Pamphlet Series
No. 55
Fiscal Adjustment
for Stability and Growth
James Daniel, Jeffrey Davis,
Manal Fouad, and Caroline Van Rijckeghem
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
2006
Pamphlet Series
Fiscal Adjustment
for Stability and Growth
James Daniel, Jeffrey Davis,
Manal Fouad, and Caroline Van Rijckeghem
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
Washington, D.C.
2006
No. 55
ISBN 1-58906-513-1
ISSN 0538-8759
August 2006
Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Fiscal adjustment for stability and growth/James Daniel . . . [et al.] —
Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 2006 — (Pamphlet series;
no. 55)
“Updates and replaces the original 1995 pamphlet, Guidelines for fiscal
adjustment”— Introduction.
Includes bibliographical references.
ISBN 1-58906-513-1
1. Fiscal policy. 2. Economic stabilization. I. Daniel, James, 1967– II. Series:
Pamphlet series (International Monetary Fund) ; no. 55
The views expressed in this pamphlet, including any legal aspects, are those of
the authors and should not be attributed to Executive Directors of the IMF or
their national authorities.
Cover design and typesetting: Multimedia Services Division
Please send orders to:
International Monetary Fund, Publication Services
700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, USA
Tel.: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201
E-mail:
[email protected]
Internet: http://www.imf.org
Contents
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
v
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii
I . When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Fiscal Adjustment for Growth and Poverty Reduction . . . . . . . .
Fiscal Adjustment to Reduce Vulnerability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Fiscal Adjustment for Short-Term Macroeconomic Stability . . .
1
1
4
8
II . How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed? . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Coverage of the Public Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
When to Record Government Transactions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Main Fiscal Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
14
14
16
17
III . What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful? . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Timing and Speed of Adjustment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Size of Fiscal Adjustment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Quality and Durability of Adjustment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
23
23
24
29
IV . How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out? . . . . . . . . . 35
Improving the Tax System and Mobilizing Revenue . . . . . . . . . 35
Rationalizing Public Expenditure and Protecting the Poor . . . . 40
V . What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment? . . . . . . . . . .
Modernizing Revenue Administration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Effective Public Financial Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Effective Intergovernmental Relationships . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
48
48
51
56
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
Boxes
1. Expansionary Fiscal Contractions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
2. Key Differences between the 2001 and 1986 GFSMs . . . . . 15
3. Fiscal Policy and Nonrenewable Resources . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
iii
CONTENTS
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
Civil Service Reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Fiscal Transparency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Dangers of Tax Holidays . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Fundamental Public Expenditure Reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Key Issues in Pension Reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Features of a Dedicated Large Taxpayer Office. . . . . . . . . .
Tracking Poverty-Reducing Spending . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Rebuilding Fiscal Institutions in Post-Conflict Countries . .
iv
31
34
37
41
44
50
54
57
Preface
This pamphlet is the product of a collaborative effort of the staff of
the Fiscal Affairs Department (FAD). In particular, Peter Barrand, Matt
Davies, Robert Gillingham, Michael Keen, Wojciech Maliszewski, Paulo
Medas, and Theo Thomas provided valuable input. Advice and support
from Teresa Ter-Minassian (Director of FAD) is gratefully acknowledged.
The pamphlet also benefited from comments by staff of other departments
within the IMF. Marina Primorac of the External Relations Department
coordinated production of the publication.
v
Introduction
The IMF’s approach to fiscal adjustment focuses on the role that sound
and sustainable government finances play in promoting macroeconomic
stability and growth. Achieving and maintaining such a fiscal position
often requires adjusting fiscal policy, as well as strengthening fiscal institutions. Fiscal adjustment may involve either tightening or loosening the
fiscal stance, depending on each country’s circumstances.1
This paper updates and replaces the original 1995 pamphlet, Guidelines for
Fiscal Adjustment. It reflects the significant changes in the world economy
and in the way the IMF has approached fiscal adjustment since then. The key
changes include globalization, which raises new challenges and opportunities for fiscal policy; the increasing importance of balance sheet variables,
as highlighted by debt and capital account crises; the growing perception of
institutions as key determinants of development success and macroeconomic
stability; and the greater emphasis on helping low-income countries scale up
productive expenditure and make good use of increased aid.
Fiscal policy and adjustment involve many fundamental and complex
issues, about which much has been written and on which debate still flourishes. To be focused and more widely understood, this paper necessarily
simplifies some of these issues. The paper also concentrates on broad topics and practical policy options, rather than on more technical or theoretical aspects, and is selective in the topics it addresses.2 And, while much of
the analysis is relevant for advanced economies, its focus is on emerging
market and low-income economies.
In keeping with this practical emphasis, the paper is organized around
five questions:
• When is fiscal adjustment needed?
• How should the fiscal position be assessed?
• What makes fiscal adjustment successful?
• How should fiscal adjustment be carried out?
• What institutions can help fiscal adjustment?
1This broader definition of fiscal adjustment (compared with common usage equating fiscal adjustment with consolidation) reflects the increased emphasis on situations that warrant
fiscal expansion.
2Only a few references are included in the main text. The bibliography section provides
a fuller listing.
vii
I .
When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
Governments are necessarily continuing concerns. They
have to keep going in good times and in bad. They therefore
need a wide margin of safety. If taxes and debt are made all the
people can bear when times are good, there will be certain
disaster when times are bad.
—Calvin Coolidge (1872–1933)
Fiscal adjustment may be necessary to achieve longer-term goals, such
as economic growth and poverty reduction, while heading off such fiscal
vulnerabilities as the buildup of public debt. Shorter-term fiscal objectives
should be pursued within this longer-term framework.
Fiscal Adjustment for Growth and Poverty Reduction
Governments typically aim to promote strong and sustainable economic
growth, and lasting poverty reduction. Research indicates that a sound fiscal
position is key to achieving macroeconomic stability, which is increasingly
recognized as critical for sustained growth and poverty reduction. Highquality fiscal adjustment can also mobilize domestic savings, increase the
efficiency of resource allocation, and help meet development goals.
Achieving Durable Macroeconomic Stability
Loose fiscal policy, on the other hand, can lead to inflation, crowding out, uncertainty, and volatility, all of which hamper growth (Gupta,
Clements, and Inchauste, 2004).
• Inflation. Loose fiscal policy, especially when financed by printing
money (see Section I, Fiscal Adjustment for Short-Term Macroeconomic Stability), can lead to high and volatile inflation. In addition to
other costs, this undermines the efficiency of the price system as it leads
firms and households to make incorrect decisions, confusing move1
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
ments in the price level with changes in relative prices. This in turn
reduces overall productivity (Fischer, 1993).
• Crowding out. When the government borrows to finance a looser fiscal
position, the greater demand for loanable funds can reduce private investment (and other interest-sensitive components of private spending)
by raising interest rates.3 Under a floating exchange rate, higher interest
rates will also tend to attract foreign capital, leading to an appreciation
of the exchange rate, which will also crowd out exports.
• Uncertainty and volatility. Loose fiscal policy may not be sustainable.
It implies, for example, continuously rising debt levels, which creates
uncertainty as to how and when the loose policy will be corrected (e.g.,
through a burst of inflation, a disorderly depreciation, price and foreign
trade restrictions, or large tax increases). These circumstances reduce
private investment as they cause investors to wait and see how the uncertainty will be resolved and they prompt capital flight. Loose fiscal
policy may also make the economic environment more volatile (e.g.,
by recurrent, and ill-timed, bursts of fiscal contraction and expansion),
which can weaken investment by increasing risk and focusing investment on the short run (Bernanke, 1983).4
Indeed, in situations of high debt and deficits, fiscal consolidation can
immediately expand output (see Section I, Fiscal Adjustment for ShortTerm Macroeconomic Stability). In such situations, fiscal consolidation
can reduce the risk premium on interest rates, catalyzing higher private
investment and raising asset values. This boosts private consumption and
eases supply constraints. The expectation of lower government spending
can also lead the private sector to reduce its estimates of current and future tax liabilities, further boosting consumption and investment. It is not
only the size of the fiscal deficit and the initial debt reduction that matter, however, but also the composition and the perception of the sustain-
3If, however, the government “represses” financial markets by controlling domestic interest rates, more government borrowing will result in either higher inflation and low (even
negative) real interest rates or reduced financial intermediation—a reduction in the share of
savings channeled through formal financial institutions to private investors. The quality of
private investment suffers too: with credit rationed, governments typically end up choosing
who gets credit and choosing less well than the market would.
4Excess economic volatility can also cause irreversible losses in human capital—
including through the effect of more frequent spells of unemployment on learning-by-doing
opportunities—compounding the negative effect on growth (Martin and Rogers, 1997).
2
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
ability of the adjustment effort (see Section III, Quality and Durability of
Adjustment).
Mobilizing and Allocating Resources
Economic growth and human development critically depend on accumulating physical and human capital, which in turn requires an adequate level
of national savings. As private sector savings are often low in developing
(especially low-income) countries, fiscal policy can play a central role
in mobilizing resources by raising revenue and reducing less productive
spending. But the mobilized resources must be invested productively, and
history is littered with examples of poor government investments. Indeed,
a key channel through which expenditure consolidation in developing
countries can spur growth is higher factor productivity, as public sector
resources are freed up for the more efficient private sector. The impact of
government spending on improving human development and growth depends on the efficiency of these outlays and how well they are targeted at
the poor, not just on the level of spending.
Efficiency arguments suggest that public spending should be directed to
areas with the highest social return and should complement, rather than compete with, the private sector. This involves either financing or supplying directly needed public goods that the private sector will not supply adequately
because of market failure. Several categories of public expenditure can
influence long-term growth—especially spending on education, health, and
infrastructure—although what will work best depends on specific country
circumstances. Higher growth, in turn, generates increased fiscal resources
to finance productive spending, further bolstering the dynamism of the
economy. Governments have, however, often tried to spur growth through
producer subsidies and the tax system by, for example, imposing high tariffs
or offering generous tax holidays (rather than the better method of reducing
distortionary taxes; see Section IV, Improving the Tax System and Mobilizing Revenue). These have generally created inefficiencies and administrative
complications, as well as larger fiscal deficits, and have not resulted in the
anticipated growth benefits.
Meeting Development Goals
In recent years, fiscal policy in low-income countries has been increasingly geared to meeting the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs).
These goals grew out of the agreements and resolutions of world confer3
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
ences organized by the United Nations since the early 1990s. They have
been commonly accepted as a framework for measuring development
progress, and indicators of achievement of these goals are being monitored
by the international community. The goals are directed at reducing poverty
in all its forms. They include halving global poverty, achieving universal
primary education, reversing the spread of HIV/AIDS, reducing child and
maternal mortality, and ensuring environmental sustainability.
Fiscal policy can play a pivotal role in achieving the MDGs by fostering
robust economic growth, which is critical for sustainable development and
for improving social outcomes. For example, research suggests that growth
usually benefits the poor and that there is a strong link between economic
growth and improvements in nonincome dimensions of poverty, such as infant mortality and female literacy (IMF, 2002). Meeting the MDGs will also
generally require changes in the structure of the budget to include higher
outlays on productive social spending, a scaling up of aid, and more efficient government spending (see Section III, Size of Fiscal Adjustment).
Fiscal Adjustment to Reduce Vulnerability
A country’s public finances may appear sound now, but may be vulnerable if underlying weaknesses threaten its future fiscal position and limit
the government’s ability to respond to fiscal policy challenges. Reducing
fiscal vulnerability allows fiscal policy to respond countercyclically to
downturns or shocks.
All countries, but especially developing ones, face shocks (e.g., termsof-trade shifts, “sudden stops” in capital inflows, natural disasters, and
aid shortfalls) that undermine, directly or indirectly, their public finances.
Such shocks can reduce revenue, generate pressing expenditure needs, and
make financing more difficult and expensive. Countries that have built up
reserves in good times can draw on these resources during bad times. And
those with low levels of debt may be able to increase their fiscal deficits,
including through borrowing, during a downturn or even a crisis, without
losing market confidence. But countries without such buffers are often
forced to take emergency fiscal measures and have limited scope for countercyclical fiscal policy. Emergency fiscal tightening measures are more
likely to damage investment, growth, and social indicators, as they can be
less well planned and are often based on measures that produce short-term
financial gains at the expense of longer-term efficiency.
4
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
The most common fiscal vulnerabilities stem from public debt—its sustainability, its structure, and the degree to which vulnerabilities are hidden
(as through contingent liabilities). Rigidities in the structure of the fiscal
sector can also undermine fiscal policy, as do longer term fiscal pressures.
Globalization too heightens the importance of sound fiscal policy.
Debt Sustainability
Public debt is sustainable when the government can continue servicing
it without requiring an unrealistically (from a social and political point
of view) large correction to its future revenue or primary (noninterest)
expenditure path. This broad definition implies that, at credible levels
of primary balances, the government is both solvent (discounted future
primary balances exceed the current net debt stock) and liquid (able
to meet obligations as they come due; see Section III, Size of Fiscal
Adustment).
In addition to fundamentals, market expectations play an important
role. Even when debt is stable or declining under current policies, markets may be concerned about the government’s continued ability to generate the requisite primary balances. This, in turn, raises risk premiums
on public debt and can cause it to become unsustainable. Managing
expectations thus becomes important: when countries are able to assure
markets about future fiscal policies, they may be able to maintain larger
debt levels than otherwise. Governments should be able to demonstrate
that their overall debt burden is manageable and is likely to remain so
under a range of plausible scenarios. Medium-term fiscal frameworks,
which set out government targets and projections for fiscal policy, and
strong fiscal institutions, such as effective tax administrations and expenditure management systems, may help improve both policies and
expectations (see Section V).
Contingent Liabilities and Debt Structure
Contingent liabilities are financial obligations that are triggered by certain events, and are not readily captured by standard fiscal statistics and
analysis. Contingent liabilities fall under two main categories: those that
become due if certain events materialize, such as defaults on governmentguaranteed debt that the government must then assume; and those that result from the government’s implicit or “moral” commitment, for example,
to protect depositors after a bank failure or to pay pensions if the pension
5
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
scheme goes bust. Because their fiscal cost is typically invisible until they
are triggered, contingent liabilities are a hidden subsidy, blur fiscal analysis, and can drain future government finances.
Debt contracted by public enterprises, local governments, and extrabudgetary funds often carries an explicit or implicit guarantee by the government. When such debt is not repaid, it has to be assumed by the government. Similarly, in public-private partnerships—such as build-operatetransfer contracts—the government frequently offers assorted guarantees
(e.g., of minimum revenues). When market conditions prove to be unfavorable, liabilities for the government are triggered.
The structure of debt can also be an important source of vulnerability
and risk. For example, when government debt is short term, indexed to
short-term interest rates, or foreign-exchange-denominated/linked, pressures in the money and foreign exchange markets can rapidly translate
into debt-servicing problems. The “balance sheet approach,” which looks
at links between the balance sheets of the various sectors of the economy,
can help identify vulnerabilities and potential pressures stemming from
balance sheets (Allen and others, 2002).
