Historia, 66, 1, May 2021, pp 2-38
Perspectives
Introduction
Julie Parle
In August 2019, economist Johan Fourie of Stellenbosch University invited Historia to
publish a “reflection piece” he had written and presented in March that year at the
University of the Free State. In it, he puts forward his views of what History does, what
it ought to do, and how it can perhaps be done better here in (South) Africa. His central
concern is with big data and digitising records. He issues a number of seemingly bold
challenges and provocations to historians. A slightly edited version of that piece is
reproduced below.
Rather than publish it as a stand-alone piece, however, and in the spirit of
respectful exchange, we are publishing four substantial engagements with several of
the arguments made by Fourie. These responses are by Faeeza Ballim, Gerald
Groenewald, Jennifer Upton and Tinashe Nyamunda, all of whom are experts in their
respective fields and experienced in their craft. Each takes the substantive points made
by Fourie seriously, and responds to them in different ways. Best read as perspectives
on a complex and enduring debate amongst people who are mindful of the politics of
the past as well as being critically engaged with what historians “do” in the present,
they recognise the technological and methodological promises of digital histories and
big data, but eloquently remind us too of their limitations and indeed their potential
pitfalls. There is much more to discuss, not the least of which is the responsibility for
the ownership of and access to such records in a democratic and socially just world.
The authors’ information is included at the close, after a brief “Response” by Fourie.
◆ ◆ ◆
How to cite this article: J. Fourie, F. Ballim, G. Groenewald, T. Nyamunda and J. Upton, “Perspectives: Making South African
Historians Count”, Historia, 66, 1, May 2021, pp 2–38.
http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/2309-8392/2021/v66n1a1
Copyright: © The Author(s). Published under a Creative Commons Attribution Licence.
Perspectives: Making historians count
Making South African historians count1
Johan Fourie
Stellenbosch University
This paper suggests that historians can do more to make themselves count. By
recognising the benefits that new technologies have to offer and equipping themselves
with these tools, historians can traverse the often-deep divides of the humanities and
social sciences. This will not only allow them to have an impact beyond their narrow
disciplinary boundary by, for example, helping economists to be more cognizant of
context, but it would also allow them to be more ambitious in their research questions
at a time when this is urgently needed. They can do this because history remains one
of the few human and social sciences – if not the only one – that is, almost by definition,
interdisciplinary. Whereas the humanities and social sciences have become pockets of
speciality, each with its own jargon and journals, theories and theologies, history, in
my brief sojourn into the field, still seems to be more inclined to using a variety of
approaches, methods and theories. That is something, I would like to argue, worth
celebrating. And, more importantly, it is a value worth instilling in the next generation
of scholars, for the benefit of both the history discipline, the broader human and social
sciences and society at large.
Academic traders and their tribulations
In suggestion that historians should make themselves count, I want to argue for three
things. First, historians must be open to itinerant merchants from other social sciences.
Sometimes the benefits of these wares might not be immediately apparent. Computer
scientists interested in Big Data may seem far removed from the historian’s domain,
but their skills, as I’ll demonstrate later, could turn unremarkable probate inventories
into novel historical artefacts. Trade is at the heart of growth and development. This is
as true for science as it is for an economy.
A second way historians can make themselves count is by sending out their own
merchants, even to those social sciences that have a very different world view and may
be, as a consequence, hostile to them. Exchange would require a knowledge of the
cultural traditions and linguistic specificities present in those disciplines. It would
mean reading their work and attending their conferences, things that are expensive
and hard; the specialisation of the social sciences makes traversing the rugged terrain
of the subfields tiresome and treacherous. In my own field, economics, research is
characterised by dense mathematical modelling and econometric estimations. To be
1.
This is a revised version of the Stanley Trapido seminar I presented to the International
Studies Group at the University of the Free State in Bloemfontein on 18 March 2019. I
want to thank seminar participants for their comments and fruitful discussion. In
particular, I wish to thank the following colleagues who have provided detailed
comments on an earlier version of this paper: Anton Ehlers, Kate Ekama, Lindie Koorts,
Nobungcwele Mbem, Laura Phillips, Laura Richardson, Amy Rommelspacher and
Danelle Van Zyl-Hermann.
3
Perspectives: Making historians count
clear: this is not a call for historians to become vassals of economics. To the contrary, I
believe the economists’ tools can be unhinged from the causal imperialism that has
characterised the discipline for the last three decades.2 Epistemological diversity can
only benefit from the trade in toolkits.
Yet I fear that many young historians are sadly denied the opportunity to learn
new (and rapidly advancing) tools outside the confines of their own field. This may be
because an older generation of historians, given the historically violent nature of
engagement between history and economics, have not acquired the necessary tools
and were not taught the skills to use them. It may also be because the older generation,
in a battle for the field’s leadership, have to ensure that they only train apprentices that
share their own methods and beliefs. And perhaps also, it is because experienced
historians sense that these tools are only applicable to certain tasks, and not, as
economists would often claim, superior in every setting. Regardless of the reasons for
this lacuna, for the future fecundity of history, I would argue that some (but perhaps
not all) apprentices should be sent to other social science disciplines to acquire new
tools and the ability to use them. This will not only make the field of history stronger
and prevent their annexation in future, but it may help to position them as future
consuls of the social science community.
The third thing historians should do is to be bolder in their research questions.
For fear of being forced to trade and barter with other social sciences, the historians
have lowered their ambitions, sometimes producing what seems to be, at least to
outsiders, artisanal artefacts that are otiose and ornamental. Perhaps it is fear of
failure, the consequence of past ambitions unrealised, or possibly a calculated
commitment to specificity, local conditions, context and historical contingency. But the
demands of the time necessitate a different approach. I would argue that history is one
of the few that can accommodate – and actually thrive – with audacious projects.
Because of their ability to operate at the intersections of the different social sciences –
and perhaps the natural sciences in some ways too – the modern historian should be
well-positioned to ask the big research questions about human and societal behaviour.
She is the ideal unifier, bringing the best from the social sciences together to work on
major issues that affect all. This is desperately needed in the academic world of today,
where global concerns of climate change, automation and populism, to name a few, will
continue to affect all of us for a long time to come.
2.
B. Fine and D. Milonakis, From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics: The Shifting
Boundaries between Economics and Other Social Sciences (Routledge, New York, 2009).
4
Perspectives: Making historians count
The microdata merchants
What skills should historians acquire? There are several: from text mining with rapidly
improving Optical Character Recognition (OCR) techniques to using neural networks
to date historical photos.3 New technologies allow historians to ask new questions or
answer existing ones in novel ways. My focus here will be on one that I have worked
on in my own research: microdata.
The surge in computing power and access to data processing software and
online resources, has enabled social scientists over the past two decades to capture
historical statistics on a much larger scale than before. In a 2016 paper published in
the Journal of Interdisciplinary History, I argue that the data revolution is especially
valuable when applied to regions where written records are fairly scarce, such as subSaharan Africa.4 I showed how a new generation of economists, geographers, and
historians are rewriting African history using archival sources along with geographical,
climatic and demographic projections into the distant past and finding some surprising
answers.
Let me give a few examples from my most recent work. Although several reports
record the wages of black mine workers in twentieth-century South Africa, these
sources are often unrepresentative and incomplete. Not all black workers were mine
workers, and compensation was not always paid in cash. If we therefore want to
understand how black living standards evolved over the twentieth century, black wage
rates offer, at best, a distorted view. Other variables that can help us understand living
standards include infant mortality or life expectancy, but often these suffer from the
same biases in that collection methods for these statistics may change over the period
of analysis – for example, urban residents may have a higher chance of being recorded
and because urbanisation rapidly increased over the period, the validity of the results
is suspect.
So, instead, economic historians are forced to be creative. An alternative
measure of living standards, one with a rich tradition in the economic history
literature, is stature – or a person’s height. Around 80 per cent of one’s height is
determined by genetics, but the rest is the result of a complicated interaction with one’s
environment. More protein at a young age makes us stronger, healthier and taller. A
bad disease environment, with malaria and pollution, makes us weaker and shorter.
The quality of life can therefore be traced through the changing heights of a population.
The taller people are within one, two or three generations, the more likely it is that they
grew up in better conditions, with improved nutrition, than earlier generations.
3.
4.
P. Thompson, R.T. Batista-Navarro, G. Kontonatsios, J. Carter, E. Toon, J. McNaught, C.
Timmermann, M. Worboys and S. Ananiadou, "Text Mining the History of Medicine",
PloS one, 11, 1, 2016; E. Müller, M. Springstein and R. Ewerth, “‘When was This Picture
Taken?’ Image Date Estimation in the Wild", in J. Jose et al (eds), Advances in
Information Retrieval: ECIR 2017 (Springer, Cham, 2017), pp 619–625.
J. Fourie, "The Data Revolution in African Economic History", Journal of
Interdisciplinary History, 47, 2, 2016, pp 193–212.
5
Perspectives: Making historians count
Bokang Mpeta and I teamed up with Kris Inwood, a Canadian scholar who had
assembled data from a large number of attestation forms in the South African National
Defence Force Archives. We extracted information on the height of black recruits and
several other observable characteristics. We then went in search of other sources. We
ascertained the heights of a series of cadavers at Wits University Medical School, which
we incorporated into our analysis. And in more recent surveys – the Demographic and
Health Survey and the National Income Dynamics Survey – we also found height
information. Combining these four sources, we were able to plot, for the first time,
height as a proxy for living standards over the twentieth century (see Figure 1). Our
paper was published in 2018 by the South African Journal of Science.5
Figure 1: Black male heights, birth years 1895–1985.6
The next step is to extend the series back into the nineteenth century. There is already
a team of scholars at Oxford University that is attempting to do this. Its findings suggest
that black men were much taller in the nineteenth century, but their heights were
declining by the end of the century, matching up to our series almost perfectly. There
is, of course, much to debate about these numbers. Are they representative? Who was
recorded, and why? But despite these concerns, it is undeniable that they provide us
with a new perspective on the economic lives of people who have thus far only been
written of as peripheral actors in the economic history of South Africa.
Let’s take another example. Both English and Afrikaner historians of the
twentieth century argued that the eighteenth-century settlers who would later become
known as Afrikaners lived just above subsistence. There were good reasons for this.
Afrikaner historians hoped to emphasise the economic self-determination that allowed
Afrikaners to escape the poverty inflicted on them by war and natural disaster at the
5.
6.
B. Mpeta, J. Fourie and K. Inwood, "Black Living Standards in South Africa before
Democracy: New Evidence from Height", South African Journal of Science, 114, 1/2,
2018, pp 1–8.
Mpeta, Fourie and Inkwood, “Black Living Standards”.
6
Perspectives: Making historians count
end of the nineteenth century. Hermann Giliomee, in his seminal contribution on the
history of the Afrikaner, gives a general consensus on early Afrikaner livelihoods: “The
problem of white poverty in South Africa was initially predominantly a rural problem
that manifested itself after two centuries of subsistence farming”.7 A recent book on
twentieth-century Afrikaner prosperity collapses this sentiment into one sentence:
“Afrikaner capitalism: from dirt poor to stinking rich”.8
English-speaking historians had a somewhat different objective. They aimed to
use the Afrikaners’ history as an explanation for the racist apartheid policies
implemented in the twentieth century. In The Mind of South Africa, Allister Sparks
writes:
[T]he mind of the Afrikaner was shaped during the six generations they were lost
in Africa: a people who missed the momentous developments of eighteenthcentury Europe, the age of reason in which liberalism and democracy were born
and which had its climax in the great revolution of the French bourgeoisie; a people
who spent that time instead in a deep solitude which, if anything, took them back
to an even more elementary existence than the seventeenth-century Europe their
forebears had left; a people who became, surely, the simplest and most backward
fragment of Western civilization in modern times.9
Both groups of historians assume that on average, settler farmers were relatively poor.
