Original Article
Towards an ecology of care:
Basic Income after the nation-state
SOCIETY REGISTER
2022 / 6(3): 29–56
ISSN: 2544–5502
DOI: 10.14746/sr.2022.6.3.03
Julio Linares1& Gabriela Cabaña2
Basic Income Earth Network (BIEN), 286 Ivydale Road, London SE15 3DF, London, UK. ORCID:
0000-0003-0330-0001 Email:
[email protected]
2
London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, WC2A 2AE, London, UK. ORCID:
0000-0002-1661-6892, Email:
[email protected]
1
ABSTRACT: The following paper is about care1. It proposes a political vision to move
towards a care-centred society that will allow the flourishing of everyone while keeping the planet inhabitable and thriving. For this utopian horizon that we name an
ecology of care, we propose the creation of a Basic Income system that is constituted
outside of and beyond the realm of the nation-state, as a means of changing humanity’s relationship to itself and transitioning from capitalism to a commons-based society. It argues for a dis-embedding of work—and the time allocated to it—from money,
through a reformulation of the production of money in the form of an income distributed as an equal share to all those who are part of the planetary commons. Finally, it
connects this Basic Income proposal with degrowth as a radical and necessary reformulation of society that considers its ecological roots and replaces the obsession with
endless economic growth with the principle of taking care of people.
KEYWORDS: basic income, pluriverse, care, commons, debt
I. INTRODUCTION
T
his essay is about care. It proposes a political vision to move towards a care-centred society that will allow the flourishing of everyone while keeping the planet
inhabitable and thriving. For this utopian horizon that we name an ecology of care,
we propose the creation of a Basic Income system that is constituted outside of and
beyond the realm of the nation-state, as a means of changing humanity’s relationship
to itself and transitioning from capitalism to a commons-based society. It argues for
a dis-embedding of work—and the time allocated to it—from money, through a refor-
This essay was prepared for a keynote lecture given by the authors in August 2019 at the 19th World
Basic Income Congress held in Hyderabad, India.
1
30
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
mulation of the production of money in the form of an income distributed as an equal
share to all those who are part of the planetary commons. Finally, it connects this Basic Income proposal with degrowth as a radical and necessary reformulation of society
that considers its ecological roots and replaces the obsession with endless economic
growth with the principle of taking care of people.
This paper argues that if we are to fundamentally revert the crisis of today and create this ecology, there are three simultaneous transformations to start:
(1). Money Commons: which means the re-appropriation of the money system
outside the realm of the state and banks and into the commons, where value is
created and wealth is defined, reproduced, shared and maintained by all those
who participate in the reproduction of the commons, beyond the borders of nation-states.
(2). Degrowth: in order to encourage self-reliance for all within planetary
boundaries, a money system which is alive and hence decays when it is not used
is proposed as the basis for the creation of a different type of money, made itself
with a different set of values. Creating ecologies of money means bringing diversity to the monetary ecosystem as a way of healing the harm done by today’s
money monoculture, where money is created as a form of a debt with an interest
on people’s time by private banks and states. Making money alive aims at creating money within and for the commons to have the life needed for them to
achieve a viable economic alternative.
(3). Pluriversal Basic Income: recentering our awareness on care as the source
of the value in work—which decouples labor from income or wage slavery from
people’s time—can be achieved through the distribution of a Basic Income given
to people unconditionally, just because they exist. This formulation of a Basic
Income offers a different epistemic base from nation-state proposals, and it can
be a tool for the emergence of new political projects and social forms. Politically,
the pluriverse is a weaving together of different forms of knowing, imaginations
and practices of freedom organized democratically as a confederation in order to
transcend the nation-state.
The ecology of care rests on an argument that the establishment of a free society is
underpinned by a flourishing of relationships that foster care and that these practices
of caring are means to the creation, expansion and maintenance of the material and
immaterial elements of the commons. These three prospects—Money Commons, Degrowth and Pluriversal Basic Income—are therefore to be seen as implying each other
and as a whole, each forming a leg for a table which cannot do without one of its three
pillars.
II. RECOVERING CARE AS A PRECONDITION FOR FREEDOM
Bringing care to the core of our thinking requires a deep questioning of the way in
which the discipline of economics has built its object (‘the economy’). Most of the
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
31
sub-schools in the field of economics tend to treat the work of care—by some conceptualised as social reproduction—as invisible, making it a valueless and unaccounted
form of labour. This labour is treated as pre-economical and is therefore not measured
in metrics like GDP. Today, this care or reproductive labor is socially assigned predominantly to women. It is made invisible through a hierarchy of value which dualistically
divides between some forms of labor as material (and hence productive) and others
as immaterial (and hence communicative or ‘feminine’) (Yanagisako, 2012; Bear, Ho,
Tsing, & Yanagisako, 2015).
This is not a casual theoretical mistake. The invisibilization of reproductive work
completely decenters the processes that make human life possible by putting them
outside the sphere of what is considered as part of the economy. But in fact, what we
call production is only a secondary moment in the process of social reproduction or
the production of people (Graeber, 2013). Any economy is fundamentally a human
economy, and it is only by invisibilizing things like reproductive work that capitalism
can justify its costs of production and pretend that the economy is about things and
not social relations (Hart & Laville, 2010; Federici, 2014).
In reality, the freedom of the proletariat to sell his labor is only possible because of
the unfreedom of the housewife which subsidizes their reproduction for eventual capitalist exploitation (Mies, 1998). As some note, the level of freedom in a society can be
measured by the level of freedom that women have (Öcalan, 2015). Hence, without the
systemic liberation of women and all others who perform the basis upon which life is
built, and therefore the reproduction and defense of the commons, society as a whole
cannot be liberated. The exploitation of those mainly dedicated to care is the material
counterpart of the theoretical overlooking of this form of labour.
It is through fostering and encouraging the recognition of care work as a source of
value in work that another world can be built: a care centered economy (Praetorious,
2015). This implies a shift from valuing the end point of things, as done under capitalism, to a valuing of the processes that make life possible to begin with.
An economy based on care, or the care economy, is a response to capitalist and patriarchal systems of domination. The care economy tries to recenter the value of care
labor (as these reproductive activities have come to be known) at the center of the human economy, or rather, an ecology for human relations that is strengthened through
their interdependence. Thus, the reproduction of human processes is the first step and
precondition for the production of what is known under capitalism as the production
of ‘goods and services’.
Underpinning this economy is an ethics of care, a moral system which recognizes the interdependence amongst humans and their capacity to autonomously decide
which relations they wish to enter, change or exit. Most importantly, it is based on the
universal experience of being cared for and the giving of care. At its core, an ethics of
care is about ‘attending to and meeting the needs of the particular others for whom we
take responsibility’ (Held, 2006).
With this in mind, we can think of the ecology of care as the soil that nourishes human relationships directed at mutually making each other free through an acknowledgement of our interdependence and the care that goes into making us who we are.
32
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
Care is therefore a precondition for free relationships to be established. As argued
below, this type of morality and system of value is embedded within a reformulation
of how money is created; shifting to a system which provides every human being with
an amount of money necessary to live in harmony with nature and within planetary
boundaries.
III. MONEY, BASIC INCOME AND THE CRITIQUE OF CAPITAL: BUT WHERE
WILL THE MONEY COME FROM?
Money is a new form of slavery, and distinguishable from the old simply by the
fact that it is impersonal—that there is no human relation between master and
slave.
Leo Tolstoy
The circuit of capital, identified by Marx’s formula M-C-M’ denotes the fact that, under the capitalist mode of production, money begets more money through the exchange of commodities (Marx, 1982b [1894]). These are produced through a mixture
of humanity’s labor power and nature i.e. the means of production, all mediated by the
circulation of value in the form of money, given as an interest-bearing debt.
Monetary creation under capitalist conditions is the ignitor and precondition for
economic growth. This is mainly because money is today lent out with an interest,
meaning that more money has to be repaid than what was given, which translates to
more resource extraction. This is the mechanism that fuels the expansion of future
production with the sole goal of profit maximization. The endless expansion of economic growth using this type of money creation leads inevitably to ecological disaster,
as enclosures on land and people’s labor power become the means of money’s infinite
reproduction, making wealth inevitably accumulate at the top 1%, as recent studies
have demonstrated (Piketty, 2013).
