IPEG Papers
in
Global
Political
Economy
1
IPEG papers in Global Political Economy is the official working paper series of the
International Political Economy Group (IPEG) of the British International Studies
Association (BISA). The working paper series is intended to provide a forum for debate
and discussion. All of the papers published in the series have been subjected to a mild
refereeing process to maintain quality. As with all working paper series, the papers
published here do not necessarily appear in their final form. As such, their appearance as
an IPEG paper does not preclude revision for submission to another forum. IPEG papers
in Global Political Economy are only available on-line to all members of IPEG, BSIA
and other visitors to our website. While these papers are free to all, we nevertheless
require that when drawn upon for the purposes of research and argumentation they are
acknowledged in the appropriate manner.
Paul Langley
IPEG Convenor
Andrew Wyatt
Series Editor
April 2007
2
IPEG Papers in Global Political Economy no. 28, May 2007
Ireland as a ‘competition state’
Peadar Kirby and Mary Murphy
Ireland’s economic boom from 1994 to 2000 (from which the term ‘Celtic Tiger’ was
coined) has generated an extensive academic literature debating its causes, impacts and
consequences. While an initial reading emphasised that economic transformation had
been achieved through market liberalisation (Barry, 1999; Sweeney, 1999; Clinch,
Convery and Walsh, 2002), this was soon contested by a literature that focused more on
the crucial role played by the state. Scholars at the influential Economic and Social
Research Institute (ESRI) argued that ‘there was a great deal more to Ireland’s success
than liberalization of markets. The state has been deeply implicated in the entire process,
managing both economic development and the welfare state’ (Nolan, O’Connell and
Whelan, 2000: 3). They conclude that ‘it is not a simple story of globalization, forced
withdrawal of the state and the promotion of neo-liberalism’ (ibid.: 1). Ó Riain (2000,
2004) applied to the Irish state the concept of ‘embedded autonomy’ taken from Evans
(1995) and he characterised it as a ‘flexible developmental state’ in contrast to the
bureaucratic developmental states of East Asia, arguing that this constitutes a new model
of state-led development that is more responsive to the demands and pressures of
globalisation. His later work slightly amended the concept to that of a Developmental
Network State (DNS) as ‘network centrality is critical to this new state – isolation from
the local or the global renders it ineffective’ (2004: 4). While contested by O’Hearn
(2000) and Kirby (2002), the concept of the developmental state was adopted by the
National Economic and Social Council (NESC) in its 2003 tri-annual statement of the
state’s economic and social strategy and used as the basis for proposing a Developmental
Welfare State (DWS) for Ireland (NESC, 2003: 29-33; 2005a, 2005b).
In critiquing the adequacy of the concept of the developmental state for the Irish case,
Kirby (2002, 2005) argued that the concept of competition state describes more
accurately the nature and operation of the Irish state in the era of the Celtic Tiger since it
prioritises goals of economic competitiveness over those of social cohesion and welfare.
Following Kirby, Dukelow also adopts the concept of competition state for the Irish case
as ‘the state has taken a selective interventionist role in the manner of a competition state
to re-orient social security policy to enhance economic competitiveness by tackling
unemployment, yet leaving levels of income inequality and poverty remain relatively
high’ (2004: 27). Boyle, though seemingly unaware that the concept had already been
introduced into debates on the Irish state, baldly states: ‘Contemporary Ireland is an
exemplar of the competition state, where social policy is subordinated to the needs of the
economy’ (2005: 16). Meanwhile, the competition state concept was itself criticised by Ó
Riain since it ‘unnecessarily narrows our understanding of the institutions underpinning
economic growth’ and obscures ‘the existence of a political space for struggles within
3
and through existing institutions over how development could and should be structured’
(2004: 18).
Understanding the institutional underpinnings of the Celtic Tiger, therefore, has given
rise to two competing conceptions of the state. Is the contemporary Irish state a new type
of developmental state thereby holding lessons of successful development for many other
states, or is it a competition state, an exemplar of how globalisation resituates the state so
that it prioritises the needs of global capital over those of its own citizens? The purpose of
this paper is to take this debate further. The paper begins by elaborating further what is
meant by the competition state, broadening the treatment beyond the Irish case and
linking it to the political economy of development under the conditions of today’s
globalisation. The paper then tests the concept of the competition state empirically
through examining the changing nature of Ireland’s social security regime and analysing
the features and actors of the Irish state that help account for the particular outcomes
observed. The paper concludes by summarising the argument, emphasising the role of
state agency in the changes identified and raising a key question about the future
direction of the Irish state.
The approach taken in this paper seeks to overcome a number of limitations of the
competition state concept and, more generally, of political economy approaches to
theorising the state, as identified by Phillips (2005). She identifies economism (namely a
concentration on state economic policy and strategies) and a functionalist bias (namely
understanding the form of state as an outcome of its adaptation to the challenges of
economic globalisation) as characterising these approaches. This bias, according to
Phillips, results in a ‘generalized failure to consider or advance clear understandings of
the processes by which outcomes are produced’ (2005: 103) so that politics, in the sense
of ‘variation, contingency and specificity in the institutional structures of states, the
nature of state strategies and the types of state-society linkages that prevail in particular
political economies’ is largely missing (ibid: 110; emphasis in original). In choosing to
focus on an aspect of the state’s social policy rather than on its economic strategies and in
seeking to explain in quite some detail what accounts for the outcomes observed, it is
intended that this paper break new ground in political economy analyses of how the state
is adapting to the pressures of globalisation.
Globalisation and the competition state
Whereas the developmental state concept emerged from analysing the ways in which
certain developing states (in East Asia and in Latin America) succeeded in building a
modern and competitive industrial economy, the competition state concept emerged from
analysing the ways in which developed industrial states were restructuring themselves in
response to the constraints and opportunities opened up by neoliberal globalisation in the
1990s. Already, even before a new international context shaped by globalisation had
emerged, the national compact between capital and labour that characterised such states
(the Keynesian welfare state or KWS as it was often called) was under pressure from
internal factors. Recession in the 1970s focused attention on the expense of maintaining
generous welfare states and analysts began to see them as putting a fetter on economic
success due both to their high cost and to their rigidities (protection for labour, high
4
taxes, lack of incentives). While these pressures originally derived from within, by the
1980s and 1990s pressures deriving from outside were also being recognised, such as
those of international competitiveness, the mobility of capital worldwide and intensified
international trade (Pierson, 2004:100-102). A central cause has been the impact of new
information and communications technologies (ICTs) which have made possible both the
more intense and immediate global interconnectedness that drives finance, production
and trade and also new forms of corporate organisation that have come to dominate more
and more key production chains worldwide, thereby strengthening the power of global
market forces as against that of national state authorities. As Ruggie has recognised, the
globalisation of financial markets and production chains challenged the premises on
which the grand bargain between capital and labour rested since that bargain presupposed
a world in which the state could effectively mediate external impacts through such tools
as tariffs and exchange rates (Ruggie, 2003: 94). In this situation, welfare states have not
collapsed in the way that communist and developing states did but they are under
pressure to reduce costs and erode the level and extent of protection they previously
provided (Mishra, 1999; Scharpf, 2000). This global context, therefore, has created new
pressures to which all states have to respond. It is out of analysing the ways in which
states are responding that the concept of the competition state emerged.