Active management of government liabilities can help address these
problems. By reducing the risk that the government’s debt will become a
source of instability for the private sector, prudent policies in this area—as
well as with respect to contingent liabilities—can make countries less susceptible to contagion and financial risk.
Fiscal Rigidities
Experience suggests that rigidities in the structure of the fiscal sector
may undermine the government’s capacity to adapt to changing circumstances. By ossifying current fiscal structures, rigidities can undermine
future macroeconomic stability, debt sustainability, and fiscal policy. For
example:
• Earmarking revenues for certain expenditures hampers the government’s
ability to adjust the revenues, or to spend them on changing priorities
(e.g., schools rather than roads). If fiscal consolidation is needed, raising
earmarked revenues is of little use as they automatically lead to higher
spending.
• Constitutionally, or otherwise, mandated spending, employment levels,
or taxation rates, impinge on governments’ ability to adjust fiscal policy.
Numerical fiscal rules, such as debt or deficit limits, especially if set in
6
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
the constitution, may also have the (in some cases, desired) effect of
reducing a government’s room for fiscal maneuver.
• Large shares of nondiscretionary spending (e.g., interest payments or
spending on entitlement programs) in total expenditure complicate expenditure adjustment and can force cuts on higher-quality discretionary
spending.
• Some fiscal federalism arrangements can undermine fiscal control.
For example, arrangements that require certain revenues to be shared
are likely to make fiscal consolidation more difficult (see Section V,
Effective Intergovernmental Relationships).
Globalization
The importance of sound fiscal policy is further heightened by globalization. The credibility that derives from successfully maintaining, or restoring,
sound fiscal policy can help emerging market economies (and developing
countries more generally) exploit open labor and capital markets and free
trade—including in services facilitated by modern communication systems.
But if poor fiscal discipline compromises stability and growth objectives,
access to international capital will likely be reduced. Tax competition has
also become a fact of life, and tariff reductions have resulted in some loss of
revenues, at least until the positive effects on growth materialized.5
Emerging Fiscal Pressures6
Developing countries in particular face many fiscal challenges that may
lead to acute resource needs and require government intervention.
• In some parts of the world, the spread of HIV/AIDS and other pandemics inflict a high cost in terms of human suffering, loss of human capital, and need for more public sector support. More generally, ongoing
technological innovations in health care, while effective in raising life
expectancy, are likely to be financially costly.
5The initial stages of trade liberalization—which typically involve replacing nontariff barriers, such as quotas, with tariffs—tend not to be associated with revenue loss (IMF, 2005a).
But many low-income countries seem to have had difficulty in replacing any revenue loss
resulting from trade reform. Those that succeeded (1) sustained efforts, over several years,
to broaden tax bases, including by improving revenue administration; (2) strengthened the
domestic consumption tax system, through excise taxes and especially by a simple, broadbased, VAT; and (3) increased income taxes.
6See Heller (2003) for a fuller discussion of long-term fiscal challenges.
7
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
• Demographic changes, mainly aging populations, are likely to pose
increasing burdens on public finances of some developing—as well
as industrial—countries. Pension reforms may necessitate transitory
financing requirements and higher explicit public debt when countries
shift from public to private plans.
• Financial liberalization that frees banks from providing directed credit
to favored sectors and enterprises may shift this burden onto the government by way of budgeted or unbudgeted credit subsidies channeled
through public banks.
• Environmental degradation and global climate change may have wideranging implications that require government intervention.
Fiscal Adjustment for Short-Term Macroeconomic Stability
Short-term fiscal policy should be consistent with longer-term goals.
Within this longer-term context, fiscal policy can contribute to short-term
macroeconomic management. Most traditionally, fiscal adjustment can
help mitigate cyclicality (recurrent recessions and booms), reduce large external current account imbalances, and contain inflation. In capital account
crises, fiscal adjustment can restore confidence, ease financing constraints,
and support growth.
Conducting Countercyclical Policy
Countercyclical fiscal policy—that is, adding to aggregate demand during
downturns and withdrawing demand during upturns—can potentially play a
role in responding to both normal variations in aggregate demand and larger
aggregate demand shocks (supply shocks would typically require a neutral
or procyclical fiscal response as the economy has to adjust to a lower level
of potential output). For countercyclical fiscal policy to succeed, however,
certain requirements must be met (Hemming, Kell, and Mahfouz, 2000).
Fiscal policy should be well coordinated with monetary policy. Monetary policy is generally a more effective countercyclical policy instrument
because interest rate changes can be made in days and can be quickly
reversed. But monetary policy adjustments may take longer than fiscal
policy adjustments to affect aggregate demand. Moreover, fiscal policy
contributes to broader-based stabilization through the impact of taxes
and government spending on income-sensitive (in addition to interestsensitive) components of aggregate demand.
8
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
When monetary policy is constrained in responding to output variations,
fiscal policy should take a more central role. This may be the case if the
mandate of the central bank focuses on securing low inflation, rather than
stabilizing output. Also, if nominal interest rates are close to zero, monetary
policy options are limited as interest rates cannot be lowered further. The
relative effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policies will also depend on the
exchange rate regime. Fiscal policy is relatively less effective under a flexible exchange rate regime and more effective under a fixed rate regime.
In some circumstances, the usefulness of countercyclical fiscal policy
during downturns and recessions is limited. Most notably:
• If domestic and external imbalances are large, countercyclical fiscal
policy may be inappropriate. Even though the economy may be turning
down or in recession, avoiding or responding to rising inflation and a
weakening balance of payments may be paramount.
• Financing constraints may place an upper bound on the fiscal deficit.
Many emerging market and low-income countries face constraints on
their borrowing, owing to undeveloped financial systems and a limited
ability to tap external financial markets.
Even if countercyclical fiscal policy is appropriate, it may not have the
desired impact on aggregate demand. Some factors could contribute to the
impact being quite small. Moreover, in certain circumstances, fiscal contractions can be expansionary (Box 1).
• Fiscal expansions may be crowded out, at least partially. This happens
when increased borrowing causes interest rates to rise and the exchange
rate to appreciate. Fiscal expansions will therefore tend to be relatively
ineffective in open economies with flexible exchange rates.
• In response to a debt-financed fiscal expansion, individuals who are
not liquidity constrained may increase their saving so that they (or their
children, via bequests) can pay the higher taxes that will be needed in
the future to service the debt (the “Ricardian equivalence effect”). The
offset is, however, likely to be partial and will depend on the extent to
which consumers can borrow and lend to smooth consumption, as well
as their degree of time preference (desire to consume now rather than
later) relative to that of the government.
• The composition of measures may be inappropriate. For example, increases in transfers that benefit high-income individuals with relatively
strong tendencies to save additional income would be less effective in
influencing demand.
9
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 1 . Expansionary Fiscal Contractions
Fiscal tightening may expand the economy in the short term. The consolidation episodes of Denmark and Ireland have been particularly well
documented, and there is evidence of expansionary fiscal contractions elsewhere—in particular, in such high-debt emerging market economies as
Turkey. These episodes have a number of features:
• They are associated with fiscal adjustment in high-debt countries. As the
government gains credibility in being able to service its debt and the threat
of higher taxes and default subsides, risk premiums on interest rates fall,
confidence rises, and aggregate demand is stimulated.
• They are a function of the size and composition of fiscal adjustment and
deficit financing. In particular, consolidations based on cutting transfers
and government wages tend to be associated with better growth outcomes,
as are those that lead to lower domestic financing (see Section III, Quality
and Durability of Adjustment).
• They can manifest themselves either through changes in private consumption and investment or through factor productivity. Changes in
consumption and investment occur primarily through the credibility and
wealth effect channels. The factor productivity channel is more important in developing countries (owing to the lower productivity of public
spending).
• There may be long implementation lags, for example, because tax and
expenditure measures are held up by the political process and budget
procedures.
Where countercyclical fiscal policy is appropriate, research suggests that
it may best be implemented through automatic stabilizers (IMF, forthcoming). Automatic stabilizers derive from the responsiveness of tax revenue
and certain categories of spending (e.g., unemployment benefits) to output,
which means that they take effect quickly and are self-reversing. However, automatic stabilizers are somewhat arbitrary, reflecting past decisions
about the structure of taxation and spending, and are typically weak in
emerging market and low-income countries.
Discretionary tax and spending measures may also have a role to play.
They can be used to routinely bolster weak automatic stabilizers or offset
strong ones, or they can be held in reserve to respond to larger aggregate
demand shocks. The advantage of discretionary measures is that they can
be tailored to stabilization needs, in particular by directing them to where
10
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
they will have the largest impact on spending. Their main shortcomings are
that they can be subject to long implementation lags and are not quickly
reversible, and that they have been a particular source of procyclicality,
especially in upturns.
Reducing External Current Account Imbalances
Fiscal adjustment may be needed to facilitate external adjustment,
especially to reduce excessive current account deficits or surpluses (Easterly, Rodriguez, and Schmidt-Hebbel, 1994). As an ex post identity, a fiscal
deficit must be matched by either net domestic private sector savings (the excess of private savings over private investment), an external current account
deficit, or a combination of both.7 But cutting the fiscal deficit (surplus) will
not generally result in a one-for-one cut in the current account deficit (surplus), as the private sector’s saving-investment balance will be affected too.
For example, the lower fiscal deficit could spur private investment, as credit
becomes cheaper and more plentiful, and reduce private sector savings.
Fiscal adjustment can also support current account adjustment through
its effect on the real exchange rate.8 Fiscal consolidation, for example, will
tend to depreciate the real exchange rate by reducing the demand for, and
thus the price of, nontradables, thereby increasing the relative profitability
of the tradable sector and boosting (net) exports. And devaluing the nominal exchange rate without correcting fiscal disequilibria may primarily affect inflation rather than the real exchange rate, thus failing to bring about
significant external adjustment.
Tackling Inflation (or Deflation)
Fiscal policy can affect inflation through many channels. In the short
run, it can affect the price level through its impact on aggregate demand.
Specifically, government purchases of nontradable goods and services
add to aggregate demand, while transfers and tax changes affect private
7More
formally: CA = (Spriv – Ipriv) + (Spub – Ipub), where CA is the external current account
balance; Spriv, private sector savings; Ipriv, private sector investment; Spub, public sector savings;
and Ipub, public sector investment. Spub – Ipub is a measure of the overall fiscal balance. The
precise definition of each sector is critical (see Section III, What Makes Fiscal Adjustment
Successful?).
8The real exchange rate is the relative price of tradables (such as televisions) to nontradables (e.g., haircuts). A real exchange rate depreciation (appreciation) improves (worsens) the
external current account by diverting resources from the nontradable (tradable) to the tradable
(nontradable) sector.
11
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
demand. Administered price rises also affect the price level, and public
sector wage increases can induce cost pressures.9 Sustained inflation,
however, generally requires an ongoing increase in the money supply that
outstrips money demand. Fiscal policy can play a central role to the extent
that money creation is due to deficit financing. Monetary financing of the
deficit is a cheap source of financing in the short run, but once it goes
beyond accommodating the increase in money demand, it contributes to
excess money supply and inflation.
Fiscal adjustment can also affect inflation via the demand for money,
including through inflation expectations, interest rates, and confidence.
For example, if monetary policy is seen to be accommodating, fiscal
expansion—even if initially not financed by the central bank—can quickly
lead to expectations of future money supply increases, and thus to inflation
(Sargent and Wallace, 1981).
Financing deficits by relying on high inflation is particularly pernicious
but increasingly rare. It means obtaining resources at the expense of those
with fixed nominal assets or incomes, usually among the poorer groups
in society. Over time, the scope for collecting the inflation tax narrows:
when inflation rises, households and businesses reduce their holdings of
domestic currency (after adjusting for inflation) as they seek alternatives to
preserve the value of their assets (such as foreign currency). High inflation
can also undermine revenue from explicit taxes if there are collection lags
(the “Tanzi effect”) or heavy reliance on specific taxes.
Similarly, expansionary fiscal policy can help tackle deflation. A welltimed tax cut will increase disposable incomes, encouraging consumption,
and higher government spending can help boost production and reduce
unemployment. But fiscal policy must be tailored to credibly boost aggregate demand. Spending programs and tax relief should ideally target
low-income consumers and good-quality projects that boost the return to
private investment.
Managing Capital Account Crises
Capital account crises—that is, a loss of investor confidence manifested
in rapid capital outflows—can severely constrain fiscal policy. Once such
9Public
sector wage increases could increase private sector wages by, for example, forming
a benchmark for private sector wage increases or by raising the wage the private sector would
need to offer to be competitive.
12
I. When Is Fiscal Adjustment Needed?
a crisis hits, fiscal consolidation becomes unavoidable as the deficit is
constrained by a lack of financing. More generally, fiscal consolidation
is important in those emerging market countries where crises originate
mainly in market perceptions of fiscal profligacy and in unsustainable debt
dynamics. In these countries, the direct contractionary impact of fiscal
tightening on demand is likely to be offset by the beneficial effect of fiscal
consolidation on market access and the cost of borrowing.
But where fiscal problems are not the root cause of the loss of confidence, fiscal retrenchment may be counterproductive, as the dampening
effect on growth exacerbates the loss of confidence. A more relaxed fiscal stance, in this context, could offset the weakening economic activity
(Ghosh and others, 2002). Moreover, to the extent that such weakening is
in itself a concern to investors, too tight a fiscal stance risks eroding, rather
than enhancing, confidence. This underlines the more general point that
prudent fiscal policies during “good” times greatly increase the room for
maneuver during “bad” times.
13
II .
How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed?
Without data, all you are is just another person with an opinion.
—Anonymous
Just as fiscal adjustment has many objectives, it can be measured in
many ways. Even the best designed adjustment will fail if the fiscal
indicators on which it is based are flawed. Different problems, objectives, and economic structures imply that no single measure will fit all
circumstances. Individual country practices reflect this diversity, and
international statistical standards themselves are changing as countries
gradually adopt the IMF’s Government Finance Statistics Manual 200110
(Box 2). The main issues relate to what should be included in the public
sector, when fiscal transactions should be recorded, and what indicators
should be used.
Coverage of the Public Sector
The components of the fiscal sector are the central government, subnational government, social security funds, and public corporations.
• Central government refers to the activities of a country’s central authority. Transactions at this level should reflect the legal budget of the central government as well as fiscal actions of any extrabudgetary funds or
autonomous agencies relevant to central government policies or under
the central authorities’ effective control.
• Subnational governments consist of the budgetary and extrabudgetary
activities of decentralized governments operating only in parts of the
country, such as regional, state, and local governments. The central and
subnational governments together constitute the general government.
10The Government Finance Statistics Manual 2001 is a reference volume for government
finance statistics. It covers concepts, definitions, classifications, and accounting rules, and
provides a comprehensive analytic framework within which to summarize and present fiscal
data in a form appropriate for analysis, planning, and policy design.
14
II. How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed?
Box 2 . Key Differences between the 2001 and 1986 GFSMs
The 2001 edition of the Government Finance Statistics Manual (GFSM)
differs from the 1986 edition in three main ways:
• Accrual basis . Unlike GFSM 1986, the 2001 manual emphasizes recording fiscal statistics on an accrual basis—at the time the economic event
occurs, not necessarily when cash is paid or received.