This happens through the issuance of interest-bearing debt, which makes money
scarce and hence competitive for people to obtain, tying humanity’s fate with an expansive spiral of destructive growth. Some economists have empirically demonstrated
that monetary interest rates set by central banks follow and are positively correlated
with GDP growth. Bank credit creation not only mobilizes future production but is
the basis for economic growth (Werner, 2016; Werner & Lee, 2018). As evidence is increasingly showing, we cannot have infinite growth in a finite planet (Meadows, 1972;
Hickel & Kallis, 2019).
More recently, feminist autonomous Marxist intellectuals like Silvia Federici, among
many others, have traced the historical changes in the circuit of social reproduction
and its relationship to the circuit of capital, namely women’s historical central function in the process of primitive accumulation as the producers and reproducers of the
most essential capitalist commodity: human labor power (Dalla Costa & James, 1975;
Federici, 2014; Praetorious, 2015). The enclosure of the commons and of women’s
bodies was the pre-condition for the rise of capitalism. As historian Peter Linebaugh
puts it: “reproduction precedes social production. Touch the women, touch the rock”
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
33
(Linebaugh, 2008).
Our ecology of care draws on and is inspired by already existing political efforts to
overcome the state/capitalist system. The rebuilding of the commons as a viable political project has been defined and practiced dispersedly around the world. This essay is
an attempt to deepen the imagination of the economic self-reliance of the commons.
As Federici herself notes, talking about the recent appropriation of the commons discourse by hegemonic forces:
While international institutions have learned to make commons functional to
the market, how commons can become the foundation of a non-capitalist economy is a question still unanswered. (Federici, 2011)
The idea of Basic Income, without having been implemented fully anywhere, has
stimulated already stirred the political imagination of a wide political spectrum (Standing, 2017). In this essay, more than engaging in creative solutions of how we could
redistribute diverse funds for a Basic Income, we propose instead to unpack current
understandings of the monetary system and its underpinning institutions to formulate politically relevant questions about the nature of the system itself. Understanding
(1) what money is and (2) how to transform our current monetary institutions for the
horizon of political emancipation are the purpose of the following sections.
MONEY IS DEBT
From the archeological record, we know that money historically emerges in human
civilization from our social relationships of debt. Underpinned by violence and mathematics, the creation of credit has been employed throughout history as a mechanism
of enslaving human beings, from ancient Sumeria to today’s International Monetary
Fund and World Bank (Hudson, 2004).
The history of debt is a history of patriarchy, defined here broadly as the rule of
fathers. The long structures which underpin this logic of domination, the long durée
of money, have remained roughly the same for the past 5000 years, going through
different oscillations2. Traditionally, kings and bureaucrat priests who had power over
the hegemonic ideology would pair up with armies in order to enslave people into becoming their subjects through debt (Graeber, 2011; Öcalan, 2015). This 5000 year old
pattern has been reproduced to today’s Federal Reserve and Wall Street, underpinned
by the violence of the US army.
This phenomena could be described as the Military-Coinage-Slavery complex;
whereby a king would hire an army in order to subject people to his command, enslave
them and make them work in order to pay the wages of soldiers in newly issued money (Graeber, 2011, p. 229; Ingham, 2004, p. 99). This complex continues to exist until
today, with elite groups in private banks having the privilege over monetary creation,
Anthropology has countless examples of what some call ‘social currencies’, which are aimed at rearranging social relations as a means rather than the mere movement of commodities for the sake of the
capital accumulation as an end in itself. Just as markets are not the same thing as capitalism, money
does not necessarily imply capitalism and can thus be transformed.
2
34
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
making everybody else indebted and enforcing payment through state violence. Banks
are thus the temples of today, where the debts of the many get accumulated by the
few. But what is money?
Economic textbooks define money as a neutral thing: a means of exchange, a store
of value and a unit of account. This formulation assumes that money, to exist as such,
has to achieve all of those three characteristics, with people often arguing about each
of these as what makes money ‘really’ money to begin with. In reality, these are the
functions of money, what it does, not what money is (Lietaer & Dunne, 2013).
Money is a set of promises we make to one another (Graeber, 2001). As a mutual
promise between people, money is not just one thing but is fundamentally a social
convention or an agreement, a semantic system akin to language, underpinned by the
trust people give to it (Aristotle, 1954; Polanyi, 1977, pp. 97-119).
This acknowledgement of money as a mutual promise is based on an arrangement
that recognizes our interdependence to other people, which is constantly renewed
and revised. It is a recovery of money fundamentally as a social process before a commodity-like thing (Simmel, 2004; Dodd, 2014). Money is a social relation of debt and
credit between people, a process and a thing at the same time which guides the whole
of what we call ‘the economy’ (Hart, 1986)3.
But the way that money works today follows a logic that goes against the natural
yield of ecosystems to reproduce themselves. This is because money can infinitely
make more money through arbitrary positive interests in bank deposits, which necessarily implies some form of material resource extraction somewhere down the line.
But there is nothing natural about interest rates (Gesell, 2007)4. Those who possess
money and reproduce these cycles of accumulation often take the ability of those with
none of it to reproduce their livelihood; through the repayment of debts, wage-slavery, rent and interest rates, money’s relationship to human beings has been, for the
most part of the last 5000 years history, one of domination and exploitation.
Modern money is produced in the form of debt by private and central banks, which
often do not use it to mobilize production but to speculate in financial markets. Today,
97% of all the money supply in most countries is produced in the form of bank deposits issued by private banks. The remaining 3% is produced by states in the form of cash
(Mcleay et al., 2014). These institutions both produce money out of thin air, by merely
typing a number on a computer screen5.
Money as a commodity is how most people and schools of thought, including orthodox Marxists,
defined it up until now. The aversion towards money is prescient in most leftist circles as it is equated
with capitalism and slavery and hence is seen as something rotten which should be abolished. Against
this, we follow the view that money is always utopic (Dodd, 2014) and we should therefore appropriate
monetary institutions within the realm of the commons, making it multiple, a plurality. For the commonification of money, see the next section.
4
In fact, interest rates have shifted according to various religious and philosophical traditions, from the
famous Saint Ambrosio exception in the Middle Ages which stated that a Christian cannot charge an
interest on another person’s time, to Calvin and Luther who argued that, in fact, you can. See Graeber
(2011) for a detailed analysis of this history.
5
The latin word fiat is used today to denote the type of money made by nation-states: fiat money. The
term can be found in Genesis i.3—“let there be light” or fiat lux—denoting the making of something out
3
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
35
There is no fortuity in this. The so-called divine power once used by temples and
priests to create something out of nothing today rests in the hands of private bankers,
who issue money as debt, and ultimately with nation-states, whose sovereignty guarantees that they can perpetually issue money without having to pay it back, as Modern
Monetary Theory (MMT) proponents have argued, synthesizing both state and credit
theories of money (Mitchell-Innes, 1914; Knapp, 1924).
Ultimately, to understand money we need to understand debt. In German, schuld
is the word for both debt and guilt6. This ‘demonic ambiguity’ as Walter Benjamin
called it, is why money has such a powerful effect on human beings (Benjamin, 1996).
According to Benjamin, it is the internalized morality of guilt in human civilization
which underpins the current agreement of how money works, from the origins of patriarchy to early Christianity, to the Protestant work ethic, to today’s ‘post’ modern
world. This guilt over money is ultimately what reproduces the moral economy of debt
which capitalism is based upon. How do we start to change this?
IV. THE FIRST LEG: MONEY COMMONS
In this section, we rely mostly on Massimo De Angelis’ study of the commons as social
systems. In his approach, De Angelis analyzes the processes and complex dynamics
that go into the creation and reproduction of different commons and the different
values and practices embedded within such processes (De Angelis, 2007).
In Omnia Sunt Communia De Angelis draws out the circuit of social reproduction as
a moment in a set of moments that reproduce the commons and its relationship to the
circuit of capitalism (De Angelis, 2017). The relationships between the different moments in the reproduction and capitalist (production) circuits are outlined as follows:
Figure 1: Coupling Between Production and Reproduction Circuits
Source: adapted from De Angelis (2017, pp. 189)
of nothing.
6
For an archeological study of the biblical usages of sin and debt and the jubilee year, see Hudson
(2018).