Various attempts have been made to characterise the new regime that is emerging as a
successor to the Keynesian welfare state. Jessop sees this ‘new state form’ as a
Schumpeterian workfare state (SWS) which seeks ‘to strengthen as far as possible the
structural competitiveness of the national economy by intervening on the supply-side;
and to subordinate social policy to the needs of labour market flexibility and/or to the
constraints of international competition’ (Jessop, 1994: 24). In his work, Cerny describes
the emergence of a ‘competition state’ out of the tensions between the demands of
economic globalisation and the embedded state/society practices that characterised the
national welfare state as the priorities of policy move away from the general
maximisation of public welfare (full employment, redistributive transfer payments and
social service provision) to the promotion of enterprise, innovation and profitability in
both private and public sectors. These reactions, however, follow no set pattern or master
plan: ‘The emerging embedded neoliberal consensus is therefore not simply a developing
“from outside” or “from above”; it is also a political construction promoted by political
entrepreneurs who must design projects, convince others, build coalitions and ultimately
win some sort of political legitimacy “from inside” and “from below”’(Cerny, Menz and
Soederberg, 2005: 19). Tracing this process as they see it happening in western European
states and the European Union itself, in North America and New Zealand, in Latin
America and in eastern European countries, they identify a process that is ‘almost without
exception elite-driven …. based on sustained support from converted academics, policy
advisers and consultants both within and outside the public sector, government officials,
and firms and other economic actors, especially representatives of employers and
business organisations, and, especially consumers and many taxpayers (ibid.: 22-23).
What can be observed, therefore, ‘is not so much the continuity or maintenance of older
“varieties of capitalism”, but rather the emergence of varieties of neoliberalism – of
diversity within convergence, of the forging of different “roads to globalization”. …
States are increasingly becoming “competition states”’ (ibid.: 21, 22; emphasis in
5
original). This belies any easy claim that the state is retreating or that its role is
marginalised in the political economy of today’s globalised world order. Rather, what is
happening is the redefinition of its core activities as it adapts to the new global
environment in which it operates. This helps make sense of what otherwise may seem a
contradiction between the state’s ever weakening ability to secure the welfare of its
citizens while on the other hand it becomes ever more intrusive in the life of the national
economy such as, for example, through a myriad of new regulatory agencies. As Cerny et
al. point out: ‘Deregulation was never really deregulation; it increasingly became the
replacement of outcome-orientated and discretionary interventionism with new market
friendly regulations – a form of pro-market re-regulation. Indeed, in many cases the new
regulations were more complex and onerous than the old type. A well known example is
that of insider trading regulation in financial markets, almost unknown (except in the US)
before the 1980s’ (ibid.: 17-18; emphasis in original).
Following Cerny, therefore, the emerging model can be characterised as one in which
state actors, both politicians and bureaucrats, react to the pressures of the global market
by ‘promoting the competitive advantages of particular production and service sectors in
a more open and integrated world economy’ (Cerny, 2000a: 22). In this situation, state
actions ‘are often designed to enforce global market rational economic and political
behaviour on rigid and inflexible private sector actors as well as on state actors and
agencies. The institutions and practices of the state itself are increasingly marketized or
“commodified”, and the state becomes the spearhead of structural transformation to
market norms both at home and abroad’. As a result, ‘the actual amount or weight of
government imbrication in social life can increase … at the same time the power of the
state to control specific activities and market outcomes continues to diminish’
undermining the ‘overall strategic and developmental capacity’ of state agencies (ibid.:
30-34; emphasis in original). Indeed, this situation results in ‘the splintering of the state
itself’ as ‘state actors themselves, once said to be “captured” by large, well-organized
domestic constituencies, are increasingly captured instead by transnationally-linked
sectors which set state agencies against each other as in the desire to “level the playing
field” for their domestic clients in the wider world’ (Cerny, 2002: 11). Many
domestically oriented interest and pressure groups are increasingly marginalised in the
formulation of policy while transnationally linked groups not only gain influence but also
can play state actors off against one another. Cerny concludes: ‘The crucial point … is
that those tasks, roles and activities [of states] will not just be different, but will lose
much of the overarching, macro-political character traditionally ascribed to the effective
state, the good state or the just state’ (2000a: 23).
More fully and adequately than does any other characterisation of the state, the
‘competition state’ best interprets the changing nature of governance in the Irish case.
Four ways in which it does this can be identified:
1) It accounts for the fact that, far from retreating and weakening under the impact of
globalisation, the Irish state has become much more active and extensive. As
Taylor recognises, ‘Irish political institutions have altered radically in response to
the pressures of competing in the global economy’ and ‘this has involved a
fundamental shift in the nature of governance, since economic management has
6
not been left solely to the market or to the state’ (Taylor, 2005: 5). This contrasts
therefore with the account offered both by neo-classical economists (Barry, 1999;
Walsh, 1996) and by radical critics (O’Hearn, 1998; Allen, 2000) who give the
key role to the free market in accounting for Ireland’s economic success, though
both groups evaluate it very differently.
2) In contrast to the concept of the ‘developmental state’, it accounts for the
profound ambiguities that characterise the state’s relationship to society as its
capacity to win high levels of foreign direct investment in key targeted sectors
contrasts with its low social spending. As the NESC put it, commenting on data
that show a clear positive correlation between levels of social spending and
economic performance across the EU 15: ‘Ireland, however, is the country whose
relative wealth is the least guide to the relative level of is social spending’ (NESC,
2005a: 108).
3) While such ambiguities have to be seen by developmental state theorists as
contradictions – state capacity in one sector contrasts with the lack of capacity in
another – for the competition state theorist the contrast between economic success
and social failure derives from the central logic that informs state actions – the
imposition of competitive pressures on the economy and on society. In writing
about Irish welfare reform, Taylor identifies that ‘its principal motivation has
rested firmly upon enhancing the flexibility of the labour market’ rather than upon
extending social rights (Taylor, 2005: 94).
4) While there may be a central logic of economic competitiveness informing state
actions, this logic also results in the fragmentation of state actions (‘the
splintering of the state itself’ as described by Cerny) as the state gives power and
resources to different agencies to achieve key elements of public policy with little
coordination between them. The effectiveness of the Industrial Development
Agency (IDA) in winning foreign direct investment has received extensive
attention in this regard (see Mac Sharry and White, 2000); yet Boyle draws
attention to the role of FÁS, the state’s labour market agency, which offered the
possibility of addressing a myriad of problems cheaply and effectively,
increasingly by-passing other government departments and agencies in doing so.
Reflecting the ‘pragmatic-populist streak in Irish politics’ this has tended to deal
with symptoms while neglecting the deeper roots of problems, offering ‘cheap,
flexible solutions that avoided long-term commitments’ (Boyle, 2005: 113-14).
In these ways, the competition state concept is the most adequate to characterise the
contemporary Irish state. However, Ó Riain has raised three criticisms of the concept that
deserve attention. He writes that it extends ‘important observations about the specific
features of many contemporary capitalist states into too general an argument regarding a
new mode of capitalist regulation’. In doing this, it ‘does not capture the empirical
complexity of uneven development in contemporary capitalism and unnecessarily
narrows our understanding of the institutions underpinning economic growth’ (Ó Riain,
2004: 18). This criticism rests on a claim central to developmental state theorists, namely
that ‘some economies have been able to move up the hierarchy of the international
division of labour and increase national income levels’ (ibid.: 21) which is Ó Riain’s
primary definition of development. He claims that the concept of the developmental state
7
better captures this potential of the state whereas the concept of the competition state
neglects such potential. Of all his criticisms, this is the most important and central one.
To some extent, the difference between both concepts in this regard rests on different
understandings of what constitutes development. For Ó Riain treats social development
as being analytically distinct from economic development; his claim for Ireland being a
developmental state rests entirely on the role it has played in transforming the nature of
the economy. Competition state theorists also acknowledge that neoliberal public
policies, as Cerny et al. put it, ‘do not merely constrain but also bring opportunities.
