006:Q2 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 2006:Q22012:Q2 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 1998:Q12012:Q1 Midwest Southeast Southwest East Coast West Coast Full sample 6 9 13 36 30 13 19 32 39 48 55 38 72 79 39 21 3 32 19.3 26.1 15.8 4.9 10.1 14.6 27 33 18 33 45 31 4 4 9 12 15 6 80 81 65 59 65 70 21.8 26.1 21.1 24.4 27.6 23.9 30 42 42 107 141 73 24 37 27 32 34 30 61 62 79 204 231 130 2.5 0.1 5.3 19.5 17.4 9.3
Home Structure Land Change in lands share of value (percentage points)
NOTE: Nominal values for home, structure, and land values are deflated with the BEAs core PCE index (2004 = 100). Unweighted averages of the individual percent changes for each MSA are taken across sample cities in each region. A total of 46 MSAs are included in the full sample (see the appendix). The changes in land share percentages were obtained by averaging the individual differences in MSA land share percentages for the two quarters in question.
levels for the boom period, the bust period, and overall, a number of observations are apparent. Table 4 shows that average home values tend to be much higher for metropolitan areas on the East and West Coasts than in the Midwest, Southeast, and Southwest. For example, housing prices during 1998:Q1 for metropolitan areas in the East Coast region were 40 percent higher than in the Midwest, 41 percent higher than in the Southeast, and 48 percent higher than in the Southwest. Meanwhile, housing prices in the West Coast region were roughly double those in the Midwest, Southeast, and Southwest. We now turn to observations highlighted by Table 5. First, during the boom period, home values increased substantially more in metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast than in metropolitan areas elsewhere. In metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast, real home prices more than doubled, while in metropolitan areas elsewhere (i.e., Midwest,
358 September/October 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW
Southeast, and Southwest) the increase was less than 50 percent. Second, during the bust, the percentage declines in the metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast were only slightly larger than in other areas. Third, over the entire period (i.e., the beginning of the boom to the present [as of 2012:Q1]) home prices showed substantial increases in the metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast and only small changes elsewhere. In addition to grouping the metropolitan areas into regions, we also examined patterns in housing price changes across the 46 metropolitan areas. A rank correlation coefficient of 0.74 indicates that metropolitan areas with the largest percentage gains in housing values during the boom also tended to be the areas with the largest percentage declines during the bust. With a rank correlation of 0.69, the same pattern holds between the boom and overall changes in housing prices. However, no statistically significant relationship was found between the bust and overall changes in housing prices. Shifting to an examination of the relative importance of changes in land values relative to structure values, a number of observations stand out. First, Table 4 shows that at the beginning of the boom, the land share of a homes total value was substantially larger in metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast than elsewhere. For example, the land share was 44 percent on the East Coast and 58 percent on the West Coast, while it was 25 percent in the Midwest, 35 percent in the Southeast, and 29 percent in the Southwest. Second, during the boom, the land share of a homes total value rose substantially in metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast, while this share changed minimally elsewhere. Using Table 5 (rounded values), the land share increased 20 percentage points on the East Coast and 17 percentage points on the West Coast, while it increased 2 percentage points in the Midwest, was roughly unchanged in the Southeast, and increased 5 percentage points in the Southwest. Third, during the bust, the land share of a homes total value declined substantially in metropolitan areas throughout the United States. The average decline was 24 percentage points nationally, ranging from 21 percentage points