36
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
In the reproduction circuit drawn in Figure 1, the money (M) obtained in exchange
for labor power (LP) is used to buy commodities (C). These commodities are then processed in the household through an expenditure of reproductive labor (RP), which
allows for the physical and psychological reproduction of regenerated labor power
(LP*), which is then sold to capitalists in order to make more commodities. Similarly,
In the capitalist circuit of production, the M-C-M’ formula is expanded to take into
account the means of production (MP) and labor power that goes into the production
process (P), in order to produce more commodities.
The reproduction circuit is here expanded from the C-M-C formula used by Marx to
show “the general metabolism of the reproduction of labour power, but also the circuit
of production of commodities involving self-employed, petty producers, craft people,
small organic farmers, reclaimed factories, water associations and so on” (De Angelis,
2017, p. 192).
This is only but a moment in a larger set of moments of social reproduction. Unlike
the production circuit of capitalism, the reproduction circuit serves as a means and
not as an end. Taking a broader view, the reproduction circuit at large could be conceptualized as a set of moments that recreate the commons (De Angelis, 2017, p. 193).
As seen from Figure 1, the sphere of reproduction is inevitably tied to money that
is created outside in the sphere of production as an end in itself, hence making social
reproduction—or rather, the commons—dependent on the circuit of capital for their
survival. From this we can observe how capitalism and patriarchy are subsidized by
and depend at large on reproductive labor for them to continue functioning.
An approach to solve this exploitation has been the post-Keynesian argument of
having states rather than private banks creating and allocating credit (Jackson & Dyson, 2013; Pettifor, 2017). This ‘productive versus speculative’ debate in the monetary
realm fails to recognize the feminist critique that production is a secondary moment
in the process of social reproduction. There cannot be goods and services and much
less workers without the reproductive, domestic, intimate, emotional and care work
done by those who make life what it is to begin with. But today, the money system
values only that which is seen as ‘productive’, invisibilizing unwaged work and the
dependence ‘the real economy’ has on it.
To go to the root, we must therefore create a type of money system which not only
breaks with the monoculture of today but is aimed at issuing unconditional reproductive tokens to all people in society, produced within itself. These tokens are not meant
as a debt to be paid back with an interest to a bank or to a state, as is consumer credit,
but as an income with purchasing power based on the acknowledgement of human
interdependence and the commonwealth which reproduces their livelihood.
The link between human work and the money received for the labor expenditure is
part of the mechanism through which systems of exploitation are reproduced today.
Private and state money are the medium through which capitalism and the state reproduce themselves at the expense of the commons. This money nexus hinges on the
reproductive capacity of the commons to become a viable alternative, as the people
who are often involved in their reproduction rely on wage labour for their livelihood
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
37
or spend their time on earth paying back unpayable debts.
Decoupling work from income would mean that the energy expenditure and resources that goes into reproducing existing systems would decrease. This would fundamentally change the arrangement of the systems themselves, as people are free to
decide what they wish to embody their time without the pressure to produce in the
same way. This decoupling necessarily implies a change in the source of monetary
creation as the basis for a new economic paradigm. This new monetary system would
serve as the means for the reproduction of people’s livelihood through the expansion
of the commons.
Thus, the ecology of care requires the links between labor and money to be severed
and then to create them anew, with radically different values and practices that follow
an ethics of care to emerge from the already existing spaces where the commons live.
This can be done in the form of a Basic Income which favors the circulation and the
sharing of wealth, rather than its accumulation.
Through a plural dividend which functions as a commons, it becomes possible to
change how money is designed, whilst distributing communities with the money necessary for social reproduction to take place without the need for waged labor. This
process of transforming money—its production and circulation—can be understood
as the appropriation and collective transformation of the institution of money into a
commons (De Angelis, 2017).
According to De Angelis, the autonomy or sympoesis of the commons can be derived in two ways. The first is through the point of view of a social system vis-á-vis
others, where autonomy defines the dynamic of the commons in relationship to other
systems in their environment i.e. the state and capitalism. In this sense, autonomy is
understood as a political struggle, a struggle over the values that constitute different
social spheres (De Angelis, 2007; 2017, p. 226). The politics of the commons are not
one of patriarchal productionism but a politics of distribution, which acknowledges
the reality that today’s systems of production have cut off and do not need human
labour power as they once did (Ferguson, 2015). In this sense, the sympoetic autonomy of the commons is the ability to re-appropriate and to redistribute the wealth
produced inside of them and to define what value is and where it moves. Money as a
commons is also thus a means of commoning resources together.
The second notion of autonomy is a property derived through the internal workings
of the commons, whose components recursively interact in such a way that the network that produced these interactions is regenerated and a boundary is defined (Varela, 1981, p. 15). Rethinking money as a commons, under democratic control, keeps the
value of the system inside its boundaries, which helps to nurture sufficiency within
any given community. The people who use this money commons would interact with
other people without having to be subjugated to state money or private debt issued
by banks. Basic Income in this sense would be the means for communities to claim
autonomy in horizontal interconnectedness with other communities and social forms.
The commons are also interdependent to the constituent parts that reproduce it,
which at times might in turn be dependent on the state, capital or other structures for
their reproduction. The interdependence between the commons and capitalism today
38
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
ensures the reproduction of capitalism at the expense of plundering the commons.
The Lauderdale Paradox—which states that the private riches grow by degrowing public wealth—has its correlate in our currency monoculture system, as the private money
issued by the private riches is what reduces the public wealth of the commons. In this
context, resolving the lauderdale paradox implies the creation of a monetary circuit
which increases public wealth and decreases massive accumulation of private wealth
(Hickel, 2019).
THE COMMONITY FORM
In the first sentence of the first paragraph of the first volume of Das Kapital, Marx
opens it by stating the following:
The wealth of those societies in which the capitalist mode of production prevails,
presents itself as ‘an immense accumulation of commodities’; the individual
commodity appears as its elementary form. Our investigation therefore begins
with the analysis of the commodity. (Marx, 1982a, p. 125)
Marx then goes on to analyze the complex ways in which commodities are reproduced, mainly starting through what he termed commodity fetichism, reification, and
alienation. This fetichism works in a mirror-like process, whereby us as human beings give power to objects until suddenly, these objects have magical powers over us.
This false coin of our dreams is key in understanding how capitalism manages to turn
basically anything into mere products for sale. By abstracting all the social relations
that make people and things unique and diverse to begin with, the commodity form
homogenizes social reality and destroys natural ecosystems, all for the sake of its own
infinite deity-like reproduction.
Crucially, the relationships of production underpinning the commodity form follow the logic of private ownership, which is a sacred taboo in today’s modern society.
Hence Karl Polanyi’s notion that land, labor and money are fictitious commodities
(Polanyi, 1944). The fiction that nature, human beings and the promises we make to
one another can be owned in the form of a commodity is the beginning of a logic
which began to systematically kill life at the expense of making more money the sovereign king and end all.
If commodity money is premised on private ownership as the basis for the reproduction of other commodities, is it possible to imagine and create a common money that is premised on common relationships of ownership? The commonity form in
question would be one where the value(s) which flow through it reflect and reproduce
the common ownership of resources outside of states and current circuits of capital.
What if instead, we posit the following:
The wealth of those societies in which the commons mode of production prevails, presents itself as an immense circulation of commonities. Its units being
the plurality of the commons. Our investigation must therefore begin with the
analysis of the commonity.
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
39
COMMONIFYING MONEY7
Making money a commons means people everywhere claiming the power to severe
money’s long standing relationship to states and private banks and bringing its very
creation to the realm of people. In this sense, the issuance of money is decentralized
to potentially all human beings on the planet with confederated currencies that fit the
local conditions of each particular place.
Commonifying money means that the issuing of credit starts at the individual level
and runs through the circuit of reproduction and the circuit of the commons for its
own regeneration before going into the realm of the state and capitalism. Through
this bottom-up monetary creation, the shareholders of the planet’s resources become
the commoners who issue their own reproductive income on an unconditional basis.
Divided as an equal share of the total planetary wealth, money in the commons is
transformed into what could be called sympoetic money or libre money8, as it is co-produced from within the commons themselves and for the commons to use. This fulfills
De Angelis’ understanding of the commons as systems that put money at the service
of their own existence, and not the other way around. Before expanding on this point,
let us first outline how the commons are reproduced.