• Integration of stocks and flows . The GFSM 2001 is underpinned by a set
of well-defined relationships between flows and stocks. Specifically, the
government’s opening and closing balance sheets are reconciled with the
flows derived from government operations and other economic flows (e.g.,
valuation changes or the extinction of assets from natural disasters).
• The analytic framework . This consists of three main tables and four main
balances.
• The Statement of Government Operations distinguishes among transactions
(1) affecting net worth, i.e., revenue and expense; (2) in nonfinancial assets;
and (3) in financial assets and liabilities. The difference between revenue
and expense is the net operating balance (similar to the current balance in
GFSM 1986). Subtracting net acquisition of nonfinancial assets gives the
net lending/borrowing balance (similar to the overall balance in GFSM
1986, except for net lending now excluded). This, in turn, is equal to the net
acquisition of financial assets minus the net incurrence of liabilities.
• The Balance Sheet shows the government’s net worth at the end of the
period. It is equal to the stock of nonfinancial assets plus net financial
worth (the stock of financial assets minus liabilities). The change in net
worth during a year is the sum of changes attributable to revenue and
expense transactions and to other economic flows.
• The Statement on Sources and Uses of Cash shows purely cash flows
associated with revenue and expense transactions and transactions in
nonfinancial assets, which yields the cash surplus/deficit. Adding cash
flows in financial assets (other than cash) and liabilities to the cash surplus/deficit yields the net change in the stock of cash.
While full implementation of the GFSM 2001 will be challenging for many
countries, many of its benefits can be reaped in the interim just by presenting
existing fiscal data in this new framework.
• Social security funds either form their own subsector or are part of the
level of government at which they operate and are consolidated with
either the central or general government.11
11In IMF publications, social security funds are normally classified with the level of government at which they operate. If the social security system is autonomous, with its liabilities
perfectly matched with its assets (a defined contribution, or fully funded, scheme), it would
be treated as part of the nonfinancial public sector.
15
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
• Public corporations consist of financial public corporations (FPCs, including the central bank) and nonfinancial public corporations (NFPCs).
Consolidating NFPCs with the general government yields the nonfinancial
public sector, and adding FPCs constitutes the consolidated public sector.
Fiscal policy can be carried out by different levels of government and
through a range of institutions. Normally, it is implemented by entities
wholly devoted to the economic functions of government, such as central
and local governments. But public corporations (both financial and nonfinancial) can also carry out fiscal policy, typically without being explicitly
recorded in the budget. For example, central banks may extend subsidized
loans and nonfinancial corporations may not operate at market prices,
or may provide social services. Such activities—known as “quasi-fiscal
operations” (Mackenzie and Stella, 1996)—can have a fiscal impact comparable with that of more traditional government activities, although they
are often difficult to measure.
Determining the specific coverage of the public sector for a given country entails striking a compromise between what is administratively feasible
and what is important for fiscal policy. As a rule, fiscal policy should be
assessed for policy purposes based on general government plus public
corporations—whether financial or nonfinancial—that pose a significant
risk to public finances. If some levels of government (e.g., local governments) are constrained by the need to run balanced budgets, it may be
possible to abstract from them for some analytic purposes.
Whatever the exact coverage of fiscal indicators for policy purposes,
fiscal statistics should be compiled both for general government and the
public sector. Given that any public corporation, financial and nonfinancial, is a potential source of fiscal risk, the operations of all public corporations should be reported and monitored. This will improve transparency and accountability and also help identify any emerging problems.
When to Record Government Transactions
Governments generally record transactions on four bases: commitment,
accrual, due-for-payment, and cash. Under the commitments basis, transactions are recorded when commitments to them have been entered into
(usually when purchase orders are issued); under the accrual basis, transactions are recorded at the time of the economic event (e.g., when ownership
of goods changes or services are provided); under a due-for-payments
16
II. How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed?
basis, at the latest time they can be paid for without incurring additional
charges or penalties (or, if sooner, when the cash payment is made); and
under the cash basis, when cash is received or disbursed.
Many countries, especially those with weaker public expenditure management systems, use a cash (or modified cash) basis. While operationally easier, it can distort the analysis of fiscal policy (e.g., its impact on
aggregate demand and fiscal sustainability). This is because it records
transactions after they have occurred economically and ignores noncash
transactions, such as arrears and grants-in-kind.
Information on cash flows will still be important, even with accrual accounting—for example, to manage government liquidity and to assess the
impact on monetary variables. This does not require a cash basis of recording, but a separate statement on cash flows. Cash-based systems can also
be modified to allow some items to be recorded on a noncash basis (e.g.,
recording interest on a due rather than paid basis).
Main Fiscal Indicators
The fiscal position should be assessed in terms of both flow indicators,
such as the overall balance, and stock indicators, such as the amount of
government debt.
Flow Indicators
The overall fiscal balance is the most common fiscal indicator. It is the
difference between total revenue (including grants) and total expenditures
plus lending minus repayments. The widespread use of the overall balance
reflects its links to the government’s net financing requirements and to the
external current account.12
An adjusted overall fiscal balance is an overall balance excluding such
items as grants or revenue from certain enclave activities (e.g., the oil sector), or certain lumpy expenditure items.
• External grants are included under total revenue and grants because they
do not add to debt and may finance expenditures that would otherwise
12The exact linkages are complex and depend on the specific accounting definitions. For
example, including lending minus repayments “above the line” (unlike in GFSM 2001; see
Box 2) would imply that the overall balance would not equal the change in the government’s
net financial position.
17
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 3 . Fiscal Policy and Nonrenewable Resources
Having nonrenewable resources, such as oil, should be a blessing, but experience suggests it is often a curse. It is a blessing in that exploiting such resources
relaxes the traditional obstacles to growth (foreign exchange, domestic savings,
and fiscal revenues), but it is a curse in that many such countries seem to suffer
from excessive dependence on these resources .
Heavy dependence on nonrenewable resource revenue complicates fiscal
policy. Nonrenewable resource revenues are typically volatile and uncertain—
linking spending to such revenue induces macroeconomic volatility and reduces
its quality. As the resource is by definition nonrenewable, it will, sooner or later,
run out—consuming all the revenue now may mean difficult fiscal consolidation later. The influx of foreign exchange can appreciate the real exchange rate,
shrinking traditional tradable sectors (“Dutch disease”). And the large windfalls
can foster corruption and undermine governance. That said, many, especially
low-income, nonrenewable-resource-producing countries face large and pressing social and development needs.
There is no “silver bullet” to fix these problems, and no substitute for prudent
macroeconomic management. But research suggests some approaches can help
(Davis, Ossowski, and Fedelino, 2003).
• Adjust expenditure gradually. Setting expenditure (or, more precisely, the primary balance excluding nonrenewable resource revenue as a ratio to GDP excluding the nonrenewable resource sector) in a medium-term framework will
help avoid procyclicality. Countries with stronger financial positions have
more leeway to increase spending in response to more permanent price rises,
whereas those with weaker positions have less scope to finance downturns.
not take place. But grants are often volatile, unpredictable, and outside
government control. Moreover, they may not last and do not reduce domestic demand. Thus, when grants are significant, the overall balance
is often reported both with and without grants. The balance excluding
grants also indicates the extent of grant dependency.
• Like grants, oil revenue is highly volatile and unpredictable. It is also,
however, nonrenewable and consuming it reduces government wealth.
Countries that are heavily dependent on oil (or on other nonrenewable
resources) should focus on the non-oil balance, ideally as a ratio to nonoil GDP (Box 3). Privatization receipts are also often excluded from the
overall balance for similar reasons.
• Externally financed project spending may be excluded as it is outside
the government’s control, typically has a large import component with
18
II. How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed?
• Save part of nonrenewable resource revenues. Fiscal policy should be set
so that no abrupt consolidation is needed when production wanes. This
typically requires saving a significant share of the nonrenewable resource
revenues, especially when production is not expected to last long. Financial
savings should be held offshore to avoid imparting volatility to the domestic
economy and excessive real appreciation (some real appreciation may be an
intrinsic part of the process of absorbing resource revenues).
• Be transparent. Governments should establish a clear legal and regulatory framework for the nonrenewable resource sector and comprehensively disclose related revenue data. International and national nonrenewable resource companies should comply with international accounting
standards.
• Nonrenewable resource funds should be transparent and well integrated
with the budget. A well-designed fund, such as Norway’s State Petroleum
Fund, can help manage nonrenewable resource revenues, mainly for political
economy reasons. A poorly designed fund, however, can complicate fiscal
policy management, for example, by creating a dual budget and making cash
management inefficient.
• Consider hedging. Hedging can help governments make their nonrenewable
resource revenue stream more stable and predictable, but this requires institutional capacity and stringent control.
• Set domestic nonrenewable resource product prices at international
levels. Subsidization is generally inefficient, poorly targeted, and often
nontransparent.
consequent limited impact on domestic supply, and is automatically
financed (though if financed by lending, it does increase debt). Excluding external grants, externally financed project spending and external
interest payments yields the domestic balance (with specific definitions
varying across countries).
• The primary balance—revenue minus noninterest (primary) expenditure—
is an indicator of fiscal “effort,” in that interest payments are predetermined
by the size of previous deficits; the primary balance is a critical variable
for debt sustainability analysis. The debt-stabilizing primary balance is the
primary balance necessary to keep the debt-to-GDP ratio stable.
• The operational balance (the overall balance minus the part of debt service that compensates debt holders for inflation) is often reported when
there is high inflation.
19
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
The current balance, the difference between current revenue and current expenditures, indicates the extent of government savings. Targeting
the current balance could help safeguard investment in times of fiscal
consolidation, while leaving the net worth of the government unaffected
and promoting intergenerational equity. But focusing exclusively on the
current balance is risky (IMF, 2004a) for the following reasons:
• Investment spending adds to aggregate demand.
• In countries where financing is constrained, there is little alternative to
focusing on the overall balance. Indeed, if amortizations are large, fiscal
targets may have to be set in the light of total, rather than net, financing
availability.
• Borrowing may need to be constrained because of longer-term debt
sustainability concerns.
• Debt can become unsustainable if public investment projects are not
of high quality. Even when they are, governments may not be able to
realize the fiscal dividends of growth (i.e., public investment does not
typically pay for itself).
• Other uses of public funds—notably reducing tax rates or investment
in human capital and operations and maintenance—may have a higher
rate of return than public investment. Excluding public investment from
fiscal targets would create a bias against these choices and may also
discriminate against private sector involvement in infrastructure.
• Focusing on the current balance may invite creative accounting, with a
view to classifying current expenditure as capital.
The cyclically adjusted balance13 measures the fiscal position net of the
impact of output effects on the budget (IMF, forthcoming). It is obtained
by removing the cyclical component of the budget from the nominal fiscal
balance. The cyclical component in turn depends on the size of the output
gap and on the output elasticity of the budget (determined by the extent
that individual budgetary items react to fluctuations in output, as well as
by the size of the budget).
Budgetary targets are seldom framed in cyclically adjusted terms. This
partly reflects the relative complexity of the techniques used to estimate
output gaps and budgetary elasticities. But while the computation of cycli13While the terms cyclically adjusted and structural balances are often used interchangeably, structural balances refer to fiscal balances adjusted for deviations from benchmark
levels of all economic variables with a significant fiscal impact (not just output).
20
II. How Should the Fiscal Position Be Assessed?
cally adjusted balances is fraught with difficulties, a variety of measures
can be undertaken to address them.14 Cyclically adjusted balances can play
a useful role as a reference for policy design and implementation.
The augmented balance is the overall balance, including such exceptional outlays as the fiscal costs of bank recapitalization or enterprise
restructuring not otherwise captured in expenditure. Such outlays need to
be financed and may have a significant impact on aggregate demand.
Gross financing needs and sources helps focus on liquidity issues.
Needs comprise the overall deficit, any other transactions that require financing, plus amortization. This is equal to the necessary financing, from
which the implications of meeting this need can be drawn. For example,
if the necessary financing entails a level of external market access much
greater than the government had previously enjoyed, this could portend
liquidity problems.
Stock Indicators
Fiscal policy analysis has traditionally focused on such flow variables
as the overall balance. But flows are changes in stocks, and stocks are
increasingly seen as important yardsticks for gauging fiscal policy in their
own right. Reconciling flows and stocks also serves as a consistency check
on the quality of fiscal data. The starting point is the public (or government) balance sheet at a given moment. It comprises, on one side, public
assets, both financial (e.g., government deposits) and nonfinancial (e.g.,
roads), and on the other, public liabilities (e.g., government debt) and net
worth (the difference between assets and liabilities).
Liabilities, the bulk of which typically consists of debt, are a commonly
used stock variable. Large or growing liabilities (typically measured
against a scalar, such as GDP or revenue) may signal future debt-servicing
problems.
Net financial worth recognizes that liabilities may be matched by financial assets, and thus looking just at liabilities may misrepresent the
government’s financial position.15 But only liquid financial assets can be
14These include taking into account changes in the composition of output when estimating
the output gap, as well as relying on estimates of built-in elasticities, excluding the impact
of discretionary measures.
15The composition of liabilities can also be an important source of vulnerability (see
Section I, Fiscal Adjustment to Reduce Vulnerability).
21
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
used to meet liabilities coming due. For example, government equity in
public corporations may not be easily sold, and withdrawing government
deposits from public banks may precipitate their collapse. In addition,
netting offsetting claims/liabilities within the public sector against each
other may mask mismatches, such as the central government’s inability to
service its debt to the social security fund.
Net worth goes further by recognizing that liabilities may also be
matched, not just by financial assets, but also by nonfinancial assets. This
is the most demanding stock variable to measure as it involves, for example, valuing nonfinancial assets.
The balance sheet can miss potentially critical aspects of the government’s financial position and should be supplemented with additional
information. For example:
• Contingent liabilities, such as loan guarantees (see the discussion in
Section I on Fiscal Adjustment to Reduce Vulnerability), are frequently
entered into for fiscal policy purposes, have important economic effects,
and can threaten fiscal sustainability. The nominal amount, and the nature, of such liabilities should be published, as should, if possible, an
estimate of their expected cost. Where guarantees are significant, budgets should limit their amount and include provisions for their expected
cost.
• Public-private partnerships are essentially leasing arrangements in
which the private sector provides initial finance and the state retains
ownership and bears certain future costs. While public-private partnerships can elicit additional financing for investment and may increase efficiency, they may also (possibly deliberately) conceal fiscal activity and
expose governments to greater (often hidden) costs than direct procurement of public works. To improve their transparency and assessment,
governments should include information on public-private partnerships
in budget documents and in end-year financial reports.
22
III .
What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
If it were done when ’tis done, then ’twere well it were done quickly.
—William Shakespeare (1564–1616)
Successful fiscal adjustments durably and efficiently improve the fiscal
position while minimizing any welfare costs. Success depends on a range of
variables, especially the timing and speed, size, and quality of adjustment.