in metropolitan areas in the Southwest to 28 percentage points in metropolitan areas on the West Coast. Fourth, the current land share of a homes total value is only marginally lower than it was at the beginning of the boom in metropolitan areas on the East Coast and West Coast, while it is substantially lower elsewhere. For example, the land share is 5 percentage points lower on the East Coast and 10 percentage points lower on the West Coast, while it is 20 percentage points lower in the Midwest, 26 percentage points lower in the Southeast, and 16 percentage points lower in the Southwest. Thus, the land share of a homes total value has remained relatively higher on the East Coast and West Coast than elsewhere in the United States. Examining the 46 metropolitan areas individually provides additional insights concerning changes in land prices and structure prices across these areas. No statistically significant relationship was found for land price percentage changes using the boom and bust periods. However, metropolitan areas with the largest percentage increases in land prices during the boom also tended to have the largest increases overall, and metropolitan areas with the largest percentage declines during the bust tended to have the smallest increases overall. The rank correlation coefficients were 0.54 and 0.82, respectively. The rank correlation of 0.40 for structure prices suggests that metropolitan areas with the largest percentage increases in structure prices during the boom tended to be the areas with the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW September/October 2012 359
smallest percentage declines during the bust. In addition, metropolitan areas with the largest percentage increases in structure prices during the boom also tended to have the largest increases overall, and metropolitan areas with the largest percentage declines during the bust tended to have smaller increases overall. The rank correlation coefficients were 0.79 and 0.81, respectively. In contrast to Davis and co-authors (2007, 2008), Kuminoff and Pope (2011) estimate the market value of residential structures as opposed to the replacement cost of residential structures. It is certainly possible that these two measures could differ. If so, then the estimates of residential land by these groups of authors would differ as well. In fact, this is what Kuminoff and Pope (2011) find when they compare their annual estimates for 1998-2009 for Miami, San Francisco, Boston, and Charlotte with those of Davis and Palumbo (2008). Kuminoff and Pope (2011) find evidence suggesting that the market values of structures may have exceeded their replacement costs during the boom period.22 This implies that during the boom period the land shares estimated by Kuminoff and Pope (2011) should tend to be less than those estimated by Davis and Palumbo (2008).23 Moreover, an implication of Kuminoff and Popes (2011) study is that changes in the market value of structures played a larger role in home price volatility than implied by Davis and Palumbo (2008).24
Table 6
Percent Change in Inflation-Adjusted International Housing Price Changes
Country United States Australia Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway South Korea Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom Boom (1998:Q12006:Q2) 49.9 78.5 55.2 53.3 79.5 68.4 102.2 11.4 131.4 53.4 25.6 61.0 64.2 53.0 4.4 108.6 83.4 10.7 112.2 (15) (7) (11) (13) (6) (8) (4) (18) (1) (12) (19) (10) (9) (14) (17) (3) (5) (16) (2) Bust (2006:Q22011:Q3) 22.6 17.7 12.4 28.5 19.5 2.7 5.1 5.7 25.3 7.9 8.3 6.9 1.7 24.3 6.5 20.8 16.0 14.2 7.3 (2) (17) (14) (19) (4) (11) (12) (9) (1) (6) (5) (8) (10) (18) (13) (3) (16) (15) (7) Overall (1998:Q12011:Q3) 16.0 110.1 74.4 96.9 44.6 72.9 112.6 16.5 72.9 41.2 31.8 49.8 61.4 90.2 11.1 65.3 112.9 26.4 96.6 (16) (3) (7) (4) (13) (8) (2) (18) (9) (14) (19) (12) (11) (6) (17) (10) (1) (15) (5) Similar to United States? No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No Yes No No Yes
NOTE: Data for Canada and Denmark are available until only 2011:Q2; data for Ireland are available only until 2010:Q4. Thus, the Bust and Overall figures provide percent change values with these quarters as the end quarter. The numbers in parentheses indicate the international ranking within this group of 19 countries.