The possibility that the early Cape settlers and their descendants might have been
contributing to a thriving commercial economy is not considered.10 Such beliefs have
persisted into the post-apartheid era. Charles Feinstein, in his authoritative book
entitled An Economic History of South Africa published in 2005, dedicates only a few
pages to the first two centuries of European settlement at the Cape.11 After discussing
them briefly, he concludes that “the great majority of colonists were poor and
discontented”.12 There are several other examples.13
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
H. Giliomee, The Afrikaners: Biography of a People (University of Virginia Press,
Charlottesville, 2003), p 321, my emphasis.
D. Meades, Afrikaner-Kapitalisme: Van Brandarm tot Stinkryk (Naledi, Cape Town,
2019).
A. Sparks, The Mind of South Africa (Jonathan Ball, Johannesburg, 2003), p 40.
J. Fourie, “Subverting the Standard View of the Cape Economy: Robert Ross's Cliometric
Contribution and the Work it Inspired”, in I. Pesa and J-B. Gewald (eds), Magnifying
Perspectives: Contributions to History, a Festschrift for Robert Ross, ASC Occasional
Publication, 26 (African Studies Centre, Leiden, 2017), pp 261–273.
C.H. Feinstein, An Economic History of South Africa: Conquest, Discrimination, and
Development (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2005).
Feinstein, An Economic History of South Africa, p 24.
S. Trapido, “From Paternalism to Liberalism: The Cape Colony, 1800–1834”, The
International History Review, 12, 1990, pp 76–104; M.H. de Kock, Economic History of
South Africa (Juta, Cape Town, 1924), pp 24, 40.
7
Perspectives: Making historians count
But is this true? This is the question I attempted to answer in my doctoral
dissertation.14 I analysed more than 2 500 probate inventories of settler households in
the eighteenth and early-nineteenth centuries and counted 28 different commodities
and household goods. I found these settlers to be remarkably affluent. On average,
farmers owned 5 enslaved people, 54 head of cattle and 350 head of sheep. I also used
other sources, such as the opgaafrolle, to confirm my results.15 And I found other
historians, such as Robert Ross and Pieter van Duin, who had questioned, almost three
decades earlier, the supposed poverty of the settlers.16 By analysing probate
inventories using the standard economics toolkit, I was able to debunk some of the
myths that an earlier generation of historians had wanted to believe.17
Figure 2: Share of interracial marriages, by year (1911–1965)
Much more work of this type must be done. One aim of the Biography of an Uncharted
People project, an Andrew W. Mellon-funded initiative which I head up at Stellenbosch
University, is to transcribe South African microdata sources that have hitherto been
largely inaccessible to historians. Using methods that are fairly common in other social
sciences, we are transcribing marriage records in Cape Town to say something about
female empowerment and interracial marriages (Figure 2). 18 We are transcribing
baptism records so that we are able to calculate bridal pregnancy, uncovering the
hidden histories of premarital sex in South Africa. (It was surprisingly high.) We are
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
J. Fourie, “The Remarkable Wealth of the Dutch Cape Colony: Measurements from
Eighteenth-Century Probate Inventories”, The Economic History Review, 66, 2, 2013, pp
419–448.
Fourie, “The Remarkable Wealth”, p 434.
P. van Duin and R. Ross, The Economy of the Cape Colony in the 18th Century (The Centre
for the Study of European Expansion, Leiden, 1987), p 3.
J. Fourie, “The Quantitative Cape: A Review of the New Historiography of the Dutch
Cape Colony”, South African Historical Journal, 66, 1, 2014, pp 142–168.
J. Fourie and K. Inwood, “Interracial Marriages in Early Twentieth-Century Cape Town:
Evidence from Anglican Marriage Records”, History of the Family, 24, 3, 2019, pp 629–
652.
8
Perspectives: Making historians count
also transcribing death notices to comment on the effects of the Spanish influenza and
the speed of urbanisation. We are transcribing slave emancipation records and Cape
auction rolls to gain a better understanding of why an institution as immoral as slavery
persisted for so long. (It was because slaves were used as collateral.19) We are
transcribing Cape Colony opgaafrolle – the Cape of Good Hope Panel project – to
understand the labour relations between Khoe, Xhosa, settler and slave on the eastern
Cape frontier.20 We are transcribing nineteenth-century blue books and voter rolls to
understand the process of state formation and disenfranchisement. We are
transcribing patient files of the Grahamstown Lunatic Asylum, so that we can analyse
the living standards of patients during the late nineteenth century. We are also
transcribing the records of the incorporation of firms established in the Cape in the late
nineteenth century, to understand the nature and scope of capitalism in nineteenthcentury South Africa (the Frontiers of Finance project). And this is only the tip of the
iceberg. What should be clear from the topics mentioned above is that few of them
would be considered economic history. The microdata revolution and, more generally,
the digital humanities revolution is sweeping the entire field of History. As Pim de
Zwart notes, “even cultural historians are refocussing on the digital humanities and are
starting to analyse ‘big data’”.21
A second aim of the Biography project is thus equally important: to equip the
next generation of scholars with the tools of the digital humanities. I am recruiting
students to Stellenbosch and inviting itinerant merchants, from near and far, to coach
these students in using microdata and other research methods. Interdisciplinary
approaches are challenging, but they are also likely to be more rewarding – and
increasingly necessary. We hope to sell our wares locally and abroad. I hope to see
some of our graduates move to other universities in South Africa, exchanging ideas and
spreading the message. And as president of the Economic History Society of Southern
Africa, I’ve set it as my goal to host interdisciplinary conferences where historians,
economists and other social scientists are welcome to present their work in a setting
that welcomes a variety of approaches.22
But we can also learn from our colleagues abroad, and therefore urge my
colleagues and students to attend international workshops, summer schools and
conferences. I think it is essential for future South African historians to be conversant
in the language of other social scientists, and in particular the languages of Economics
and Geography. This, I believe, can only benefit the history profession, but, as I will
argue next, it will also be of great benefit to economics and broader social sciences.
19.
20.
21.
22.
J. Fourie, “Slaves as Capital Investment in the Dutch Cape Colony, 1652–1795”, in P.
Svensson and E. Hillbom (eds), Agricultural Transformation in Global History
Perspective (Routledge, London and New York, 2013) pp 136–159.
J. Fourie and E. Green, “Building the Cape of Good Hope Panel”, The History of the Family,
23, 3, 2018, pp 493–502.
P. de Zwart, “The Future of Global Economic History: Regional Comparisons to Address
Global Questions”, Tijdschrift voor Sociale en Economische Geschiedenis, 15, 2/3, 2018,
pp 129–142.
The first of these conferences is planned for 8 October 2021 in Stellenbosch.
9
Perspectives: Making historians count
Consuls of the community
It is not only historians that will benefit from their interactions with other social
sciences. Trade is not a zero-sum game. Both parties gain from exchange. I shall try to
convince you that historians have at least three things to teach other fields: firstly,
about methods, secondly, about sources and finally about causality.
In his 2011 presidential address to the Economic History Association, Barry
Eichengreen, professor of economics at UC Berkeley, made a case for analogical
reasoning: that is, the ability to use a shared past experience to convey meaning.23
While many scientists use deductive and inductive reasoning in their research,
Eichengreen’s exposure to the policy debates following the Great Recession of 2007,
showed him the power of what could otherwise simply be called story-telling.
Here’s what happened. When the severity of the 2007 financial crisis became
apparent, policy-makers had to think on their feet. They could have followed a
deductive approach to decide which policies to implement. This would have required
them first to agree on the theoretical reasons for the crisis, but this would have been
incredibly difficult given the deep divides in the field of macroeconomics. Alternatively,
they could have followed an inductive approach. But this would have required detailed
statistical evidence, the like of which was not yet available in the midst of the crisis. So,
what did they do? They told a story about a past crisis – the Great Depression of the
1930s. It just so happened that a student of the Great Depression, Ben Bernanke, was
chair of the Federal Reserve, and could avoid the same mistakes that policy-makers
had made almost eighty years earlier. As Eichengreen notes: “Journalists, market
participants, and policy makers all turned to history for guidance on how to react to
this skein of otherwise unfathomable events”.24
Historians are great storytellers. They should use their skills of narration to help
us to gain a better understanding of the world we live in. But it is not only about telling
better stories. It is about telling stories of the stories that were told while these events
were happening. In his 2017 presidential speech to the American Economic
Association, Nobel-prize winning economist Robert Shiller called for the study of
“narrative economics”.25 As he put it:
When we as economists want to understand the most significant economic events
in our history, such as the Great Depression of the 1930s, or subsequent
recessions, or policies towards wealth and poverty, we rarely focus on the
important narratives that accompanied them. We have lagged behind other
23.
24.
25.
B. Eichengreen, "Economic History and Economic Policy", The Journal of Economic
History, 72, 2, 2012, pp 289–307.
Eichengreen, “Economic History”, p 289.
R. J. Shiller, “Narrative Economics”, American Economic Review, 107, 4, 2017, pp 967–
1004.
10
Perspectives: Making historians count
disciplines in attending to the importance of narratives, and while all disciplines
use narratives more since 2010, economics (and finance) remain laggards.26
The narratives we use matter because they affect our behaviour. People are seldom
convinced by fact or figures; we are far more likely to be swayed by a story that
strengthens our existing beliefs and biases.27 The way we tell history, therefore, and
the topics we talk about have real world consequences.
Roy Havemann has recently produced wonderful insights into the collapse of
Saambou and other small banks in the early 2000s. 28 Most of what we knew about
recent banking failures in South Africa depended on haphazard and superficial
newspaper articles, perhaps an official government-sanctioned report or the one-sided
biographies of those involved in the crisis. Havemann does a brilliant job of combining
empirical sources and estimation techniques to show how the crisis spread, and why it
was not necessarily the most at-risk banks that ultimately collapsed. But what the
historian could add is the perspective from below: what did the bankers, or Treasury
officials, or Reserve Bank governor believe was happening? Through which networks
did news spread, and who were part of those networks? Why did it go wrong when, as
Havemann shows, it did not need to? Robert Shiller reminds us a “deep understanding
of history requires imputing what was on the minds of those people who made history,
what their narratives were”.29 Narratives, in short, allow for historical analyses which
point to the importance of human agency as much as (or even more than) structure.
A second contribution historians can make to the study of economics is to teach
us source critique. Few economists nowadays collect their own data. Some African
economic historians sit happily in Starbucks while downloading datasets from
repositories with little concern about what we would call “the data generating
process”.30 Who compiled the data? From where? Why? For what purpose? These are
not typical questions that economists answer. Economists care a great deal about
selection, yes. Is this a representative sample of the total population? But once we have
confirmed that it is, we are happy to believe that the data is reliable – or, at least, that
the remaining errors are orthogonal to what we hope to prove.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
Shiller, “Narrative Economics”, p 969.