Contemporary politics entails both a process of choosing between different versions of
neoliberalism and the attempt to innovate creatively within the new neoliberal playing
field’ (2005: 20; emphasis in original). This seems a far more accurate way of
characterising the Irish state’s success in a small number of productive sectors of the
economy than does Ó Riain’s rather more sweeping generalisation of this as
developmental success. Indeed, the very weakness of the developmental state concept is
that it is far too blunt an instrument to capture the ambiguous nature of what the state is
able to achieve in the conditions of neo-liberal globalisation.
Ó Riain’s second criticism is that the competition state concept fails to recognise ‘the
internally contradictory nature of “market liberalism” itself’. ‘Far from being smoothly
integrated with market competitiveness, the institutions supporting capitalist development
need to be protected from excessive marketization of the institutions of the economy,
particularly the growing financialization of its firms and institutions’ (Ó Riain, 2004: 18).
This is a rather more puzzling criticism as it makes an abstract point that in no way
contradicts any aspect of the competition state concept. One can fully agree with Ó
Riain’s claim here while holding that the intense competitive conditions of today’s
neoliberal capitalism are eroding the ability of public institutions to play the essential role
he posits. If there were disagreement on this point, it would be on the empirical issue of
whether this is happening rather than on any theoretical difference between proponents of
the competition and developmental state. The third criticism raised by Ó Riain is that the
competition state concept obscures ‘the existence of a political space for struggles within
and through existing institutions over how development could and should be structured’
and it ignores ‘the many political possibilities that the institutions of economic
development present for future transformation’ (2004: 18). What here distinguishes
proponents of each of the concepts is the potential for transformation that exists. For, as
made clear above, competition state theorists also recognise that politics matters and that
it results in different outcomes in different states – ‘different versions of neoliberalism’.
Ó Riain goes further in claiming that spaces exist for going beyond neoliberalism to
social democracy and his book ends by outlining what this might entail (ibid.: 237-42).
Here again what is at issue is more empirical than theoretical: Cerny et al. (2005) outline
at some length the erosion of the basis for a social democratic alternative as it is
happening in practice in many parts of the world whereas Ó Riain’s account is limited to
a purely theoretical outline of what such an alternative might look like while neglecting
entirely the political or social bases for its emergence. On the contrary, he acknowledges
that the developmental state ‘will face an increasingly contentious politics of national
inequality because unequal integration into the globalization project undermines
solidaristic national social contracts’ (2004: 38); however, he fails to address how it
8
might overcome these to build a more social democratic alternative. In this situation,
therefore, the onus rests on those who claim that such a possibility exists to show in
practice how it might emerge or how it is emerging. Failure to do this undermines this
criticism of the competition state.
Recommodification ‘Irish-style’
A major weakness of competition state theory is that it has been developed largely in the
abstract, with little empirical application or testing. Since the competition state prioritises
economic competitiveness over social cohesion and welfare through subordinating the
latter to the logic of the former, it follows that empirical examination of how Ireland’s
social security regime has changed over the past two decades offers evidence to test the
applicability of the competition state to Ireland. This is the purpose of this section. Four
indicators of social security recommodifcation are examined in turn – regulation,
retrenchment, residualisation, and activation/conditionality. These competition state
indicators are developed based on the work of Cerny and Jessop and reflect how, in the
competition state model, the role of the state and governance shift, while fiscal policy
becomes more neo-liberal, resulting in greater vulnerability and inequality and a tendency
to rely more on the market to provide public and private goods. The indicators are also
applicable to other areas of policy like health, housing or education. Testing each
indicator highlights where Irish social security policy is consistent with or deviates from
movement towards a competition state. However, competition state theory also stresses
political agency and the role played by domestic institutions and practices, national and
international interest groups and the evolving relationship between the public and private
in determining policy choices (Cerny et al., 2005: 19-20). Hence, we analyse how these
factors manifest themselves in the Irish case, helping account for the distinctive outcomes
observed. We end by highlighting a fundamental challenge facing those who seek more
egalitarian outcomes even within the confines of the Irish competition state.
The social security characteristics of a competition state can be described as follows:
domestic social security policy is subordinated to the economic needs of international
competitiveness. Low levels of taxation and wage moderation limit the state’s capacity to
fund social security more generously and create pressure for public-sector spending cuts.
Public goods, especially those related to social justice and redistribution, are increasingly
privatised or subject to profit criteria. Their distribution becomes more consumer driven
and less based on rights derived from citizenship. Increased women’s labour market
participation impacts on the capacity of families to provide welfare and results in the
greater reliance on market-based provision of both child and elder care. Fiscal pressures
cause shifts to more targeted means-tested social protection. Reliance on targeted and
ungenerous transfer payments increases the depth of poverty and widens income
inequalities. There are new forms of inequality where those with weak capacity to
participate in the labour market suffer most in the ‘pauperization of segments of society’
(Cerny et al., 2005: 29). The welfare system becomes more active, productivist and
oriented to employment. Public investment focuses on enhancing labour supply through
learning and training. Rights become conditionally linked to the obligation to participate
in the labour market. Supportive carrots and punitive sanctions both encourage and
compel labour market participation. (Cerny et al., 2005: 18). The recommodification of
9
social security occurs as ‘redistributive’ welfare is transformed into ‘productivist’
workfare policy. We have developed the following typology to summarise this
recommodification: 1
•
•
•
•
Regulation: The function of the state changes. New public management
regulatory frameworks enable governments ‘to steer but not row’ (Cerny et al.,
2005: 17). New forms of governance lead to the delegation of policy to new
actors at national and other levels. This empowers business and professional
technical elites. Privatisation of provision occurs either directly or by organising
public service delivery around commercial or market consumer principles.
Retrenchment: The prioritisation of international competitiveness results in a
‘low tax, low inflation’ fiscal policy as expressed and supervised in the EU’s
Growth and Stability Pact. Fiscal pressures lead countries to resort to short-term
cost cutting and long-term cost containment and cost avoidance.
Residualisation: In order to decrease welfare recipients’ dependence on the state,
employment is prioritised as a route out of poverty at the expense of redistributive
and egalitarian objectives. The focus on maintaining low welfare rates to promote
work incentives has inegalitarian implications for those who cannot exercise
employment routes out of poverty. Non-labour market participants including the
elderly, people with disabilities and those involved in ‘caring’ duties at home are
more vulnerable in the increasing relative gulf between the rich and poor.
Activation/conditionality: Passive income maintenance shifts to active spending
on training and education. Welfare is reinvented into ‘workfare’ where income
support is more conditional and linked to obligations to participate in the labour
market. Positive encouragement coexists with punitive sanctions. Increased labour
market participation of women weakens family capacity resulting in the greater
commodification of caring functions.
How each of these four indicators applies to the Irish case is now reviewed. The review
shows that Irish social security trends have moved in a direction consistent with the
competition state indicators. However, this has happened in a distinctive way and it is
highlighted throughout how particular policies were mediated through Irish political
institutions, ideology and culture. The end result is a particular ‘Irish style’
recommodification.
Regulation
Competition state theory stresses the transformation of the role of the state and changes in
the nature of governance. Here we examine trends in regulation, shifts in power to
international capital and business, an emerging international policy community,
privatisation and new public management, as they have occurred in Ireland’s social
security policy community.
1
The authors developed these indicators. The retrenchment and activation/conditionality indicators are
central to competition state theory but also used by other political economists (Pierson, 2001). The
residualisation indicator and regulation indicator are more specific to competition state theory.
