Least-Cost Air Pollution Control: A CGE Joint Production Framework
by
Deborah Vaughn Aiken*
and
Carl A. Pasurka, Jr.**
*Occupational Safety and Health Administration
Washington, DC
**Office of Policy, Economics and Innovation
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (1809T)
1200 Pennsylvania Ave., N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20460
Phone: (202) 566-2275
Fax: (202) 566-2373
E-mail:
[email protected]
July 15, 2002
C:\cge-jointprod\mps104.wpd
DO NOT QUOTE OR CITE WITHOUT THE PERMISSION OF THE AUTHORS
To be presented at 14th International Input-Output Conference
Montreal, Canada in October 2002
An earlier version of this study was presented at the First World Congress of Environmental and
Natural Resource Economists in Venice, Italy (June 1998). All views expressed in this study are the
authors' and do not reflect the opinions of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration or the
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.
Abstract
This study proposes a new, more flexible approach to modeling pollution abatement
activities within the CGE framework, one that treats the problem as an issue of the joint production
of “good” and “bad” outputs. More specifically, this study employs a joint production technology
to derive the production possibilities frontier for those industries producing both “good” and “bad”
outputs. This avoids some of the difficulties associated with attempting to model separate
technologies for production of the good output and pollution abatement activities. We demonstrate
an application of the CGE model by estimating the cost associated with not pursuing least-cost
strategies for abating air pollutants in the United States.
I.
Introduction
Application of computable general equilibrium (CGE) models to environmental policy
analysis has become commonplace (see Atkins and Garbaccio 1999, Conrad 1999, 2002). CGE
models appeal to policymakers because of their ability to capture distributional consequences
and identify sectors disproportionately affected by environmental standards. For example, CGE
analyses of the economic consequences of measures to reduce greenhouse gas emissions has
played a key role in understanding the potential economic consequences of policies aimed at
reducing greenhouse gas reductions.
In this study, we develop a CGE model that extends previous work by specifying a
flexible approach to incorporating emissions and pollution abatement processes. More
specifically, we follow a two-step process. The production technology associated with those
sectors producing both good and bad outputs are specified is modeled as a joint production
technology through the use of distance functions. We specify and estimate the joint production
technology as a translog distance function (see Färe et al 1993). The distance function is a multioutput production technology that specifies the technical relationship between good outputs and
bad outputs. Once the distance function is estimated, it can be used to calculate producer
shadow prices for emissions for any point on the production frontier.1 These shadow prices
reflect the opportunity cost (i.e., marginal abatement costs) in terms of foregone revenue to the
producer of reducing emissions by one unit. Using a data set for 1970 through 1996 which
consists of inputs, marketable outputs (“good” outputs), emissions of sulfur dioxide (SO2) and
particulate matter less than ten microns in diameter (PM-10), we estimate the joint production
Throughout this study, the “good” output is the marketed output produced by an industry
and the “bad” outputs are pollutants emitted by an industry.
1
technology for the manufacturing sector. This allows us to establish a joint production
technology based on observed data as opposed to engineering data for each polluting sector. The
important advantage of this approach is that it avoids the problem of modeling pollution
abatement technologies separately from the technologies used to produce the good output. This
is interesting from a policy perspective because in recent years there has been an increasing use
of changes in the production process as opposed to using end-of-pipe abatement technology as a
means of reducing emissions.2 This makes modeling separate pollution abatement technologies
an increasingly difficult task. We demonstrate how to model joint production technologies
within a CGE framework by calculating the least cost policy to reducing air pollutants in the
U.S.
The remainder of this study is organized as follows. Section II reviews previous CGE
analyses of environmental regulation and describes how they modeled emissions and pollution
abatement. Section III briefly outlines the distance function approach to specifying the joint
production technology, while Section IV describes the features of our CGE model of the U.S.
economy. Section V presents the results of our analysis and Section VI presents conclusions.
II.
Modeling Emissions and Pollution Abatement Activities within an Applied General
Studies that estimate the economic effects of environmental regulations typically use
estimates of the pollution abatement costs incurred by the manufacturing and electric utility sectors.
One difficulty associated with these data is measuring “change in production process” capital
expenditures for pollution abatement (i.e., the built-in pollution abatement features of a production
process). These expenditures for pollution abatement have become increasingly important relative
to “end-of-pipe” capital expenditures. For example, “change in production process” as a share of
manufacturing air pollution abatement capital expenditures increased from 17.4 percent in 1973 to
48.3 percent in 1994 (U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1976, p. 47 and 1996, p. 25).
2
-2-
Equilibrium Framework: Review of the Literature
The first efforts to incorporate emissions and pollution abatement activities into general
equilibrium models were primarily theoretical. Ayres and Kneese (1969) represents the first
effort to incorporate emissions and abatement activities into a theoretical general equilibrium
framework. Empirical work on this topic originates in the input-output literature (see Leontief,
1970). Pearson (1989) surveyed environmental applications of input-output analysis and
Hafkamp (1991) surveyed studies incorporating emissions into economic models.
One class of CGE models introduces bad outputs by modeling them as a constant
proportion of the good output (see Robinson (1990), Robinson, Subramanian, and Geoghegan
(1993), Goulder (1994), Smith and Espinosa (1996), and Lee and Roland-Holst (1997)). As a
result, this approach requires either fixed input-output coefficients or it does not allow for fuel
combustion emissions. Hence, for a given level of production of the good output, it does not
allow for substituting away from fuel consumption toward capital may reduce emissions. If
input-output coefficients are not fixed, modeling emissions as a constant proportion of good
output within the CGE framework implicitly assumes all emissions are “process” emissions for
which no abatement technologies exist.3 Thus, this approach fails to allow for the possibility that
industry may respond to environmental regulations by installing equipment that reduces the
production of the bad output per unit of production of the good output (i.e., produce fewer
emissions per unit of its marketed output). As a result, the only available abatement strategy is
to reduce production of the good output.