J.T. Kaplan, S.I. Gimbel and S. Harris, "Neural Correlates of Maintaining One’s Political
Beliefs in the Face of Counterevidence", Scientific Reports, 6, 2016, 39589.
R.C. Havemann, “Lessons from South African Bank Failures 2002 to 2014”, PhD thesis,
Stellenbosch University, 2019.
Shiller, “Narrative Economics”, p 969.
J. Fourie and N. Obikili. “Decolonizing with Data: The Cliometric Turn in African
Economic History”, in C. Dieboult and M. Haupert (eds), Handbook of Cliometrics
(Springer, Cham, 2019), pp 1721–1745.
11
Perspectives: Making historians count
Figure 3: World Bank data versus South African statistics.31
Let me provide a simple example. Let’s say you would want to look at the sex ratio at
birth for a host of African countries. Where do you go first? The World Bank World
Development Indicators is probably the most reliable source: this is exactly what one
of my colleagues at Stellenbosch, Francisco Marco-Gracia, did. He downloaded the data
and found something fascinating: the sex ratio at birth for several African countries,
including South Africa, had not changed over the entire period of data availability
(1962–1990). He then did what any good historian would do – he went to other sources
to confirm the results. Unsurprisingly, when he looked at the original South African
censuses, he found the WDI statistics had been completely fabricated (economists
would say it was imputed, but that is just a rhetorical trick).
This matters. Sex ratios at birth are sometimes used in regression analysis for a
variety of reasons. While economists think very hard about the econometric
specifications of their analysis – probably because they are trained to do this and are
rewarded by journals for doing so – what should clearly matter more is the data they
put into their models. Rubbish in, rubbish out. I am not the first to argue this, of course.
Morten Jerven has written eloquently about the dangers of poor numbers.32 Historians
can help us understand the value of historical context in our data-generating processes
– and should be more critical of economists who try to bamboozle their audience with
nifty techniques without a similar effort to understand the sources they use.33
31.
32.
33.
F. Marco-Gracia and J. Fourie, “Missing Boys: Explaining South Africa’s Unbalanced Sex
Ratio, 1894–2011”, ERSA Working Paper 804, November 2019.
M. Jerven, Poor Numbers: How We are Misled by African Development Statistics and What
to Do About It (Cornell University Press, Ithaca, 2013).
Lamoreaux makes this and several other points in arguing that the future of economic
history must be interdisciplinary. See N. Lamoreaux, “The Future of Economic History
Must be Interdisciplinary”, The Journal of Economic History, 75, 4, 2015, pp 1251–1257.
12
Perspectives: Making historians count
Let me make one side-remark about sources. Both Economics and History are
fundamentally empirical sciences. We do theorise about the world, but much of what
we do is to test our theories with real-world evidence. Economists use cross-sectional,
or panel or time-series datasets, historians use a kaleidoscope of archival sources.
When either or both of those fields become too theoretical – as has happened in the
past and could likely happen again – Economics with all its mathematical models and
History with its postmodernist bent, then we are both poorer for it. As economist Gary
Fields wrote in December 2000 about South Africa’s high unemployment rate: “A
fundamental truth is sometimes forgotten: if you're poor, you can't get rich by selling
to yourself”.34
Just as no country has become prosperous by closing its borders, no academic
field has grown influential by talking to itself. Theory is only useful when tested against
evidence. “The most daunting aspect of analysing society, whether in its historical
dimension or its present structure, is an awareness that much of what we write must
sooner or later be faulted by different and more satisfactory methods of using
evidence”.35 These are Stanley Trapido’s words in 1972. Let us be open to new sources
and methods of analysing them, and wary of economists who just train students in
Mathematics, or historians who abolish courses that take students into the archive.
A third way in which historians can help economists is to think about causality.
The credibility revolution in Economics, with clever identification strategies to confirm
a causal relationship between two variables empirically, has had a considerable
influence on Economic History and beyond.36 Good students of Economics who are
interested in History are urged to find “natural experiments” – a random, exogenous
shock that could be used to test its causal effect on some later outcome. There is much
to praise in these types of studies – and we have learned a lot from them. Whereas the
first papers to use these methods were only interested in proving that “history
matters”, the more recent wave of papers care more about why and how it matters.37
That is a good thing. But there is a danger lurking. Soon we will run out of “natural
experiments” that are cleanly identified.38 What then? And more importantly,
outcomes like higher incomes, upward mobility or taller individuals are never the
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
G.S. Fields, “The Employment Problem in South Africa”, Trade & Industry Monitor, 16,
2000, pp 3–6.
S. Trapido, “South Africa and the Historians”, African Affairs, 71, 285, 1972, pp 444–448.
J. D. Angrist and J-S. Pischke, "The Credibility Revolution in Empirical Economics: How
Better Research Design is Taking the Con out of Econometrics", Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 24, 2, 2010, pp 3–30.
C. Monnet and E. Quintin, "Why do Financial Systems Differ? History Matters", Journal
of Monetary Economics, 54, 4, 2007, pp 1002–1017; E. Huillery, "History Matters: The
Long-term Impact of Colonial Public Investments in French West Africa", American
Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1, 2, 2009, pp 176–215; P. Jones, "History
Matters: New Evidence on the Long-run Impact of Colonial Rule on Institutions",
Journal of Comparative Economics, 41, 1, 2013, pp 181–200.
J. Diamond and J. A. Robinson (eds), Natural Experiments of History (Harvard University
Press, Cambridge, 2010).
13
Perspectives: Making historians count
result of just one monocausal origin. What these studies often do is to explain one
causal factor with a high degree of accuracy, but the factor may only contribute a small
component of the actual effect. This is especially true when the other determinants are
difficult to measure.39 As several economists now admit, the focus is too readily on
statistical rather than economic significance.40
This is certainly not an attempt to repudiate the economists’ causal inference.
But it is a plea for historians to engage economists and question their assumptions and
inferences. Historians’ deep knowledge of the past is necessary to expose missed
mechanisms and invisible interactions; to point out the obvious (more important)
questions hidden from view when regression analysis is the only method in the
researcher’s employ, and to complicate the often over-simplified, narratives which, as
Gareth Austin says, “compress history”.41 “Big data” is a complementary source for
historians. In the same way, archival material/oral history can explain things that large
data sets cannot. In South Africa, historians are largely on the periphery of research
and policy debates. My message here is that this need not be the case. Historians must
play a more active role, in academe and in government, to tell the stories that will shape
our views, to critique the poor numbers we economists have come to rely upon, and to
inject a more complicated view into the monocausal pasts we so easily construct.
Final thoughts
History may not strictly be considered a science, but History makes for better science.
In fact, History is the nexus of the human and social sciences. That is because,
ultimately, almost all empirical evidence is historical. Even psychology or behavioural
economic experiments are performed within a certain time and space. Devoid of that
context, the interpretations of the results may be biased towards the ethics and
experiences of the observer’s own time and space. Context matters, and the methods
and sources historians use help us to understand that. I want to urge South African
historians to travel to neighbouring and distant human, social and natural sciences, to
learn their tools and techniques, and to use them to answer ambitious research
questions. It won’t be easy, but it is necessary. Not only for the survival of the history
profession, but for the good health and prosperity of the social science community at
large. That is why historians count, in South Africa and elsewhere. Let us hope they
take up the challenge.
39.
40.
41.
◆ ◆ ◆
For a recent critique, see S. Bourgeois-Gironde and É. Monnet, “Natural Experiments
and Causality in Economic History: What Relation to Theory and Temporality?”,
Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales, 72, 4, 2017, pp 1087–1116.
S. Ziliak and D.N. McCloskey, The Cult of Statistical Significance: How the Standard Error
Costs Us Jobs, Justice, and Lives (University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, 2008).
G. Austin, “The ‘Reversal of Fortune’ Thesis and the Compression of History:
Perspectives from African and Comparative Economic History", Journal of International
Development: The Journal of the Development Studies Association, 20, 8, 2008, pp 996–
1027.
14
Perspectives: Making historians count
How should historians count?
Faeeza Ballim
University of Johannesburg
Johan Fourie’s plea for South African historians to be more audacious in their research
ideas is a compelling one, although vague on the definition of a suitably bold project. In
this commentary I consider these possible directions, while sounding a note of caution
on their portents.
Fourie argues that historians should engage more extensively with
contemporary socio-political issues. It is important to note that historians are not
entirely devoid of interest in national policy-related matters. Land reform in South
Africa is an excellent illustration of this. Historians such as William Beinart and Peter
Delius, who are experts in transformations in the countryside, have made significant
contributions to policy and litigation concerned with land restitution, communal
tenure and traditional authorities. It is ultimately challenging to identify the types of
historical writing that constitute social engagement given the fact that all historians
speak to present concerns, even the seemingly “ornamental” ones. As E.H. Carr noted
in 1961, “…history is an unending dialogue between the present and the past”.1 Even
the preoccupation with the local, which Fourie mentions, was born out of political
activism.
The preoccupation with the local emerged from the disillusionment with the
grand, overarching explanations of historical change in vogue in the 1970s at a time
when Marxist historiography captured the imagination of scholars around the world.
In response, a generation of historians in the 1970s and 1980s, sympathetic to charges
of academic elitism, were concerned with furthering the struggle against apartheid.
They were inspired by emerging approaches of social history and urged that attention
be paid to the voices and experiences of ordinary South Africans. In so doing they gave
attention to the experiences of the individual and examined processes at the local level
to shed light on broader historical trends. I agree that inadvertently this has led to a
neglect of the levers of power, the activities of the state and changing economic trends,
and that historians need to re-centre the role of the state and the macro-level political
economy in studies of historical change.2 Indeed, there has been a surge of interest in
1.
2.
E.H Carr, What is History? The George Macaulay Trevelyan Lectures Delivered in
the University of Cambridge January–March 1961, second edition (Penguin Books,
London, 1987), p 30.
Exceptions to this over the years include: C.H. Feinstein, An Economic History of South
Africa: Conquest, Discrimination, and Development (Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, 2005); B. Fine and Z. Rustomjee, The Political Economy of South Africa: From
Minerals-Energy Complex to Industrialisation (C. Hurst & Co. Publishers, London, 1996);
D. Posel, The Making of Apartheid, 1948–1961: Conflict and Compromise (Oxford
University Press, Oxford and New York, 1991).
15
Perspectives: Making historians count
the state and of state corporations in recent years, likely spawned by the signs of its
debilitation in the midst of the South African state capture saga.3
It is true that a macro-level requires different techniques to the granular,
intimate methodology of social history. Fourie’s phrase “making historians count”
naturally leads one to consider the use of quantitative methods. Quantitative studies
by definition rely on the force of numbers, or on large amounts of data from which to
draw conclusions and so is far removed from the intimate concern with the experiences
of the individual that animate social historians. South African historians have neglected
quantitative methods of analysis, with students of History receiving little to no training
in statistical methods at universities. These methods have their own drawbacks, not
least of which is their inability to establish causation convincingly. But as Fourie writes,
this is not an insurmountable obstacle to conducting valuable historical research. The
value of quantitative methods in establishing plausible explanations for historical
phenomena has been ably demonstrated by a historian of the British Industrial
Revolution, Robert Allen. Allen has made a strong case for the significance of high
wages in Britain to the Industrial Revolution, using a database of historic wages for the
cities of London, Amsterdam, Vienna, Florence, Beijing and Delhi.4 Based on the
assumption that higher wages incentivise employers to replace labour with machines,
Allen demonstrates the financial impetus for technological ingenuity and invention in
Britain.