The second category consists of the countries that had a run-up in housing prices but experienced little or no bust in housing prices. Nine countries fall into this category. During the boom period, seven of these countriesAustralia (78 percent), Belgium (55 percent), Canada (53 percent), Finland (68 percent), France (102 percent), Norway (53 percent), and Sweden (83 percent)experienced larger run-ups in housing prices than the U.S. increase of 50 percent. Meanwhile, two of the nine countriesSouth Korea (4 percent) and Switzerland (11 percent) experienced smaller run-ups. Given the lack of a significant bust, eight of the nine countries experienced substantially larger increases in housing prices than the United States over the entire period. For example, the increases over the period for these eight countries ranged from 26 percent in Switzerland to 113 percent in Sweden. Only South Korea, with an increase of 11 percent, experienced an increase less than the U.S. increase of 16 percent. We now focus on the seven countries with a boom and bust somewhat comparable to the U.S. boom and bust. While these countries experienced rising housing prices during the boom and falling prices during the bust, the magnitudes of the changes were often much different from those for the United States. For example, during the boom period, three countriesIreland
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW September/October 2012 361
(131 percent), the United Kingdom (112 percent), and Spain (109 percent)had inflationadjusted housing price increases that were more than double the U.S. rate of 50 percent. The remaining four countriesDenmark (80 percent), Italy (53 percent), the Netherlands (61 percent), and New Zealand (64 percent)also had larger increases than the United States. During the bust, the (absolute) percentage declines in these seven countries were either roughly equal to or somewhat less than the U.S. decline. Overall, these seven countriesDenmark (45 percent), Ireland (73 percent), Italy (41 percent), the Netherlands (50 percent), New Zealand (61 percent), Spain (65 percent), and the United Kingdom (97 percent)have had much larger increases than the U.S. increase of 16 percent.
CONCLUSION
The housing market in the United States continues to draw much attention. This paper attempts to summarize key changes in housing prices during recent years from both a national and a metropolitan-area perspective. In addition, our examination of 18 other advanced foreign economies reveals that the boom and bust of housing prices was not simply a U.S. event. Using 1998:Q1 as the beginning of the boom and 2006:Q2 as the turning point separating the boom from the bust, several observations about housing prices can be made. From a national perspective, the S&P/Case-Shiller index more than doubled in nominal terms during the boom and has fallen by roughly a third subsequently. Overall, this index shows an increase of slightly less than 50 percent. Meanwhile, the FHFA Purchase-Only index shows a relatively smaller run-up during the boom (83 percent) and a relatively smaller decline during the bust (18 percent). However, the overall change in this index is slightly less than 50 percent, which is virtually the same as the change in the S&P/Case-Shiller index. In inflation-adjusted terms, the overall change in the S&P/Case-Shiller index is 14 percent and in the FHFA index is 16 percent. An important development during the bust was the increasing frequency of distressed sales, which often exceeded 30 percent of total sales, which is far greater than during the boom. Given the downward price pressure associated with distressed sales, it is no surprise that the CoreLogic national housing price index including distressed sales has fallen more rapidly (31 percent) than one that excludes distressed sales (25 percent) during the bust period. Major differences are seen across metropolitan areas with regard to housing price changes. While national developments played a key role in housing prices at the metropolitan level, various other factors undoubtedly also affected these prices. During the boom, housing prices tended to rise much faster in metropolitan areas on both coasts than in the interior. In the three metropolitan areas with the largest percentage increasesLos Angeles, San Diego, and Miaminominal housing prices tripled. During the bust, housing price declines across metropolitan areas also varied greatly. Three areasLas Vegas, Phoenix, and Miamiexperienced nominal declines of 50 percent or more. Meanwhile, housing prices in Denver and Charlotte declined 9 and 11 percent, respectively. Metropolitan areas with the larger booms tended to have the larger busts. After adjusting for inflation, 7 of 19 metropolitan areas experienced real declines in housing prices from the start of the boom (1998:Q1) to the present (2012:Q1). Overall, housing prices
362 September/October 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW
declined the most in Detroit: 36 percent in inflation-adjusted terms. Meanwhile, on the other end of the spectrum, housing prices increased the most in Washington, D.C.: 55 percent in inflation-adjusted terms. A number of regularities emerged when housing prices in metropolitan areas were separated by price. During the boom, houses in the low tier had the largest percentage increase, while houses in the high tier tended to have the smallest percentage increase. During the bust, houses in the low tier experienced the largest (absolute) percentage decrease, while houses in the high tier generally experienced the smallest (absolute) percentage decrease. Combining the two periods, the most favorable percentage price changes were generally found in the high tier. Because the price of a house can be separated into the price of its physical structure and the price of the land on which it is located, we explored the limited evidence concerning the changes in the prices of these two components. It appears that changes in land prices, especially for cities on the coasts, have driven housing prices to a greater extent than changes in the prices of structures. However, Kuminoff and Pope (2011) suggest that the magnitude of this factor might be less than suggested by estimates of Davis and co-authors (2007, 2008). Finally, during the present boom and bust it is clear that the United States was not alone. Of the 18 foreign countries reviewed, 7 experienced booms and busts roughly similar to the U.S. experience. However, these countries tended to have larger booms and smaller absolute busts. As a result, for the entire period these countries experienced larger inflation-adjusted increases in housing prices than the United States. A complete explanation of the U.S. experience might provide some insights that apply to these other countries. Moreover, the experiences of these 18 countries might provide instructive information for policymakers and others.