For a CGE analysis of Costa Rica, Dessus and Bussolo (1998) link emissions to the
3
Manufacturing emissions are produced by either fuel combustion or processes.
-3-
consumption of polluting inputs. This specification allowed for the substitution of nonpolluting
inputs for polluting inputs. This is analogous to how CO2 emissions are modeled.
Two approaches have been employed to model pollution abatement activities within a
CGE framework.4 The first approach models pollution abatement activities separrately from the
technology associated with the production of the good output. Bergman (1991) developed a
CGE model that specified increasing marginal abatement costs for CO2 emissions. His strategy
was followed by Conrad and Schröder (1991a, 1991b, 1993, 1994). Robinson, Subramanian, and
Geoghegan (1994) assume fixed coefficient production functions for the abatement technologies
with identical marginal abatement costs across sectors. Dellink (2000) and Dellink et al (2002)
extended Bergman’s approach by calibrating a pollution abatement function. For a CGE
analysis of China, Xie and Saltzman (2000) assume production of the bad output is directly
linked with production of the good output; and abatement activities are modeled separately from
production of the good output. For a CGE analysis of India, Nugent and Sarma (2002) also
model the production of the good output and associated generation of bad outputs separately
from pollution abatement activities.
The second approach used to model pollution abatement activities involves modeling
pollution control costs, but excludes explicitly modeling the generation and abatement
emissions. Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1990a and 1990b) assume that an industry's production
function for pollution abatement directly mirrors the production function for its good output, or
equivalently, is represented in the economy as a Hicks-neutral cost increase (see Wilcoxen,
Some of these efforts rely on engineering estimates of alternative production technologies
rather than actual data; while others invoke important assumptions regarding pollution abatement
processes.
4
-4-
1988, p. 35). Hazilla and Kopp (1990) invoke a similar assumption. Ballard and Medema
(1993) assumed that pollution abatement activities involve only purchases of capital and labor.
Nestor and Pasurka (1995b) use detailed data on the specific inputs used for pollution abatement,
and attempt a more accurate modeling of the general equilibrium effects of pollution abatement
activities in Germany. In addition, Nestor and Pasurka (1995a) investigated the consequences of
difference assumptions about the inputs employed by the abatement technology. This approach
has been primarily used in ex post facto analyses of regulations.
While the approaches to modeling pollution abatement processes separately are varied,
increasingly they must confront the issues associated with the fact that an increasing share of
pollution abatement activities are not “end-of-pipe.” This makes modeling a separate pollution
abatement function an ever more difficult problem. In addition, survey estimates of the costs
associated with pollution abatement activities are also subject to increasing scrutiny. Even when
pollution abatement activities are end-of-pipe, Färe, Grosskopf, and Pasurka (2002) found
substantial differences between survey (i.e., accounting) estimates of pollution abatement
operation and maintenance (O&M) costs and the opportunity costs of pollution abatement
activities that are derived from modeling the joint production of good and bad outputs. This
study proposes a way of avoiding this problem by specifying a more flexible approach to
modeling pollution abatement within a CGE framework, one that treats the problem as an issue
of the joint production of good and bad outputs. The following section describes the approach
specified in this study to model pollution generation and abatement activities.
III.
Joint Production Model and Pollution Abatement Activities
For those industries that produce at least two outputs (one good and one bad), it is not
-5-
possible to specify a traditional production function. Instead, distance functions and directional
distance functions have been used to specify both the non-parametric and the parametric
production technologies. In this study we calibrate the joint production technology by
estimating a translog (i.e., parametric) distance function and then using those results to calibrate
the CGE model.
There are several advantages of modeling the joint production of good and bad outputs.
One advantage is that it does not require information on pollution abatement technologies and
their associated costs. Hence, there is no need to estimate the inputs associated with a particular
pollution abatement activity nor is it necessary to estimate the quantity of emissions abated as a
consequence of that pollution abatement activity. Instead, the cost of pollution abatement
activities is captured by the reduced production of the good output that occurs as a result of
inputs being reallocated to pollution abatement activities. Another advantage of modeling the
joint production of good and bad outputs is that it avoids the difficulties encountered by survey
efforts to measure the costs associated with “change in production process” pollution abatement
techniques. In the joint production model, the synergies in the abatement process of two or more
pollutants are automatically handled by the production technology. Pollution abatement
functions require information on the synergies that exist among various pollution abatement
processes. Finally, the distance function methodology estimates the joint production technology
and associated producer shadow prices based on the actual behavior producers and not on
engineering estimates.5
Kolstad and Turnovsky (1998, p.445, footnote #1) expressed concern that the endogenity
and simultaneous equation bias problems associated with the econometric estimation of production
functions also apply to the LP estimation of distance functions. However, such biases may not be
5
-6-
There are two approaches to modeling the joint production of good and bad outputs. One
approach assumes a non-parametric piece-wise linear production technology (see Färe,
Grosskopf, and Pasurka (1986 and 1989)). The joint production framework was first used by
Kohn (1975, pp. 29-37) to investigate the costs of pollution abatement activities. Brännlund, et
al. (1998) specified a non-parametric distance function (i.e., an activity analysis) within a partial
equilibrium framework in order to estimate the cost savings associated with an emissions trading
program. Willett (1985) had already specified a theoretical general equilibrium model that
incorporated emissions into the CGE model by using an activity analysis specification of the
production technology. Using a CGE model, Komen and Peerlings (2001) specified input-output
vectors representing three technologies (two active and one latent) that are available to the dairy
farming sector representing different mixes of good and bad outputs.