The appeal of Allen’s analysis lies in the scale of comparison it allows. While the
average British worker was by no means opulent, they were paid more than workers
in other European cities, making higher wages a plausible explanation for the
particularly British nature of the Industrial Revolution. But the definitions and proxies
that Allen adopted in the study were a subject of debate. Jane Humphries argued that
Allen’s assumption of the calorific needs of the British working class at the time of the
Industrial Revolution were too low, thus challenging Allen’s conclusion that people had
wages to spare after their expenditure on subsistence. Based on qualitative evidence,
Humphries also claimed that the average family unit was larger than Allen assumed,
which meant that the wages of a single male breadwinner had to stretch further among
more children. In addition, the prevalence of absentee fathers meant that a male
breadwinner was not always present.5 Since the past will always be a foreign country,
and present-day historians are unable to identify entirely with the lifestyles of its
inhabitants. It is important for quantitative historians to be transparent about the
categories and proxies they choose and to be open to critique from those of a
qualitative bent.
3.
4.
5.
B. Freund, Twentieth-Century South Africa: A Developmental History (Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, 2018).
R. C. Allen, “Why the Industrial Revolution was British: Commerce, Induced Invention,
and the Scientific Revolution”, The Economic History Review, 64, 2, 2011, pp 357–84.
J. Humphries, “The Lure of Aggregates and the Pitfalls of the Patriarchal Perspective: A
Critique of the High Wage Economy Interpretation of the British Industrial Revolution”,
Economic History Review, 66, 3, 2013, pp 693–714.
16
Perspectives: Making historians count
The recent proliferation of big data has opened a range of analytical
possibilities. It is driven by the mass of data that an increasingly networked society has
enabled through various internet platforms. One of these, which Fourie mentions, is
neural networks, a technique currently used by practitioners of artificial intelligence.
It is important to note that neural networks rely on longstanding statistical techniques.
But they also prize conformity above all else. This is due to the underlying statistical
methods, which urge the discovery of the mean by reducing of the distance between
the otherwise scattered data points. This is a far cry from the social historian’s more
intimate concern with the lived experience of individuals and societies.
As Fourie writes, insights from other disciplines can be valuable to the project
of history-writing. While economic historians are more likely to utilise quantitative
methods, Economic History is not an exclusively quantitative field. The particularly
economic nature of this lens warrants further examination. African historians began to
study African economies seriously in the 1970s, with Antony Hopkins’s An Economic
History of West Africa, a pioneering work in African economic history.6 This and similar
interventions went a long way to undoing the racist conception of African societies as
primitive, timeless and unchanging by demonstrating that Africans responded to
economic incentives and the opportunities proffered by global trade much like people
anywhere else in the world. At the same time the primacy of economic motives within
the studies of economic history contains the underlying assumption that people are
motivated by the desire to maximise their self-interest, a supposition that historians of
other persuasions might quibble with.
In conclusion I agree that there is value to historians in extending our reach
wider towards the grander narratives of politics and the economy that have been
neglected in the last forty years or so. While there is a variety of methods to choose
from, particularly quantitative methods, it is important that historians be transparent
and critical of the methodological limits of these.
◆ ◆ ◆
6.
A. G. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (Longman, London, 1973).
17
Perspectives: Making historians count
Making people count: writing the history of the Dutch Cape
Gerald Groenewald
University of Johannesburg
The past is lost. As Robert Ross reminds us:
The past is dead and gone. What we can do is study material remains of the past
which have been preserved into the present. And on the basis of which we make
the attempt to reconstruct, we make intellectual constructs of what the past might
have been like.1
What we work with are the remnants of the past, most often ink on paper. Here the
historian of the empire created by the Dutch East India Company (VOC) is truly
fortunate. The massive administrative network of this merchant company constantly
produced documents, and many copies of them, so that the paper empire of the VOC is
spread over three continents, from the Netherlands to the Cape of Good Hope to
Southeast Asia and beyond. Much of this data is both serial in nature (i.e., similar
information, year after year, such as census records) and standardised across the
empire (similar tax records, similar legal records, similar civil records such as marriage
and birth registers). This makes it possible to do comparative history on a large scale
within the framework of the VOC empire.
Historians of the VOC world have long been utilising these sources; in fact, a
striking feature of VOC historiography is how much of it focuses on economic and
administrative matters.2 Even in South Africa, long before the revisionist historians of
the 1970s and 1980s, pioneers of VOC Cape history have used serialised data to map
out extensively the economic landscape of the seventeenth and eighteenth-century
Cape. Under the leadership of P.J. van der Merwe, starting in the 1930s, two generations
of students at Stellenbosch University compiled their MA theses on virtually every
aspect of economic life at the Dutch Cape: ranging from grain and wine farming, to the
history of fishing and forestry.3 Even when historians such as James C. Armstrong, Nigel
1.
2.
3.
R. Ross, “Comparisons and Ways Forward”, in N. Worden (ed.), Continent Lives: Social
Identity and Material Culture in the VOC World (Historical Studies Department,
University of Cape Town, Cape Town, 2007), p 611.
For example, M.A.P. Meilink-Roelofsz, Asian Trade and European Influence in the
Indonesian Archipelago between 1500 and about 1630 (Martinus Nijhoff, The Hague,
1962) and H. Furber, Rival Empires of Trade in the Orient, 1600–1800 (University of
Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, 1976). This line of research culminated in the now
standard work of E.M. Jacob, Merchant in Asia: The Trade of the Dutch East India
Company during the Eighteenth Century (Amsterdam University Press, Amsterdam,
2006).
On Van der Merwe’s contribution, see J.S. Bergh, “P.J. (Piet) van der Merwe and D.J.
(Dirk) Kotzé aan die Stuur by Stellenbosch, 1959–77: Goue Jare of Verspeelde
Geleenthede?”, Historia, 53, 2, 2008. This line of research culminated in two
publications based on magisterial works dealing with the Cape economy from the
1980s: D. Sleigh, Die Buiteposte: VOC-Buiteposte onder Kaapse Bestuur, 1652–1795
18
Perspectives: Making historians count
Worden and Robert C.-H. Shell began investigating Cape slavery in the late 1970s, they
did so chiefly via an economic lens, making extensive use of serial data such as ship
records, sale records, tax records, household inventories and testaments. Their
arguments and analyses were underpinned with statistical tables and graphs.4
Yet counting people is not the same as knowing them, or understanding their
experiences. Johan Fourie admits that economists do not practise source criticism and
do not question their data (p 11). Historians increasingly acknowledge that statistics –
despite their “clinical” appearance in graphs and tables – are not objective: As Tim
Rowse recently argued, the statistical table renders “difference in quantitative terms,
representing peoples as if they were populations amenable/knowable to
observing/managing authority”.5
Luckily, Cape historians soon realised that although the VOC’s paper archive is
very much obsessed with serial sources, there is one large group of records that is
amenable to qualitative analysis: court records. This being so, by the early 1980s
Robert Ross and Nigel Worden started making use of these qualitative sources to write
on topics such as slave life, discipline and resistance.6 It is my contention that it was
this line of research, rather than the more cliometric approach, that resonated so much
with the descendants of slaves in the Western Cape, and which made slavery an
increasingly “hot” topic in the 1980s and 1990s.7 Likewise, the use of court records to
reclaim aspects of the lived reality and mentalities of a wide range of people at the early
Cape acted as an inspiration for a new generation of historians who were drawn to the
rich archives of the VOC in the 1990s and early 2000s. This is behind the flowering of
research into the VOC Cape over the past two decades.8 Using qualitative data in
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
(HAUM, Pretoria, 1993), based on his 1987 Stellenbosch doctoral thesis; and P. van
Duin and R. Ross, The Economy of the Cape Colony in the Eighteenth Century (The Centre
for the Study of European Expansion, Leiden, 1987).
J.C. Armstrong, “The Slaves, 1652–1795”, in R. Elphick and H. Giliomee (eds), The
Shaping of South African Society, 1652–1820 (Maskew Miller Longman, Cape Town,
1979); N. Worden, Slavery in Dutch South Africa (Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, 1985), based on his 1982 Cambridge doctoral thesis; and R.C.-H. Shell,
Children of Bondage: A Social History of the Slave Society at the Cape of Good Hope, 1652–
1838 (Wits University Press, Johannesburg, 1994), based on his 1986 Yale University
doctoral thesis.
T. Rowse, “The Statistical Table as Colonial Knowledge”, Itinerario 41, 1, 2017, p 68.
R. Ross, Cape of Torments: Slavery and Resistance in South Africa (Routledge & Kegan
Paul, London, 1983); and Worden, Slavery in Dutch South Africa, chapters 7 to 9.
K. Ward and N. Worden, “Commemorating, Suppressing and Invoking Cape Slavery”, in
S. Nuttall and C. Coetzee (eds), Negotiating the Past: The Making of Memory in South
Africa (Oxford University Press, Cape Town, 1998); and N. Worden, “The Changing
Politics of Slave Heritage in the Western Cape, South Africa”, Journal of African History,
501, 2009.
For a summary of the achievements of this scholarship, see G. Groenewald, “Culture and
Society at the Cape of Good Hope, 1652–1795”, in T. Spear et al. (eds), Oxford Research
Encyclopedia of African History (Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, 2020),
19
Perspectives: Making historians count
conjunction with the more traditional, quantitative data, historians have investigated
how groups ranging from the VOC elite and free burghers to the underclasses
consisting of slaves, soldiers and sailors, have performed their identities, dealt with
their feelings about shame and honour, and expressed their loves and desires.9
It is only through having a fully-rounded view of human beings on the ground,
and the way in which larger structural forces interacted with their personal agencies,
that we can begin to know what it was like to be a young woman with a child born outof-wedlock,10 a slave man whose jealousy over a beloved one drives him to violence, or
a sailor who feels compelled to defend his honour in a duel. We should not just count
people in the past; we must make them count and save them from “the enormous
condescension of posterity”;11 also from the serial data of the VOC archives, which
reduce their rich and complex lives to mere numbers.
◆ ◆ ◆
9.
10.
11.
see online at https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277734.013.451 (accessed
20 February 2021).
See, among others, N. Worden (ed.), Cape Town between East and West: Social Identities
in a Dutch Colonial Town (Jacana, Johannesburg, 2012); and P. Russell and N. Worden
(eds), Honourable Intentions? Violence and Virtue in Australian and Cape Colonies, c.
1750 to 1850 (Routledge, London and New York, 2016).