The Commons Formula, drawn by De Angelis, is as follows:
Figure 2: The circuit of the commons
Source: adapted from De Angelis (2017, p. 193)
The commons (Cs) come into contact with the outside world either as buyers or
sellers (left and right side of the picture). Commons are constituted by people’s associThe idea of the money commons is not new. Many theorists and financial activists have explored the
concept and its practical implementation at length. See, for example, Greco (2009); Dodd (2014); Slater
& Jenkins (2016).
8
Today, there is already an autonomous monetary movement all over France called Libre Money, where
people issue their own money on an equal basis from the bottom up, based on a peculiar ‘Relative Theory of Money’, which uses Einstein’s theory of relativity to produce money. See: https://duniter.org/en/
7
40
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
ations (A), understood as any group with common goals, practices and values, together with the common wealth (CW) they hold, which is in turn made up of both a mixture
commodities and non-commodities like knowledge, dexterity and public spaces (De
Angelis, 2017, p. 193).
The process of commoning (cm) is inherently a social process that takes place
whenever all these aspects come into play. Yet this picture still misses the relationships that make commodities (C) come into being i.e. the circuit of capital we saw in
Figure 1. Figure 3 adds the money nexus that connects the circuit of the commons to
that of capital:
Figure 3: The circuit of the commons expanded
Source: adapted from De Angelis (2017, p. 193)
Expanding the commons formula, we come back to the question of commodities
and the material forces that go into their production. As noted above, it is through
the mixture of labour power (LP) and means of production (MP) that commodities are
produced. But the precondition for these two forces to mix, the root link that ties them
together, is money.
The only missing part of De Angelis formulation of the commons is the root of all
money. As mentioned, the institutions that are responsible for the production of money are private banks and states. Capitalists who pay wages get their money, at some
point or another, from banks and high-finance, which lend it to them at an interest.
Making money a commons means that the traditionally ‘divine’ power over monetary
creation held by the sovereign would be decentralized and distributed by all humans
from the bottom-up, without intermediary banks but by the people who want to collectively share the commonwealth of society as a whole, through their individually
distributed incomes.
This new promise is co-produced by everybody, distributed constantly and equally,
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
41
and governed by the principles of the commons and direct democracy. It is an attempt
at explicitly acknowledging that our existence is shared interdependently. It is not
tied to the protestant work ethic (Weber, 2001) but is given unconditionally of one’s
actions, just because we exist and without a positive interest embedded to its creation.
The commons have as an ultimate goal the reproduction and the care of their people, the planet and what they consider valuable. Is the means to the end of taking care
of people. Having this understanding of money as commons in mind, we can re-think
a Basic Income that allows for people to take care of each other without the ‘where
will the money come from?’ concern that implicitly underpins current Basic Income
debates. If the objective is to take care of people, then the question is not how will the
state finance a Basic Income, but what is the form of money that will allow us to take
care of people and the monetary institutions that bring it into being.
In so far as finance is the imagination of capitalism (Haiven, 2011), the appropriation of the means of the production of money as a commons is a key step to move
towards a more comprehensive transformation of society. This approach to money as
a commons is a way of fighting back against finance as an appropriation of the commons (Hardt & Negri, 2009).
V. THE SECOND LEG: DEGROWTH AND THE LIFE AND DEATH OF MONEY
So far we have argued for a re-making of money into a commons. In this section,
we argue that a monetary system like the one we propose fits with the principles of
degrowth. Moreover, we also suggest that any serious attempt to move towards a degrowth society must consider the transformation of money as central to its political
objective.
While many social movements and political projects have fought back the destructive consequences of capitalism (Kothari, Demaria, & Acosta, 2014), in this paper
we focus on the degrowth tradition for its explicit and central critique to economic
growth, as well as the articulation of robust evidence of the implausibility of ideas like
‘green growth’ or ‘sustainable growth’ from an ecological perspective (Kallis & Hickel,
2019). This expansive, extractionary and predatory nature of economic growth as the
goal of a society is precisely the main point of critique in the varied thinking that can
be labelled as ‘decroissance’ or ‘degrowth’ (Latouche, 2009; Kallis et al., 2018).
Degrowth gives ground to think about money as ‘alive’ while being consequent in
putting care as the centre of economic life. Degrowth not only acknowledges the ecological limits of wealth accumulation but also restores the role of care and maintenance to the centre of society. Based on this, we also develop an expansive and democratically grounded understanding of care that this form of Basic Income would allow.
As we explored in previous sections, growth and the way the money system works are
intimately intricated. Compounded interest demands the constant increase in profit
beyond covering ‘needs’ to satisfy the profit of those producing the money (Robbins,
2018). In order to get more growth, more debt has to be issued.
Many proponents of degrowth base their approach on the principles of ecological
economics and the limits of the ecosystems in their ability to regenerate and sustain
42
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
all forms of life. Initially, economists focusing on the ecological implications of production and consumption in the rich world emphasized the impossibility of sustaining
economic growth in a finite planet (Meadows et al., 1972; Gorz, 1977; Georgescu-Roegen, 1979; Latouche, 2009). When counting and embedding economic activity in society and the environment, it becomes clear that compounded growth cannot continue
indefinitely when the ecosystem’s capacity to regenerate is limited, and, in some cases—like with fossil fuels—almost null. Rather than aiming for detachment from limits—as some forms of green growth and techno-optimism do—more recent iterations
of degrowth embrace this recognition of limits in a (re)productive, liberating manner
(Kallis, 2019; Pueyo, 2014).
The serious theoretical acknowledgement of the biophysical world and its boundaries (Raworth, 2017) makes explicit that trying to pursue infinite growth in wealth (of
which the increase of money is its only measure) will exert violence over people and
ecosystems alike (Patel & Moore, 2018)9. With this ground, degrowth has made its way
in recent proposals to address the climate and ecological breakdown in dialogue with
the care debate (Paulson et al., 2020; Pérez Orozco, 2017).
Degrowth has already shown the need to revalorise and strengthen the circuits of
care. Growth sceptics have recognised how some of the most beneficial economic activities (usually care related) are not just uncounted in traditional GDP accounts, but
actively discouraged and displaced by the need to increase commoditised production
and consumption (Jackson, 2017). Jackson’s proposal of ‘prosperity without growth’,
for instance, relies on the advancement of the ‘Cinderella economy’, which includes
some of the daily activities which are usually underplayed or ignored in mainstream
economic accounting, as ‘these sectors of the economy—care, craft, culture (...) are inherently labour-intensive as well as being potentially lighter in environmental terms’
(Jackson, 2017, p. 204).
Feminist scholars working with the concept of degrowth have made explicit the
conflict of existing economic model with care work (Pérez Prieto & Domínguez-Serrano, 2005; Dengler & Seebacher, 2019; Pérez Orozco, 2017) and call for feminist perspectives to be put at the centre when thinking how to ‘scale down’ the economy. They
reinforce the already theorized role of women in the provision of care—disproportionate, exploitative and unrecognised—that has been displaced for the sake of profit and
accumulation. The core message is put by Pérez Orozco as ‘ecofeminist degrowth or
barbarism’ (Pérez Orozco, 2017, p. 223). As we understand that surviving the ecological breakdown requires moving to a care-centred society, transforming our paradign
of what economics is for (Praetorius, 2015), we see an affinity between degrowth and
feminist critiques to lead the way conceptually.
More practically, when it comes to visions and formulas to move towards a degrowth society we can find concepts like low tech (Alexander & Yacoumis, 2018), low
energy demand (Grubler et al., 2018), and strategies for making food systems sustainable as in agroecology (Mier y Terán Giménez Cacho et al., 2018). All follow the idea of
‘cooling down’ the economy and focusing more on keeping things going—the work of
9
To see how this contrasts with forms of modernist socialism, see Robbins (2020).
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
43
maintenance—and regenerating ecosystems rather than producing and discarding. In
other words: an economy that fosters care as the core of society, rather than being put
conceptually in the margins (an ‘externality’) as our current model does. It is a counter-movement against accumulation through the exploitation of care to a circulation
of care as the basis to build the commons.