10
A regulatory state ‘should provide a working framework of rules and performance
indicators or targets for market actors to follow’ (Cerny et al., 2005: 17). Historically
Ireland has been a mixed economy welfare state but social security has been an almost
exclusive statutory responsibility. Over the last two decades the state has made some
attempts to divest itself of social security responsibility and so follow a more regulatory
path. It promoted the social inclusion role of the non-profit private sector. The
Programme for Economic and Social Progress (Government of Ireland, 1990) initiated
the first local Area-Based Partnerships to which the state delegates employment support
functions including the Local Employment Service. A 1999 White Paper sought to define
and regulate the relationship between the state and the community and voluntary sector,
the state has since signalled a shift to service contracts requiring a new model for thirdsector organisations. NESC (2005a: 206-7) proposes a further shift in governance and
reinvention of the role of the state away from provision of services to ‘a regulator of
rights and standards and enabler of local activist networks’. A further but failed example
of the state’s attempt to divest itself of its traditional social protection role was when a
proposal to transfer disability protection to employers was blocked by the veto power of
employers in both 1988 and 1992. This contrasts with the British experience where the
state was able to transfer this function to private business. Irish government is more
vulnerable to veto players blocking policy and less able to divest social protection
functions.
The political process of globalisation changes the nature and role of the state and policy
contestation. Patterns of governance change, the state plays a more regulatory role and
power shifts to business and capital. Regular delegation of policy to committees avoids
communicative public discourse and minimises public debate about values. Changes tend
to be uncontroversial and mediated, potentially conflictual policies like abolition of payrelated benefit and taxation of benefits are negotiated in a consensus framework. Roles
are blurred, social partners chair key state boards, key policy-making functions are
delegated to private consultancies and agencies, and there are public/private partnerships
in social services. When consensus is not reached policy tends to be paralysed, childcare
policy being an obvious example.
Employers and business are major veto players blocking restructuring of disability
benefits and paid parental leave payments and asserting the needs of international
competitiveness in a political advocacy coalition with two key Departments (Finance, and
Enterprise, Trade and Employment). International companies impact on social protection
by providing private packages that reinforce second-tier market-led social security
provision; these structurally impact on social protection by changing the context and
choices around work-related social provision. A further example of international
organisations becoming more pivotal is the EU procurement process which obliges
tendering, to private and public bodies, of delivery services previously monopolised by
statutory bodies (for example An Post’s social security delivery contracts).
There is more overlap between domestic and international policy coalitions, particularly
in the EU Open Method of Co-ordination across employment policy, social inclusion and
11
pensions policy but also in more regular public discourse with the OECD. The shift from
the redistributive adequacy agenda of the 1986 Commission on Social Welfare to a more
productivist policy 2 reflected the agenda of the international policy community as
expressed in the OECD Jobs Study (1995) (concerned with work incentives) and the
European Employment Strategy (1997) (concerned with activation). In this merged
public/private and national/international space we see the emergence in Ireland of a
professional technical elite whose members engage in coordinative discourse at one
remove from the political realm.
Changing governance means more than a simple delegation of tasks, as renegotiation of
the relationship between the private and public spheres involves a shift in power. The
clearest example is perhaps the government invitation to the private pension industry to
chair the National Pensions Board. It is no coincidence to see private, business-led style
of governance result in promoting the commodification or privatisation of pensions.
Strongly advocated by the international financial services sector, the Pensions
(Amendment) Act 2002 introduced second-tier private Pension Savings Retirement
Accounts. This policy was chosen in spite of opposition from civil servant advisors
(disempowered by new forms of governance?). International and national private-sector
pressures allied to sectors of the state drove the logic behind these moves. The
international context was the World Bank’s promotion of a privatisation agenda in
pension policy.
Consumerism, choice and new public management discourse are evident in the Public
Services Management Act (1997) and initiatives like ‘customer service plans’, ‘customer
service targets’, and ‘service delivery models’. A process of ‘expenditure reviews’
emphasising value for money has had some impact on policy development; however
there is considerable resistance to new public management practices and institutional
change in the Irish public service (NESC, 2002). The capacity of a strong centralised
bureaucracy to resist change is reinforced by the strength of public sector trade unions to
veto change. This power has been reinforced through the lack of transparency in how pay
increases were decided upon as part of the public sector benchmarking process. We can
conclude that there is strong evidence of the state engaging in a new public management
ethos of customer-focused delivery but it remains to be seen whether such engagement
has fundamentally transformed staff and claimant experience of social security delivery.
Retrenchment
As mentioned earlier, in a competition state we expect a low-tax development model to
necessitate budgetary constraint and cost containment measures. In the Irish context two
factors are worth highlighting. One factor is path dependency. Irish social security policy
is characterised by a liberal residual welfare state with a high degree of reliance on
means-tested payments with little room to reduce already ungenerous payments. The
second factor is Ireland’s exceptional economic performance. Given Ireland’s high
economic growth rates and limited pressures from an ageing population from the mid
1990s to the mid 2000s, Ireland not only suffered less fiscal pressure than did other
OECD countries but had budget surpluses and the capacity to expand social security rates
12
and coverage. That such expansion did not happen is as much part of the story as what
actually happened. The Irish story is one of arrested development where government
abstained from using the fruits of economic growth to expand and improve social
protection to the degree that might have been anticipated in a period of economic growth
(Alber and Standing, 2000: 99). It is necessary, therefore, to review retrenchment
experience not only from the perspective of short-term cost cutting but also longer-term
cost containment and cost avoidance.
Allan and Scruggs (2004) and Korpi and Palme (2003: 441) provide evidence of Irish
cost cutting. Ireland ranks alongside Britain, New Zealand, Denmark, Canada, the
Netherlands and the US, as countries that experienced major retrenchment. The social
protection value of social insurance payments reduced between 1980 and 2000 through
the abolition of Pay-Related Benefit, the taxation of benefits and restrictions on
eligibility. There has been less retrenchment of social assistance payments but
considerable cuts in the safety net Supplementary Welfare Allowance scheme. Other
cuts such as the 1994 child-income support reforms which froze the monetary value of
means-tested child-dependant allowances, reflect policy restructuring motivated by work
incentives rather than fiscal pressures. 3 Two sets of social security cuts, the 1992 ‘Dirty
Dozen’ and the 2003 ‘Savage Sixteen’, were short-term responses to periods of tight
fiscal austerity (the 1992 EMU preparations and the post 9/11 recession in 2002-03).
Both sets of cuts happened when inexperienced first time Ministers were unable to resist
strong pressure from Department of Finance officials to cut social security budgets.
These cuts are exceptions that prove the rule. Politicians at all cost seek to avoid blame
associated with direct social security cuts which, more than any other kind of public
spending cuts, are transparent to claimants. Experienced Ministers, especially those in
electoral systems based on proportional representation, know it is politically expedient to
avoid directly cutting social security (Pierson, 1998).
Less obvious long-term cost-containment policies have had a more serious impact on
Irish society. The Department of Finance, with its concern for controlling expenditure,
dominates the setting of social security rates. Proposals in 1998 for a pensions adequacy
benchmark and in 2001 for an adequacy benchmark for the lowest social assistance
payments 4 were rejected by an advocacy coalition of the Department of Finance,
employers’ representatives and the Department of Enterprise and Employment. They
were motivated by a combination of future cost containment, maintenance of work
incentives and ensuring a level of flexibility considered essential to adapt to the global
economy. More puzzling in the Irish case is the failure in the early 1990s to index earned
income disregards. 5 Freezing income disregards makes work incentive policy less
effective and is inconsistent with a productivist-focused competition state. Such deviation
3
NESC (2005a: 52) outlines the distributional outcome of this child income support reform. The value of
child income support for higher income groups receiving only universal child benefit payments increased
by 173% over the 1994-2004 period while low income families relying on the combined child-dependant
allowances and child benefit experienced only a 52% increase over the same period.