The history of pre-marital sex at the Cape is not “hidden”, as Fourie claims. There exists
a sizeable historiography on this topic, from the seventeenth to the twentieth centuries,
based on quantitative and qualitative data. See, among others, G. Groenewald, “‘A
Mother Makes No Bastard’: Family Law, Sexual Relations and Illegitimacy in Dutch
Colonial Cape Town, c. 1652–1795”, African Historical Review, 39, 2, 2007; and “‘Een
Spoorloos Vrouwspersoon’: Unmarried Mothers, Moral Regulation and the Church at
the Cape of Good Hope, circa 1652–1795”, Historia, 53, 2, 2008. See also V.C. Malherbe,
“‘In Onegt Verwekt’: Law, Custom and Illegitimacy in Cape Town, 1800–1840”, Journal
of Southern African Studies, 31, 1, 2005; and “Born into Bastardy: The Out-of-Wedlock
Child in Early Victorian Cape Town”, Journal of Family History, 32, 1, 2007. Also S.
Burman and M. Naude, “Bearing a Bastard: The Social Consequences of Illegitimacy in
Cape Town, 1896–1939”, Journal of Southern African Studies, 17, 3, 1991.
E.P. Thompson, The Making of the English Working Class (Penguin, Harmondsworth,
1980), p 12.
20
Perspectives: Making historians count
The place of History and historians
Jennifer Upton
The historian cannot do history without dealing with archives. Archives vary in form,
as do the types of material that are taken as evidence and the manner historians engage
with this evidence. But at its core, writing, narrating, or creating history is based on
how the historian treats evidence. Given the variety of sources that can be used as
evidence – among them oral history and memory, newspapers, minutes and
newsletters, court documents, census records, ancient manuscripts, archaeological
evidence, diaries, novels, financial records and, yes, statistics – the types of history (and
historians) are many. The field of economic history, which is not limited to
econometrics and quantitative methods, is one subset. Methodologies and theoretical
frameworks have formed around historians’ approaches to evidence, their convictions
about the extent and limitations of what can be said about the past, and critical
appraisals of the very frameworks they use, by placing them in their historical contexts:
the history of History.
One of the crucial insights that this history can offer the field of digital
humanities (and historians) is the awareness that all researchers enter conversations
that span time and geography. Our findings are contingent – they have a genealogy –
and our methods have a history. This means that archives are not simply repositories
from which to extract information, a territory to be conquered. They come into being
within political contexts, influenced by state, society, and individuals. The narrative a
scholar might glean from an archive depends on the questions that are asked.
There are questions that numbers do not answer. Just as sources do not “speak
for themselves”, neither do numbers or statistics. They require attention and
interpretation. Scholars therefore need to consider, as Jill Lepore asks, “what kind of
knowledge numbers add up to, and subtract”.1 Measurements of societal trends and
human behaviour told through numbers “are subject to intense ideological debates
about what, in fact, they do measure”, as Khalil Gibran Muhammed has pointed out.2
The deployment of quasi-empiricism to justify racist, dehumanising policies in South
Africa, the United States, and elsewhere is well documented.3 The point here is not that
one approach is more likely than another to be used in bad faith: it is that scholars need
1.
2.
3.
J. Lepore, “Detection of Deception”, The Last Archive (podcast), 2020. See
https://www.thelastarchive.com/season-1/episode-2-detection-of-deception
(accessed 27 January 2021).
K.G. Muhammed, “How Numbers Lie: Intersectional Violence and the Quantifications of
Race”, Lecture, Schlesinger Library at the Radcliffe Institute for Advanced Study,
Cambridge: MA, 25 February 2016.
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=br0ZYTGuW9M&t=415s (accessed 27 January
2021).
S. Dubow, Scientific Racism in Modern South Africa (Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, 1995); and A Commonwealth of Knowledge: Science, Sensibility, and White
South Africa 1820–2000 (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2006).
21
Perspectives: Making historians count
to apply a similarly critical lens to all types of data and recognise the processes involved
in acquiring them.
The tools of the digital humanities offer intriguing research possibilities that
were not previously available. For example, Enslaved: Peoples of the Historical Slave
Trade is an online portal that brings together digital databases containing over half a
million records relating to the Atlantic slave trade, so that biographical information
about enslaved people can be pieced together from records in different archives and
data sets.4 With the relative novelty of big data and digital humanities methodologies,
it is incumbent on researchers to develop a rigorous ethical framework for their
scholarship. Novelty notwithstanding, the digital humanities are also subject to the
evidentiary obligations that historians have long debated: what can we say about the
past? On what basis are we making our claims?
Looming over the invitation to historians to make themselves “count” – in
Fourie’s formulation, by applying quantitative methods, complicating simplistic
narratives, asking bolder research questions and, ultimately, shaping national policy –
are the power structures of contemporary academia. The question of the university’s
place and purpose in society is both economic and social, and is being debated in and
beyond South Africa. To receive state funding, universities are expected to justify their
economic value, with students increasingly being positioned as customers in a
knowledge economy. Academics, too, are pressured to participate in this model of their
work’s value, in which research “counts” by the number of articles published and
funding grants awarded, and learning is made measurable by positive student surveys
and post-university employment. Under the so-called marketisation of the university,
humanities departments face particular pressure to prove their value. Combined with
the competitiveness of the academic job market and the precarity of contractual
employment within it, these factors point to a different kind of crisis: one whose
solution would not only require historians to advocate for the worth of their discipline,
but for colleagues, university administrators, and policy makers to recognise and
defend it.
An alternative to the intellectual marketplace Fourie describes, in which
historians need to promote their wares for the survival of their craft, is the challenging
and rewarding space of truly interdisciplinary discussion. The lively History and
African Studies Seminar, which ran at the Durban campus of the University of KwaZuluNatal from 1996 to the late 2000s, was one such example.5 In addition to those working
within the traditional disciplinary boundaries of historical studies, the seminar series
drew in students, anthropologists, political scientists, community activists, literary
4.
5.
M. Solly, “Who Were America’s Enslaved? A New Database Humanizes the Names
behind the Numbers”, Smithsonian Magazine, 22 December 2020 at
https://www.smithsonianmag.com/history/sweeping-new-digital-databaseemphasizes-enslaved-peoples-individuality-180976513; and “Enslaved: Peoples of the
Historical Slave Trade”, at https://enslaved.org (accessed 27 January 2021).
Archive of the History and African Studies Seminar, at https://phambo.wiser.org.za
(accessed 27 January 2021).
22
Perspectives: Making historians count
scholars, sociologists, economists, archivists, clinician-scholars, nurses and others
from the region and internationally. The robust debate in these seminars did not
override their general sense of collegiality – collegiality not as a strategic metric of
academic success, but a mark of mutual respect and intellectual curiosity.
Like artefacts, our narrated histories are created and fashioned, remnants of
lives which cannot be replicated. The methodologies of social history can offer insight
into quantitative approaches, revealing their contexts and influences – reminding us
that those who produce history are also subject to its processes.
◆ ◆ ◆
23
Perspectives: Making historians count
Must historians count to count?
Tinashe Nyamunda
University of Pretoria
For the survival of History as a discipline, and for the “good health and prosperity” of
the social sciences in general, Johan Fourie urges historians “to travel to neighbouring
and distant human, social and natural sciences, to learn their tools and techniques, and
to use them to answer ambitious research questions”. “This will not only make the field
of history stronger”, he argues, but also “prevent their annexation in future”. This
argument assumes that History is facing a serious crisis and Fourie suggests that if
South African historians do not heed his advice, the discipline is in danger of becoming
irrelevant. Although concluding that history is important, he suggests that the best way
to make historians count is by taking up the challenge to expand their methodological
tool kit. To buttress this point, Fourie cites Stanley Trapido’s reminder that:
…the most daunting aspect of analysing society, whether in its historical dimension
or its present structure, is an awareness that much of what we write must sooner
or later be faulted by different and more satisfactory methods of using evidence.1
It is unsurprising that Fourie cites Trapido, having first presented the article
published in this issue as a paper at a seminar series named after Stanley Trapido.2
Presented before an audience made up predominantly of historians (although some
colleagues from the Department of Economics were present), the paper invited
interesting discussion. Fourie’s decision to publish his challenge to historians to “be
open to new sources and methods of analysing them” invites equally vibrant
engagement. He encourages historians to be “wary of economists who just train
students in mathematics, or historians who abolish courses that take students into the
archive”, but more than that, Fourie’s departure point is that historians are not doing
enough to make themselves count. But to be clear, although Fourie’s point on
“academic trade” between History and other disciplines is broad, his major concern
focuses on economic history, particularly his assumption of the novelty of big data. As
far as he is concerned, contemporary historical writing can now be faulted on the basis
of more satisfactory methods of using big data.
In responding to Fourie’s challenge, I engage the following points underpinning
his argument: first, that History is in crisis, facing the risk of becoming irrelevant and
being annexed. Secondly, I challenge the argument’s methodological assumptions and
fallacies about the interdisciplinary limits of history. Thirdly, I demonstrate that what
Fourie presents as novel methodological developments with respect to big data are in
fact nothing new, and had his appeal engaged more deeply with the history of such
debates, this would have been clear. Finally, on the basis of the above analysis, I suggest
that Fourie’s call to historians says more about the limitations of Economics as a
1.
2.
S. Trapido, “South Africa and the Historians”, African Affairs, 71, 285, 1972, pp 444-448.
Tinashe Nyamunda chaired the seminar in which Johan Fourie presented “Making
Historians Count”, at the University of the Free State in March 2019.
24
Perspectives: Making historians count
discipline, at least on the basis of his article, than it does about the challenges that
History faces as a discipline.
To be or not to be counted! Is that the question?
By discussing how to make “South African historians count”, Fourie uses a clever play
on words. The word “count” can be used in multiple ways based on its different
meanings. As a transitive verb, it can mean either add up, enumerate, ascertain the sum
of or account. As an intransitive verb, it can refer to one who has value, importance or
influence, among other meanings. It can also be used as a noun to represent the act of
counting, among other meanings.3 In his work, Fourie appears to use the word both as
a transitive and intransitive verb as well as, in some cases, a noun. For example, at one
point, he suggests that historians can make themselves count by acquiring quantitative
skills such as using Optical Character Recognition techniques to capture and date
photographs or data processing software to capture historical statistics. In another
context, he uses the term “count” to depict value. Either way, Fourie’s suggestion is that
for historians to be valued, to stand up among the social sciences and “be counted”,
they must include in their methodological tool kit the ability “to count” – that is,
incorporate quantitative techniques.
History is one of the most receptive disciplines in the humanities. This is
particularly because it is among the most interdisciplinary of the humanities. Without
immediately invoking Richard J. Evans’s In Defence of History, historians are open to
embracing invitations to novel methodological approaches.4 Fourie is not incorrect to
point out that historians can only enrich the discipline if they incorporate large data
sets, statistics and computational methods. If History is indeed the mother of all
disciplines, why should historians not embrace methodological eclecticism? To be
clear, there is nothing to lose and more to gain by imploring historians to incorporate
Fourie’s suggestions in their work to attract a variety of readers and students.
Indeed, any student of the history of climate change, for example, would benefit
immensely by using a variety of data sets, including isotope and landscape analysis as
well as geographic information systems, among others.5 Others in cognate disciplines,
such as Archaeology, which make use of historical methods, grapple with similar issues
of methodological “trading”, to borrow Fourie’s term.6 To make sense of some of their
findings, archaeologists borrow or incorporate methods used in Palaeontology, and a
3.
4.
5.
6.
Collins English Dictionary,
https://www.collinsdictionary.com/dictionary/english/count (accessed 5 February
2021).