Figure 1 illustrates the simplified case where the production process generates one good
output (Q) and one bad output (e) from a vector of inputs. When using an activity analysis
framework, a finite number of production processes exist for a given vector of inputs. Each
process is represented by a ray from the origin that represents different combinations of good
and bad outputs which can be produced by a given technology. In Figure 1, three processes (T1,
T2, and T3) are available to the producer. Steeper rays (e.g., T1) represent production
technologies that allocate relatively more inputs to pollution abatement activities, while a
relatively flat ray (e.g., T2) represents a production technology with fewer inputs devoted to
as significant as previously believed. For example, Coelli (2000) provides evidence that the
simultaneous equation bias associated with the OLS estimation of production functions may notbe
as severe as previously believed and Coelli and Cuesta (2001) provide evidence that the
simultaneous equations bias of the econometric estimation of distance functions is no worse than
the bias associated with estimation of production functions in general.
-7-
pollution abatement activities. Once the vector of inputs is known, it is possible to determine the
combination of good and bad outputs that a process can produce (i.e., points a, b, c).
The points on the frontier represent the different combinations of good and bad outputs
that can be produced with a given vector of inputs. It is possible to construct linear combinations
of the different production processes. For the case of one good output, one bad output, and a
single input, the production unit will use the two processes to efficiently produce a given
combination of good and bad outputs. In Figure 1, process T1 can be used to produce bundle
represented by point x and process T2 can be used to produce bundle represented by point y.
Combining these two output bundles yields point z on ray ab (adopted from Kohn, 1975).
In our model, emissions decrease as inputs are shifted from production of the good output
to pollution abatement activities. The “output” of the pollution abatement activities is the
reduced production of the bad output (i.e., emissions) for a given vector of inputs. In Figure 1,
the line segments labeled 0abc represent the economically relevant portion of the piece-wise
linear production-possibilities frontier consisting of the good and bad outputs. A consequence
and limitation of specifying an activity analysis framework is that the production possibility
frontier for the good and bad outputs is piece-wise linear.
A second approach used to model the joint production of good and bad outputs specifies
a parametric production technology. Most empirical studies that specify a parametric distance
function have used a translog function (see Färe et al., 1993); however, recently a quadratic
production technology was specified (see Färe, Grosskopf, and Weber 2001) . The advantage of
specifying a translog distance function is that the production frontier is smooth.
While McKitrick (1998) and Perroni and Rutherford (1998) discuss the merits of
-8-
different functional forms used in CGE models with good outputs, there is no comparable
discussion regarding the proper modeling of the joint production of good and bad outputs within
a CGE framework. Perroni and Rutherford (1995) describe an n input production technology
can be approximated by a nonseparable nested constant elesticity of substitution (NNCES)
functional form.6 Perroni (1999) extends Perroni and Rutherford (1995) by describing an m
output n input production technology can be approximated by a NNCES / constant elasticity of
transformation (CET) restricted profit function. Jensen, Kristensen, and Nielsen (1999)
estimated a multiple good output NNCES cost function. However, there has been no
investigation of the feasibility of extending the NNCES technology to the case of the joint
production of good and bad outputs.
We specify a parametric translog distance function in order to obtain parameter estimates
for those industries that produce good and bad outputs (see Färe et al., 1993, for a detailed
discussion of the application of distance functions to model good and bad outputs). In particular,
we consider a production unit that produces outputs Q = (Q1, Q2, ..., Qm) using inputs X = (X1,
X2, ..., Xn) at each period of time t = 1, ..., T. Of the outputs, i = 1, ..., k represent emissions (bad
outputs) while i = k+1, ..., m represent good outputs. We assume weak disposability of outputs
and constant returns to scale. Thus, the technology is represented as an output distance
function:7
Do(X, Q) = min ω:
ω
(1)
Q
0 G(X)
ω
Rutherford (1995) provides insights into calibrating an NNCES function.
6
See Shephard (1970) or Färe (1988)
7
-9-
where G(X) is the set of technically feasible output vectors that employ input vector X and Q 0
G(X) when Do(X, Q) # 1. The output distance function measures the greatest possible radial
expansion of output bundle Q to the production possibilities frontier for a given input bundle X.
When Do(X, Q) = 1, the producer is maximizing the production of the good and bad outputs for
a given level of inputs. Hence, the producer is technically efficient. When Do(X, Q) < 1, then the
producer is producing “inside the frontier,” or is technically inefficient. One advantage to using
the output distance function as opposed to a production function representation of technology is
that it easily models the joint production of multiple outputs.
The duality between the output distance function and the revenue function allows the
derivation of producer shadow prices for the bad outputs. Since the distance function is
equivalent to the revenue function at the revenue maximizing output price vector, applying
Shephard's dual lemma yields revenue deflated (i.e., normalized) output shadow prices (P*) as
follows
(2)
MDo(X, Q)
MQi
(
= Pi (X, Q), i = 1, ..., m
The undeflated (i.e., absolute) shadow prices (P) can be expressed as the product of the
revenue function and the deflated shadow price (P*). Hence, when the revenue function is
known, P can be computed. The difficulty in computing P is the revenue function depends on P,
which are unknown. However, if we assume the observed price for the good output is equal to
its undeflated shadow price, then the revenue function is the ratio of its undeflated and deflated
shadow prices. It is assumed that the undeflated shadow price of Qm, which represents a good
-10-
output, is equal to its observed market price (Pm).8 The remaining undeflated shadow prices (P1,
P2, ..., Pm-1) are calculated
(3) Pi =
Pm
(
Pm (X, Q)
(
Pi (X, Q) = Pm
MDo(X, Q)/MQi
MDo(X, Q)/MQm
, i = 1, ..., m-1
Equation (3) states the undeflated shadow price of an bad output equals/is the product of the
actual product of the price of the good output (Pm) and the marginal rate of transformation
(MRT). The MRT is the quantity of the good output that must be foregone in order to reduce the
quantity of an bad output by one unit. The undeflated shadow price of an bad output is negative,
which reflects the opportunity cost (i.e., in terms of foregone revenue) of reducing production of
the bad output.