Timing and Speed of Adjustment
The timing of adjustment is critical, although governments sometimes
have little room for maneuver. For example, severe financing constraints
may leave governments little choice but to consolidate, and political considerations may prevent consolidation until the problems posed by current
policies result in a crisis. But when governments do have room to maneuver, as a rule, fiscal consolidation should occur during good times. More
specifically, key considerations could usefully include the following.
• The point in the domestic business cycle. Fiscal consolidation (on a cyclically adjusted basis) should ideally begin to kick in as the economy starts
the expansionary phase of the business cycle, which would mitigate any
contractionary first-round effects. Similarly, fiscal loosening is most appropriate as the economy enters the contractionary part of the cycle.
• The point in the global business cycle. A worldwide recovery phase offers a window of opportunity to substitute rising external demand for
any fiscally induced slowdown in domestic demand.
• The stance of monetary policy. Adjustment will be more successful when
it is well coordinated with monetary policy. For example, to minimize any
output loss, monetary conditions should ideally relax when fiscal policy
contracts, the macroeconomic and public debt situation permitting.
Spreading any social costs over time may help reduce political resistance
to fiscal consolidation. And it takes time to design and implement goodquality measures. Together, these factors may also make consolidation more
credible. That said, frontloading is at times needed, for example, when a
government must show a decisive break with the past or to seize the opportu23
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
nity of political support, which may wane over time. Resistance to a gradual
approach may also flare up at some intermediate stage, leaving the process
incomplete, and a prolonged period of austerity can build up discontent.
Size of Fiscal Adjustment
The exact amount of fiscal adjustment needed depends on individual
country circumstances, objectives, and constraints, and should be assessed
relative to a baseline (unchanged policies) scenario. A decision-tree approach can help pin down the needed magnitude of adjustment. (1) Is debt
sustainability (or financing) binding? (2) If not, does the macro-economy
need stabilizing? (3) If the answers to (1) and (2) are “no,” then fiscal
policy has more space to maneuver to directly meet development goals.
Ensuring Public Debt Sustainability
For countries with public debt sustainability problems, the need to
achieve fiscal sustainability should anchor the medium-term fiscal path. In
these cases, the overriding objective is to improve the primary balance so
that it is consistent with debt sustainability. The slower the improvement,
the greater it will need to be, as the debt-to-GDP ratio will continue to
increase in the meantime.
In theory, solvency requires that the present discounted value (PDV)
of a government’s current and future primary expenditure be no greater
than the PDV of its current and future path of income, net of any initial indebtedness (Chalk and Hemming, 2000). In practice, solvency is
typically assessed by checking whether the public debt–to-GDP ratio is
stable or declining. Broadly speaking, the debt-to-GDP ratio increases
owing to the sum of its own dynamics (the product of its initial value and
the excess of the real interest rate over the real growth rate) and the primary deficit.16 Thus, when the real interest rate exceeds the real growth
rate, a primary surplus is needed to stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio.17
16In algebraic terms: Δb = d + (r – g) b, where b is the ratio of government debt to GDP
(with Δ indicating the change in the ratio from one year to the next); d, the primary deficit
ratio to GDP; r, the real interest rate; and g, the growth rate of real GDP.
17More sophisticated versions of the formula differentiate between domestic currency debt
and foreign currency debt, while also taking into account non-debt-creating deficit financing
(e.g., privatization receipts) and debt-creating items (such as the recognition of contingent
liabilities), which are not captured in the deficit.
24
III. What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
The main drawback of this approach is that it is silent on whether the
initial, or targeted, debt-to-GDP ratio is appropriate. For example, even
though the debt-to-GDP ratio might be falling, the debt may still be excessive as it may be causing high interest rates and crowding out private
investment. Critically, solvency assessments ignore short-term liquidity
issues. For example, a government may be solvent but unable to raise the
financing necessary to meet a lumpy repayment. Solvency and liquidity are
often interlinked: concerns about a country’s solvency may lead to financing problems, and financing problems may induce insolvency, as larger
primary surpluses are required to meet the higher interest bill.
Estimates of “safe” levels of government debt vary greatly and depend
on individual country circumstances. Liquidity crises and sovereign debt
defaults have occurred at very different public debt levels. Safe levels of
public debt for low-income countries depend especially on the quality
of a country’s institutions. Countries operating in a weaker institutional
and policy environment are likely to experience debt distress at significantly lower debt ratios. This is because such countries tend to have more
difficulty raising revenue or cutting expenditure and are more prone to
misuse and mismanage funds. Governments with more volatile revenue
bases and primary balances will also tend to be able to sustain only lower
levels of debt, especially if their economies are also volatile. As much of
low-income-country public external debt is concessional, the PDV should
be used, rather than nominal amounts, in calculating public debt ratios
(although this requires a judgment on the appropriate discount rate).
Projected primary balances are another useful tool for assessing sustainable debt levels. If the PDV of the projected primary surpluses is below the
current debt level, the government will not be able to repay its debt. A key
decision is what levels of primary surpluses to project and the following
are two useful approaches:
• What average, or peak, primary surpluses were generated in the past.
While readily ascertainable, and a valuable reality check, the past may
not reflect the current or future policymaking environment.
• What primary balances could the country generate given its institutions and other fundamental factors, derived from a cross-country
model. This approach has the advantage of relying less on the country’s historical performance. But it requires consideration of factors
specific to other countries and may also not reflect a changed policymaking environment.
25
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Recognizing that countries will always face shocks, that projections are
necessarily uncertain, and that there is no single measure of debt sustainability, debt sustainability projections should be subjected to stress tests
and assessed from different angles. Stress tests should be tailored to risks
facing individual countries, but typical risks include lower growth, higher
interest rates, sharp depreciation, lower primary surpluses, debt recognition, and market financing constraints. Comparisons to historical levels
and past volatility can help gauge the degree of risk. Other useful indicators of sustainability include the ratios of external debt service to exports
of goods and services, debt (or debt service) to revenue, gross new borrowing to amortization coming due (the “rollover” ratio), and domestic debt
to broad money.
Stabilizing the Macroeconomy
Determining the exact amount of fiscal adjustment depends critically
on the quality and type of fiscal adjustment measures. It ideally calls for
a full-fledged macroeconomic model, where fiscal policy is linked to
macroeconomic objectives through a set of well-defined equations. Such
models are rarely available in practice, however, especially in developing
countries.
For IMF-supported adjustment programs, the standard methodological
framework within which fiscal policies are designed is generally referred
to as “financial programming” (Ghosh and others, 2005). The objectives
of a financial program are usually specified in terms of the targets for
growth, inflation, and the balance of payments. The program is individually formulated within a set of economic and financial accounts (mainly
the national income and product accounts, the balance of payments, and
the fiscal and monetary accounts), which provides a consistent framework
for policy analysis.
A central constraint driving financial programs is that the financing of
the fiscal deficit should be consistent with macroeconomic objectives and
constraints. Most critically:
• External borrowing should be based on an assessment of the balance
of payments, the market’s appetite for sovereign bonds, prospects for
other official borrowing, and expected inflows through the banking
system.
• Domestic borrowing should be based on assumptions about changes in
broad liquidity, which in turn depend on money demand developments
26
III. What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
(given macroeconomic parameters such as growth and inflation), net
foreign asset projections consistent with balance of payments projections, and assumptions regarding credit to the private sector that are
consistent with the growth projections.
Meeting Development Goals and Creating Fiscal Space
Countries without binding debt sustainability, financing, or macrostability constraints have more scope to increase government spending to
meet development goals. In particular, in many low-income countries, the
government plays a central role in providing infrastructure, education, and
health services and public spending needs are large. The quantity and quality of these services are critical not only for achieving higher growth but
also for human development. The twin goals of higher growth and human
development are interrelated, as human capital can be a powerful engine
of economic growth.
Fiscal scope for higher government spending on such priority needs
can be created by reprioritizing nonproductive spending, increasing revenue, stepping up borrowing, and attracting larger external grants (Heller,
2005a). Public-expenditure-tracking surveys in some low-income countries reveal substantial waste and leakage that could be reduced by better
public financial management and improved project selection. Tax revenue
can be raised from a low base, but an excessive tax burden will hurt private sector activity. Excessive domestic borrowing will also crowd out the
private sector and could lead to debt sustainability problems. Concessional
external borrowing is an option, but it may not be available or sustainable.
External grants, however, can be a convenient and effective way around
these constraints.
That said, grants can complicate fiscal policy, especially when they are
large and volatile. In particular, rapid increases in aid could (1) result in
inflation and exchange rate appreciation (“Dutch disease”) when spent
on nontradables; (2) crowd out the private sector, for example, as central
banks sell domestic debt to offset (“sterilize”) the impact of aid inflows
on the domestic money supply; (3) strain the limited absorptive capacity18
18Absorptive capacity typically refers to limits on a country’s ability to use aid effectively
owing to the quality of a country’s policies and institutions and lack of administrative capacity in the form of specific skills or, more generally, of insufficient human resources and physical conditions (infrastructure and equipment) for policy and program implementation.
27
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
(especially if spending is increased rapidly) and impair governance; (4)
undermine efforts to enhance the domestic revenue base; and (5) give rise
to ongoing current spending requirements that cannot be met when aid
flows decline (Heller, 2005b).
These potential adverse effects can be mitigated through such domestic
policy responses as smoothing out aid fluctuations through international
reserve cushions, strengthening public expenditure management, improving governance, easing supply bottlenecks, and addressing constraints
faced by entrepreneurs. Donors can help by making their grants less volatile, more predictable, and less tied to specific projects. They can also usefully channel them through the budget and coordinate better with recipient
country development frameworks and other donor countries.
Central to managing a scaling up in aid inflows is the coordination of
fiscal policy with exchange rate and monetary policy (IMF, 2005b). From
a fiscal perspective, the issue is whether to spend or save the additional
aid. From a central bank perspective, the issue is whether to absorb the
incremental aid by allowing the current account deficit (excluding aid) to
widen, including via exchange and monetary policies.19
Absorbing and spending are the most appropriate responses to aid over
the long run—the government increases expenditure and aid finances the
resulting rise in net imports. Some real exchange rate appreciation may be
necessary to enable this reallocation of resources. In the short run, other
responses may also be useful:
• Saving incremental aid (i.e., neither absorbing nor spending it) may be
a good way to smooth volatile aid flows and their effect on spending,
build up international reserves from too low a level, and avoid real exchange rate appreciation.
• Absorbing but not spending substitutes aid for domestic financing of the
government deficit. Where the initial level of domestically financed deficit
spending is too high, this can help stabilize the economy, reduce government debt, and lower interest rates, thus “crowding in” the private sector.
To spend and not absorb is problematic, often reflecting inadequate
coordination of monetary and fiscal policies. This response is similar to
19Absorption in this context measures the extent to which aid engenders a real resource
transfer through higher imports or through a reduction in domestic resources devoted to producing exports. If the incremental aid directly finances imports, or is in-kind aid, spending
and absorption are equivalent.
28
III. What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
a fiscal stimulus in the absence of aid. The aid goes to reserves, so the
increase in government spending must be financed by printing money or
through government borrowing from the domestic private sector. There is
no real resource transfer given the absence of an increase in net imports. In
other words, a given aid dollar can be used to build reserves or to increase
the fiscal deficit—but not both.
Quality and Durability of Adjustment
Research indicates that the success of fiscal adjustment, especially the
growth response, depends on the quality and durability of the specific
measures underpinning it. Government expenditures that are productive
and a tax system that is efficient and broad based contribute to growth and
development. And measures perceived as durable allay concerns about
debt sustainability and alter people’s behavior. Fiscal responsibility laws,
transparency, and good governance can also play an important role in
achieving high-quality and durable adjustment.
Quick Fixes
In reality, policymakers face constraints that can preclude smooth and
timely implementation of high-quality reforms. This may be especially true
when immediate fiscal tightening is needed to avert an impending crisis.
In such cases, policymakers may opt for short-term reduction of deficits
through measures that cannot be sustained or that hamper growth (“quick
fixes”)—which are typically spending cuts. If they cannot be avoided, they
should at least be quickly replaced with better-quality measures.
• Across-the-board cuts often seem attractive; this approach allows each
individual operating ministry to decide how to cut its budget and it appears to imply equal hardship for all. But cuts in dissimilar programs
will not have the same economic consequences. Such cuts can also
quickly lead to arrears, add to long-term costs (e.g., by postponing
maintenance), avoid having to revisit priorities, and lead to inefficiencies by disturbing work patterns (e.g., no gasoline for tax inspection
vehicles or ambulances). In the absence of a more fundamental review,
any savings are likely to be reversed sooner or later.
• Across-the-board cuts in nonwage current spending can result in less
funds for highly productive nonwage social sector inputs, such as medicines or textbooks.
29
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
• Spending financed from privatization proceeds may need to be reversed
once this one-off source of financing dries up.
• Financial transactions taxes can drive financial transactions underground, especially if set at relatively high levels. Fewer financial transactions result in falling revenue yields, the economy loses productivity,
and the banking system suffers.
• Export surcharges undermine the competitiveness of the critical export
sector, reduce the country’s access to foreign exchange, and weaken
growth.
• Repeated tax amnesties—apart from raising fairness issues—erode taxpayers’ incentives to comply with tax laws and damage the credibility of
tax authorities. This results in lower revenues over the longer term, with
the benefits typically accruing to the better-off in society.
Durable Adjustments
Durable expenditure reductions in industrial countries typically involve
tackling the wage bill, subsidies, and transfers (Alesina and Perotti, 1997).
Evidence also suggests that emerging market economies with lower subsidies and transfers or higher revenues are more likely to sustain consolidations. Similarly, developing countries that cut selected current spending
while protecting capital expenditures tend to experience longer-lasting
adjustment. For countries with low revenue-to-GDP ratios (most developing countries), revenue increases can also lengthen the duration of fiscal
consolidation (Gupta and others, 2004).
Higher-quality and more durable reforms typically take time to implement and to yield budgetary benefits. This is true, for example, for broadening the tax base or shifting from trade taxes to broad-based sales taxes,
especially when administrative capacity is weak. Civil service reform
requires prior groundwork preparation, such as civil service censuses, and
may also require severance outlays (Box 4). Such measures should therefore be implemented as part of an overall policy package that provides for
an appropriate degree of short-run deficit reduction.
Fiscal Responsibility Laws
Fiscal responsibility laws aim to impose durable fiscal discipline and
overcome the problem of “deficit bias” (IMF, forthcoming). Such laws
attempt to impose an underlying constraint, of varying degrees of formality, on fiscal policy and often on those that make it. Fiscal responsibil30
III. What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
Box 4 . Civil Service Reform
Civil service reform often plays a central role in fiscal adjustment programs. Such reforms typically aim to reduce high wage bills (which they
have often failed to do), improve productivity, and lessen incentives for
corruption. A centralized reform strategy is based on a functional review
that identifies unnecessary programs and positions. A decentralized strategy
focuses on changing the incentive structure (freedom in hiring/firing/pay decisions and performance-based budgeting and assessment of top personnel).
The prerequisites for a successful decentralized reform are a high degree of
transparency and accountability.