R. J. Evans, In Defence of History (Granta Books, London, 1997).
See, for example, I.N. Gregory and P.S. Ell, Historical GIS: Technologies, Methodologies
and Scholarship (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2007).
See, for example, G. Carver, “Archaeology and History, the History of Archaeology, and
the Archaeology of Archaeology”, in A. Baeriswyl, G. Descoeudres, M. Stercken and D.
Wild (eds), Die mittelalterliche Stadt erfoschen: Archaologie und Geschichte im Dialog,
(Schweizerische Burgenverein, Basel, 2009), pp 43–52.
25
Perspectives: Making historians count
range of anthropological methods. Being methodologically eclectic, Fourie suggests,
especially where counting is concerned, will allow historians to ask bold, new,
ambitious and important research questions.
Although presented as a call to History in general, Fourie’s emphasis on the data
revolution must be viewed in the context of debates on the new economic history of
Africa. In 2009, Antony G. Hopkins published a pathbreaking study that traced the
developments in African economic history in the 1980s, following both a decline in
interest and the rise of postmodernism as well as the shift from material towards
cultural considerations.7 It was only in the 2000s, with the rise of “new institutional
history” spurred by Darren Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson that
renewed interest in African poverty was triggered by economists. 8 Although Hopkins
celebrated the bold attempts to revisit the African economic past and encouraged
historians to take up the challenge to engage “new institutional history”, he was equally
critical of the methodologies used, which were replete with problematic assumptions
and the use of poor data which not only misrepresented that African past, but also
flattened its history.9
As Hopkins made his call for a revival of interest in African economic history,
scholars such as Gareth Austin and others established the African Economic History
Network (AEHN), which began meeting annually at the London School of Economics
(LSE) between 2005 and 2011 before being hosted by other universities thereafter.10
This ultimately led to the publication in 2014 of a special issue in an international
journal dedicated entirely to the economic history of Africa. It covered a wide range of
topics including population and growth, national income accounting and the economy,
the Ghana cocoa take-off, rubber production in Nigeria, anthropometrics and living
standards, comparative growth at the Cape and currency in Liberia and Sierra Leone,
among others. The Economic History Review stimulated an economic history approach
to the study of the African economic past, not based on “limited or illustrative use of
numbers”, but more strikingly, on “systematic presentation of time series, often
painstakingly recovered from archival sources and processed into a consistent data
set”.11 Using quantitative and, in some cases, regression analysis, the issue represented
for the members of the AEHN a revival in interest in African economic history that
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
A.G. Hopkins, “The New Economic History of Africa”, Journal of African History, 50,
2009, pp 155-177.
See D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson and J. A. Robinson, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation”, American Economic Review, 91, 5, 2001, pp
1369–1401.
Hopkins, “The New Economic History of Africa”; See also the work of G. Austin.
See “African Economic History Network”, at https://www.aehnetwork.org/conference
(accessed 5 February 2021). The AEHN was to be hosted by the International Studies
Group at the University of the Free State from 21–23 September 2020. However,
because of the Covid-19 pandemic and the global lockdown it has caused, the meeting
has been postponed to 2021.
G. Austin and S. Broadberry, “Introduction: The Renaissance of African Economic
History”, Economic History Review, 67, 4, 2014, p 18.
26
Perspectives: Making historians count
would trigger more sustainable and continuous research outputs in top international
economic history journals. But this revival, as Austin and Broadberry’s introduction to
the 2014 African economic history special issue in the Economic History Review shows
in its bibliography, was predominantly led by European scholars with the exception of
the mention of Kenneth Dike, Joseph Inikori and Johan Fourie.12
Even as the revival of African economic history took off in Europe following the
fascinating work of the AEHN and its members, the conversation did not expand to
African historians at universities in sub-Saharan Africa to any significant degree until
the footprint of the AEHN expanded. I learned about it in 2011 and managed to secure
funding from its organisers when they held a conference at Lund University in 2013,
after which I have tried to attend as many of the network’s meetings as I can, including
helping to organise its forthcoming conference to be held at the University of the Free
State in 2021. However, its expansion to Africa has been by involving scholars such as
Wapumuluka Mulwafu of the University of Malawi, Ushewhedu Kufakurinani of the
University of Zimbabwe, and Johan Fourie of the University of Stellenbosch. Of these
scholars, Fourie’s background as an economist allowed him not only to contribute to
the Economic History Review’s special issue that announced the “revival of African
economic history”, but to encourage the use of quantitative methods as a new way
forward. Fourie was a central figure in the launching of the Laboratory for the
Economics of Africa’s Past (LEAP) in 2015. According to its website, LEAP “is dedicated
to the quantitative study of African economic and social history”.13 Affiliated to the
Economics Department at Stellenbosch, it consolidates scholars “interested in
understanding and explaining the long-term economic development of Africa’s diverse
societies”.14
Fourie’s call to “make historians count” is informed by this background, which
forms part of his broad intellectual project. In 2017, Fourie became president of the
Economic History Society of South Africa (EHSSA). According to the LEAP newspaper,
the “chief purpose of EHSSA is to promote economic history research at universities in
Southern Africa”.15 Its main mouthpiece is the Economic History of Developing Regions
12.
13.
14.
15.
Austin and Broadberry, “Introduction: The Renaissance of African Economic History”.
Of these African scholars, Johan Fourie is an economist by training. A look at the board
of the AEHN also shows that the majority of its members are not from, or resident on
the African continent. Of the 18 members on the board, only three are black Africans
and only three, including Johan Fourie, work at African universities. This suggests the
need for a bit more representation.
“Laboratory for the Economics of Africa’s Past”, at https://leapstellenbosch.org.za
(accessed 5 February 2021).
“Laboratory for the Economics of Africa’s Past”.
“Fourie voted EHSSA President”, The LEAP Times, 1, May 2018 at
https://leapstellenbosch.org.za/wp-content/uploads/2019/07/LEAP-Newsletter1.pdf (accessed 5 February 2021).
27
Perspectives: Making historians count
journal.16 Having secured Mellon Foundation funding of US$860 000 for five years in
2017 for LEAP’s Biography of an Uncharted People project, Fourie led “the construction
of large datasets and digital technologies for historical research”.17 This project was
hosted at Stellenbosch, where Fourie and colleagues could recruit postgraduate
students working, in part, on this project.18 As such, Fourie was well positioned not
only to advance the expansion of African economic history, but also to influence a
particular quantitative methodology of doing history. His intention was clear from as
early as 2016 when he called for the use of big data in Africa.19
But despite his consistent calls to historians to acknowledge “new” African
economic history and adopt its methodologies, few historians beyond LEAP have
adopted it across South Africa and the region. While the editors of the 2014 special
issue of the Economic History Review were confident that there would be a sustained
revival of interest in the discipline, this was not the case for quantitative economic
history across Southern Africa. This is the context in which, six years later, Fourie is
reaching out to historians to adopt quantitative methods. His is not just a call, but a
warning that if historians do not count (adopt quantitative research methods), they
will cease to count (be relevant) and therefore risk having their discipline taken over.
But do historians need to count to be counted? These are the critical questions that
Fourie has left some historians asking. Is economic history only defined by the kinds of
methodologies that Fourie is promoting? The next section engages with these issues.
Big data, the politics of knowledge production and the struggle for disciplinary
control
The question of whose interest in African economic history was revived by Hopkins’s
2009 call is crucial. It is critical to our understanding of the politics, and sometimes, the
location, of knowledge production. Hopkins correctly identified the rise of economic
history in the global north in the 1960s, its growth with the 1973 publication of his An
Economic History of West Africa, culminating around 1987 with the publication of Ralph
Austen’s work.20 Hopkins argued that with the rise of postmodernism and the cultural
turn in the 1990s, historians had then abolished the study of poverty in Africa. As a
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
See the Economic History of Developing Regions website:
http://www.ehssa.org.za/index.php/economic-history-of-developing-regions
(accessed 5 February 2021).
“Mellon Funded Project Kicks off”, The LEAP Times, 1, May 2018.
“Mellon Funded Project Kicks off”.
J. Fourie, ‘The Data Revolution in African Economic History”, Journal of Interdisciplinary
History, 47, 2, 2016, pp 193–212.
A.G. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (Longman, London, 1973). A second
edition was published recently by Routledge in 2019; R. Austen, African Economic
History: Internal Development and External Dependency (James Currey, London, 1987).
Other books published later but only viewed as standing out in a context of declining
economic history include P.T. Zeleza, A Modern Economic History of Africa, Vol 1, The
Nineteenth Century (CODESRIA, Dakar, 1993); and Feinstein, An Economic History of
South Africa.
28
Perspectives: Making historians count
result, Hopkins suggests, the new approaches to history resulted in a mix of “remote
and unhistorical” positivist economic history (that had abandoned materialism and
macro historical projects), “and cultural analysis, which was removed from cultural
considerations and, though historical in intent, was sometimes defective in its use of
historical sources”, resulting in the languishing of economic history.21 Even though
Hopkins’s assessment is not incorrect, he may not have been aware of developments
taking place in other places on the African continent.
At around the time identified by Hopkins as the high point of economic history
followed by its decline in Zimbabwe, the discipline crystallised into a stand-alone
department at the University of Zimbabwe. While it had hitherto existed as part of
broader historical studies within the History Department, there was a clique of
historians such as Joseph Mtisi, Victor Machingaidze, Alois Mlambo and others who
were behind the establishment of the discipline. Within South Africa, from 2001, the
work of the Wits History Workshop, has dealt with many economic and social history
issues, perhaps most notably associated with the late Belinda Bozzoli. Moreover,
economic historian Bill Freund had taken up the chair of Economic History at the
University of Natal in 1985.22 I mentioned earlier that Hopkins made a call for the
revival of African economic history in 2009, and rightly so. Hopkins’s 1973 text was a
classic, but there have been others since. Freund’s 1984 study, The Making of
Contemporary Africa, was among the important books that would be followed by other
studies on African economic history, for example, his own The African Worker.23 Other
scholars were also making important contributions in different parts of the continent.
Ian Phimister’s work on Hwange Colliery and the economic and social history of
Zimbabwe and Alois Mlambo’s studies on the Economic Structural Adjustment
Programme and others stand out as important publications in the late 1980s and
1990s.24 Furthermore, scholars, such as Thandika Mkandawire and Paul Tiyambe
21.
22.
23.
24.
Hopkins, “The New Economic History of Africa”, p 157.
See an obituary of Professor Freund by Robert Morrell, “Bill Freund (1944–2020):
Pioneering Economic Historian of Africa and South Africa”, Maverick Citizen, 21 August
2020, at https://www.dailymaverick.co.za/article/2020-08-21-bill-freund-19442020-pioneering-economic-historian-of-africa-and-south-africa (accessed 5 February
2021).
B. Freund, The Making of Contemporary Africa (Macmillan, London, 1984); and B.
Freund, The African Worker (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1988).