DEGROWTH MONEY
Even though the degrowth movement has shown the limits of our civillization’s obsession with growth, and has promoted and proposed complementary currencies for
its implementation (Hornborg, 2017), the degrowth critique has yet to incorporate
the role money/credit creation plays more explicitly. Ecological economics has still
to develop a monetary theory of its own as well (Ament, 2019). To become a viable
alternative, the second leg of our ecology of care aims at outlining the relationship between growth and monetary creation and lay the foundation of what we call degrowth
money. We argue that money’s ‘nature’ itself also has to be changed and expanded
in order to avoid the growth imperative from destroying the diversity of the world’s
ecosystems.
Silvio Gesell10 is considered to be the first person in the modern era to think about
the idea of demurrage, or letting money “rot like potatoes, rust like iron and evaporate
like ether” (Gesell, 2007; Dodd, 2014, p. 348). We suggest that the concept of demurrage, or degrowth money can help us solve our current economic, social and ecological
crisis for the following four reasons:
1. Time Horizon: The way the money system works today affects our time horizon, as the short term is valued over the long term. Any investment which provides profit faster is given priority over long term production and planning. Because money today is made scarce through the production of credit, people have
to compete over the interest in labor markets, making humanity’s time on earth
an endless cycle of debt (Guyer, 2007; Eisenstein, 2011; Lietaer & Dunne, 2012).
In contrast, demurrage or degrowth money incentivizes long term decision making via discounted cash flows (Macleod, 2009). Demurrage is a way of going slow,
valuing the long term present value of things over the short term. Using the
words of an economist, we have a situation where money has a negative interest
rate embedded in its design.
2. Liquidity Trap: Modern central banks are theoretically responsible for setting
interest rates and managing the supply of money. These are the initial conditions which private banks use to issue credit to people. But as it is widely known,
capitalism is prone to boom and bust cycles. A liquidity trap is a term economists use to describe the situation when money in an economy stops circulating
John Maynard Keynes referred to Gesell as a “strange, unduly neglected prophet” and that “the future
will learn more from the spirit of Gesell than from that of Marx”. Of demurrage Keynes thought that the
“idea behind stamped money is sound. It is, indeed, possible that means might be found to apply it in
practice on a modest scale.” See Keynes (2008: 298-300).
10
44
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
regardless of the actions of central banks to increase the supply of money and
affect interest rates. As trust in the economy disappears and a financial crisis
starts, people start to hoard any money they can get their hands on. Degrowth
money solves the liquidity trap by putting a limit on the amount of time money
can carry value. Lower or negative interest rates disincentives saving and encourage spending. As complementary currency expert Bernard Lietaer put it, it is
like charging ‘a parking fee on money’ (Lietaer & Dunne, 2012). Because people
do not want their money to decay, they start to circulate it, as the many historical
experiences during the Great Depression demonstrate11.
3. Integrating Entropy: We know from thermodynamics that energy can neither be created nor destroyed, just transformed. Degrowth money integrates
the second law of thermodynamics into monetary theory by designing a money
that is meant for circulation rather than accumulation (Macleod, 2009). Money
today expands through bank credit creation. Debt produces a vacuum for the
extraction of value which sucks wealth back into the hands of the lender at
the expense of the planet’s resources and most of humanity’s labor power. The
accumulation of wealth made by our current systems of production implies the
production of a lot of waste, or energy that irreversibly increases the total level
of entropy of the planet. Increasing entropy levels lead to an overshooting of our
planetary boundaries and the useful energy needed to reproduce life. Put more
simply, wealth is waste (Dodd, 2014, pp. 163-210). By making the value of money
have a life-span12, a degrowth money system has the potential to change the way
energy is distributed and reintroduced within the system (and hence reduce its
waste). This not only makes perceived wealth increase due to the higher velocity
of money in circulation but also makes the deterioration of the quality of energy
(entropy) slow down.
4. Ending the Material Growth Imperative: The way money is designed today
favors creditors (money lenders) and savers (money holders). As we explained
above, a positive interest on money creation necessarily leads to economic
Yale economist Irving Fisher is perhaps the most famous exponent of Gesell’s ideas of rotting money
during the time of the Great Depression. He wrote extensively about the positive ‘miracle’ experiences
of demurrage currencies used in the German speaking countries and in the US during the 1920s and
30s. He even took the idea to congress but it failed to pass legislation. At the time, these monies were
referred to as “emergency currencies” and were seen as an alternative to the New Deal. In the end, President Roosevelt opted for the New Deal and it became official government policy, favoring centralized
government spending ala Keynes over decentralized decision making via local currencies. Situating
these historical lessons in the context of today, it is worthwhile to question the limits of proposals
invoking the past such as the “Green” New Deal and see where their predecessors led today’s economy
after the war. Can we afford to repeat the Liberal/Keynesian pendulum once more or is there a third way
yet to be explored? See Fisher (1933) for a detailed description of the stamp scrip movement of the 30s.
12
Demurrage is different from inflation in that in demurrage the amount of currency one holds decreases over time while its purchasing power remains the same. In contrast, with inflation, the amount of
currency held today stays the same but it loses its purchasing power over time.
11
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
45
growth. A degrowth money would stop the imperative to increase our material
output as the effective interest rate on a yearly basis is zero or negative in comparison to previous years, instead allowing for qualitative growth in individuals
and communities alike (Macleod, 2009). This allows for complementary monies
to be used for investment in local infrastructure, basic services, health and education. Degrowth money is fundamentally a different type of money which has
the potential to make our human ecosystem more resilient as a whole through
the introduction of monetary diversity, separating money’s functions (means of
exchange/payment, unit of account, store of value) in multiple money forms (Polanyi, 1977; Lietaer & Dunne, 2013).
As the social ecologists remind us, the very notion that men can dominate nature
is rooted in the real domination of men over other men and over women (Bookchin,
1982). While the planet’s biosphere might recover without us as a species, we will not
recover without the biosphere. The extraction of nature’s resources for the sake of
short term profit and people’s capacity to reproduce and produce their life is organized by how money works. The ecology of money today is one of a monoculture, where
we use the same type of money to arrange everything in our lives, from education to
housing to the marketplace. While it might be efficient, a money system without a
break or escape valve is dangerous as it makes the system in which we live rigid and
fragile (Lietaer, 2002).
Just like the nervous system helps to transmit information about our bodies from
one part to the other, so should our money system help to nurture people’s social
reproduction. Instead of private banks creating most of the money supply as an interest-bearing monoculture which extracts the yield of living ecosystems, overwhelming
our planetary body, we should think of money holistically and adapt it to the needs
of each bioregion, embedding for example the principles of permaculture into its very
design and the institutions that maintain it (Scott, 2014)13.
The ecology of care thus aims at giving people money unconditionally, with the
goal that income is divorced from work and people do not have to rely solely on a wage
in order to get what they need to reproduce their daily life. This Basic Income is distributed as a share of the yield of the wealth held in common. The issuance level necessary for people to have self-reliance should be equivalent to the price of the material
conditions needed to meet people’s basic needs: housing, food, education, health, etc.
Making money alive through demurrage means that money will also gradually die
when not in use. Adding demurrage as the second step of the three legged table allows
us to limit the extent to which accumulation can take place in the system and instead
foster circulation and exchange within the values of the commons. Like this, both
the issuance and the decay of money take place constantly and adapt to the seasonal
needs of people who govern it, following the principles of the commons outlined by
Östrom and others (Östrom, 1990).
A currency that decays requires us to rethink the whole structure of the interdeFor example, the three ethics of permaculture are people care, earth care and fair share. See more at
https://permacultureprinciples.com/principles/
13
46
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
pendent social relations which keep the economic, biophysical, and social systems together. The ideas of the degrowth literature discussed so far share an expansive notion
of care, in the sense that the provision of social care cannot be detached from the care
of nature and its regenerative limits. Degrowth requires the care of our environment
in harmony with the care of people; to go beyond ‘the illusion of an independent human existence’ (Praetorious, 2015, p. 50), both independent of other people and of
the worlds we form part of. This intertwined human condition becomes clear when
we try to figure out how to take care of people at a practical level: we understand that
no care is possible in a destroyed, biodiversity poor and polluted environment. People
are, after all, part of their ecosystems. We suggest a degrowth money to move towards
this utopia.