Civil service reform is particularly difficult but careful sequencing helps.
• Civil service censuses and functional reviews should precede the design
of retrenchment programs. In Cambodia, for example, a civil service census and the fingerprinting and registration of civil servants in all provinces
reportedly eliminated thousands of ghost workers.
• Civil service wages should be set within the budget process (rather than
independently by parliament), and monetization and consolidation of benefits should precede reforms of pay structures. In Honduras, for example,
before reforming the salary structure, a new wage policy law had to be
passed. The law eliminated special wage regimes and gave the ministry of
finance (rather than congress) the power to determine government wage
increases.
ity laws can entail numeric rules, such as a balanced budget, or impose
procedures focusing on enhancing transparency and accountability. They
typically require that the government commit to a monitorable fiscal
policy strategy or to specific fiscal targets.20 Some contain well-defined
sanctions for noncompliance. Fiscal responsibility laws generally include
explicit escape clauses that suspend their application during exceptional
circumstances, such as natural disasters or severe recessions. They can
also define fiscal targets in terms of multiyear horizons or structurally
adjusted indicators.
20Independent fiscal authorities are an alternative to numerical rules to depoliticize fiscal
policy decisions, but devolving such authority can be politically difficult. Fiscal councils that
provide independent analysis are a less politically difficult option, but they are less binding
on policy.
31
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Because in most countries fiscal responsibility laws have not been
around for more than a few years, evidence on their effectiveness remains
preliminary. But some tentative lessons seem to be emerging:
• Institutions should be sufficiently developed to support the requirements
included in the legal framework. Public finance management systems,
in particular, should be sufficiently advanced to credibly implement, and
enforce, the procedural and fiscal rules.
• Fiscal responsibility laws require broad political consensus to be successful and are not a substitute for political commitment. While the
adoption of such laws can potentially catalyze meaningful reforms promoting fiscal prudence, experience suggests that broad support for fiscal
prudence is a precondition for their success. Designing the framework
takes time and should be aimed at addressing country-specific weaknesses in fiscal management that underlie poor fiscal outcomes. These
requirements may not be met in countries facing large macroeconomic
imbalances or political instability.
• Fiscal responsibility laws should cover a broad definition of government. Those with broader coverage of the public sector tend to be more
successful than those more narrowly focused (e.g., only on the central
government).
• In countries with a weak track record of policy implementation, procedural rules may work better than numeric rules. Under these circumstances, procedural rules21 can often be beneficial by promoting fiscal
discipline through increased transparency and accountability.
• Numeric fiscal rules, if included, should be carefully designed. Numerical rules can be helpful, for instance, in containing a deficit bias,
but they are not in themselves the solution to structural fiscal problems. Numeric fiscal rules can even foster creative accounting and lowquality measures.
• While fiscal rules have worked in particular cases, the evidence on their
effectiveness in improving fiscal outcomes remains tentative. If adopted,
fiscal rules should be (1) well-defined regarding the specific fiscal
indicator to be targeted, the institutional coverage, and, if any, escape
21Procedural rules aim to enhance transparency, accountability, and fiscal management.
They typically require the government to commit up-front to a monitorable fiscal policy
strategy, usually for a multiyear period, and to routinely report and publish fiscal outcomes
and strategy changes.
32
III. What Makes Fiscal Adjustment Successful?
clauses; (2) simple and transparent, to serve as an effective instrument
of communication of government policy objectives; and (3) monitorable, so that noncompliance can be easily detected and addressed. Their
credibility ultimately depends on the government’s track record and on
political and social consensus.
• Enforcement mechanisms should be credible and effective. Escape
clauses should be reduced to a minimum to ensure the credibility of the
process. These frameworks should also define enforcement mechanisms
that could include financial or administrative sanctions for responsible
government officials.
• Fiscal responsibility laws should enhance transparency. Countries
with poor transparency and budget procedures are also unlikely to
effectively monitor a meaningful quantitative fiscal target or enforce
accountability.
Transparency and Governance
Fiscal transparency can support fiscal adjustment by contributing to better and more sustainable policies, and by strengthening accountability. Fiscal transparency seeks to enhance the public’s understanding of the structure and functions of government, fiscal policy intentions, the soundness of
public sector accounts, and fiscal projections (Box 5). It should contribute
to a more balanced adjustment, especially in the short term, since targets
can only be set on activities that are reported fairly reliably.
Fiscal transparency should make adjustment measures more durable by
generating broader public support and understanding; by facilitating donor
support through credible assurances about the use of donor funds; and by
increasing predictability for, and confidence in, financial markets. Transparency also makes officials more accountable and reduces the scope for
circumventing the declared adjustment effort by, for example, thwarting
attempts to shift activities off budget. Parliaments can play a particularly
important role in enforcing transparency.
Globalization has increased the pressure on, and rewards for, countries
to be more transparent and accountable in managing their economies. It
creates incentives for policymakers to reform policies and institutions
to enable their countries to benefit from the rising international flows of
capital, technology, and information. Increasingly, attracting foreign direct
investment and accessing financial markets at reasonable rates requires
33
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 5 . Fiscal Transparency
The IMF’s Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency (IMF, 2001b)
is a set of good practices that can be implemented by most countries over the
medium to longer term. It presents a standard of fiscal transparency that provides assurances to the public, to donors, and to markets that a sufficiently
complete picture of the government’s structure and finances is available to
facilitate a reliable assessment of the soundness of a country’s fiscal position. The code is based on four general principles.
• The principle of clarity of roles and responsibilities requires specifying
the structure and functions of government, responsibilities within government, and relations between government and the rest of the economy.
• Public availability of information emphasizes the importance of publishing comprehensive fiscal information at clearly specified times.
• Open budget preparation, execution, and reporting covers the type of
information made available about the budget process. Budget documentation should specify fiscal policy goals, and the macroeconomic framework, and should clearly describe new policies and identify major fiscal
risks.
• Assurances of integrity stress the quality of fiscal data and the need for
independent scrutiny of fiscal information. This includes an external audit
by a national audit body and assessment by independent experts of fiscal
forecasts, the macroeconomic forecasts on which they are built, and all
underlying assumptions.
not only sound macroeconomic policies but also more transparent and accountable public institutions.
Governance plays a critical role in determining the quality of fiscal
adjustment, especially in scaling up expenditure in low-income countries.
Good governance is generally recognized as a core ingredient of successful
development. It is pivotal for translating resources into outcomes, given
the strong link between the quality of a country’s governance system and
its development performance. And in an aid environment that increasingly
rests on mutual accountability between donors and recipient governments,
governance plays a vital role in stimulating and maintaining donor flows.
34
IV .
How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
The most welcome way of increasing revenue would be for the
prince to abolish superfluous expenditure, to disband redundant
offices, to avoid wars and foreign tours, . . . to check the
acquisitiveness of officialdom, and to pay more attention to the just
administration of his territory than to its expansion.
— Desiderius Erasmus (1469–1536)
Fiscal adjustment should ideally be carried out through high-quality
structural measures early in the process. These include sound revenue and
expenditure policies for the medium term, as well as short-run options that
are best for growth. Social safety nets can mitigate any short-term costs
imposed by fiscal consolidation on the poor.
Improving the Tax System and Mobilizing Revenue
Structural problems in the tax system may well be a major contributor to
fiscal deficits, and also to poor growth and unemployment. The ability to
generate revenue by raising tax rates may be limited, particularly when an
economy is undergoing substantial structural change, tax bases are narrow,
hard-to-tax sectors (e.g., agriculture and the self-employed) are large, existing rates are high, or tax administration is weak—conditions that often
reinforce one another. Thus, fiscal consolidation is often accompanied by
measures to improve the tax system, while taking into consideration the
equity and efficiency impact of reforms.
Tax systems need to balance macroeconomic and microeconomic
objectives (Tanzi and Zee, 2000). In particular, a tax system should
ideally be:
• Productive. A central goal of the tax system is to raise revenue to finance government spending. This requires a system that can generate
revenue increases at least in line with the growth in income without
frequent changes in tax rates or introducing new taxes. Charging low
rates on a broad base typically best meets this objective. Exemptions
35
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
and incentives—such as (and arguably worst of all) tax holidays—can
severely undermine revenue-raising capacity, often with little if any
offsetting benefits (Box 6).
• Efficient. Taxes distort relative prices and thus affect the pattern of
production, consumption, investment, and income. Unless there is
strong reason to suppose that market prices are themselves sending
the wrong signals—which may be the case, for example, when some
activity causes environmental damage—an efficient tax system imposes low and reasonably uniform tax rates on as broad a tax base as
possible. It also avoids exemptions or special tax rates that artificially
encourage investment in projects with below-market returns. However,
when environmental or other externalities are present—where parties to
some transaction do not bear all the social costs or enjoy all the social
benefits—then particular taxes (e.g., on pollution) or, subsidies (e.g.,
to basic education) although less likely (given their revenue cost and
potential for abuse) are in principle appropriate.
• Fair. Each country must decide for itself exactly what constitutes fairness. Distinguishing between vertical and horizontal equity can be useful. Vertical equity refers to differentiation of the tax burden according
to ability to pay, and horizontal equity, to equal treatment of those in
similar economic circumstances. Certain types of taxation may affect
income distribution—for example, a progressive income tax or a reduced rate of value-added tax (VAT) on basic foods. But experience
has shown that taxation is relatively ineffective in influencing income
distribution in general, and in helping the poor in particular. And this is
becoming increasingly true as tax bases (especially, but not only, capital
income) become more mobile internationally. Expenditure policy is
generally better suited to influencing income distribution, and equity
effects should be designed and assessed comprehensively, embracing
not only all taxes but also the spending they finance.
• Simple and transparent. Taxes with a single rate or a low number of
rates and minimal exemptions are easier to administer and easier for the
taxpayer to understand, comply with, and—ultimately—express views
about. Tax rates should be stable and predictable. Once tax laws that
generate buoyant revenue growth are in place, frequent amendments
should be avoided. If changes are planned, taxpayers should ideally
know the implications in advance (unless this creates unacceptable
scope for tax avoidance).
36
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
Box 6 . Dangers of Tax Holidays
Tax holidays—exemptions from tax, sometimes for many years—are
a particularly ill-designed form of investment incentive for the following
reasons:
• They attract the most footloose forms of business, since they can easily
move elsewhere at the end of the holiday. These are the firms least likely
to offer spillovers to the wider economy in terms of training or deep linkages with the domestic economy.
• They are open to abuse, undermining tax revenue not only directly but
indirectly, by providing entrepreneurs with an incentive to use transfer
pricing and financial arrangements that shift taxable income to holiday
companies from companies that would otherwise be taxed. For example,
taxpaying companies (able to deduct the interest payments) can arrange to
borrow from holiday companies (not taxable on interest received).
• In many cases, the appeal of tax holidays has been that they protect companies from exploitation by corrupt tax administrations. By the same token,
offering a holiday can be seen as signaling a low-quality civil service.
• They are relatively inefficient at encouraging employment (often the
claimed objective) since, like other investment-based incentives, they
encourage the use of capital, not labor.
• Developing countries have felt compelled to offer such incentives because of tax competition with each other, and this appears to be one of
the reasons for the reduction in corporate tax revenues in many countries.
But tax holidays do nothing to address the underlying problems that may
deter foreign investment (e.g., instability of the tax system, an ineffective
judicial system, arbitrariness in administration and red tape, and foreign
exchange restrictions). The evidence suggests, indeed, that tax factors,
while they do matter, are far from the main concern of foreign investors
in deciding where to place their funds.
There are better options for stimulating investment, such as accelerated
depreciation and capital allowances. Maintaining a reasonably broad base
for the corporate income tax makes it easier to set a reasonably low corporate tax rate. This in itself is likely to protect the revenue base and provide
a supportive environment for investment. Realizing this, a number of countries have scaled back tax holidays and other tax incentives for investment.
Sometimes, however, countries feel pressure to retain or expand such incentives to compete with those available elsewhere. This leads to a mutually
damaging form of tax competition. In such cases, regional agreements can
be helpful—for example, on a code of conduct on business taxation, as adopted by the European Union.
37
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
The design of the major taxes should draw on the following criteria:
• Sales tax or VAT. This should be a broad-based tax on final domestic
consumption that does not tax intermediate consumption or exports,
and does not differentiate by source of production (foreign or domestic;
see Ebrill and others, 2001). Because of its efficiency (in not affecting
business use of inputs) and revenue security (in collecting revenue at all
stages in the production chain, not just at final sale), the ideal instrument
to achieve this goal is usually a VAT levied at a single positive rate—key
elements being crediting provisions to remove businesses’ input purchases from tax and zero rating22 of exports. Exemptions should be
avoided as far as possible, since they reduce the efficiency of the VAT
by causing it to “cascade” through the chain of production (Harrison
and Krelove, 2005). Zero-rating other than for exports should also be
avoided, since it creates a need to pay refunds that can cause great administrative difficulty. Nevertheless, exemptions are often given either
on technical grounds (for financial services) or—albeit misguidedly,
since most of the benefit often goes to the better off, who buy more
of these items than the poor—for equity reasons, as for selected basic
foodstuffs and basic education and health services.
• Excises. Imposing excises (which, unlike the VAT, are not creditable)
on a limited number of commodities can be a good tax handle when
demand for the commodities is inelastic and the commodities can be
easily monitored. They are appropriate for dealing with negative externalities (e.g., a gasoline tax to address problems of local air pollution
and global warming) and have, for some, a particular appeal in limiting
consumption of “harmful” items (e.g., alcohol and tobacco). Excises
should be levied equally on domestic production and imports and, with
a few exceptions—notably for petroleum products (to avoid worsening
volatility)—on an ad valorem basis.23
• Customs duties. A low, across-the-board tariff is useful for revenue
reasons in countries where other, preferable, taxes may be hard to
administer. Schemes are needed to relieve exporters of the anti-export
bias caused by customs duties on inputs, either by a system of drawback
22Under both “zero-rating” and “exemption,” no tax is charged on sales; they differ, however, in that taxes paid on inputs are refunded under zero-rating but not under exemption.
23A tax, duty, or fee that varies based on the value of the products, services, or property on
which it is levied.
38
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
•
•
•
•
(refunding duties paid on imports used to produce exports) or by one
of suspension (excluding such imports from duty altogether). Exemptions from customs duties should be limited and clearly defined to avoid
abuse. As trade liberalization proceeds, revenue from this source is likely
to fall. For many developing countries, a key challenge is to strengthen
their domestic revenue systems to replace lost trade tax revenues.
Export taxes. Export taxes should generally be avoided as they tend
to draw resources from the export sector toward less efficient uses,
compromising growth. But they can be useful on a limited basis for
hard-to-tax activities (common in the agriculture sector), as a temporary
substitute for income taxation, and to absorb one-time windfall gains
(e.g., from devaluation or from exceptional movements in world commodity prices).
Business income taxes. A tax on profits should ideally be levied at a single rate, broadly comparable with the top marginal rate of the personal
income tax. This minimizes the likelihood of tax-induced shifts between
personal income and enterprises. Deductions, allowances, and credits
are best applied neutrally across sectors and assets to foster efficiency.