4
National Irish Pensions Initiative and PPF Benchmarking and Indexation Working Group 2001 majority
recommendations
5
Earned income disregards allow claimants to disregard a certain amount of earnings from social assistance
means tests and are therefore considered an important welfare-to-work incentive.
13
might be explained by a cost-fixated Department of Finance dominating annual budget
negotiations.
As well as cost containment there has also been significant ‘cost avoidance’ or resistance
to accommodate new social risks through the social security system. The significant
structural increases in labour market participation of women happened without
substantial social security restructuring to enable such participation or to respond to
emerging social care needs. Irish social security remains a strong male breadwinner
regime with structural barriers to women registering as unemployed or accessing labourmarket supports. Reliance on market-led responses to childcare (Government of Ireland,
2000a) means that childcare subsidies, maternity leave and paid parental leave are
underdeveloped relative to other countries. Eldercare responses are limited to tax
incentives to provide private nursing homes. Failure to individualise social security or to
introduce child and elder care supports is paradoxical in a competition state aiming to
increase the labour force participation of mothers. A neo-liberal fixation on limiting state
intervention is a partial explanation but policy inaction is not just about ideology or cost
avoidance. Policy paralysis is due to politicians’ fears of introducing reforms in the
absence of policy consensus and to the political difficulty of mediating between those
advocating conflicting policy options. 6 Policy is also limited by the strong veto power of
employers who resist parental leave policies. The lack of policy to promote women’s
economic participation is also due to a deeply rooted ideological ambiguity about
mothers’ labour-market participation in a conservative, patriarchal political culture
(McLaughlin, 2001). Finally, cost avoidance can also be seen in recent policy responses
to inflows of asylum seekers and migrant workers. State policy is to exclude these needs
from Irish social security and leave migrants to the mercy of the market. Asylum seekers
are limited to ‘direct provision’ welfare entitlement. Government responded to EU
enlargement with legislation restricting welfare entitlement to ‘habitual residents’. As a
result of direct lobbying from international companies, legislation was introduced to
exempt certain non-EU migrant workers from social insurance coverage. Social security
policy is therefore actively responding to the needs and desires of international capital.
Residualisation
Competition state theory anticipates new forms of inequality as well as increased gaps
between rich and poor. It expects those most distant from the labour market (older
people, carers, women in the home, lone parents and people with disabilities) to suffer
most poverty. Here we review Irish trends towards more use of targeted means-tested
payments, increased relative poverty, and shifts in the risk of relative poverty.
Competition states shift from universal to selective social security payments (Alber and
Standing, 2000: 101); however already ‘Ireland is exceptional within the EU for the high
proportion of its social spending which is means tested’ (NESC, 2005a: xvi). Despite
6
Montague (2003) describes three key policy coalitions comprised of the trade union SIPTU and the IBEC
employers’ confederation lobbying for tax relief, the Open Your Eyes to Child Poverty Initiative lobbying
for child benefit increases, a Childcare 2000 campaign lobbying for a parental Childcare payment, and
‘Women in the Home’, a lobby group campaigning against tax relief.
14
employment growth, decreases in unemployment and inward migration of labour, levels
of dependency on social welfare among the working aged are stubbornly high. 7 Such
path dependency would be reinforced by the NESC recommendation that Ireland
maintain its hybrid model and reliance on means-tested payments (NESC, 2005a). 8 High
dependency on means-tested payments might not matter if payments were adequate.
However, Irish policy has always stressed work incentives and low replacement rates,
and rates are characterised by a minimal subsistence type of support and have been
allowed to decline relative to average net earnings. 9 While consistent deprivation-based
poverty fell, the inequality indicator or relative income poverty, increased to 21.3 per cent
(CSO, 2005), the highest relative income poverty in the EU where the average is 15 per
cent (Eurostat).
Table 4.1 Percentage of persons below 60% of median income by labour force
status, 1997-2003
Employee
Self Employed
Farmer
Unemployed
Ill/Disabled
Retired
Home Duties
1994
3.2
16.0
18.6
51.4
29.5
8.2
20.9
1997
4.7
14.4
16.7
57.7
52.5
13.5
32.6
1998
2.6
16.4
23.9
58.8
54.5
18.4
46.8
2000
6.5
17.9
24.1
57.1
52.2
30.3
44.3
2001
8.1
14.3
23.0
44.7
66.5
36.9
46.9
2003
9.2
42.1
54.0
31.0
37.0
Source: CSO (2005), European Survey on Income and Living Conditions, First results 2003
Table 4.1 shows the shift in the composition of groups experiencing relative poverty.
Consistent with what would be expected under a competition state, those outside the
labour market experience a higher risk of poverty. Unemployment, while still significant,
is no longer the major risk factor; those with disabilities are now most likely to
experience poverty (up 24 per cent) and these are closely followed by the aged (up 23 per
cent) and people in home duties/lone parents (up 16 per cent). Consistent with
competition state theory on the working poor, those in work experienced a 6 per cent
increased risk of poverty. The trend is clear. Those relying primarily on social welfare,
particularly those in receipt of social assistance means-tested payments, are most likely to
fall below poverty lines linked to average incomes. While fewer people were
unemployed, the risk of poverty for those remaining unemployed doubled from 23.9 per
cent in 1994 to 43.1 per cent in 2001, while for older people the risk increased from 5.3
per cent in 1994 to 49 per cent in 2001 (ESRI, 2003: Table 4.22). This pauperisation of
segments of society is directly attributable to a conscious policy decision to keep social
welfare payments low.
7
Benefit dependency rose from 12.4% in 1980 to hold constant at 20% for claimants (37% for all adult and
child recipients) over 1985-2005.
8
This represents a significant policy shift from the 1986 Commission on Social Welfare consensus
recommendation to expand social insurance coverage and reduce the use of social assistance payments.
9
Social welfare increases fell considerably below net increases in earnings over the 1991-2001 period with
the long-term unemployment assistance payment increasing by 64% compared to net average industrial
earnings increasing by 109.1% (Government of Ireland, 2001: 46, Table 6.6).
15
Activation/Conditionality
Irish social security offers less social protection in 2001 than it did in 1994. The
traditional principle of designing social security to preserve work incentives is now
underpinned by a new Irish focus on ‘performative inclusion’, which stresses
employment as the best route out of poverty (Government of Ireland, 1997b). This policy
direction is reinforced through employment support services (Dukelow, 2004: 16-18) and
activation policies (McCashin, 2004: 211). This section seeks to establish the particular
style and scale of Irish commodification by reviewing three key trends: spending on
active measures, changes in ‘conditionality’ and extension of activation beyond
unemployed claimants.
In the competition state we expect public investment to shift to active labour market
spending. Significant active labour market expenditure is a long-standing feature of the
Irish welfare state. 10 Irish spending on active labour market programmes increased from
an already comparatively high 1.46 per cent of GDP in 1985 to 1.53 percent GDP in 2000
(a significant real spending increase). Active labour market programmes are administered
by a number of government departments, such as the Department of Social and Family
Affairs, the Department of Education and Science and the Department of Enterprise,
Trade and Employment. Irish active labour market policy has been criticised for a lack of
focus on progression to employment (Cousins, 2005a). Boyle explains this as an
outcome of strong advocacy coalitions, including backbench politicians, supporting the
social-policy rather than the labour-market aspect of programmes. Over time, the labourmarket focus is gaining the upper hand, while programmes have become more
progression oriented and linked to participation obligations. Irish institutional experience
remains differentiated from other liberal welfare regimes by the separation of social
security administration from active employment services, and further policy development
in this area seems hampered by institutional competition between key government
departments. ILO (1999: 4) evaluations highlight how reforms in the delivery of labour
market policies through local employment services made labour market policies ‘more
responsive to local enterprise needs’.