According to equation (3), the absolute shadow price of the bad output for an inefficient
producer is determined by making a radial projection to the production possibilities frontier from
the observation.9 The shadow prices of the bad outputs associated with that observation are
calculated at that point on the frontier. Hence, the absolute shadow price reflects the actual
proportions of good and bad outputs produced by an inefficient producer.
Figure 2 provides a representation of these concepts for the case of the production of one
good output (Q2) and one bad output (Q1). Figure 2 illustrates that the firm cannot decrease
production of Q1 without decreasing Q2, and that technology satisfies weak disposability. The
To the extent that markets are not perfectly competitive, or there are subsidies or taxes, the
assumption that the price of the good output equals its shadow price is inaccurate.
8
The radial projection assumes a proportional expansion of all good and bad outputs for a
given input vector until the production possibilities frontier is attained.
9
-11-
output distance function measures the proportion by which both Q1 and Q2 can be increased with
the original input vector, while using the original production process (i.e., this radial projection
maintains the initial ratio of the good to bad outputs). For the combination of output depicted by
point a, the value is given by the ratio 0a/0b. Figure 2 illustrates the condition for optimality, or
that the ratio of the output prices P1 and P2 must equal the slope of the distance frontier. This
condition holds even if an observation is inefficient, so the methodology for assigning shadow
prices is not sensitive to the existence of technical inefficiency.
For purposes of estimating the shadow prices, we follow Färe et al. (1993) and specify a
translog output distance function. For a panel consisting of s=1,. . ., S industries observed over
t=1,. . ., T years the distance function has the form:
ln Do (X s,t, Q s,t) = α0 + j βjlnXj
n
t
s,t
j=1
n
m
1
1
s,t
s,t
s,t
s,t
s,t
+ j j ωii´lnQi lnQi´ + j j φijlnXj lnQi + νtt + νttt 2 + j βjttlnXj
2 i=1 i=1
2
´
i=1 j=1
j=1
m
(4)
1
s,t
s,t
s,t
j j βjj´lnXj lnXj´ + j ωilnQi
2 j=1 j=1
´
i=1
n
+
m
m
+ j ωittlnQi
m
i=1
s,t
+ j τkDIk ,
n
n
s
s'1,...,S; t'1,...,T.
k=1
where X1, X2, X3, represent capital, labor and an aggregate intermediate input, respectively. Q1,
Q2, Q3, represent production of the good output, PM-10 emissions and SO2 emissions,
respectively. Finally, the industry dummy variables, DIs, capture industry-specific effects and t
is a time trend variable. Since a single distance function is estimated, input and output
substitution possibilities are constant over time and across industries.
We estimate (11) as a linear programming (LP) problem. Specifically, for observations t
= 1, ..., T, and s = 1,..., S, we maximize:
-12-
s,t
s,t
j ln Do (X , Q )
T
(5)
t
t=1
subject to the following constraints:
t
(6i) ln Do (X s,t, Q s,t) # 0,
s ' 1,...,S;
t ' 1,...,T
t
(6ii)
Mln Do (X s,t, Q s,t)
s,t
Mln Qi
# 0, i = 1, ..., k; s = 1,...,S; t = 1,...,T
s,t
(6iii)
Mln Do (X t, Q s,t)
s,t
Mln Qi
$ 0, i = k+1, ...m; s = 1,...,S; t = 1,...,T
s,t
(6iv)
Mln Do (X t, Q s,t)
s,t
Mln Xj
# 0, j = 1, ...n; s = 1,...,S; t = 1,...,T
(6v) j ωi = 1, j ωii ) = j βij = j ωit = 0, i=1,...,m; j=1,...,n; t = 1,...,T
(6vi)
m
m
m
m
i=1
i=1
i=1
i=1
βjj ) = βj )j , j ' 1,...,n, j ) ' 1,...,n
ωii ) = ωi )i , i ' 1,...,m, i ) ' 1,...,m
The first constraint forces observations to fall on or within the production frontier.
Constraint (6ii) restricts the shadow prices of the bad outputs must be non-positive while
constraint (6iii) restricts the shadow prices of the good outputs to be nonnegative.
The constraints in (6iv) impose monotonicity on each input for all observations. Because the
output distance function exhibits monotonicity when it is non-increasing in the inputs, for fixed
quantities of the good and bad outputs, more inputs decreases the value of the distance function
-13-
(i.e., decreases technical efficiency). The constraints in (6v) impose homogeneity of +1 in the
outputs. This assures that as outputs expand proportionately for a given input vector and
technology, the value of the distance function increases in the same proportion. This ensures the
outputs are weakly disposable. The constraints in (6vi) impose the usual symmetry conditions.
The specification of (4) allows for neutral and biased technical change. The effect of neutral
technical change is captured by the νt and νtt parameters. The extent of biased technical change
is estimated by the βjt parameters, and the effect of changes in output (i.e., scale augmenting
technical change) is estimated by the ωit parameters.