VI. THE THIRD LEG: PLURIVERSAL BASIC INCOME
In our dreams we have seen another world, an honest world, a world decidedly
more fair than the one in which we now live. We saw that in this world there was
no need for armies; peace, justice and liberty were so common that no one talked
about them as far-off concepts, but as things such as bread, birds, air, water, like
book and voice.
― Subcomandante Marcos
The third and last element of our ecology of care is the political leg. The version of a
common dividend that we have called a Pluriversal Basic Income (PBI). This formulation of a Basic Income is epistemologically different from nation-state proposals,
as it aims to go beyond and within its boundaries to weave a pluriverse (Kothari et
al., 2019). The pluriverse serves as a practical and conceptual tool to overcome the
homogenization of reality made by the violent social relations of capitalist modernity,
that has brought about the destruction of our ability to understand the world (Öcalan,
2015).
The formulation of the pluriverse goes against the modernizing logic of the nation-state, in that it does not create a separation between the subject and the object
but instead looks at reality as one interconnected whole, where the past and the future are contained in the present (Rivera Cusicanqui, 2019). This ‘indigenization’ of
the world is also a recognition that all languages are in fact indigenous languages
from the communities in which they emerge from. But as Rivera Cusicanqui stresses,
colonialism has a very specific usage for words: they encover instead of designating
what things are. History is filled with countless examples of double-think, where the
meaning of words is twisted in order to control and dominate others.
Similarly, if we are to think of money as a semantic system akin to language, a
promise which carries values and meanings about the world, a memory bank, it becomes clear that its fiction as a commodity is what reproduces the colonization of the
planet (Hart, 2001; Polanyi, 1977; Zelizer, 1997). To decolonize money we need epistemes that recognizes that people are all part of nature before they are anything else,
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
47
interconnected to the whole14. This decolonization practice aims at understanding the
roots of our individual and collective trauma. It is an exercise at healing the internal
colonialism of our experiences and their relationship to money and the bureaucratic
institutions that underpin it (Rivera Cusicanqui, 2015, p. 175).
As some note, the emancipatory value of a Basic Income is higher than its monetary value (Standing, 2017). The gradual production of this new money thus aims at
challenging the long standing guilt over our debts, work and wealth, through its equal,
abundant and unconditional predistribution. It is therefore an attempt at reformulating the relationships we have with each other and with the world. It is different
in the sense that it is constituted democratically as a political plural entity with the
potentiality to encompass all human beings in a planetary federation15. This pluriversal dividend is a share of the wealth of the collective and it only becomes basic once
it can pay for people’s basic livelihood needs such as food and housing, which in turn
is inherently embedded with the reproduction of the commons, understood in their
holistic sense.
We propose that the social form any given society takes is marked by its monetary
institutions. These institutions are responsible for allocating the means of production
(land, labor, capital) and ultimately determine what value is through the circulation
of currency, whatever its form. The monetary institutions of the day are a remnant of
enlightenment rationality and do not reflect current understandings in the field of
complexity science or even quantum physics. In so far as money is a credit that can be
individually issued as a promise to pay another person, money can be conceived as an
emergent property of human relations, regulated through strange attractors such as
debt, which tie people together and to their ecosystem.
The banking structures of today have the monopoly over society’s trust to issue
credit. This privilege produces a centralized and fragile monetary structure which creates a scarcity of money and a vacuum for the extraction of value. The complexity of
the money system can no longer be managed by a central planning committee. The
decentralization of the production of money as a credit or money commons, organized
democratically by all who use it, would potentially create more resilient and ecological circuits that go beyond the binarism of nation-states and their globalized financial
institutions. A relocation of the source of money means the transformation of how
value is produced, defined and distributed.
Currently, the nation-state is the sovereign of money, the ultimate backup of promises based on fear and violence. If we want to reclaim the control of money, we need to
change how it is produced; through the reformulation of the principle of sovereignty in
Social ecologists speak of first nature as non-human nature and second nature as an emergent property of life in the form of human consciousness and society. At a systemic level, money today is one of
the links that ties first nature to second nature together in a hierarchical relation which must be severed and made anew. See Bookchin (1982).
15
We base this on the already-existing organizational practices and systems of communal indigenous
government in Latin America, confederated systems based on direct-democracy in the Middle East and
elsewhere. See, for example, Xochitl, L. et al. (2008); Rivera Cusicanqui (2015, p. 17); Sousa Santos et al.
(2018, p. 127); Kothari et al. (2019, p. 151).
14
48
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
human organization. Whether the decentralization of sovereign, its transformation as
a pluriversal, planetary commons or its abolition; the imagination required to change
the sovereignty of nation-states today is deeply tied together through money and the
violence it upholds. Money as a promise means that the fiction of the nation must continue to exist in the near future. Otherwise, the money would not be worth anything.
In a way, it is the very threat of violence that gives future value to nation-state money.
Embedding money into the pluriverse means to start creating institutions which
embody the diversity of the world without commodifying it. A monetary pluriverse
forms the basis for a democratic confederation of political imaginations. It is a union
of what we are and the identities that capture our individual and collective stories.
All respecting each region with its own democratic control, where power is seen and
embody by all, distributed equally and negotiated through assemblies.
A planetary income is an unconditional amount of money given to all human beings on the planet. A planetary income necessarily needs a planetary politics, a paradigm shift from current nation-state politics, where wealth is democratized and administered by people in confederated assemblies, from the local, to the regional, to
the planetary.
A planetary income is the recognition of our interdependency to the whole and to
each other. It aims at emerging from capitalist modernity through the reshaping of the
tokens of value that fetichize the definitions of our wealth and their corresponding institutions. The pluriverse sets the stage for a fundamental break from the patriarchal
systems of sovereignty, which include by excluding the other into its formulation of
the self and its cosmic-polities (Sahlins, 2017). Instead, the pluriverse tries to weave
the different epistesmes in order to understand the impermanence of reality in its
different emergent levels and let the polity emerge from there (Kothari et al., 2019).
In this way we can ease the death of the world as we know it and lay at rest the ashes
of the old. As the Zapatistas and other groups often remind us, the world has ended
many times before. We must accept that. Once we do we will realise that the phoenix
of rebirth is ever more near.
VII. CONCLUSION: THE COMMONIFICATION OF CARE
AND THE DECOLONIZATION OF MONEY
So far we have presented the possibilities of a degrowth money system that is alive,
created as a commons in the form of a Pluriversal Basic Income, as a means for building a caring society. Now we want to go back to what care is and how we can give each
other the best possible care.
If care is understood as a commons (Akbulut, 2017), no one should be denied basic
care. This care takes a relational shape in a double sense: primarily between someone
caring and someone being cared for, but also inside a community of care practitioners.
What constitutes proper care hardly relies on a single individual’s judgement, but is
rather carefully and constantly debated and negotiated. Giving more space and power
to those spaces of deliberation—as well as making them more democratic—improves
the care that is given.
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
49
This point is fundamental to avoid a usual critique of the political use of care as a
principle: that care is only a cover of relations of domination. Many forms of care can
be controlling, repressive of authoritarian. Anthropological scholarship is full of examples in which hierarchies are introduced and those in higher positions claim to take
care of those dependent on them (Haynes & Hickel, 2018).
We acknowledge that there is a tension between care and dependency or control.
But still, people in their everyday lives use criteria to say that some relations are not
built on care, but in forms of control and oppression that are ultimately damaging
those being dominated. For instance, we can probably agree in saying that a prison is
not a caring institution—even though those within are fed and given shelter. They are
still deprived of freedom, and that takes away all the emancipatory aspect of receiving
care. One’s agency is taken away. This is why we propose the working definition of care
not as the satisfaction of need under some objective physical standard, but as whatever
action is taken to increase someone else’s freedom (Graeber, 2018).
This is why, for instance, we should be suspicious of forms of care—or at least, labelled as care—that work under a logic of ‘human capital’ or ‘social investment’ (as
in some Conditional Cash Transfer programs in Latin America). Such policies rely on
a logic of stigma, including people as productive citizens as a substitute for social
justice. These concepts put people not as an end in themselves, but at the service of
production (Carrasco, 2001). They work as a temporary support to ‘lift’ people from
poverty by introducing them in the formal employment market. Rejecting this conditionality as a prerequisite for receiving care goes with the idea of ‘a life worth being
lived’ under which sustaining life is not put at the service of the market economy
(Perez Prieto & Dominguez-Serrano, 2005).