In addition to a great many journal articles by these and other scholars of African
economic history, see especially, I. Phimister, An Economic and Social History of
Zimbabwe to 1948: Capital Accumulation and Class Struggle (Longman, London, 1988);
and I. Phimister, Coal, Capital and Labour in Colonial Zimbabwe, 1894–1954 (Wits
University Press, Johannesburg, 1994). See also A. Mlambo, The Economic Structural
Adjustment Programme: The Case of Zimbabwe (University of Zimbabwe Press, Harare,
2000); and A. Mlambo, I. Phimister and E. Pangeti, Zimbabwe: A History of
Manufacturing, 1890–1995 (University of Zimbabwe Press, Harare, 2000). Also P. Bond,
Uneven Zimbabwe: A Study of Finance, Development and Underdevelopment (Africa
World Press, Trenton, 1988), among others.
29
Perspectives: Making historians count
Zeleza, both from Malawi, were leading figures in the discipline.25 There are numerous
examples of work produced between the 1980s and the 2000s on the economic history
of Africa that could be mentioned here. And yet the narrative that has been presented
by Fourie is that African economic history went into decline until the call for its revival
in the 2000s. Thus, the critical question is: why, despite all this work produced, is this
his claim?
History, and economic history in particular, was quite healthy in certain parts
of the continent and certainly in no danger of being annexed. If anything, the 1980s and
1990s were the golden age of African economic history at some South African and
Zimbabwean universities as evident in the work of many African scholars published in
history journals in this period. The work of leading scholars throughout the 1980s and
1990s attests to this, and perhaps this is something Fourie could have considered. The
issue of the revival of African economic history, more specifically, must be properly
contextualised based on where the call was made in 2009. To some degree, this speaks
to the issue of the politics of knowledge production. When Hopkins made the call for
the revival of the discipline, he was correct to do so. But I think it important to identify
that the discipline had declined within the context of Europe (my emphasis). Yet, the
work being done in Africa was nowhere near as visible as it ought to have been in the
USA and Europe. The call for the “revival” of African economic history amongst scholars
in Europe resulted in a conversation that finally drew in African students and some
scholars at AEHN meetings, where the disconnect was confronted. Nowhere was this
clearer than when it led to the publication of a debate about the state of African
economic history in the continent. This is the subject of the following section.
History, methodology and debates about what African economic history is and
should be
The special issue of the Economic History Review appeared in 2014, around the time
that debates on “reviving” economic history emerged. Among the most important
journals leading this revival on the continent was the Economic History of Developing
Regions, housed at Stellenbosch University. But one look at the editorial board reveals
the extent to which there is more global North influence than there is African
representation. Moreover, the number of articles published by African scholars, not
least those based at African universities in the last ten years, is miniscule.26 By their
own admission, the representation of African authors in European and American
economic history journals is very limited. Fourie and Leigh Gardner heeded the call for
the revival of interest in the discipline and they were puzzled by the limited
25.
26.
T. Mkandawire and C.C. Soludo, Our Continent, Our Future: African Perspectives on
Structural Adjustment (Africa World Press, Dakar, 1998); and P.T. Zeleza, A Modern
Economic History of Africa, Volume 1: The Nineteenth Century (Codesria Book Series,
Dakar, 1993).
To Fourie’s credit, the use of numbers could have been illustrative here as part of the
methodology. I left out the figures deliberately, to demonstrate that while they are
sometimes important, qualitative texts can also be an important consideration in
telling a story.
30
Perspectives: Making historians count
contributions from African scholars to mainstream economic history journals.27 But
Fourie and Gardner attracted the interest and response of Erik Green and Pius
Nyambara, who challenged the notion that interest in the history of African economies
had declined in the 1980s and 1990s.28
Green and Nyambara’s argument was straightforward. They argued that far
from declining, African economic history had actually flourished in the 1980s, 1990s
and 2000s. What was viewed as a puzzle could simply be explained by methodological
differences between what Fourie saw as African economic history, and the practice at
African universities. This also influenced the outlets in which African scholars
published. Many of the studies on the African economic past had been informed by
qualitative methodological approaches, using material found in archives, and
interviews, among other sources. As a result, they tended to be published in History
journals rather than those devoted solely to economic history. Some of the studies
published by US and western European-based scholars tended to be based on
quantitative methodologies. Studies based on qualitative methodologies submitted by
African scholars tended to be rejected for not conforming closely enough to the
standards of economic history practice, because they were not based on robust,
rigorous, big quantitative data sets and methodologies. For example, I submitted an
article to a local South African economic history journal and it was rejected on these
grounds – only to be accepted immediately in a history journal.29 At the heart of the
debate on what constitutes economic history is methodology and the question of what
informs it. Are “counting” and the use of statistical methods the sole determinants of
what defines the discipline? Could Fourie have weighed other considerations? What is
clear though, is that the big data techniques Fourie views as novel may well be new in
terms of some developments, but quantitative versus qualitative methodologies have
always been central to debates over what constitutes economic history.30
From the Annales School from the 1930s to the cliometrics of the 1970s, the call
for historians to count is only the latest manifestation of debates by economic-minded
scholars to influence history methodologies. In fact, Hopkins’s 2009 call for the revival
of economic history was, in part, a critique of the new institutional economists’ use of
quantitative methods, which he viewed as “flattening” history.31 One of the founding
members of the AEHN, Gareth Austin, was equally concerned, although a little more
accepting of the possibilities that could arise from using both qualitative and
quantitative methods. But both Austin and Stephen Broadberry were clear about the
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
J. Fourie and L. Gardner, “The Internationalisation of Economic History: A Puzzle”,
Economic History of Developing Regions, 29, 1, 2014, pp 1–14.
E. Green and P. Nyambara, “The Internationalisation of Economic History: Perspectives
from the African Frontier”, Economic History of Developing Regions, 29, 1, 2014, pp 68–
78.
See T. Nyamunda, ‘The State and Black Development: The Small Enterprises
Development Corporation and the Politics of Indigenization and Economic
Empowerment in Zimbabwe”, Historia, 61, 1, 2016, pp 41–65.
See, for example, Fourie, “The Data Revolution in African Economic History”.
Hopkins, “The New Economic History of Africa”.
31
Perspectives: Making historians count
renaissance of the discipline: although there was renewed interest amongst European
historians of African economic history, this interest simply reflected the new frontiers
in a discipline that had long thrived, despite the slump of the previous two or so
decades.32 Indeed, in the 1960s and 1970s, for example, both quantitative and
theoretical debates had raged on the contours of the discipline.
Among the most prominent of these debates were those between Giovanni
Arrighi and William J. Barber on the question of the development of central African
economies.33 Within South Africa, some of these debates had been informed by writing
in the liberal school and the rise of social history in the 1970s. Freund captured these
debates well in his contribution to Vishnu Padayachee’s edited book, The Political
Economy of Africa, particularly noting the Marxist challenges to neo-classical
mainstream economics.34 In the case of central Africa, Barber adopted a model from W.
Arthur Lewis’s 1954 study on economic development with unlimited labour supplies.35
The model was to some degree suited to a European context. Lewis suggested that
economic development takes place under certain conditions. In a context where a
developing urban industrial economy is growing, labour moves voluntarily from a
traditional, less developed sector to the capitalist sector, thus triggering development
until a level of full employment has been attained. Barber applied the same model in
the context of Southern and Northern Rhodesia and Nyasaland, and suggested that the
same would apply, with labour moving from the traditional or “primitive” African
sector to the European capitalist sector, triggering colonial development until a level
of full employment and economic development had been attained. Such was the
influence of neo-classical mainstream economics. The theories and arguments were
buttressed by numbers, tables and other econometric tools.
Arrighi challenged and convincingly dismissed the suggestion of a two-sector
model in which there was a traditional and more developed capitalist sector, and
secondly, the suggestion that labour moved “voluntarily” from a “primitive” region of
“low productivity” to that of “high productivity” in the European sector. He argued that
theories which were applied without context, even if they were accompanied by robust
numbers, were misleading. In his rebuttal, he historicised the labour supply in
Southern Rhodesia. His study found that prior to the colonisation of Southern Rhodesia
by the British, Africans were highly productive and engaged in a degree of gainful trade.
Even after the arrival of settler Europeans, commercial activity by Africans became a
vent for surplus as they became a market for agricultural and other products. But for
32.
33.
34.
35.
See, for example, Austin and Broadberry, “Introduction: The Renaissance of African
Economic History”.
W.J. Barber, The Economy of British Central Africa: A Case Study of Economic
Development in a Dualistic Society (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1961); G. Arrighi,
“Labour Supplies in a Historical Perspective: A Study of the Proletarianization of the
African Peasantry in Rhodesia”, Journal of Development Studies, 6, 3, 1970, pp 197–234.
B. Freund, ‘The Social Context of African Economics Growth, 1960–2008”, in V.
Padayachee (ed.), The Political Economy of Africa (Routledge, London, 2010) pp 39–59.
W.A. Lewis, “Economic Development with Unlimited Labour Supplies”, The Manchester
School, 22, 2, 1954, pp 139–191.
32
Perspectives: Making historians count
Europeans to subdue Africans and subject them to the labour requirements of a
colonial state, meant that the productive and competitive Africans had to lose their
means of production. Arrighi’s findings were extended by Charles Van Onselen’s 1976
study, Chibaro.36 He showed that because of a shortage of labour, the colonial state
engaged in forced labour, and ultimately imposed monetised taxes to obligate Africans
to work for European enterprises, instead of for themselves. When these measures
failed and Africans remained productive and in continued competition with white
colonial enterprises, the state ultimately took away the Africans’ means of production
through the Land Apportionment Act (1930), which reallocated the majority of the
productive land to white settlers while Africans were displaced to overcrowded,
infertile reserves.
The same observations were made in the case of South Africa. Scholars such as
Ben Magubane traced the historical dynamics of race and class that resulted in white
settlers getting the balance of the land and other economic resources, with Africans
being pushed to the reserves and ultimately the so-called “homelands” or Bantustans.37
As Sol Plaatje’s work demonstrated, the Native Land Act (1913) had a devastating
impact on African livelihoods and heritage.38 The colonial state ensured that Africans
were subject to colonial and repressive apartheid laws. The bigger point is that labour
supplies to the so-called capitalist sector were manufactured by various colonial laws
and state acts.
The suggestion of what is modern has also been contested, as has the notion of
what is capitalist, when placed under historical scrutiny. Donald Denoon suggested
that what we have seen in countries such as the Rhodesias and colonial and apartheid
South Africa is not liberal capitalism based on free enterprise, but actually settler
capitalism based on racial segregation and repressive measures that subjected
unwilling Africans to violent colonial rule which they had to challenge through various
liberation struggles.39
Importantly, to be effective, the use of numbers, regression analysis and
statistical tools should also be specific and contextual. Quantitative historical analysis,
especially by economists, has been used to create economic indicators to measure
development, for example the Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and statistics to measure
poverty, as well as other sets of tools to manage economies such as the National Income
Accounting (NIA) system. In a 2011 article, Daniel Speich argued that these were global
abstractions which were not well suited to directing development.40 Such approaches
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
C. van Onselen, Chibaro: African Mine Labour in Southern Rhodesia, 1900–1933 (Pluto
Press, London, 1976).
B. Magubane, The Political Economy of Race and Class in South Africa (Monthly Review
Press, London, 1979).
S. Plaatje, Native Life in South Africa (Wits University Press, Johannesburg, 1916).
D. Denoon, Settler Capitalism: The Dynamics of Dependent Development in the Southern
Hemisphere (Oxford University Press, New York, 1983).