NOTES
1
Davis and Heathcote (2007) and Davis and Palumbo (2008) (see www.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/land-values/) estimate a decline in home values of more than $8 trillion using the Standard and Poors (S&P)/Case-Shiller housing price index and $4 trillion to $5 trillion using the Federal Housing Finance Agency housing price index. A Federal Reserve Board white paper (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Board, 2012) reported that home equity since early 2006 had declined more than $7 trillion. Boldrin et al. (2012) analyze the importance of housing in the Great Recession. See Anderson (2010) and Rueben and Lei (2010) for a discussion of the impact of housing prices on the public sector. For example, Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2012) conclude that borrowers and investors acted on overly optimistic beliefs about house prices rather than being deceived by financial industry insiders during the boom. Pinto (2011) explores how government housing policies contributed to the buildup and collapse of the housing and mortgage markets. Levitin and Wachter (2011) stress the role of an excess of mispriced mortgage financing. Taylor (2007) argues that the Federal Open Market Committee played a major role in the bubble by keeping the federal funds rate too low for too long. Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saiz (2008) develop a boom-bust model in which locations with a more elastic housing supply have relatively smaller price increases and fewer and shorter bubbles. For a discussion of the continuing weakness in the housing market, see the Federal Reserve Board white paper (2012). Weak labor market conditions and various housing market factors, such as a large number of houses for sale, a decline in the supply of mortgage credit, and a costly foreclosure process, are noted. We also examine estimates by Kuminoff and Pope (2011). The S&P/Case-Shiller national home price index is a quarterly index of single-family home prices. Based on a repeatsales methodology, the quality of houses used in the index is constant. The actual sales prices of homes are recorded, and when a specific house is resold, this new sales price is matched to its earlier sales price. The difference in this sale pair is aggregated with other sale pairs into an index. The FHFA house price index, produced by the Federal Housing Finance Agency, is also a repeat-sales index; it uses information on mortgage transactions for single-family proper-
4 5
September/October 2012
363
Various prices indexes could have been used for the inflation adjustment. Our use of the core inflation PCE index simply follows Davis and Heathcote (2007). In the section on international housing prices, we follow Mack and Martnez-Garca (2011) and use the respective countrys headline inflation PCE index. Rappaport (2007) discusses how the value weighting used in the S&P/Case-Shiller index rather than weighting by the number of housing units as in the FHFA index might explain the relatively larger boom and bust in the former index. This weighting difference leads Rappaport (2007) to conclude that the FHFA index is better than the S&P/CaseShiller index for estimating price changes for single-family houses, while the latter index provides a better estimate of the investment returns from owning a representative sample of U.S. homes. See endnote 1. The Federal Reserve Board white paper (2012) reported that 12 million mortgages were underwater as of 2011:Q3, with aggregate negative equity of $700 billion. For about 8.6 million of these mortgages, with $425 billion in negative equity, borrowers were current on their payments. Immergluck and Smith (2006); Frame (2010); Lin, Rosenblatt, and Yao (2009); Rogers and Winter (2009); Sumell (2009); Schuetz, Been, and Ellen (2008); Harding, Rosenblatt, and Yao (2009); and Clauretie and Daneshvary (2009). One common finding is that foreclosed houses sell for less than otherwise comparable houses. For example, Campbell, Giglio, and Pathak (2011) found that over a 20-year period foreclosed houses in Massachusetts sold for 27 percent less than other comparable houses. A second common finding is that foreclosures lower the value of nearby houses. For houses that are 0.05 miles from a foreclosed house, Campbell, Giglio, and Pathak (2011) found a price decline of 1 percent. Meanwhile, for roughly the same distance, Hartley (2010) found a decline of 2 percent in highdensity Census tracts and a statistically insignificant effect in low-density Census tracts.