If tax incentives are considered, they should consist of accelerated
depreciation—that is, allowing assets to be written off for tax purposes
more rapidly than they actually depreciate. A minimum profits tax
based on turnover or gross assets may be used in some circumstances to
promote compliance and equity, and to secure revenue. For small businesses and the informal sector, a simple presumptive tax based on gross
assets or other indicators can be used, given the difficulty of assessing
their actual incomes.
Natural resource taxation. This generally requires specialized tax instruments to ensure that risk and revenues are shared appropriately
between the government and investors, and that the resource itself is
responsibly exploited.
Personal income taxes. A basic personal income exemption should be set
high enough to exclude the poor. Sufficient progressivity can be achieved
with only a few income tax brackets. Tax bands should be adjusted periodically for inflation to avoid “bracket creep,” while incentive and compliance considerations argue for keeping rates as low as possible. It is
not prudent, however, to expect a cut in high marginal rates—as seen
recently in a number of countries that introduced a “flat tax”—to produce an actual increase in revenue. One textbook view is that income
39
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
taxes should be levied on a “global” base—charging tax on the sum of
income of all kinds. However, it is often administratively convenient to
establish schedular taxes24 on different sources of income (e.g., through
final withholding taxes on interest income). A number of countries have
recently experimented successfully with a “dual” income tax of this kind,
combining a low, flat rate of tax on capital income and a progressive tax
on labor income.
Major reforms in tax design and administration take time to implement
and to achieve their expected revenue impact. New legislation is often
required and basic systems and procedures frequently need modification.
Short-term measures may thus be needed. They should be assessed in
terms of their effect on resource allocation, fairness, administrative feasibility, and their consistency with the desired direction of longer-term tax
reform. The most promising measures for producing short- (and indeed
long-) term revenue increases typically involve expanding the tax base by
eliminating tax exemptions (especially tax privileges). Not only can this
raise revenue, it can also simplify administration, freeing up resources for
more productive activities, and it fosters taxpayer compliance as well.
Rationalizing Public Expenditure and Protecting the Poor
Public expenditure reform is typically undertaken to reduce government
spending. But even when public spending need not shrink, expenditure reform can still improve the productivity of existing spending, free resources
to help meet new needs, and improve governance and transparency (Gupta
and others, 2005a). Reducing expenditures while improving their composition need not undermine growth or social indicators.
Spending cuts should be pragmatic—adequate to achieve the intended
goals yet economically sound and socially feasible. Many measures can
be taken quickly, but durable, good-quality expenditure reform typically
demands a review of underlying government policies, the composition of
spending, the coverage of activities by the public sector, and the modes of delivery of public services. Quite often, a thorough structural reform of government spending policies can be done only over a number of years (Box 7).
24A schedular tax system disaggregates income into components such as labor income,
dividends, and royalties and then separately applies tax rates and exemptions.
40
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
Box 7 . Fundamental Public Expenditure Reform
Fundamental structural reform requires asking basic questions about
whether government activities are needed, should be provided by the public
sector, or could be made more market based. For activities to remain in the
public sector, specific objectives need to be set, desired outputs quantified
(where possible), inputs determined, and managerial freedom given to pursue the most efficient delivery of services.
A comprehensive review might generate the following types of reforms:
• Eliminate unproductive or low-priority services.
• Privatize activities that can, and should, be carried out in the private
sector.
• Introduce a more commercial approach to public activities, including
competitive tendering and contracting out of some services to the private
sector.
• Simulate market discipline, including in government purchasing and provision of services, for example, in health care.
• Enhance management of those services that are to remain in the public
sector. This would entail, for example, more devolved managerial authority and linking of managers’ salaries to performance.
• In countries where public expenditure management is advanced, introduce
“performance-based” budgets that strengthen links between the results
delivered by agencies and the funding they receive.
Longer-Term Expenditure Reform
Public spending should be judged on its impact on growth and investment, as well as on poverty and equity. Apart from core government
functions, market failures (e.g., positive externalities, public goods, and
imperfect credit markets) are a main justification for public sector activity. Public expenditures also play a redistributive role, especially when
targeted at the poor.
The private sector may refrain from certain activities that have a large social return because the private return is too low. This will be the case when
there are positive spillover effects (“externalities”) and for public goods. In
the case of positive externalities, the market will produce too little of a good
relative to the socially optimal amount—for example, too little education
relative to the benefits accruing to the community at large. In the extreme
case of public goods, where it is impossible to charge people for the benefits
41
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
they receive, these goods will likely not be produced by the private sector
at all. Alternatively, the private return of an investment may be sufficiently
high, but financing, owing to market failure, may be unavailable.
Productive expenditures are those that have a high social rate of return.
Such rates of return are difficult to measure, but at the functional level,
they are often highest in infrastructure, primary education, preventive and
primary health care, and basic public services. In terms of their impact
on poverty, programs in primary education, basic health care, water and
sanitation, roads, rural development, agriculture, judicial systems, and
anti-corruption appear to have the largest impact. Expenditure composition
in many countries suggests that there is great scope for improvement:
• About one-fifth of education spending is allocated to tertiary education,
which has a lower rate of social return than education spending at the
primary and secondary levels.
• Similarly, in the health care sector, spending on basic preventive health
care—such as immunizations—have a high social return and also a relatively larger impact on the poor. Still, almost two-thirds of public health
care outlays tend to be absorbed by curative care rather than basic and
preventive health care.
• Some governments provide generalized subsidies. These are usually
distortionary. For example, subsidies that encourage wasteful power,
water, and fertilizer use generally damage the environment and typically
benefit the better-off in society as they consume more than the poor. In
some instances, subsidies can be targeted at the poor, while in others,
they can be eliminated and the proceeds used to benefit the poor (for
example, by developing rural transportation networks).
Spending on goods and services other than wages can be highly productive, but it often bears the brunt of adjustment. Highly productive nonwage inputs, such as medicines and textbooks, are often crowded out by
wages and salaries. As a result, health care workers and teachers are left
without the necessary complementary inputs. Similarly, public investment
programs often ignore the recurrent costs of a project, resulting in rapid
deterioration of infrastructure.
Other than by targeting specific sectors, the productivity of government
spending can be increased by addressing governance and management issues. In education, the quality of teachers, and whether they turn up and
teach, is more important than class size. This underscores the relative
importance of reasonable wages over the number of teachers. Investment
42
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
expenditure is notorious for containing “white elephants,” such as underused airports and bridges. The productivity of investment can be increased
by following some basic principles. These include subjecting large projects
to tighter scrutiny and rigorous cost-benefit analysis and monitoring all
central and local governments proposed and ongoing projects.
Reducing corruption will tend to improve the quality of spending and
the amount of revenue to finance it (Tanzi, 1998). In particular, corruption
tends to be linked with less spending on health and nonwage operations
and maintenance and with more allocations for less productive investment
projects and military spending.
Countries with aging populations will require two very difficult adjustments, entailing not only changes in spending patterns but also in the
promises that governments make.
• Pension reform. Pension systems face two challenges. First, most public
pension systems promise benefits that cannot be financed with existing
contributions. Countries have several options for addressing this medium- to long-term problem (Box 8). At one extreme, they can restructure existing pay-as-you-go systems to bring benefits into actuarial balance with contributions. At the other extreme, they can shift to private,
funded systems, gradually reducing current implicit pension liabilities.
Even in this latter case, adjustments in the legacy pay-as-you-go systems will be necessary to make the transition affordable. Second, the
coverage of many pension systems is often narrow and provides preferential treatment for certain groups, such as public sector employees. It is
important to widen coverage; in developing countries, this will require
labor markets to become more formal. However, coverage should not
be widened until existing systems have been reformed to ensure their
long-run sustainability.
• Health care. Adjustments in how health care is rationed and financed
may be even more daunting than pension reform. The elderly are the
most intensive consumers of health care, and the aggregate demand for
health care will grow rapidly as populations age. Rapid technological
change in health care has been, and will likely continue, expanding
available treatments, often at substantial cost. Other demands on the
health care system, such as HIV/AIDS, may compound the growth in
the demand for health care. Allocating health care spending in a manner
that is both fiscally responsible and socially equitable is one of the biggest challenges currently facing economic policymakers.
43
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 8 . Key Issues in Pension Reform
The fiscal unsustainability of many public pay-as-you-go pension schemes
has become increasingly apparent in recent decades. Many countries—
especially developed countries with large unfunded liabilities—are
attempting to remedy this problem. In so doing, several choices must be
made:
• Public versus private. A threshold question is what role the government
should play in the pension system. It may want to take an active role
in the system if workers are myopic about their future income needs or
might refrain from saving on their own in the belief that the government
will provide assistance in any event. The government may also want the
system to have a redistributive component.
• Defined-benefit versus defined-contribution. Pension systems are typically
either defined-benefit, in which benefits are determined by formula based
on prior income, or defined-contribution, where benefits are determined
by the amount of accumulated contributions. These two choices differ
in the manner in which risk is allocated between the plan sponsor—for
instance, the government—and the participant.
• Funded versus pay-as-you-go. A system can be either funded, in which
contributions are invested and accrue market returns, or pay-as-you-go, in
which the contributions of current workers are used to pay the benefits of
current retirees.
Choices along these dimensions must be carefully considered and will—
at least for some developing countries—be dictated by the capacity of the
private sector to administer the system and provide investment opportunities. Moreover, shifting from a pay-as-you-go to a funded system entails
significant transition costs, and a country’s ability to finance these costs will
determine the feasibility and speed of such a shift. A transition to a funded
pension system may be desirable, but there is no substitute for reforming
existing pay-as-you-go systems to reduce unfunded liabilities.
Short-Term Expenditure Reform
There are no hard and fast rules about how public expenditure should be
cut in the short run, when needed. This will depend partly on the factors
driving the growth in spending (e.g., wages and salaries or the capital program), as well as on the social and political constraints facing policymakers. However, experience suggests some guidelines.
• Protect core programs. While fiscal consolidation in the short run may
require lower overall spending, it is still possible to safeguard most, if
44
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
•
•
•
•
•
•
not all, core productive expenditures and to protect the poor with welltargeted social safety nets.
Identify specific program reductions. Many programs can and should be
dropped, pruned, or consolidated as economies develop and priorities
change. For instance, free milk distribution may become unnecessary
when income levels rise above a certain level. Program elimination
usually leads to effective savings—because it requires governments to
redefine their priorities and is a first step toward a more fundamental
expenditure review—and it preserves the efficiency of operations elsewhere in the public sector.
Cut the public sector wage bill. Wage restraint and hiring freezes can be
a major source of savings in the short run, but they are politically difficult to sustain and not necessarily desirable from an efficiency point
of view. Thus, they should be seen as interim substitutes for structural
reform that entails a deeper review of employment and pay policies and
program staffing needs.
Target social programs narrowly. General subsidies could be eliminated and transfers made more efficient by targeting eligibility and
by reducing income replacement rates (Gupta and others, 2000a).
Where possible, multiple programs for social protection should be consolidated into more global schemes of income transfers. This avoids
significant overlap in entitlements provided by uncoordinated agencies.
Review the capital program. The capital program is often the prime
target for short-term retrenchment. Postponement of projects not yet
begun can save resources with relatively little disruption of day-to-day
government operations. The cost, however, may be lower growth and
development. Capital programs are best cut in the context of an overall
public investment review—often possible only as part of a medium-term
strategy.
Raise fees and charges. Governments are often reluctant to reduce volumes or standards of delivery in high-priority areas like education and
health. Savings in these areas may best be achieved by cost recovery
through an increase in the fees and charges for services, while protecting the poor.
Change public enterprise tariffs and subsidies. If public enterprises are
in deficit, their pricing structures may need to be adjusted and subsidies
eliminated. The scope of their activities may also need redefining; their employment policy, adjustment; and their capital program, rationalization.
45
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Social Safety Nets and Poverty and Social Impact Analysis
Social safety nets consist of a combination of measures aimed at protecting the poor from the adverse consequences of economic shocks and
structural reforms, and helping them escape poverty. Because social safety
nets need to work quickly and reliably, they must be tailored to the specific
circumstances of each country, including its administrative capabilities, the
strength of its informal and formal social support systems, and the characteristics of the poor. Typically, the major components of social safety nets
include:
• Targeted cash compensation, commodity subsidies, and fee waivers.
With effective targeting, these are the preferred schemes to protect
consumption by the poor in the face of falling incomes or rising prices.
When fees were introduced for budgetary reasons, fee waivers have
been used to help maintain access for the poor to education and health
services. Providing basic minimum services (such as electricity and
water lifelines) at low cost is another option.
• Enhanced unemployment benefits, severance pay, and public works
schemes. Because reforms may lead to a temporary rise in unemployment, assistance can be channeled through schemes designed to mitigate
the fall in employment. Governments should maintain the distinction
between social insurance, typically financed through contributions, and
social assistance, which should be financed through the budget. A welldefined reemployment strategy (e.g., retraining schemes) can also play
a role.
Targeting and incentives are the key issues in the design of social safety
nets. Sophisticated means testing is generally not possible, owing to the lack
of administrative capacity. Many countries rely instead on categorical targeting, such as limiting benefits to children or pensioners, or to households
in certain especially poor regions. Another form of targeting that requires
little administrative capacity is to limit subsidies to goods consumed disproportionately by the poor, or to limit the quantity that each household can
consume, for example, via coupons. The fiscal cost of the social safety net
is reduced the more sharply benefits are phased out with rising household
income. This, however, increases the implicit marginal tax rate facing beneficiaries, and thus the potential adverse impact on work incentives.
PSIA can be used to determine the impact of expenditure (and other
policies) on the poor. It is the analysis of the positive and negative consequences of changes in policy (e.g., taxation, trade reforms, public enter46
IV. How Should Fiscal Adjustment Be Carried Out?
prise retrenchment, and social expenditures) on the welfare of different
groups in society—with an explicit focus on the poor and vulnerable.
Depending on country circumstances, PSIA may employ a variety of tools
to gauge the impact of policies. These include incidence analysis, social
impact surveys, micro-simulation models using household surveys, and
computable general equilibrium models. These tools rely on inputs from
governments, which, in turn, derive from an open consultative process,
including with civil society. A PSIA may suggest modifying proposed
policies or strengthening social safety nets to accompany new policies.
47
V .
What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
The more a people feel taxation, and the more jealously they
watch over public expenditure, the better it is for them and for
their rulers.
—Francis Wayland (1796–1865)
Fiscal adjustment does not happen in a vacuum. It is not enough for a
finance minister simply to decide to adjust; the decision must be put into
effect and supported by public institutions. Without well-functioning fiscal
institutions, even the best-designed policy measures risk failure. Key fiscal
institutions for achieving and sustaining fiscal adjustment include those
that implement revenue administration (tax and customs), budget (public
financial) management, and intergovernmental relations.