In institutions and communities where there is space for debating how care is being
actively produced, this horizon is better actualized. This is why professions that are
mainly care work—teachers and health workers for example—give so much importance to sharing practical experiences and being able to consult how to deal with a
difficult situation. The same can be said about child-rearing.
Care given during our early years can work as an exemplar case for our point. The
more people are involved in it—and let’s remember that most societies until very recently practised alloparenting16 beyond the nuclear family—there are more chances
to balance potential mistreatments or controlling behaviours. When everyone has a
say in what you do with your child it is harder to fall into abusive forms of care. Controlling or ‘corrupted’ forms of care usually imply the limitation of decision-making to
one actor or one body of actors that keep the influence of other people away. Bureaucracy does this work particularly good: it is designed to keep any other perspective of
how things should get done as irrelevant (Graeber, 2015).
We suggest that the democratization of care is the improvement of care. Not
just as the distribution of care ‘burden’ but also as an issue in which all the community
has a say and there are legitimate spaces for debating and changing care practices. The
Alloparenting is a form of shared childrearing that implies the involvement—in addition to the mother, as it is common in other animals—of other relatives like fathers and grandmothers, but also other
more distant relatives and non-relatives as well, in the care given to dependant children (Hrdy, 2009).
16
50
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
capacity to adapt and accept something could be done better is crucial to keep care on
track and stop oppression from emerging. These democratic care institutions are also
the spaces where people’s Basic Income is administered.
In sum, a Pluriversal Basic Income (PBI) would enhance care in two ways: democratising the possibilities of giving and receiving care, and giving more space to the
political debate on how to better care for one another.
TOWARDS A DECOLONISED MONEY AND SOCIETY
The current form of money has been a fundamental tool of colonial projects. Moving
to an ecology of care would allow us to decolonise money. This decolonization would
mean a change of what value is, where it comes from and where it stays. It is a means of
changing the political categories of the day to ones that embody the will of the masses through the parallel and gradual redistribution of wealth. The decolonization of
money is therefore the political struggle over the definition of what value means as a
common human project. This political deliberation necessarily implies a direct-democratic break from the representative bureaucracies of capitalist modernity.
Our proposal of a new monetary system and degrowth offers a way to think of integrating multiple challenges. For PBI to succeed in the ultimate goal of making people
freer, it must rethink both the nature of money and the destructive logic of growth that
is deeply inscribed in our global economic system. If Basic Income is about taking care
of people, then it must be created and managed bottom-up, to avoid the extraction of
value from the financial institutions that rely on money for accumulation and do not
care for the ‘real economy’. Having different currencies for different things could help
with this: Basic Income money just cannot be used for accumulation and speculation.
This transformation of money would also allow us to question and rebuild our political institutions. The sovereignty of millions is bought and sold every day by the
institutions that control the flow of money. Without properly addressing the question
of the production of money, any revolutionary project which aims at changing the system is doomed to failure. Without dis-embedding money from capital and the state,
the enclosure of the commons will continue until full collapse. An acknowledgement
of our systemic crisis requires a reconstitution of value, money and wealth, and not just
their redistribution.
Our proposal is not about the commodification of care, but the commonification (or
commonalisation, following De Angelis) of care. The money produced for the goal of
taking care of people will be a different money. There is no better time than the present to bring down the walls of our political imagination and make this ecology of care
possible.
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
51
FUNDING: This research received no external funding.
CONFLICT OF INTEREST: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: We would like to thank all of people that generously gave us their comments
in the different instances where we have presented this paper since 2019, especially to basic income
advocates at BIEN
REFERENCES
Akbulut, B. (2017). Carework as Commons: Towards a Feminist Degrowth Agenda.
degrowth.info. Retrieved from https://www.degrowth.info/en/2017/02/carework-as-commons-towards-a-feminist-degrowth-agenda/
Ament, J. (2019). Toward an Ecological Monetary Theory. Sustainability, 11(3), 923.
https://doi.org/10.3390/su11030923
Aristotle (1954). The Nicomachean ethics of Aristotle (The World’s classics 546). London: Oxford University Press.
Bear, L., Ho, K., Tsing, A., & Yanagisako, S. (2015). Gens: A Feminist Manifesto for the
Study of Capitalism. Fieldsights—Theorizing the Contemporary, Cultural Anthropology, 30 March. Retrieved from https://culanth.org/fieldsights/gens-a-feminist-manifesto-for-the-study-of-capitalism
Benjamin, W. (1996). Capitalism as Religion. Selected Writings, Vol. 1. C. Gödde & H.
Lonitz (Eds.) (pp. 288-291). Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.
Bookchin, M. (1982). The Ecology of Freedom: The Emergence and Dissolution of Hierarchy. Palo Alto, Calif.: Cheshire Books.
Dalla Costa, M., & Selma, J. (1975). The Power of Women and the Subversion of the Community. Bristol: Falling Wall Press.
De Angelis, M. (2007). The Beginning of History: Value Struggles and Global Capital.
London: Pluto Press.
De Angelis, M. (2017). Omnia Sunt Communia: On The Commons and the Transformation to Postcapitalism. London: Zed Books.
Dodd, N. (2014). The Social Life of Money. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Eisenstein, C. (2011). Sacred Economics: Money, Gift and Society in the Age of Transition.
Berkeley, Calif.: North Atlantic Books.
Federici, S. (2011). Feminism and the Politics of The Commons. The Wealth of the Commons. Retrieved from http://wealthofthecommons.org/essay/feminism-and-politics-commons
Federici, S. (2014). Caliban and the witch: women, the body and primitive accumulation.
Brooklyn, NY: Autonomedia.
Fisher, I. (1933). Stamp Scrip. New York: Adelphi Company Publishers.
Gesell, S. (2007). The Natural Economic Order. Frankston, TX. TGF Publishers.
Graeber, D. (2001). Toward an Anthropological Theory of Value: The False Coin of our
Dreams. Basingstoke, U.K.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Graeber, D. (2011). Debt: The First 5000 years. Brooklyn, NY/London: Melville House
Publishing.
52
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
Graeber, D. (2013). It is value that brings universes into being. Hau, 3(2), 219-244.
Graeber, D. (2015). The Utopia of Rules. On technology, stupidity, and the secret joys of
bureaucracy. Brooklyn and London: Melville House.
Graeber, D. (2018). The Revolt of the Caring Classes. Lecture delivered at the College de
France. Retrieved from https://www.college-de-france.fr/site/evenements-culturels/22-mars-2018-David-Graeber.htm
Greco, T. (2009). The End of Money and the Future of Civilization. Vermont: Chelsea
Green Publishing.
Haiven, M. (2011). Finance as Capital’s Imagination? Reimagining Value and Culture
in an Age of Fictitious Capital and Crisis. Social Text, 29((3)108), 93-124.
Hardt, M., & Negri, A. (2009). Commonwealth. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Hart, K. (1986). Heads or Tails? Two sides of the Coin. Man, New Series, 21(4), 637-656.
Hart, K. (2001). Money in an Unequal World: Keith Hart and his Memory Bank. London:
Texere.
Hart, K., Laville, J. et al. (2010). The Human Economy. Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press.
Haynes, N., & Hickel, J. (Eds.). (2018). Hierarchy and value: Comparative perspectives on
moral order. New York: Berghahn Books.
Held, V. (2006). The Ethics of Care: Personal, Political, Global. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Hickel, J. (2019). Degrowth: A theory of radical abundance. Real-World Economics Review, 87, 54–68.
Hickel, J., & Kallis, G. (2019). Is Green Growth Possible? New Political Economy, 25(4),
1–18. https://doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2019.1598964
Hrdy, S. (2009). Meet the Alloparents. Natural History Magazine. Retrieved from http://
naturalhistorymag.com/features/15270/meet-the-alloparents?page=3
Hudson, M. (2004). The Archeology of Money: Debt versus Barter Theories of Money’s
Origins. In L. R. Wray (Ed.), Credit and State Theories of Money: The Contributions
of A. Mitchell Innes (pp. 99-127). Cheltenham, U.K., Edward Elgar Publishing.
Hudson, M. (2018). ...And forgive them their debts: Lending, Foreclosure and Redemption
From Bronze Age Finance to the Jubilee Year. Dresden: ISLET-Verlag.