8 9
10 Recent studies of the impact of foreclosures on housing prices include those by Leonard and Murdoch (2009);
11 Determining the value of land used for residential housing is challenging. Indirect methods are typically used; how-
ever, some research has measured the value of vacant land, while other research has used plots with structures slated to be demolished (i.e., teardowns) and then replaced by new housing to measure land values. See Haughwout, Orr, and Bedoll (2008) and Dye and McMillen (2007).
12 See Davis and Heathcote (2006) for details on the data and methodology underlying their estimates. For up-to-date
estimates, see the Land and Property Values in the US section of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy website (www.lincolninst.edu/resources).
13 We exclude Dallas because of a lack of data before 2000. Also, the term metropolitan area does not necessarily
mean metropolitan statistical area (MSA). For example, New York and Chicago are not identical to their MSAs. (See www.standardandpoors.com/indices/main/en/us. Click on the Economic tab and see S&P IndicesS&P/Case-Shiller Home Price Indices; choose Index Methodology, November 2009, from the menu on the left side of the page.)
14 Such variation across metropolitan housing markets is not surprising. Glaeser, Gottlieb, and Tobio (2012) found that
higher initial prices, warmer winters, lower population density, and less-educated citizens explained more than 70 percent of the variation in price growth across 300 metropolitan areas between 1996 and 2006. A major research challenge is pinning down the effects of national and local factors in explaining housing price dynamics. In addition to local factors, Saks (2008) finds that national shocks have different effects on housing prices across metropolitan areas.
15 Given the differential in housing prices in these two areas, the two houses are not assumed to be identical. 16 A comparable house would have sold for a higher price in Los Angeles than in Cleveland at the beginning of the
boom, so the difference in prices for a comparable house at the end of the boom would have exceeded $200,000.
17 During both the boom period and the entire period, the metropolitan area with the largest increase is ranked 1,
while the area with the smallest increase is ranked 19. During the bust period, the metropolitan area with the largest (absolute) decrease is ranked 1, while the area with the smallest (absolute) decrease is ranked 19.
18 For additional details on these indexes, see Davis and Heathcote (2006). 19 This result is likely due to statistical as well as financial reasons. See the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy website (end-
note 12) for a statistical reason, termed a value effect. Armesto and Garriga (2009) suggest that buyers in the low tier were affected to a larger degree by some financial factors that contributed to the boom and bust. Interest-only loans and increasing opportunities to purchase with no or a very small down payment were likely more important for those purchasing lower-priced houses than for those purchasing higher-priced houses.
364
September/October 2012
chased low-tier housing. The share of 29- to 34-year-olds acquiring a mortgage for the first time between mid-1999 and mid-2001 was 17 percent, but this share was 9 percent between mid-2009 and mid-2011.
21 The appendix lists the 46 metropolitan areas and their grouping into regions. 22 See Table 3 in Kuminoff and Pope (2011) for the numerical estimates. Within metropolitan areas during the boom,
(2008).
24 The preceding discussion about the relative importance of land and structure price changes for housing price
changes is connected to the elasticity of housing supply. Accurate measures of this elasticity are crucial for identifying the share of a price change that should be attributed to fundamentals. In addition to Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saiz (2008), Goodman and Thibodeau (2008) have explored the effects of different elasticities across metropolitan areas. They conclude that much of the large increases in housing prices on the East Coast and in California, where they also tend to find speculative activity, can be attributed to inelastic supply.