Modernizing Revenue Administration
Raising revenue and implementing revenue policies depends critically
on the quality of revenue administration (Silvani and Baer, 1997). Customs departments face additional challenges, for example, from trade
liberalization, the requirements of World Trade Organization membership,
and the heightened need to protect national borders (Keen, 2003). Strong
and modern revenue administrations will be better able to implement new
revenue measures effectively, generating a rapid revenue response. Weak
and outdated administrations typically need reforming if they are to deliver
durable revenue improvements.
Modernizing revenue administrations means moving to a principle of
voluntary compliance, where taxpayers and traders are expected to comply with their obligations with little intervention from revenue officials.
This recognizes that no revenue administration can determine the correct liability and control the compliance of every taxpayer. Voluntary
compliance is achieved through self-assessment, where taxpayers and
traders—with access to information and assistance from the tax and customs departments—calculate their own liabilities, file returns and declara48
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
tions, and pay the tax and duties that they themselves assess. If they fail to
make accurate assessments and pay the correct amounts, they risk being
audited and paying penalties. The roles for tax and customs departments
are, first, to help taxpayers and traders understand and meet their obligations, and, second, to take action against noncompliers, particularly those
with greatest impact on the revenue performance.
Beyond these general principles, modern revenue administrations require the following:
• Clear and simple laws. Laws and regulations that are easy to understand and apply facilitate efficient revenue administration and minimize
taxpayer/trader effort and compliance costs.
• Efficient collection systems and procedures. Simple forms and straightforward assessment, filing, and payment arrangements facilitate administration and compliance. Administrations need to strike a balance
between the controls necessary to protect revenue and the costs and
inconvenience imposed on businesses in meeting their obligations.
• Service orientation. Tax and customs departments face increasing demands to improve their service to the business sector. This is particularly so for customs administrations, where improvements in service
directly reduce the costs and enhance the competitiveness of exporters
and importers.
• Verification programs based on risk analysis. Modern administrations
optimize tax collection by focusing on taxpayers and traders posing
the greatest risk to revenue. Tax and customs administrations should
embrace risk-management approaches and develop analytical capabilities to better understand the make-up and compliance behaviors of the
taxpayer and trader base.
• Function-based organizational structures. Experience strongly suggests
that tax departments organized according to key functions (such as audit
and enforcement) operate more efficiently than those structured by type
of tax. Function-based administrations facilitate specialization. They
also eliminate duplication and inefficiencies characteristic of tax-typebased structures.
• High level of automation. Because a large part of revenue collection
involves high-volume transaction processing, modern revenue administrations rely heavily on information technology. Computerized systems
are also essential for supporting the information needs and analysis associated with risk-management approaches.
49
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 9 . Features of a Dedicated Large Taxpayer Office
Taxpayers covered. Depending on the selection criteria used, the taxes to
be covered, and the resources to be committed, large taxpayer offices typically cover 60–80 percent of the domestic tax revenue base but usually only
500–1,000 taxpayers (typically 1–2 percent of the total).
Taxes covered. Most large taxpayer offices and large taxpayer audit units
in developing countries focus on collection, enforcement, and audit of (1)
corporate and other income taxes; (2) VAT or sales tax; (3) excises; and (4)
taxes withheld from the salaries and wages of their employees.
Criteria used to identify large taxpayer offices. Annual turnover is the
most effective and objective way to identify large taxpayers. Other criteria
sometimes used—but not preferred—include (1) amount of tax arrears; (2)
level of imports; and (3) specific economic sectors (e.g., banks and insurance companies).
Large taxpayer office organization and functions. Function-based organizational structures work best. Key functions include registration, all
information processing tasks, taxpayer assistance, collection monitoring and
enforcement, and taxpayer audit.
Service strategy. Large taxpayer offices provide a single point of access
for large taxpayer inquiries, requests for rulings on important technical issues, and so on.
Audit strategy. Because of the large amounts of revenue involved, and the
complexity of many transactions and their taxation treatment, large taxpayers often require close audit attention. It is not uncommon, therefore, for 50
percent or more of large taxpayer office resources to be devoted to auditrelated activities.
• Differentiated treatment of taxpayers by their revenue potential. A growing trend among tax administrations has been to give special attention
to the largest taxpayers. As a first step, this often involves establishing
a large taxpayer office for the most significant taxpayers (Box 9). A
number of tax administrations have further segmented their taxpayer
population and developed enforcement and service programs tailored
to the needs and risk profiles of medium-sized enterprises and small
businesses.
• Effective management. Modern revenue administrations increasingly
recognize the importance of a strong and professional management
team to formulate the revenue administration’s strategy; communicate
50
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
the organization’s direction and objectives to its staff and external stakeholders; ensure that the organization focuses on sustained and fundamental improvements in performance, not just short-term revenue
targets; and ensure that resources match the required outputs.
All of this takes considerable time: a full-blown modernization program
can take three to five years to carry out. Benefits are likely to flow during
that time as new systems and processes come on stream. But the lag effect, as taxpayers begin to change their underlying behavior in response
to a more effective tax administration, can take longer. In the short term,
generating revenue quickly from administration reform alone is difficult
and efforts should focus on specific areas of noncompliance:
• Better controlling large taxpayers. A large taxpayer office can usually be
set up for administration of the biggest taxpayers within 12 months and it
should be staffed with the best personnel from the tax administration.
• Ensuring that state-owned enterprises are compliant. This sends a
strong signal to the private sector that the government is serious about
compliance.
• Implementing compliance-enforcement programs to target the largest
and newest arrears using task forces of specially trained staff.
• Establishing audit teams trained to deal with problematic sectors, and
conducting a program of short and sharp routine VAT audits to generate
a credible presence in the taxpayer community.
• Setting up registration task forces to bring in significant taxpayers that
have opted out of the tax system can be productive, provided that they
target medium-sized taxpayers and not a large number of nonproductive
small taxpayers.
• If the VAT threshold is set too low, raising it can free up resources from
administering a large number of nonproductive taxpayers and refocus
these resources on the more significant medium-taxpayer group. Reducing
filing frequency from monthly to quarterly for medium taxpayers can also
substantially reduce administration and allow resources to be refocused.
Effective Public Financial Management
Implementing fiscal adjustment requires an effective public financial
management (PFM) system (Potter and Diamond, 1999). Such a system provides a framework for policymakers to determine the appropriate
amount of adjustment and the tools to deliver it. A PFM system is a mul51
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
tifaceted technical process that starts with budget preparation and extends
to budget execution, accounting, and reporting. But even strong preparation and execution systems can be undermined by weak governance and
a poor institutional setup. Ultimately, budgets and PFM systems must be
supported by senior officials and politicians. Ministries of finance need to
be able to enforce fiscal discipline over spending units that are unprotected
by political patronage. In addition, different units in the PFM process need
to be well coordinated and the legal framework needs to be supportive of,
and supported by, a strong-willed executive.
The primary objective for the PFM system in fiscal adjustment is to enforce aggregate control: it must deliver expenditure outcomes consistent with
macro-fiscal policy. This fundamental tenet of sound budget management
requires getting the basics right. The budget needs to fully reflect expected
liabilities. Timely and robust information on spending should be available
so that meaningful expenditure control, which responds to changing macroeconomic conditions, can be exerted. Without these basic functions fulfilled,
even the best policymaking can fail, with deficit targets missed, persistent
payment arrears accrued, and expenditure priorities undermined.
Moving beyond these basic stabilization goals requires the public financial management system to focus on enhancing expenditure efficiency. It
should provide policymakers information and mechanisms that enable them
to pursue productive efficiency (ensuring outputs are delivered for the least
cost) and allocative efficiency (ensuring that the optimum mix of outputs is
provided). The costs of managing public funds should also be minimized.
Budget Preparation
Budget preparation will differ from one country to another, depending
on budgetary systems and capacity. But there are common principles.
Getting the basics right entails ensuring that the budget covers all relevant expenditures in a way that enables policymakers to make the difficult
decisions needed to secure an appropriate fiscal position. For many countries, this means swiftly extending budget coverage, improving the realism
of annual budget projections, and consolidating recurrent and development
budgets. The two key principles are:
• Consistency with macroeconomic constraints. This is best achieved
by having the finance ministry set an overall spending ceiling (a “topdown” approach). Under a “bottom-up” approach, where the budget
spending envelope is determined more by spending ministry requests
52
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
than by macroeconomic considerations, the credibility of the budget
could be undermined and macroeconomic stability threatened.
• Unifying the budget. Revenue and expenditure should be considered
together to determine annual budget targets. The budget should cover
all entities operated on a nonmarket basis, owned or controlled by
the government, and predominantly funded by the budget. Budget
fragmentation—involving, for example, separate development and recurrent budgets and extrabudgetary funds—complicates the development
of a consolidated picture of government finances, hampers assessment
of the recurrent costs of investment plans, and fosters duplication.
Enhancing expenditure efficiency requires a preparation system that can
identify and prioritize growth-enhancing and poverty-reducing activities.
For many countries, this means improving budget classifications, moving
to multiyear frameworks, and gradually inserting measures of output and
performance into the budget preparation system. The key principles are:
• Universality. All resources should be directed to a common pool to be allocated to government priorities. Rigidities in spending priorities—such
as earmarked funds—are often introduced for political economy reasons
and can make resource allocations inefficient and difficult to change. Rigid
spending priorities can also complicate fiscal adjustment as they are not
subject to a review and do not compete for funds with other programs.
• Multiyear planning. Expenditure efficiency requires regular mediumterm planning frameworks by function, ministry, and (ideally) program.
Budgets often focus only on the current year, or are incremental, failing
to consider future circumstances. Thus, they cannot be sustained. The
multiyear plan should be based on existing policies and should facilitate
the evaluation of new policies. It should also be coordinated with debt
management operations.
• Prioritization. Prioritizing expenditures is critical for meeting deficit or
spending targets and helps spending ministries limit their requests. If
priorities are not communicated early in the budget preparation process,
overspending or arrears are likely.
• Adequate nomenclature. Budget classification systems should permit
budgets to be adequately designed, implemented, and checked. Without adequate budget classification, it is not possible to understand how
expenditures are allocated among different items or programs, and thus
how and what to adjust. Spending items should be classified by implementing institution (administrative), purpose of spending (functional),
53
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Box 10 . Tracking Poverty-Reducing Spending
Public spending can, and should, play a major role in tackling poverty. But
this requires that governments know how much they are spending on poverty
reduction and on what items. A basic principle is that all poverty-reducing
spending should be tracked. If only parts are tracked, there can be no assurance that poverty-reducing spending is increasing overall. Well-developed
budget classification systems can rely on existing systems to identify and track
such spending. For others, setting up a “virtual” poverty fund can be a shortterm solution. Such a fund is a limited classification designed to provide financial information specifically about poverty-reducing spending. Budget items
considered (by the country) to contribute to poverty reduction are “tagged,”
and these together form the virtual fund. All tagged items are monitored by the
ministry of finance as part of overall budget execution.
Separate, institutional, poverty funds, where revenues are set aside in a
separate account, with expenditures occurring outside the normal public
financial management system, are problematic for the following reasons:
• They do not necessarily capture additional poverty-reducing spending.
Resources are fungible, and a country can offset spending by the fund by
lowering its own spending in the same area.
• They undermine the comprehensiveness of the budget. Diverting limited
technical skills to create and manage these funds aggravates problems of
transparency, duplication, and governance in the budget as a whole. Such
funds make the budget less flexible without ensuring additional funds for
reducing poverty.
Even when poverty-reducing spending is identified, tracking requires effective government accounting, reporting, and audit systems. These systems
in many poor countries have serious weaknesses and may not provide adequate oversight. In particular, donor-financed spending may not be covered,
and reports on public spending may not be timely or accurate. Devolution
of poverty-reducing programs to local governments can also make tracking
more difficult.
use of expenditure (economic), and—especially for more advanced
public financial management systems—program (e.g., to facilitate the
tracking of poverty-reducing spending) (Box 10).
Budget Execution and Reporting
Budgets, once passed, must be implemented to carry out the intended
adjustment and to adjust to any within-year shocks. This requires effective
budget execution procedures.
54
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
Getting the basics right means addressing the problems that result in
budget overruns and payment arrears. These include the proliferation of
exceptional procedures that bypass expenditure control, and difficulty in
reconciling bank statements with budget accounts, partly because of the
lack of reliable and timely data on cash expenditure. These problems can
be addressed by:
• Controlling spending during the year. Controls should encompass all
the stages of budget execution (typically, authorization, commitment,
verification, payment authorization/order, payment, and accounting).
Many cash-based systems do not provide useful information on commitments, and weak expenditure control fosters arrears.
• Cash planning that ensures the budget is executed as smoothly as possible. A cash plan should project payments coming due and the availability of cash to meet them. When a shortfall is projected over the next
few months, and cash rationing cannot be avoided, authorizations can
be reduced accordingly. Unless commitments by ministries are also
reduced, however, arrears may result.
• Reporting and reconciliation. Timely in-year budget execution reports,
systematic data reconciliations, and clarity on the accounting basis is fundamental to ensure that fiscal adjustment is implemented as planned.
Enhancing expenditure efficiency in the execution and reporting process
can be achieved mainly by reducing the costs of managing public funds—
for example, by establishing a single Treasury account and installing an
integrated financial management system. Also important is enhancing the
quality of reporting to improve transparency and accountability—for example, by moving toward accrual accounting and improving the management of, and accounting for, aid flows. These problems can be effectively
addressed by:
• Implementing an appropriate institutional framework. Line ministries and spending agencies should be responsible for budget execution through delivery of services. And the ministry of finance should
be responsible for regulatory controls and for cash planning and debt
management. To perform these functions, an increasing number of developing countries are strengthening the (typically preexisting) treasury
function within the finance ministry.
• Consolidating all government financial resources in a single account
system. There is a clear, and welcome, international trend toward consolidating all government banking arrangements in a single treasury
55
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
account (TSA), controlled by the ministry of finance. The TSA provides
complete information for government funds, strengthens control over
cash flows (and reconciliation), reduces the cost of borrowing, minimizes idle cash balances, and enhances the efficiency and transparency
of budget execution.
• Integrating the various stages of budget execution into an integrated
financial management information system. This helps manage public
monies better, allowing greater financial control, better monitoring of
the government cash position and better cash planning, and better fiscal
reporting. It also provides better data for budget formulation. Computerization of such integrated treasury systems can further improve efficiency, but it is costly and complex.
• Internal audits and controls and independent (external) audit. These
can be helpful when the staff is well qualified and compliance with audit
recommendations is strong. But it may foster corruption if governance
weaknesses are not addressed.
The list of what a public financial management system should ideally
do is long, and the resources available in many countries to strengthen
such systems are limited. Moreover, what is appropriate in an advanced
economy may not be in a developing country. This means that the design
and sequencing of PFM reforms should be country specific, depending on
needs, the starting point, and on what is practically possible. The guiding
principle for many developing countries should be to get the basics right
before tackling more sophisticated reforms. Not doing so can result in
much financial waste and can even undermine critical parts of the existing
PFM system. These issues of sequencing and capacity-appropriate design
are particularly important in post-conflict countries (Box 11).