In the next section, we specify a simple CGE model of the United States.
IV.
The CGE Model
In many respects, our model is a standard CGE model of an open economy.10 The United
States is assumed to be a small country and there is a flexible exchange rate. We use the
standard Armington assumption that imports are imperfect substitutes in both production and
consumption. Elasticities of primary factor substitution and elasticities between domestic and
imported goods are constructed on the basis of the elasticities presented in Harrison, Rutherford,
and Wooton (1991). The economy is comprised of producing sectors, a household sector,
government, and a foreign sector. All markets operate under conditions of perfect competition.
Given income from the sale of capital and labor, households choose a consumption
bundle consisting of foreign and domestically produced good output and maximize utility subject
to a budget constraint. We assume that environmental quality does not enter the representative
10
The details of the formal model and data sources are provided in an appendix available upon
request from the authors.
-14-
household's utility function. The allows us to avoid issues involved with incorporating the
benefits of pollution abatement activities into the model.
Nested Cobb-Douglas and CES functions are specified for the energy, materials, and
services components of the estimated KLEMS production technology for each sector of the
economy. Wilcoxen (1988, pp. 122-123) discusses which intermediate input industries are
contained in the energy and materials components of the KLEM model specified in his study.
The energy, materials, and services sectors consist of nested Cobb-Douglas and CES functions.
For non-polluting sectors, production is represented as a hierarchy of Cobb-Douglas and
CES production functions. The distinguishing feature of our CGE model is calibrating distance
functions to model the joint production of good and bad outputs. As with Willett (1985), we
specify a model in which each polluting sector has available a production technology that allows
different combinations of good and bad outputs to be produced by a given vector of inputs.
However, Willett assumed a piece-wise linear production technology in which difference
processes are represented by different coefficients associated with the inputs and outputs. In this
study, we employ a translog distance function in order to accomplish the same effect.
In addition to modifying the production technology, a separate constraint establishes
limits on production of the bad output whose production is regulated. These constraints show
the maximum amount of the bad output that the economy is allowed to produce. Initial
ownership of permits can be established by either grandfathering ownership of the permits or
allowing the government to auction the permits to polluters and then distribute the revenues to
the representative household as a lump-sum transfer.
V. Data and Results
-15-
In order to provide greater flexibility in our specification of the joint production
technology, we specify and estimate a translog distance function for nineteen two-digit SIC
manufacturing industries using data from 1970 to 1996.11 Aiken and Pasurka (2002) estimated
translog distance functions with two bad outputs (SO2 and PM-10) and three inputs: capital,
labor, and an aggregate intermediate input. In this study, we estimate a translog distance
function with two bad outputs (SO2 and PM-10) and the three inputs: capital, labor, and an
aggregate intermediate input consisting of energy, materials, and services. A translog distance
function is estimated using panel data for nineteen of the twenty two-digit SIC manufacturing
industries for 1970 to 1996. The parameters of translog distance function are used to calibrate
the joint production technology of those industries producing good and bad outputs in the CGE
model.
Aiken and Pasurka (2002) discuss the estimation of the translog distance function in greater
detail.
The 1992 benchmark input-output table and the associated SO2 and PM-10 emissions
serve as the basis of the CGE model calibrated in this study. For sectors that emit SO2 and PM10, translog production technologies are specified. Non-polluting sectors are assumed to
produce the good output using nested Cobb-Douglas and CES production functions as described
above. In the simulations, it is assumed that ownership of the permits to pollute are given to the
representative household which sells the permits to the polluting sectors. An alternative
distribution of the permits is to grandfather ownership of the permits based on observed level of
There are actually twenty two-digit SIC manufacturing industries; however, the U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) does not publish productivity data for SIC 21 (tobacco products).
11
-16-
emissions. The industries would then be allowed to buy and sell the permits among themselves.
Since there is no connection between emissions and consumer welfare, there households have no
demand function for the permits.
Table 2 presents the results.12
VI. Summary and Directions for Future Research
The study represents an initial investigation into the feasibility of modeling the joint
production of good and bad outputs within a CGE framework. The translog distance function
specification provides flexibility in modeling the production technologies while avoiding the
somewhat arbitrary nature of specifications of the production technology employed by previous
studies. As an increasing percentage of pollution abatement efforts involve change in
production processes, the advantages associated with specifying a joint production model in
order to depict the production technology for a sector becomes apparent.
In order to provide insights into the consequences of specifying an alternative production
technology, we could estimate the least cost solution when we assume a fixed bad-good output
ratios for all polluting sectors and a CES production technology for all sectors are employed to
determine the least cost results. The results of this simulation is representative of previous
modeling efforts and provides a means of comparing the results of the model employed in this
study with an alternative specification of the joint production technology.
The joint production modeling approach allows us to undertake a retrospective study of
the cost of environmental regulations without using survey estimates of pollution abatement
costs. We accomplish this by solving the model under the assumption “bad” outputs are freely
12
We solve the model using GAMS (see Rutherford 1999).
-17-
disposable. We calculate the cost of environmental regulations in terms of the reduction in the
level of the “good” output. In addition, we use the model to compare that cost with the good
output lost due to the allocative inefficiency of environmental regulations. Allocative
inefficiency is the increased cost of attaining a given level of emissions using a command and
control strategy instead of a least cost strategy (i.e., through permits). This provides an estimate
of the percentage reduction in pollution abatement costs that can be achieved simply by pursing
a least-cost strategy.