Ingham, G. (2004). The Nature of Money. Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press.
Jackson, A., & Dyson, B. (2013). Modernising Money: Why our monetary system is broken
and how it can be fixed. London: Positive Money.
Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without growth: Foundations for the economy of tomorrow
(Second Edition). London, New York: Routledge.
Kallis, G., Kostakis, V., Lange, S., Muraca, B., Paulson, S., & Schmelzer, M. (2018). Research On Degrowth. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 43(1), 291–
316. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-environ-102017-025941
Keynes, J. (2008). The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York:
Classic House Books.
Knapp, G. F. (1924). The State Theory of Money. London: Macmillan.
Kothari, A., Salleh, A., Escobar, A., Demaria, F., & Acosta, A. (Eds.) (2019). Pluriverse: A
Post-Development Dictionary. New Delhi, India: Tulika Books.
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
53
Lietaer, B. (2002). The Future of Money: Creating New Wealth, Work and a Wiser World,
London: Century.
Lietaer, B., & Dunne, J. (2013). Rethinking Money: How New Currencies Turn Scarcity
Into Prosperity. San Francisco, Calif.: Brett Koehler Publishers.
Linebaugh, P. (2008). The Magna Carta Manifesto. Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press.
Macleod, J. (2009). New Currency: How Money Changes the World as We Know It. Pacific
Grove, Calif.: Integral Publishers.
Marx, K. (1982a). Capital. Vol. I. Harmondsworth, U.K.: Penguin.
Marx, K. (1982b). Capital. Vol. III. Harmondsworth, U.K.: Penguin.
McLeay, M., Radia, A., & Thomas, R. (2014). Money creation in the modern economy,
Bank of England. Quarterly Bulletin, 54(1), 14-27.
Meadows, D. et al. (1972). The Limits to Growth; A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project
on the Predicament of Mankind. New York: Universe Books.
Mier y Terán Giménez Cacho, M., Giraldo, O. F., Aldasoro, M., Morales, H., Ferguson, B.
G., Rosset, P., Khadse, A. & Campos, C. (2018). Bringing agroecology to scale: key
drivers and emblematic cases. Agroecology and Sustainable Food Systems, 42(6),
637-665. https://doi.org/10.1080/21683565.2018.1443313
Mies, M. (1998). Patriarchy and accumulation on a world scale: women in the international division of labour. London: Zed Books.
Mitchell-Innes, A. M. (1914). The Credit Theory of Money. In L. R. Wray (Ed.), Credit
and State Theories of Money: The Contributions of A. Mitchell-Innes (pp. 50-78).
Cheltenhaum, U.K.: Edward Edgar Publishing.
Öcalan, A. (2015). Civilization: The Age of Masked Gods and Disguised Kings—Manifesto
for a Democratic Civilization: Volume 1. International Initiative Edition. Norway:
New Compass Press.
Östrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolutions of Institutions for Collective
Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Paulson, S., D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F., & Kallis, G. (2020). From pandemic toward carefull degrowth. Interface: A journal for and about social movements. Retrieved from
https://www.interfacejournal.net/wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Paulson-et-al.
pdf
Pettifor, A. (2017). The Production of Money: How to Break the Power of Bankers. London: Verso Books.
Pérez Orozco, A. (2017). Subversión feminista de la economía: Aportes para un debate
sobre el conflicto capital-vida. Madrid: Traficantes de Sueños.
Piketty, T. (2013). Capital in the Twenty First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Polanyi, K. (1944). The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press.
Polanyi, K. (1977). The Livelihood of Man. New York: Academic Press Inc.
Praetorious, I. (2015). The Care Centered Economy: Rediscovering what has been Taken
for Granted. Berlin: Heinrich Böll Foundation.
Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut economics: Seven ways to think like a 21st century economist. London: Random House Business Books.
54
SOCIETY REGISTER 2022 / VOL. 6, NO. 3.
Rivera Cusicanqui, S. (2015). Sociología de la Imagen: Miradas Chí’xi desde la Historia
Andina. Ciudad Autónoma de Buenos Aires: Tinta Limón.
Rivera Cusicanqui, S. (2019). Ch’ixinakax utxiwa: A reflection on the practices and discourses of decolonization. Language, Culture and Society, 1(1), 106-119. https://
doi.org/10.1075/lcs.00006.riv
Robbins, R. H. (2018). An anthropological contribution to rethinking the relationship between money, debt, and economic growth. Focaal, 81, 99-120. https://doi.
org/10.3167/fcl.2018.810108
Robbins, P. (2020). Is less more … or is more less? Scaling the political ecologies
of the future. Political Geography, 76, 102018. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.polgeo.2019.04.010
Sahlins, M. (2017). The Original Political Society. Hau: Journal of Ethnographic Theory,
7(2), 91-128. https://doi.org/10.14318/hau7.2.014
Scott, B. (2014). Applying Permaculture to Finance. Retrieved from https://www.permaculture.co.uk/articles/applying-permaculture-finance
Simmel, G. (2004). The Philosophy of Money. Third Enlarged Edition. London: Routledge.
Slater, M., & Jenkin, T. (2016). Credit Commons: A Model for the Solidarity Economy.
Retrieved from www.creditcommons.net
Sousa Santos, B. et al. (Eds.) (2018). Epistemologías del Sur – Epistemologias do Sul. Ciudad Autónoma de Buenos Aires: CLACSO, CES.
Standing, G. (2017). Basic income: And how we can make it happen. London: Pelican.
Varela, F. J. (1981). Autonomy and Autopoiesis. In G. Roth & H. Schwegler (Eds),
Self-organizing systems: An interdisciplinary approach (pp. 14-23). Frankfurt/New
York: Campus Verlag.
Weber, M. (2001). The Protestant Work Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London: Routledge.
Werner, R. (2016). A lost century in Economics: Three theories of banking and the conclusive evidence. International Review of Financial Analysis, 46, 361–379.
Werner, R., & Lee, K. (2018). Reconsidering Monetary Policy: An Empirical Examination of the Relationship Between Interest Rates and Nominal GDP Growth in
the U.S., U.K., Germany and Japan. Ecological Economics, 146, 26-34. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.013
Xochitl, L., Burguete, A., & Speed, S. (Eds.) (2008). Gobernar (en) la diversidad: experiencias indígenas desde América Latina: Hacia la investigación de co-labor. México,
CIESAS, Flacso Ecuador y Flacso Guatemala.
Yanagisako, S. (2012). Immaterial and Industrial Labor: On False Binaries in Hardt and
Negri’s Trilogy. Focaal, 64:16–23. https://doi.org/10.3167/fcl.2012.640102
Zelizer, V. A. (1997). The Social Meaning of Money: Pin money, Paychecks, Poor Relief,
and Other Currencies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
JULIO LINARES & GABRIELA CABAÑA
55
BIOGRAPHICAL NOTE
Julio Linares is an economic anthropologist and activist born in the territories known today as Guatemala. He is currently based in Berlin, where he co-founded and co-organises Circles UBI, a basic
income system for communities, leveraging direct democratic practices and p2p technologies in order
to collectively organize a basic income without, within and beyond the nation-state. Since 2018, he has
served as Public Outreach for the Basic Income Earth Network (BIEN), co-creating the Latin American
Basic Income Network and Taiwanese Basic Income Network, among others. His present focus is on
democratic municipalist approaches towards bringing basic income into being with BIRAL, the Basic
Income Research and Action Lab. He is currently working on his first book, tentatively titled ‘Decolonizing Money’.
Gabriela Cabaña is an anthropologist and PhD candidate at the London School of Economics and Political Science. Her research focuses on energy transitions in the context of ecological crisis, processes
of planning, value struggles, and the morality of work. She is a founding member of Centro de Análisis
Socioambiental (CASA) an organization based in Chile working on research and public incidence in
social-environmental issues. From CASA, she has participated in the delivery of lectures and courses
on degrowth from a Latin American perspective. She is also president of the Chilean Basic Income
Network.
OPEN ACCESS: This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution
Non-commercial License (CC BY-NC 4.0) which permits any non-commercial use, and reproduction in
any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.
JOURNAL’S NOTE: Society Register stands neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published
figures, maps, pictures and institutional affiliations.
ARTICLE HISTORY: Received 2022-06-23 / Accepted 2020-07-11