D. Speich, “The Use of Global Abstractions: National Income Accounting in the Period
of Imperial Decline”, Journal of Global History, 6, 1, 2011, pp 7–28.
33
Perspectives: Making historians count
were downright dangerous when applied to policymaking, as Alden Young found in the
case of Sudan.41 He shows that the pursuit of positive GDP and other indices is highly
problematic. Following its independence in 1956, Sudan found itself having to pursue
high modernist projects such as the Gezira Scheme, amongst others, in a bid to expand
cotton production for export and thus increase its US dollar earnings. Its economic
experts were so concerned about increasing the production of exports that they forgot
to consider several factors, one of which was the development of other options such as
synthetic fibres, which reduced the price and demand of cotton globally. Yet the
country had already borrowed a great deal of money to support this monoculture
economy, landing it into serious debt that it could not settle and plunging the country
into economic crisis.42 In that context, the econometric tools that economics experts
applied were highly problematic, no matter how robust they assumed their numbers
were or what their models predicted.43 Their numbers would have been more useful if
they had considered the skills of other disciplines that emphasise agency, and other
relevant issues.
The statement by Stanley Trapido that Fourie quotes is useful to buttress the
point I am making. Analysing society both historically and in “its present structure”
requires a mix of satisfactory methods and good evidence. This is true. However, where
Fourie and I disagree is on our interpretation of what Trapido meant, both by good
evidence and satisfactory methods. For Fourie, historians will “count” (remain
relevant), only if they are made to “count” (use numbers and other statistical methods).
He may not be incorrect in advocating the greater adoption and incorporation of
“numbers” in historical research. But I argue that Trapido would have disagreed with
Fourie’s contention that this would make historians “count”.
History is much more than just numbers. If anything, if used incorrectly and in
isolation, numbers can lead to ahistorical studies, as Hopkins’s critical analysis of the
work of new institutional scholars revealed in his well-received call to revive interest
in African economic history. In fact, his warning to historians was that if they did not
take control of the discipline and engage in debates about optimal methodologies
informing their studies, the “flattened” work such as that of Acemoglu, Johnson and
Robinson would become the mainstream idea of what African economic history is.44 In
many ways, Fourie’s call to study history by numbers mimics such approaches. At the
heart of my argument is the question of what history is, as opposed to what Fourie
suggests it should be. Inasmuch as numbers are important, qualitative evidence from
archives, interviews, and other sources, and the various methods that historians are
41.
42.
43.
44.
A. Young, Transforming Sudan: Decolonization, Economic Development and State
Formation (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2019).
A. Young, “African Bureaucrats and the Exhaustion of the Developmental State: Lessons
from the Pages of the Sudanese Economist”, Humanity, 8, 1, 2017, pp 49–75.
For a more comprehensive critique, see X. Lu and H. White, “Robustness Checks and
Robustness Tests in Applied Economics”, Journal of Econometrics, 178, 1, 2014, pp 194–
206.
See Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development”.
34
Perspectives: Making historians count
trained to adopt, ensure that history continues to be the main subject that guides
research and teaching and learning in the humanities.
Conclusion: Is the crisis in History/economic history or Economics?
Johan Fourie’s call to make historians count is problematic in several ways. The reasons
for this are: firstly, his assumption that historians are unaware of this necessity, and
secondly, that History is in danger of being taken over if it does not adapt. By its very
nature, History is eclectic. To historians, this is the most obvious characteristic of the
discipline! We have, for instance, all sorts of sub-disciplines. Fourie has been involved
in economic history, to which his call may to some degree be most relevant. But there
is also political history, social history, environmental history, gender history, the
history of emotions, medical history – the list could go on.
By their very nature, these forms of history utilise all sorts of methods to inform
their studies, but not all of them need numbers at their core for them to be counted.
This point is particularly important, given that Fourie’s call appears to be aimed at all
historians, not just those in economic history, of which he is a part. Another important
aspect to consider is that some specialties also cross fields, for example, historical
sociology or anthropology, or even political and economic history.
There is also no question that academic history faces a perennial funding
challenge. It appears that to this extent, economics may be more privileged compared
to the discipline of History. To his credit, Fourie’s LEAP has enjoyed support from
generous funders and many international partnerships.45 Elsewhere on the continent,
Leonard Wantchekon has established a mainstream economics-based university in
Benin with the support of Princeton University and other international partners.46
Catering for students from West Africa, the African School of Economics also has as one
of its main programmes, quantitative economic history.47 Unlike academic history,
economic studies are very well funded. What makes the programmes so attractive is
that the graduates sometimes land lucrative positions as experts in the World Bank and
other multi-lateral and development and policy advising institutions. While the lack of
such funding for history constitutes a crisis of sorts, I am not sure it would be in the
way Fourie suggests. For a long time, History has not been considered an important
subject in primary and secondary schools as the science, technology, engineering, and
Mathematics (STEM) subjects. But following the 2008 xenophobic attacks in South
45.
46.
47.
See the LEAP website for more information. This is an excellent academic initiative that
Fourie must be celebrated for. Whatever academic perspectives one may have of the
programme, Fourie has used its success to fund and support many young academics
who have gone on to have successful academic careers across the world. See
“Laboratory for the Economics of Africa’s Past”, at https://leapstellenbosch.org.za
For the story of Professor Leonard Wantchekon, see I. Dieng, “Ground Breaker”, IMF
Finance & Development, 53, 2, 2016 at https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/
2016/12/people.htm (accessed 5 February 2021).
See the website of the African School of Economics, 2021, at
https://africanschoolofeconomics.com (accessed 5 February 2021).
35
Perspectives: Making historians count
Africa, the Department of Basic Education formed the History Ministerial Task Team to
oversee the compulsory inclusion of History in the Further Education and Training
phase and strengthen the History content in the General Education and Training band.
Notwithstanding any limitations of the programme, the importance of History to
identity, nation-building, and critical citizenship, among other considerations, is not in
doubt.48 To this extent, at least – and there are other important contexts worth
exploring – History will always count. I suppose the question at this stage is why
economists feel that History does not count and is in danger of being annexed.
With the global crash of 2008, the discipline of Economics came under attack
for failing to anticipate the recession.49 After all, econometrics techniques are designed
to forecast just this, whereas historians are generally sensitive to the reality that
history never moves in a straight line, and would usually shy away from making
predictions. But following the crash, economists once again recognised the importance
of history, recalling the 1930s global recession, for example. Many took up economic
history, but not being fully conversant in its methods and discourses, applied neoclassical methods to its study. For many economists, whose studies tend to be based on
temporal phenomena, it seemed novel. The call for historians to count appears to have
emerged from this background.
Moreover, even as there have been calls to decolonise humanities curricula
across the world, there have been more specific calls to rethink economics. Indeed,
organisations such as Rethinking Economics (which also has a South African chapter
based at Wits University and a Zimbabwean chapter based at the University of
Zimbabwe) have become influential globally.50 Other organisations, such as the
Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET), have funded actions such as the Young
Scholars Initiative and made contributions from its Africa working group.51 Instead of
calling on other disciplines to adopt their methodologies, they have instead embraced
the wisdom they can learn from other disciplines.
So, the call from Fourie, for me, appears to be based less on the need for History
to count than the question of relevance in the discipline of economics, which finds itself,
in many ways and despite access to national and international support and funding, in
a crisis of identity. Historians have always been relevant and History will continue to
count, where it counts.
◆ ◆ ◆
48.
49.
50.
51.
M. Noor Davids, “‘Making History Compulsory’: Politically Inspired or Pedagogically
Justifiable?”, Yesterday and Today, 15, 2016, pp 84–102.
G. De Martino, “The Economic Crisis and the Crisis in Economics”, in M.A. Starr (ed.),
Consequences of Economic Downturns (Palgrave Macmillan, New York, 2011), pp 25-54.
See their website: Rethinking Economics, at https://www.rethinkeconomics.org
(accessed 5 February 2021).
See their website: Institute for New Economic Thinking, at
https://www.ineteconomics.org (accessed 5 February 2021).
36
Perspectives: Making historians count
Count me in
Johan Fourie
My plea submitted to Historia in mid-2019 already looks like preaching to the
converted. Later that year, several projects using digital humanities methods were
funded by the Mellon Foundation. In 2020, Mellon also supported several digitisation
projects: the Adler Museum Bulletin by Wits, the Hansards by UJ, indigenous African
sheet music by UP, and the South African black press by CPUT, to name but a few.
Historians are finding that the digitisation of African materials makes it easier for
students to engage with primary source documentation and do original research.52
This push towards digitisation is exciting news. As the Covid-19 lockdown showed us,
digitisation is not a luxury but a necessity, for both teaching and research. But we need
to look beyond the obvious sources for digitisation. We may find new questions (and
new answers) in unconventional sources formerly of little interest to historians.
I want to thank the commentators for their thoughtful reflections. Yes, not
everything that counts can be counted, and vice versa. Yes, counting used to be the
economic historian’s province. But today more of what was previously uncountable can
be counted. In my own recent work, counting has illuminated such diverse topics as
military technology, slaves’ names and voter disenfranchisement.53 The possibilities
are endless. The work of an itinerant merchant is never done. There will be new towns
to visit and new wares to acquire in the bustling future entrepôt of South African
history.
◆ ◆ ◆
52.
53.
J.E. Kelly and O. Badsha, “Teaching South African History in the Digital Age:
Collaboration, Pedagogy, and Popularizing History”, History in Africa, 47, 2020, p 297.
J. Fourie, K. Inwood, and M. Mariotti, "Military Technology and Sample Selection Bias",
Social Science History, 44, 3, 2020, pp 485–500; K. Ekama, J. Fourie, H. Heese and L-C.
Martin, “When Cape Slavery Ended: Introducing a New Slave Emancipation Dataset",
Explorations in Economic History, 2021, 101390; F. Nyika and J. Fourie, "Black
Disenfranchisement in the Cape Colony, c. 1887–1909: Challenging the Numbers",
Journal of Southern African Studies, 46, 3, 2020, pp 455–469.
37
Perspectives: Making historians count
CONTRIBUTORS
Faeeza Ballim is a senior lecturer in History at the University of Johannesburg. With
an MSc from the University of Oxford and PhD from the University of the
Witwatersrand. Faeeza’s research focuses on science and technology studies, economic
history, state corporations, manufacturing, and farming in South Africa.
Johan Fourie is a professor of Economics at Stellenbosch University and the
coordinator of Biography of an Uncharted People (a project of the Laboratory for the
Economics of Africa’s Past). Johan gained his PhD from Utrecht University and
researches in the areas of Digital Humanities and South Africa’s economic history.
Gerald Groenewald is an associate professor of History at the University of
Johannesburg. In addition to other areas of research, his work centres on the society of
the Cape Colony in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, in the contexts of the
Indian Ocean world of the Dutch East India Company and Western Europe.
Tinashe Nyamunda is a historian of twentieth and twenty-first century financial and
economic history of southern Africa. Having worked at North-West University until
early 2021, he then joined, as associate professor, the Department of Historical and
Heritage Studies at the University of Pretoria.
Jennifer Upton has an MA from the University of Warwick and a PhD from the
University of Cambridge. She is interested in the connections between historiography,
life writing and literature. With Catherine Burns and Janet Giddy, Jennifer is co-writing
a book on McCord Hospital and its response to the HIV crisis.
38