This study demonstrates pollution abatement activities and emissions can be incorporated
into a CGE model. In fact, the joint production of good and bad outputs has been specified in
CGE models such as Jensen and Rasmussen (2000) to estimate the costs associated with
proposed reductions in CO2 emissions. The treatment of CO2 emissions in CGE models are
revealed to be a special case of the more general model specified in this study.
Incorporating a translog parametric distance function that represents the joint production
technology presents problems for the solution of CGE models. Unfortunately, solutions to CGE
models with translog distance functions are not guaranteed. In order to make this approach
practical, it will be necessary to determine which parametric specification of the production
function will be well behaved and will allow CGE models to converge to meaningful results.
One possible solution to the convergence problem is extending Peronni (1999) to develop
nonseparable nested CES (NNCES) functions for the case when multiple outputs includes good
and bad outputs. This would allow GAMS/MPSGE to solve the joint production CGE model
developed in this study.
-18-
References
Abdelkhalek, Touhami and Jean-Marie Dufour (1998), “Statistical Inference for Computable
General Equilibrium Models, with Application to a Model of the Moroccan Economy,” Review
of Economics and Statistics, 80, No. 4 (November), 520-534.
Aiken, Deborah Vaughn and Carl Pasurka (2002), “Adjusting the Measurement of U.S.
Manufacturing Productivity for Air Pollution Emissions Control,” mimeo.
Atkins, Liwayway G. And Richard F. Garbaccio (1999), “A Bibliography of CGE Models
Applied to Environmental Issues,” mimeo, http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/cbg/ptep/cge.bib.2e.pdf
Ayres, Robert and Allen Kneese (1969), “Production, Consumption, and Externalities,”
American Economic Review, 59, No. 3 (June), 282-297.
Ballard, Charles and Steven G. Medima (1993), “The Marginal Efficiency of Taxes and
Subsidies in the Presence of Externalities: A Computable General Equilibrium Approach,”
Journal of Public Economics, 52, No. 2, 199-216,
Baumol, William and Ed Wolff (1994), “A Key Role for Input-Output Analysis in Policy
Design,” Regional Science and Urban Economics, 24, No. 1 (February), 93-113.
Bergman, Lars (1990), “Energy and Environmental Constraints on Growth,” Journal of Policy
Modeling, 12, 671-691.
Bergman, Lars (1991), “General Equilibrium Effects of Environmental Policy: A CGE-Modeling
Approach,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 1, No.1, 43-62.
Brännlund, Runar, Yangho Chung, Rolf Färe, and Shawna Grosskopf (1998), “Emissions
Trading and Profitability: The Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry,” Environmental and Resource
Economics, 13, 245-356.
Coelli, Tim (2000), “On the Econometric Estimation of the Distance Function Representation of
a Production Technology,” Working Paper, Center for Operations Research and Econometrics
(http://www.core.ucl.ac.be/services/psfiles/dp00/dp2000-42.pdf).
Coelli, Tim and Rafael A. Cuesta (2001), “Simultaneous Equation Bias in Production Function
Estimation: A Monte Carlo Investigation,” Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis,
Working Paper No. 5/2001, University of New England
(http://www.une.edu.au/febl/EconStud/emet/cepawp.htm)
Conrad, Klaus (1999), “Computable General Equilibrium Models for Environmental Economics
-19-
and Policy Analysis,” in Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, pp. 1060-1088,
ed. Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh, Edward Elgar Publishers, Northampton, MA.
Conrad, Klaus (2002), “Computable General Equilibrium Models in Environmental and
Resource Economics,” in Macroeconomics and the Environment, 601-01, ed. Mohan
Munasinghe, Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc., Northhampton, MA. CONRAD-601.PDF.
Conrad, Klaus and Michael Schröder (1991a), “An Evaluation of Taxes on Air Pollutant
Emissions: An Applied General Equilibrium Approach,” Swiss Journal of Economics and
Statistics, 127, No. 2, 199-224.
Conrad, Klaus and Michael Schröder (1991b), “The Control of CO2 Emissions and Its Economic
Impact: An AGE Model for a German State,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 1, 289312.
Conrad, Klaus and Michael Schröder (1993), “Choosing Environmental Policy Instruments
Using General Equilibrium Models,” Journal of Policy Modeling, 15, No. 5/6 (OctoberDecember), 521-543.
Conrad, Klaus and Michael Schröder (1994), “Environmental Policy Instruments for Controlling
Air Pollution: An Applied General Equilibrium Modeling Approach for Quantifying their
Efficiency and Effectiveness,” in Economic Incentives and Environmental Policies: Principles
and Practice, pp. 129-151, eds. J.B. Opschoor and R.K. Turner, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
Boston.
Dellink, Rob (2000), “Dynamics in an Applied General Equilibrium Model with Pollution and
Abatement,” for Global Economic Analysis Conference in Melbourne, Australia
http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/conf/5Dellink.pdf
Dellink, Rob, Marjan Hofkes, Ekko van Ierland and Harmen Verbruggen (2002), “Dynamic
Modelling of Pollution Abatement in a CGE Framework,” presented at the Second World
Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Monterey, CA., June.
http://weber.ucsd.edu/~carsonvs/papers/596.doc
Dessus, Sébastien and Maurizio Bussolo (1998), “Is There a Trade-Off Between Trade
Liberalization and Pollution Abatement? A Computable General Equilibrium Assessment
Applied to Costa Rica,” Journal of Policy Modeling, 20, No.1 (February),11-31.
Dufournaud, Christian M., Joseph J. Harrington, and Peter P. Rogers (1988), “Leontief’s
Environmental Repercussions and the Economic Structure... Revisited: A General Equilibrium
Formulation,” Geographical Analysis, 20, No. 4 (October), 318-327.