Irish social security literature is ambiguous about trends towards greater compulsion.
McCashin (2004: 220), Van Oorschot (2002), McLaughlin (2001), Boyle (2005: 59), Ó
Riain and O’Connell (2000: 334), Daly and Yeates (2003: 94), Martin and Grubb (2002)
and Pearson (2003) all conclude that compulsion is remarkably absent in the Irish policy
regime relative to more conditional practice in both liberal regimes and small open
economies. It may be that perceptions are somewhat obscured by the positive discourse in
social partnership and elsewhere. Empirical evidence, however, supports Taylor’s (2003:
57) and Dukelow’s (2004: 22) conclusion that policy shows significant supportive and
punitive changes which, when combined, push welfare claimants towards employment. 11
10
As a high net recipient of EU Structural funds, Ireland was required to spend on active labour-market
policies.
11
Up to 40 significant punitive or supportive changes took place over the period 1986-2005, some of which
had a substantial impact on the quality of social protection experienced by the claimant. Negative changes
included freezing child income support, limiting duration of payments, means-testing insurance payments,
and restricting part-time workers’ access to insurance payments.
16
Stricter work availability tests were also applied to unemployment payments. Irish social
policy discourse of ‘supportive conditionality’ and ‘sensitive activation’ masks a harder
reality. Historically, job search conditions always applied to unemployment payments
and Irish policy required limited adjustment to reach a ‘competition state’ level of
conditionality. The 1987 Jobsearch programme was followed by 1992 legislation
increasing and broadening the scope of sanctions. From 1996 onwards fears of labour
shortages sparked vigorous debate about the need for more conditionality which resulted
in a new Live Register Management Unit focused on ‘a more effective application of
conditionality’ (Dukelow, 2004: 22). New regulations to tighten work availability and
job-seeking guidelines were introduced in 1997 and 1998. Practical use was made of
these sanctions. Appeals Office data show that since the 1997 National Employment
Action Plan (NEAP) implemented a policy of systematic engagement with unemployed
claimants there has been a substantial rise in appeals for loss of payment, with a 47 per
cent increase (representing 1,700 extra claimants) in such appeals in 2000.
This stronger style of commodification was introduced through a window of opportunity
presented in the European Employment Strategy Open Method of Co-ordination, which
required each national government to enter into a national policy dialogue and produce a
National Employment Action Plan to promote activation and other policy. We can see in
this process how increased links between national and international interests is a factor
determining policy choice but also how international policy processes shift power at the
domestic level. In this instance the EU required the more productivist Department of
Enterprise, Trade and Employment (DETE) to lead this national policy process. This
empowered the DETE, giving them some leverage over the Department of Social and
Family Affairs (DSFA), and it weakened institutional vetoes on conditionality.
Ireland still deviates from a strong model of conditionality in its reluctance to extend
conditionality to lone parents, spouses of male claimants, and people with disabilities.
DSFA (2001) argues that reluctance to extend conditionality is due to the lack of a
coherent childcare infrastructure and of services for people with disabilities.
Procrastination may also be due to fear of a political backlash from those who might
conservatively respond to measures designed to deny women their ‘right’ to work in the
home. The patriarchal culture may not yet be comfortable with measures to promote
women’s economic participation. The recent NESC (2005a: 178) proposal that all social
assistance payments enable a ‘lifetime attachment to the labour force’ therefore reflects a
significant shift in policy consensus. It also reflects DSFA’s own internal reinvention of
social security and its desire to move from a contingency-structured social security
regime to one that identifies claimants by reference to their relationship with the labour
market: claimants are young, old or ‘working age’ 12 .
Conclusion
12
Cousins (2005a) notes the significance of this new focus on ‘working age’. The language, more
developed in UK policy discourse, is highly ideologically motivated implying that those of working age
should be at work. He notes the approach has important gender implications placing all working aged
claimants including mothers, on an employability continuum.
17
The Irish reinvention of social security has its own distinctive style, pace and discourse.
Social security is still in the process of becoming a ‘tool of commodification’ (Holden,
2003) and the remaining journey to this recommodified regime will remain slow and
incremental. There is still a considerable journey to go on the path to a comprehensive
welfare to work strategy (NESF, 2000: 65). This slow cautious pace of change means
Irish social security policy has yet to adapt fully to the needs of competitiveness
(Cousins, 2005a: 339). The strategically ambivalent, hesitant and nervous discourse in
NESC (2005a) reflects the challenge in Irish political culture of forging consensus
between different advocacy coalitions around the remaining Irish recommodification
project. Earlier we outlined how explanations for particular policy choices can be found
in the interaction between domestic institutions and practices, national and international
interest groups and the evolving relationship between the public and private sectors
(Cerny et al., 2005: 15). We conclude by reflecting how particular Irish political features
might be explanatory factors for this ‘Irish style’ recommodification.
Path dependence of existing social security institutions has played a key role in
influencing the trajectory of change and the type of competition state social development
model that has emerged in Ireland. The Irish social security system has always been well
targeted and employment focused and so contained elements of a competition state
regime. The legacy of a strong male breadwinner model combined with patriarchal
ideologies and opposing political coalitions account for the slow progress in the
individualisation of social security, the reluctance to extend conditionality to mothers and
the paralysis in childcare policy. The Irish electoral system based on a single transferable
vote in multi-seat constituencies makes the electorate a significant veto player. An
electoral system based on transferring votes between candidates (in many cases of the
same party) perpetuates a consensus-based political culture biased towards conservative
and incremental policy development. The trend towards coalition government and social
partnership reinforces middle ground consensus policy-making and slows down change.
Government is increasingly reliant on using social partnership as a litmus paper to test for
consensus. Lack of consensus is often masked by sensitive but ambiguous discourse.
Policy shifts are often correlated with international policy community initiatives such as
the European Employment Strategy.
The inconsistent, slow Irish transformation to date means we should expect more
recommodification. Given the ambiguous developmental discourse it is less than clear
what style further recommodification will take. Cerny et al. remind us there is ‘room for
maneuver’ (2005: 3). Torfing (1999: 24) argues that workfare or activation policy can be
focused on supportive carrots and be ‘offensive’ like Dutch and Danish policy or can use
punitive sticks and be ‘defensive’ like UK and US policy. The former brings more
equality while the latter results in higher percentages of working poor. The present Irish
situation with rising inequality and increasing numbers of working poor, while not as
neo-liberal as in Britain or the US, is clearly far from the Dutch or Danish model. The
choice for the medium term is which variety of competitive capitalism Ireland wishes to
follow. Does Ireland wish to reinforce this neo-liberal competition state development
model or shift to a more egalitarian social democratic state model? The choice for the
18
longer term is whether it is possible to shift to a new global model of development that
can produce more social, economic and environmentally sustainable outcomes.
The NESC Developmental Welfare State (2005a) represents the latest consensus about
Irish social development. The NESC proposals straddle two different varieties of the
competition state. Based on promoting high levels of participation in a rights and
standards framework of activist measures, it opens up the possibility of an offensive
model. Certain path dependencies enable a more offensive model to emerge and Ireland
is institutionally oriented towards an offensive model on two fronts, a tradition of high
levels of investment in active labour-market training and education, and a separation of
employment services from surveillance and control functions. However the NESC
recommendation of adequate but basic welfare generosity locks in the traditional Irish
dependence on low replacement rates. It is ultimately its more generous payments which
give the Danish model its equality outcomes. 13 The recommendation that ‘payment
arrangements facilitate employment’ opens up the possibility of conditional and modest
social welfare payments in a more defensive social development model.