25 See the Dallas Feds International House Price Database (www.dallasfed.org/institute/houseprice/index.cfm) and
Mack and Martnez-Garca (2011). The Dallas Feds database contains housing price information for Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
26 Nominal housing prices, which are seasonally adjusted and then rebased so that 2005 = 100, are deflated by the
REFERENCES
Anderson, John E. Shocks to the Property Tax Base and Implications for Local Public Finance. Unpublished manuscript, 2010, University of NebraskaLincoln; www.taxpolicycenter.org/events/upload/Anderson-paper.pdf. Armesto, Michelle T. and Garriga, Carlos. Examining the Housing Crisis by Home Price Tier. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Monetary Trends, August 2009; http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/mt/20090801/cover.pdf. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The U.S. Housing Market: Current Conditions and Policy Considerations. White paper, January 4, 2012; http://federalreserve.gov/publications/other-reports/files/housing-white-paper-20120104.pdf. Boldrin, Michele; Garriga, Carlos; Peralta-Alva, Adrian and Sanchez, Juan. Reconstructing the Great Recession. Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, May 2012. Campbell, John Y.; Giglio, Stefano and Pathak, Parag. Forced Sales and House Prices. American Economic Review, August 2011, 101(5), pp. 2108-31. Clauretie, Terrence M. and Daneshvary, Nasser. Estimating the Home Foreclosure Discount Corrected for Spatial Price Interdependence and Endogeneity of Marketing Time. Real Estate Economics, 2009, 37(1), pp. 43-67. Davis, Morris A. and Heathcote, Jonathan. Appendix to The Price and Quantity of Residential Land in the United States. University of WisconsinMadison, November 2006; www.marginalq.com/morris/landdata_files/2006-11-Davis-Heathcote-Land.appendix.pdf. Davis, Morris A. and Heathcote, Jonathan. The Price and Quantity of Residential Land in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics, November 2007, 54(8), pp. 2595-620. Davis, Morris A. and Palumbo, Michael G. The Price of Residential Land in Large US Cities. Journal of Urban Economics, January 2008, 63(1), pp. 352-84. Dye, Richard F. and McMillen, Daniel P. Teardowns and Land Values in the Chicago Metropolitan Area. Journal of Urban Economics, January 2007, 61(1), pp. 45-63. Foote, Christopher L.; Gerardi, Kristopher S. and Willen, Paul S. Why Did So Many People Make So Many Ex Post Bad Decisions? The Causes of the Foreclosure Crisis. Public Policy Discussion Paper Series No. 12-2, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, May 2012; www.bos.frb.org/economic/ppdp/2012/ppdp1202.pdf.
September/October 2012
365
366
September/October 2012
APPENDIX
Metropolitan Areas and Their Grouping into Regions (Davis and co-authors, 2007, 2008)
Region Midwest Cities Buffalo Chicago Cincinnati Cleveland Columbus Detroit Indianapolis Kansas City Milwaukee Minneapolis/St. Paul Pittsburgh Rochester St. Louis Southeast Atlanta Birmingham Charlotte Memphis Tampa Southwest Dallas Denver Fort Worth Houston New Orleans Oklahoma City Phoenix Salt Lake City San Antonio West Coast Region East Coast Cities Baltimore Boston Hartford Miami New York City Norfolk Philadelphia Providence Washington, D.C. Los Angeles Oakland Portland Sacramento San Bernardino San Diego San Francisco San Jose Santa Ana Seattle
September/October 2012
367
368
September/October 2012
Close
Jeffrey P. Cohen
Associate professor of economics, University of Hartford http://www.hartford.edu/barney/faculty/cohen.aspx
Research Focus
Professor Cohen is an applied microeconomist with specific interests in applying spatial econometrics techniques to problems in the areas of urban and regional economics; transportation, land use, and housing; and environmental and health economics.
Cletus C. Coughlin
Senior vice president and policy adviser to the president, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/coughlin/
Research Focus
Cletus Couglins research focuses on regional economics and international trade.
David A. Lopez
Senior research associate, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Research Focus
David Lopez currently assists Cletus Coughlin and David Wheelock with their research in economic history, banking, and international trade. His research interests also include economic development and public policy.