Espinosa, J. Andrès and V. Kerry Smith (1995), “Measuring the Environmental Consequences
of Trade Policies: A Nonmarket CGE Analysis,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
-20-
77, No. 3 (August), 772-777.
Färe, Rolf (1988), Fundamentals of Production Theory, Lecture Notes in Economics and
Mathematical Systems, vol. 311, Springer-Verlag: Heidelberg.
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, and Carl Pasurka (1986), “Effects on Relative Efficiency in
Electric Power Generation Due to Environmental Controls,” Resources and Energy, Vol. 8, No.
2, (June 1986), 167-184.
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, C.A. Knox Lovell, and Carl Pasurka (1989), “Multilateral
Productivity Comparisons When Some Outputs are Undesirable: A Nonparametric Approach”
Review of Economics and Statistics, LXXI, No. 1 (February), 90-98.
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, C.A. Knox Lovell, and Suthathip Yaisawarng (1993),
“Derivation of Shadow Prices for Undesirable Outputs: A Distance function Approach,” Review
of Economics and Statistics, 75, No. 2 (May), 374-380.
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, and Carl Pasurka (2002), “Estimating Pollution Abatement
Costs: A Comparison of ‘Stated’ and ‘Revealed’ Approaches,” presented at the Second World
Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Monterey, CA., June 25, 2002.
http://weber.ucsd.edu/~carsonvs/papers/391.pdf
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, and William Weber (2001), “Shadow Prices and Pollution Costs
in U.S. Agriculture,” presented at the Second World Congress of Environmental and Resource
Economists, Monterey, CA., June 27, 2002.
http://weber.ucsd.edu/~carsonvs/papers/105.doc
Goulder, Lawrence H. (1994) “Energy Taxes: Traditional Efficiency Effects and Environmental
Implications,” in Tax Policy and the Economy 8, ed. James M. Poterba, pp. 105-158, Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press
Hafkamp, Wim (1991), “A Three Decades of Environmental-Economic Modelling: Economic
Models of Pollutant Emissions,” in Environmental Policy and the Economy, Contributions to
Economic Analysis: 206, eds. Frank Dietz, Fredrick van der Ploeg, and Jan van der Straaten,pp.
19-45, North Holland: New York.
Hazilla, Michael and Raymond Kopp (1990), “Social Cost of Environmental Quality Regulation:
A General Equilibrium Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, 98, No. 4, 853-873.
Jensen, Jesper and Tobias N. Rasmussen (2000), “Allocation of CO2 Emissions Permits: A
General Equilibrium Analysis of Policy Instruments,” Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 40, No. 2 (September), 111-136.
-21-
Jensen, Jørgen, Knud Kristensen, and Connie Nielsen (1999), “Estimating Behavioral
Parameters for CGE-Models: Using Micro-Econometrically Estimated Flexible Functional
Forms,” Working Paper No. 22, Danish Institute of Agricultural and Fisheries Economics,
http://www.sjfi.dk/wp/wp199922.pdf
Jorgenson, Dale and Peter Wilcoxen (1990a), “Environmental Regulations and U.S. Economic
Growth,” Rand Economic Journal, 21, No. 2 (Summer), 314-340.
Jorgenson, Dale and Peter Wilcoxen (1990b), “Intertemporal General Equilibrium Modeling of
U.S. Environmental Regulation,” Journal of Policy Modeling, 12, No. 4, 715-744.
Jorgenson, Dale and Peter Wilcoxen (1993), “The Economic Impact of the Clean Air Act
Amendments of 1990,” The Energy Journal, 14, No. 1, 159-182.
Kohn, Robert E. (1975), Air Pollution Control: A Welfare Economic Interpretation, Lexington
Books, D.C. Heath and Company: Lexington, MA.
Kohn, Robert (1978), A Linear Programming Model for Air Pollution Control, The MIT Press:
Cambridge, MA.
Kolstad, Charles D. and Michelle H.L. Turnovsky (1998), “Cost Functions and Nonlinear
Process: Estimating a Technology with Quality-Differentiated Inputs,” Review of Economics and
Statistics, 80, No. 3 (August) 444-453.
Komen, Marinus H.C. and Jack H.M. Peerlings (2001), “Endogenous Technological Switches in
Dutch Dairy Farming under Environmental Restrictions,” European Review of Agricultural
Economics, 28, No. 2 (June), 117-142.
Kopp, Raymond J. and V. Kerry Smith (1981), “Productivity Measurement and Environmental
Regulation: An Engineering-Econometric Analysis,” in Productivity Measurement in Regulated
Industries, eds. Thomas G. Cowing and Rodney E. Stevenson, New York: Academic Press, pp.
249-281.
Lee, H. and D. Roland-Holst (1997), “The Environment and Welfare Implications of Trade and
Tax Policy,” Journal of Development Economics, 52, No. 1 (February), 65-82.
Leontief, Wassily (1970), “Environmental Repercussions and the Economic Structure: An InputOutput Approach,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 52, No. 3 (August), 262-271.
Lowe, Peter D. (1979), “Pricing Problems in an Input-Output Approach to Environmental
Protection,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 61, No. 1 (February), 110-117.
Luptacik, Mikulas and Bernhard Böhm (1999), “A Consistent Formulation of the Leontief
Pollution Model,”, Economic Systems Research, 11, No. 3, S. 263-275.
-22-
McKitrick, Ross R. (1998), “The Econometric Critique of Computable General Equilibrium
Modeling: The Role of Functional Forms,” Economic Modelling, 15, No. 4 (October), 543-573.