Clearly there is much left to fight for and political agency remains crucial in mediating
future Irish social security choices. The Irish style transition to a recommodified
competition state social security regime is likely to continue to happen in a governance
style dominated by task forces and working groups and to move in incremental and
fudged stages. 14 The challenge is to create a communicative public debate about the
desirability of a more fundamental move to a more egalitarian development model with
higher social welfare rates and adequate state investment in quality activist policies that
generate more inclusive and equal outcomes.
Conclusions
This paper has argued that the model of the competition state best characterises the Irish
state, especially as it has adapted to the pressures and opportunities of globalisation, what
in the Irish debate is usually labelled the Celtic Tiger period. The paper advanced its case
both theoretically and empirically. It firstly outlined the ways states are restructuring
themselves in response to globalisation and identified the concept of the competition state
as characterising the model of state that is emerging. This concept, it was argued,
interprets more fully and adequately than do other concepts of state the changing nature
of state governance in Ireland accounting for the greater state activism and the extension
13
NESC (2005a: 219) recommends that people of working age should receive a ‘basic payment’ to enable a
‘minimum threshold of income adequacy’ to ‘guarantee them access to the basic necessities of life’. It is
difficult to interpret as a proposal for generous rates the NAPS target of 150 euro in 2002 terms by 2007
which it proposes as ‘the minimum justified by the present circumstances’. This persistence with lack of
generosity differentiates Ireland (with replacement ratios of 24%) from offensive states’ polices
characterised by high rates of payment (replacement ratios of 89% to 96% for low income groups) (ibid:
19).
14
The peculiar mix of Irish institutions and political culture means that debate about Irish social security is
modest and unambitious. US president Bill Clinton promised the US electorate to ‘end welfare as we know
it’ and UK prime minister Tony Blair instructed his Minister for Social Security, Frank Fields, to ‘think the
unthinkable’ In the ‘blame avoidance’ consensus-dominated Irish political culture, Irish Ministers are more
likely to be told to ‘stay out of trouble’.
19
of state activity over the recent period even as the state hands over more power to private
market actors. In identifying the imposition of competitive pressures on the economy and
on society as the central logic informing state actions, the concept of a competition state
explains better, than do other concepts of state the ambiguities that can be observed
between the state’s effectiveness in dealing with foreign capital and its ineffectiveness in
addressing social needs. Finally, the concept of a competition state draws attention to the
fragmentation of state actions as different agencies are charged with implementing
different aspects of public policy with little coordination between them. Recognising that
treatment of the competition state has been largely theoretical, the paper has devoted
attention to testing its claims empirically through examining the changing nature of the
Irish social security regime, analysing both the extent to which change has moved in the
direction of a competition state model and also accounting for the distinctive features of
what has taken place, what we call commodification ‘Irish-style’.
The empirical section has highlighted the role that agency plays in the outcomes
observed, drawing attention to the fact that, while the pressures of globalisation are
moving states more and more away from a welfare or developmental state model and
towards some form of competition state, there is nothing predetermined about how that
change happens nor about the form of competition state that emerges. As was pointed out
in the paper, the state maintains room for manoeuvre to influence distributional outcomes
in a robust way. What we are witnessing therefore is the emergence of different varieties
of competition state, just as the era of national capitalism saw many different varieties of
welfare state – from the activist and egalitarian types to the more passive and residual
types. However, the evidence also seems to point to the fact that the pressures of
globalisation lead at this point in time away from the social democratic or developmental
state and towards some version of the competition state. Whether states can successfully
and sustainably combine economic competitiveness with generous and effective social
provision is still unclear. What is clear, however, is that Ireland has opted for a
particularly ungenerous approach towards social provision. Only time will tell whether
Irish society has the capacity for the sort of determined political action to move towards a
more egalitarian form of development even within the confines of the competition state
model.
References
Alber, Jens and Standing, Guy (2000): ‘Social dumping, Catch up or Convergence,
Europe in a Comparative Global Context’, in Journal of European Social Policy, Vol 10
(2), pp. 99-119.
Allen, Kieran (2000): The Celtic Tiger: The Myth of Social Partnership in Ireland,
Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Amsden, Alice (1989): Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Barry, Frank, ed. (1999): Understanding Ireland’s Economic Growth, Basingstoke:
Macmillan.
20
Boyle, Nigel (2005): FÁS and Active Labour Market Policy 1985-2004, Studies in Public
Policy: 17, Dublin: The Policy Institute.
Central Statistics Office (2005): Measuring Ireland’s Progress, 2004, Dublin, Stationery
Office.
Cerny, Philip G, Menz, Georg and Soederberg, Susanne (2005): ‘Different Roads to
Globalization: Neoliberalism, the Competition State, and Politics in a More Open World’,
in Susanne Soederberg, Georg Menz and Philip G. Cerny, eds: Internalizing
Globalization: The Rise of Neoliberalism and the Decline of National Varieties of
Capitalism, Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 1-30.
Cerny, Philip G. (2000a): ‘Structuring the political arena: public goods, states and
governance in a globalizing world’ in Ronen Palan, ed.: Global Political Economy:
Contemporary theories, London: Routledge, pp. 21-35.
Cerny, Philip G. (2000b): ‘Restructuring the Political Arena: Globalization and the
Paradoxes of the Competition State’ in Randall D. Germain (ed.) Globalization and its
Critics: Perspectives from Political Economy, Basingstoke: Macmillan, pp. 117-38.
Cerny, Philip G. (2002): ‘Globalization at the Micro Level: The Uneven Pluralization of
World Politics’, Manchester Papers in Politics: CIP Series 5/2002, Manchester: Centre
for International Politics, Department of Government, University of Manchester.
Clinch, Peter, Convery, Frank and Walsh, Brendan (2002): After the Celtic Tiger:
Challenges Ahead, Dublin: The O’Brien Press.
Commission on Social Welfare (1986): Report of the Commission on Social Welfare,
Dublin: Stationery Office.
Cousins, Mel (2005a): Explaining the Irish State, Lewiston, NY: Edwin and Mellor.
Cousins, Mel (2005b): European Welfare States, Comparative Perspectives, London:
Sage.
Daly, Mary and Yeates, Nicola (2003): ‘Common Origins, Different Paths’, in Policy and
Politics, Vol 31 (1), pp. 86-97.
Department of Social and Family Affairs (2000): Review of One Parent Family Payment,
Programme Evaluation Report No 7. Dublin, Stationery Office.
Department of Social and Family Affairs Welfare (2003): Report of the Review of Illness
and Disability Payments, Dublin: Stationery Office.
Department of Social Welfare (1997): Securing Retirement Income National Pensions
Policy Initiative, Dublin, Stationery Office
Department of Social, Community and Family Affairs (1999): Supporting Voluntary
Activity, Dublin: Stationery Office
Dukelow, Fiona (2004): ‘The path towards a more “employment friendly” liberal
regime?: Globalisation and the Irish social security system’, paper presented at the
Foundation for International Studies of Social Security Seminar (FISS), Stockholm, June
2004.
Dwyer, Peter (2003): ‘Creeping conditionality: From welfare rights to conditional
entitlement’, discussion paper at Irish Social Policy Association Conference ‘Economic
and Social Rights’, September 12th and 13th 2003.
Esping Andersen, Gosta (1990): The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Princeton NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Eurostat (2003): European Social Statistics Social Protection Expenditure and Receipts
1991-2000, Luxembourg: Eurostat.
21
Eurostat (various years): Statistics in Focus, Luxembourg: Eurostat.
Evans, Peter (1995): Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Government of Ireland (1991): Programme for Economic and Social Progress, Dublin,
Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (1996a): Expert Working Group on the Integration of the Tax and
Welfare Systems Report, Dublin: Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland, (1996b): P2000: Partnership for Inclusion Competitiveness and
Employment, Dublin: Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (1997a): Programme for National Recovery, Dublin: Stationery
Office.
Government of Ireland (1997b): Sharing in Progress: National Anti-Poverty Strategy,
Dublin: Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (2000a): National Development Plan 2000-2006, Dublin:
Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (2000b): Programme for Prosperity and Fairness, Dublin:
Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (2001) Final Report of the Benchmarking and Indexation
Working Group, Programme for Prosperity and Fairness, Dublin: Stationery Office.
Grubb, David, (2000): ‘Eligibility Criteria for Unemployment Benefits’, OECD
Employment Outlook 2000, Paris: OECD, pp.130-53.
Holden Chris (2002): ‘Decommodification and the Workfare State’, in Political Studies
Review, Vol 1, pp. 303-16.
ILO (1999): ‘Small countries, big success: Europe’s Employment Revival: How smaller
countries create jobs’, World of Work, No 29 April/May, pp. 1-6.
INOU (1997): Job Seeking, Conditions and Support: Who, How and When, Briefing
Paper, Vol 1 (7), July 1997.
INOU (1998): ‘The Employment Action Plan’, Conference Proceedings, Friday 20th
1998.
INOU: (1999) Partnership Brief, Vol 2 (1), April 1999.
Jessop, Bob (1994): ‘The Transition to post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare
State’, in Roger Burrows and Brian Loader, eds: Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State?,
London:Routledge, pp. 13-37.
Johnson, Chalmers: (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial
Policy, 1925-1975, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Jordan B., Angulnik P., Burbridge D. and Duffin S. (2000): Stumbling towards a basic
income the prospects for tax-benefit integration, London: Citizens Income Study Centre.
Kirby, Peadar (2002): The Celtic Tiger in Distress: Growth with Inequality in Ireland,
Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Kirby, Peadar (2005): ‘The Irish State and the Celtic Tiger: A “flexible developmental
state” or a competition state?’, in Graham Harrison, ed.: Global Encounters:
International Political Economy, Development and Globalisation, Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan, pp. 74-94.
Korpi, Walter and Palme, Joakim (2003): ‘New Politics and Class Politics in the Context
of Austerity and Globalisation: Welfare regress in 18 countries 1975-95’, in American
Political Science Review, Vol.97 (3), pp. 425-46.
22
Mac Sharry, Ray and White, Padraic (2000): The Making of the Celtic Tiger: The Inside
Story of Ireland’s Boom Economy, Cork: Mercier Press.
Martin, John and Grubb, David (2001): What works and for whom: A review of OECD
countries’ experiences with active labour market policies, Office of Labour Market
Policy Evaluation Working Paper 2001.14.
McCashin, Anthony (2004): Social Security in Ireland, Dublin: Gill and Macmillan.
McLaughlin, Eithne, Yeates, Nicola, and Kelly, G. (2001): Units of Assessment: Issues
and Options, A report prepared for the Trades Union Congress, November 2001.
Mishra, Ramesh (1999): Globalization and the Welfare State, Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar.
Montague, Pat (2001): Persuasive Influence, An assessment of how Irish groups
campaign around the budget, unpublished MA thesis, Dublin City University.
Moran, Marie (2005): ‘Social Exclusion and the limits of Pragmatic Liberalism’,
Discussion paper to Conference on Equality, Care and Social Inclusion, UCD/QUB, 24th
June 2005.
NESC (2003): An Investment in Quality: Services, Inclusion and Enterprise, Dublin
National Economic and Social Council.
NESC (2005a): The Developmental Welfare State, Dublin: National Economic and Social
Council.
NESC (2005b): People, Productivity, Purpose, Report No 114, Dublin: National
Economic and Social Council.
NESF (2000): Alleviating Labour Shortages, Dublin Stationery Office.
Nolan, Brian, O’Connell, Philip J. and Whelan, Christopher T., eds (2000): Bust to
Boom? The Irish Experience of Growth and Inequality, Dublin: IPA.
Ó Riain, Seán (2000): ‘The Flexible Developmental State: Globalization, Information
Technology and the “Celtic Tiger”’, in Politics & Society, Vol 28, No 2, pp 157-93.
Ó Riain, Seán (2004) The Politics of High-Tech Growth: Developmental Network States
in the Global Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ó Riain, Seán and O’Connell, Philip, (2000): ‘The role of the state in growth and
welfare’ in Brian Nolan, Philip J. O’Connell and Christopher T. Whelan, eds: Bust to
Boom? The Irish Experience of Growth and Inequality, Dublin: IPA, pp. 310-39.
O’Hearn, Denis (1998): Inside the Celtic Tiger: The Irish Economy and the Asian
Model, London: Pluto Press.
O’Hearn, Denis (2000): ‘Globalization, “New Tigers,” and the End of the Developmental
State? The Case of the Celtic Tiger’, in Politics & Society, Vol. 28, No. 1, March 2000,
pp 67-92.
OECD (1995): The OECD Jobs Study: Facts, Analysis, Strategies, Paris: OECD.
Pearson, Mark (2003): ‘Targeting social expenditure’, discussion paper to CPA Social,
Expenditure Conference 16th September 2003.
Phillips, Nicola (2005) ‘State Debates in International Political Economy’ in Nicola
Phillips, ed. Globalizing International Political Economy, Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan, pp 82-115.
Pierson, Christopher (2004): The Modern State, London: Routledge.
Pierson, Paul (1998): ‘Irresistible Forces, Immovable Objects: Post-industrial welfare
states confront permanent austerity’, in Journal of European Social Policy, Vol 5 (4), pp.
539-60.
23
Ruggie, John Gerard (2003): ‘Taking Embedded Liberalism Global: the Corporate
Connection’, in David Held and Mathias Koenig-Archibugi, eds: Taming Globalization:
Frontiers of Governance, Cambridge: Polity Press, pp. 93-129.
Scharpf, Fritz W. (2000): ‘The viability of advanced welfare states in the international
economy: vulnerabilities and options’, in Journal of European Public Policy, Vol 7 (2),
pp. 190-228.
Scruggs, Lyle and Allan, James (2004): ‘Welfare State Decommodification in 18 OECD
Countries: A Replication and Revision’, Paper presented at the Department of Social and
Political Studies, University of Edinburgh, University of Kent and University of York
Oct 2004, http://sp.uconn.edu/~scruggs/wp/htm
Social Welfare Appeals Office 2000-2004: Annual Reports, Dublin: DSFA.
Sweeney, Paul (1999): The Celtic Tiger: Ireland’s Continuing Economic Miracle,
Dublin: Oak Tree Press.
Taylor, George (2005): Negotiated governance and public policy in Ireland, Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Torfing, Jacob (1999): ‘Workfare with Welfare: Recent reforms of the Danish Welfare
State’, in Journal of European Social Policy, Vol 9 (1), pp. 5-28.
Van Hoorhis, Rebecca (2002): ‘Different Types of Welfare States? A methodological
deconstruction of comparative research’, in Journal of Sociology and Social Welfare,
XX1X (4), pp. 3-18.
Van Oorschot, W. (2002): ‘Miracle or Nightmare? A Critical Review of Dutch Activation
Policies and their Outcomes’, in Journal of Social Policy, Vol. 31 (3), pp. 399-420.
Wade, Robert (1990): Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of
Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Walsh, Brendan (1996): ‘Stabilization and Adjustment in a Small Open Economy:
Ireland, 1979-95’, in Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol 12 (3), pp. 73-86.
Whelan C.T, Layte R, Maitre B, Gannon B, Nolan B, Watson Williams J (2003):
Monitoring Poverty Trends in Ireland, results from the 2001 Living in Ireland survey,
Policy Research Series No 51, Dublin: ESRI.
Woo-Cumings, Meredith, ed. (1999): The Developmental State, Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
24