Nestor, Deborah Vaughn and Carl A. Pasurka Jr. (1995a), “Alternative Specifications for
Environmental Control Costs in a General Equilibrium Framework,” Economics Letters, 48, No.
3/4 (June), 273-280.
Nestor, Deborah Vaughn and Carl A. Pasurka, Jr. (1995b), “CGE Model of Pollution Abatement
Processes for Assessing the Economic Effects of Environmental Policy,” Economic Modelling,
12, No. 1, 53-59.
Nestor, Deborah Vaughn and Carl A. Pasurka, Jr. (1995c), “Environment-Economic Accounting
and Indicators of the Economic Importance of Environmental Protection Activities,” Review of
Income and Wealth, 41, No. 3 (September), 265-287.
Nugent, Jeffrey B. and C.V.S.K. Sarma (2002), “The Three E's– Efficiency, Equity, and
Environmental Protection – in Search of "Win-Win-Win" Policies: A CGE Analysis of India,”
Journal of Policy Modeling, 24, No. 1 (March), 19-50.
Pasurka Jr., Carl A. (2001), “Technical Change and Measuring Pollution Abatement Costs: An
Activity Analysis Framework,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 18, No. 1 (January),
61-85.
Pearson, P.J.G (1989), “Proactive Energy-Environment Policy Strategies: A Role for InputOutput Analysis?” Environment and Planning A, 21, No. 10 (October), 1329-1348.
Perroni, Carlo (1999), “A Flexible, Globally Regular Representation of Convex Production
Possibilities Frontiers,” Journal of Productivity Analysis, 12, No. 2 (September), 153-159.
Perroni, Carlo and Thomas F. Rutherford (1995), “Regular Flexibility of Nested CES
Functions,” European Economic Review, 39, No. 2 (February), 335-343.
Perroni, Carlo and Thomas F. Rutherford (1998), “A Comparison of the Performance of Flexible
Functional Forms for Use in Applied General Equilibrium Analysis,” Computational Economics,
11, No. 3 (June), 245-263.
Robinson, Sherman (1990), “Pollution, Market Failure, and Optimal Policy in an Economy
Wide Framework,” University of California at Berkeley, Department of Agricultural and
Resource Economics Working paper: 559, December, pages 17.
Robinson, Sherman, Shankar Subramanian, and Jacqueline Geoghegan (1993), “Regional,
Environmental, Computable General Equilibrium Model of the Los Angeles Basin,” University
of California at Berkeley, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Working paper:
-23-
646, April, pages 22.
Robinson, Sherman, Shankar Subramanian, and Jacqueline Geoghegan (1994), “Modeling Air
Pollution Abatement in a Market-Based Incentive Framework for the Los Angeles Basin,” in
Economic Instruments for Air Pollution Control, pp. 46-72, eds. Ger Klaassen and Finn R.
Førsund, Vol. 9, Economy and Environment Series, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
Rutherford, Thomas F. (1995), “Constant Elasticity of Substitution Functions: Some Hints and
Useful Formulae,” Notes prepared for GAMS General Equilibrium Workshop held December in
Boulder, Colorado (http://www.gams.com/solvers/mpsge/cesfun.htm).
Rutherford, Thomas F. (1999), “Applied General Equilibrium Modeling with MPSGE as a
GAMS Subsystem: An Overview of the Modeling Framework and Syntax,” Computational
Economics, 14, No. 1/2 (October),1-46.
Salvanes, Kjell G. and Sigve Tjøtta (1998), “A Note on the Importance of Testing for
Regularities for Estimated Flexible Functional Forms,” Journal of Productivity Analysis, 9, No.2
(March), 133-143.
Shephard, Ronald W. (1970), Theory of Cost and Production Functions, Princeton University
Press: Princeton, NJ.
Shortle, James and Keith Willett (1986), “The Incidence of Water Pollution Control Costs:
Partial vs. General Equilibrium Computations,” Growth and Change, 17, No. 2 (April), 32-43.
Smith, V. Kerry and J. Andrès Espinosa (1996), “Environmental and Trade Policies: Some
Methodological Lessons,” Environment and Development Economics, 1, 19-40.
Tran, Ngoc-Bich and V. Kerry Smith (1983), “The Role of Air and Water Residuals for Steam
Electric Power Generation,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 10, No. 1
(March), 18-34.
U.S. Bureau of the Census (1976), Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures: 1973, Current
Industrial Reports, MA200, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Bureau of the Census (1996), Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures: 1994, Current
Industrial Reports, MA200, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
(http://www.census.gov/prod/2/manmin/ma200x94.pdf)
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2001), Statistical Methodology for Assigning Emissions
to Industries in the United States, Revised Estimates: 1970 to 1997, EPA-240-R-01-003.
(Available under the Report Inventory at http://www.epa.gov/economics or go directly to
http://yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eermfile.nsf/vwAN/EE-0435A-01.pdf/$File/EE-0435A-01.pdf
-24-
Wilcoxen, Peter Jensen (1988), “The Effects of Environmental Regulation and Energy Prices On
U.S. Economic Performance,” A Thesis, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Willett, Keith (1985), “Environmental Quality Standards: A General Equilibrium Analysis,”
Managerial and Decision Economics, 6, 41-49.
Xie, Jian and Sidney Saltzman (2000), “Environmental Policy Analysis: An Environmental
Computable General Equilibrium Approach for Developing Countries,” Journal of Policy
Modeling, 22, No. 4 (July), 453-489.
-25-
Figure 1
Piece-wise Linear Joint production Technology
e
T1
T2
z
c
b
T3
a
x
y
0
Q
-26-
Figure 2
Shadow Price of Bad Output
-27-