Effective Intergovernmental Relationships
If fiscal adjustment is to work for a country as a whole, subnational
finances must be controlled. In particular, experience shows that market
discipline by itself does not prevent unsustainable debt accumulation and
typically needs to be complemented by other forms of borrowing control
(Ter-Minassian, 1997).
Borrowing controls can take the form of rules at lower levels of government or direct controls over subnational borrowing. Under a rules-based approach, debt limits for individual subnational jurisdictions can be set based
56
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
Box 11 . Rebuilding Fiscal Institutions in Post-Conflict Countries
Weak, or nonexistent, institutions make implementing fiscal adjustment
in post-conflict countries particularly challenging. The strategy for rebuilding these institutions must be tailored to the country’s capacity, focusing on
the basics, yet flexible and consistent with the long-term goal of moving
to a modern fiscal system (IMF, 2004b). This strategy entails a three-step
process:
• Creating a legal/regulatory framework for fiscal management. This means
reviewing existing legislation with a view to simplifying tax laws and procedures, or establishing new ones if existing laws are inadequate.
• Establishing/strengthening the central fiscal authority. Such an authority
usually comprises four departments: a budget department, a treasury department, and separate departments for tax and customs administrations.
Some countries have also established an explicit mechanism for coordinating donor assistance. The decentralization that is often needed to secure the peace should not endanger economic reforms and fiscal control.
• Designing appropriate revenue and expenditure policies while simultaneously strengthening revenue administration and public financial management. For tax policy, this means, for example, being more open to
suboptimal policies—such as export taxes—that generate urgently needed
revenue. For revenue administration, it means focusing on basic procedures, such as systems for filing and paying taxes that are easy to comply
with. And for public financial management, it means implementing simplified systems, such as budget classifications under broad categories of
outlays, to be refined later.
on criteria that mimic market discipline, such as current and projected levels
of debt service relative to revenues. Direct controls can also be used. These
include annual limits on the overall debt of individual subnational jurisdictions, central government review and authorization of individual borrowing
operations, and/or the centralization of all government borrowing.
In countries with autonomous subnational governments, the center may
not be able to legislate debt limits, or other requirements. The main leverage
in such cases is transfers from the center, in combination with a no-bailout
commitment of subnational governments by the central government.
While most countries have some form of revenue sharing (where the
central government collects revenue but transfers part of it to subnational
levels), excessive reliance on this method of funding subnational governments can hamper fiscal consolidation. For example, the central govern57
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
ment may need to raise national revenues by more than the targeted reduction in the overall deficit to accommodate extra spending by subnational
governments of shared or earmarked revenue.
Design Issues and the Right Incentives
In theory, assigning expenditure to local levels can raise the efficiency
of service delivery, because the provision of public goods is better targeted
to community needs and governance can be improved. But the potential
efficiency gains can be significantly undermined in practice by the lack
of clear and costed spending responsibilities and institutional constraints.
In addition, devolution of expenditure responsibility to lower levels of
government in countries with regional income disparities will, as a rule,
have to be accompanied by income equalization transfers, which may not
be politically feasible (Ahmad and Craig, 1997). In such circumstances,
decentralization will lead to increased regional disparities in the level and
quality of services and thus hurt the poor.
On the revenue side, the main objectives are accountability on the use
of public funds while leaving the central government with sufficient instruments for stabilization and redistribution. These point to a system of
assignment of own sources of revenue to each level of government—combined with various types of intergovernmental transfers to bridge any resulting gap between revenue and expenditure assignments.
Central government should be assigned taxes levied on the more mobile
tax bases (e.g., profit taxes) to avoid tax competition among lower levels of
government; taxes that are more sensitive to changes in income (or those that
can best be used for stabilization purposes); and taxes that are levied on bases
that are distributed unevenly across regions (e.g., taxes on natural resources),
for distributional reasons (Norregaard, 1997). Multistage sales taxes, such as
the VAT, which are difficult to coordinate and administer at the subnational
level, are also best collected centrally. By contrast, single-stage sales and
excise taxes are generally good candidates for assigning to regional governments. Property taxes, business license taxes, and various types of user fees
for local services are ideal candidates for local taxation, since their base is
relatively immobile. The personal income tax is also suitable for partial assignment—through “piggy-backing”—to the subnational level.
Most tax assignments are likely to cause large vertical imbalances—that
is, fiscal imbalances between the subnational government level and the
national level—as well as horizontal imbalances across jurisdictions, be58
V. What Institutions Can Help Fiscal Adjustment?
cause the capacity to raise own revenues and spending needs differs across
jurisdictions. These imbalances should be addressed through intergovernmental transfers. This is crucial not only to promote a more equitable
distribution of resources, but also to ensure that effective limits can be set
on the borrowing of subnational governments.
Intergovernmental transfers can be broadly grouped into two main
categories: revenue-sharing arrangements and direct transfers (grants).
Transfers can be grouped into general-purpose (unconditional) grants and
specific-purpose (conditional) grants. The latter may be open-ended or
subject to a cap. Both revenue-sharing arrangements and grants can be
tailored to distributional purposes. In general, transfers based on objective
criteria, such as population and per capita income, maintain incentives for
efficient use of resources and tax effort. Gap-filling transfers, on the other
hand, generate perverse incentives that can lead to budget overshooting
and cost overruns.
Key Institutions
Achieving the potential benefits of devolution of spending responsibilities requires strong institutions and a high degree of transparency at all
levels of government. In most developing and emerging market economies, this requires the administrative capacity of subnational governments
to be upgraded substantially. To coordinate overall fiscal policy, it is also
necessary to have timely and complete reporting and control systems at
all levels.
Poor oversight of subnational governments and soft budget constraints
have led to weak governance and to lack of accountability in many countries. In such cases, decentralization has had disappointing results in improving the efficiency and equity of public spending, while weakening the
overall fiscal position. In this context, several countries have been improving their budget processes and developing fiscal responsibility legislation
and internal stability pacts, which include fiscal targets or limits on subnational governments. These changes, to be effective, must be accompanied
by credible sanctions and enforcement mechanisms when subnational
governments breach the rules or do not meet reporting requirements.
59
Bibliography
Ahmad, Ehtisham, and Jon Craig, 1997, “Intergovernmental Transfers,” in Fiscal
Federalism in Theory and Practice, ed. by Teresa Ter-Minassian (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti, 1997, “Fiscal Adjustments in OECD Countries: Composition and Macroeconomic Effects,” Staff Papers, International
Monetary Fund, Vol. 44 (June), pp. 210–48.
Allen, Mark, Christoph Rosenberg, Christian Keller, Brad Setser, and Nouriel
Roubini, 2002, “A Balance Sheet Approach to Financial Crisis,” IMF Working
Paper 02/210 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Baer, Katherine, Olivier Benon, and Juan Toro, 2002, Improving Large Taxpayers’
Compliance: A Review of Country Experience, IMF Occasional Paper No. 215
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Baldacci, Emanuele, Arye Hillman, and Naoko Kojo, 2004, “Growth, Governance,
and Fiscal Policy Transmission Channels in Low-Income Countries,” in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy (Washington: International
Monetary Fund), pp. 67–104.
Barr, Nicholas, 2002, The Pension Puzzle: Prerequisites and Policy Choices in
Pension Design, IMF Economic Issues, No. 29 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Baunsgaard, Thomas, 2001, “A Primer on Mineral Taxation,” IMF Working Paper
01/139 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Bernanke, Ben J., 1983, “Irreversibility, Uncertainty and Cyclical Investment,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 98, No. 1, pp. 85–106.
Bruno, Michael, and William Easterly, 1998, “Inflation Crises and Long-Run
Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 41, pp. 3–26.
Bulíř, Aleš, and Javier Hamann, 2001, “How Volatile and Unpredictable Are Aid
Flows, and What Are the Policy Implications?” IMF Working Paper 01/167
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Bulíř, Aleš, and Timothy Lane, 2004, “Aid and Fiscal Management,” in Helping
Countries Develop; The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by Sanjeev Gupta, Benedict
Clements, and Gabriela Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Chalk, Nigel A., and Richard Hemming, 2000, “Assessing Fiscal Sustainability in
Theory and Practice,” IMF Working Paper 00/81 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
———, 2002, “Structural Balances and All That: Which Indicators to Use in Assessing Fiscal Policy,” IMF Working Paper 02/101 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
60
Bibliography
Coelho, Isaias, Liam Ebrill, and Victoria Summers, 2001, “Bank Debit Taxes in
Latin America: An Analysis of Recent Trends,” IMF Working Paper 01/67
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Corbacho, Ana, and Hamid Davoodi, 2004, “Expenditure Issues and Governance
in Central America,” in The Macroeconomy of Central America, ed. by Robert
Rennhack and Eric Offerdal (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Croce, Enzo, 2002, “Assessment of the Fiscal Balance,” in Macroeconomic Management, Programs, and Policies, ed. by Mohsin Khan, Saleh Nsouli, and
Chorng-Huey Wong (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Dabla-Norris, Era, and Paul Wade, 2002, “The Challenge of Fiscal Decentralization in Transition Countries,” IMF Working Paper 02/103 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Daniel, James, 1997, “Fiscal Aspects of Bank Restructuring,” IMF Working Paper
97/52 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2003, “Hedging Government Oil Risk,” in Fiscal Policy Formulation and
Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, ed. by Jeffrey Davis, Rolando Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, Jeffrey M. Davis, and Andrew M. Wolfe, 1997, “Fiscal Accounting of
Bank Restructuring,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 97/5
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Daniel, James, and Matthew Saal, 1997, “Macroeconomic Impact and Policy
Response,” in Systemic Bank Restructuring and Macroeconomic Policy,” ed.
by William E. Alexander, Jeffrey M. Davis, Liam P. Ebrill, and Carl-Johan
Lindgren (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Davis, Jeffrey M., and others, 2000, Fiscal and Macroeconomic Impact of Privatization, IMF Occasional Paper No. 194 (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Davis, Jeffrey M., Rolando Ossowski, James Daniel, and Steven Barnett, 2003,
“Stabilization and Savings Funds for Nonrenewable Resources: Experience
and Policy Implications, in Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in
Oil-Producing Countries, ed. by Jeffrey Davis, Rolando Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Davis, Jeffrey M., Rolando Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino, eds., 2003, Fiscal
Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Davoodi, Hamid, Erwin Tiongson and Sawitree Asawanuchit, 2003, “How Useful
Are Benefit Incidence Analyses of Public Education and Health Spending?”
IMF Working Paper 03/227 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Dornbusch, Rudiger, 1980, Open Economy Macroeconomics (New York: Basic
Books).
61
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Drummond, Paulo, and Ali Mansoor, 2002, “Macroeconomic Management and
the Devolution of Fiscal Powers,” IMF Working Paper 02/76 (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo, 1993, “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 417–58.
Easterly, William, Carlos A. Rodriguez, and Klauss Schmidt-Hebbel, 1994, Public
Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Performance (New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank).
Easterly, William, and Stanley Fischer, 2001, “Inflation and the Poor,” Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 33 (May), pp. 160–78.
Ebrill, Liam P., Reint Gropp, and Janet G. Stotsky, 1999, Revenue Implications of
Trade Liberalization, IMF Occasional Paper No. 180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Ebrill, Liam P., and others, 2001, The Modern VAT (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Fischer, Stanley, 1993, “The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth,” Journal
of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December), pp. 485–512.
Fouad, Manal, Richard Hemming, Davide Lombardo, and Wojciech Maliszewski,
2005, “Fiscal Transparency and State-Owned Banks,” in The Future of StateOwned Financial Institutions, ed. by G. Caprio, J. Fiechter, R. Litan, and M.
Pomerleano (Washington: Brookings Press), pp. 75–92.
Ghosh, Atish, and Steven Phillips, 1998, “Warning: Inflation May Be Harmful to
Your Growth,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 45 (December), pp. 672–710.
Ghosh, Atish, Timothy Lane, Marianne Schulze-Ghattas, Aleš Bulír̆, Javier Hamann, and Alex Mourmouras, 2002, IMF-Supported Programs in Capital
Account Crises: Design and Experience, IMF Occasional Paper No. 210
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Ghosh, Atish, Timothy Lane, Charalambos Christofides, Jun Kim, Laura Papi,
Uma Ramakrishnan, Alun Thomas, and Juan Zalduendo, 2005, The Design
of IMF-Supported Programs, IMF Occasional Paper No. 241 (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Glewwe, Paul, 2002, “Schools and Skills in Developing Countries,” Journal of
Economic Literature, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 436–82.
Gupta, Sanjeev, Kenneth Miranda, and Ian Parry, 1995, “Public Expenditure Policy
and the Environment: A Review and Synthesis,” World Development, Vol. 23
(March), pp. 515–28.
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2000a, Equity and Efficiency in the Reform of Price
Subsidies: A Guide for Policymakers (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
62
Bibliography
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2000b, Social Issues in IMF-Supported Programs, IMF
Occasional Paper No. 191 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Gupta, Sanjeev, Hamid Davoodi, and Erwin Tiongson, 2001, “Corruption and the
Provision of Health Care and Education Services,” in The Political Economy
of Corruption, ed. by Arvind K. Jain (London: Routledge).
Gupta, Sanjeev, Keiko Honjo, and Marijn Verhoeven, 2001, “The Effectiveness of
Government Expenditures: Experiences from Africa,” Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 23, No. 4, pp. 433–67.
Gupta, Sanjeev, Luiz de Mello, and Raju Sharan, 2001, “Corruption and Military
Spending,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 17, pp. 749–77.
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2002, Is the PRGF Living Up to Expectations? IMF
Occasional Paper No. 216 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Gupta, Sanjeev, Marijn Verhoeven, and Erwin Tjongson, 2003, “Public Spending
on Health Care and the Poor,” Health Economics, Vol. 12, Issue 8 (August),
pp. 685–96.
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2003b, “Transition Economies: How Appropriate Is
the Size and Scope of Government?” Comparative Studies, Vol. 45, No. 4,
pp. 554–76.
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2003a, “Foreign Aid and Revenue Response: Does the
Composition of Aid Matter?” in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 385–406.
Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, and Erwin Tiongson, 2004, “Foreign Aid and
Consumption Smoothing: Evidence from Global Food Aid,” Review of Development Economics, Vol. 8, Issue 3 (August), pp. 379–90.
Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, and Gabriela Inchauste, eds., 2004, Helping
Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2004, “The Persistence of Fiscal Adjustments in
Developing Countries,” Applied Economic Letters, Vol. 11 (March 15),
pp. 209–12.
Gupta, Sanjeev, Robert Powell, and Yongzheng Yang, 2005, “The Macroeconomic
Challenges of Scaling Up Aid to Africa,” IMF Working Paper 05/179 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2005a, “Fiscal Policy, Expenditure Composition,
and Growth in Low-Income Countries,” Journal of International Money and
Finance, Vol. 24, Issue 3 (April), pp.441-63.
Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 2005b, “What Sustains Fiscal Consolidations in Emerging Market Countries?” International Journal of Finance & Economics, Vol.
10 (October), pp. 307–21.
Harrison, Graham, and Russell Krelove, 2005, “VAT Refunds: A Review of Country Experience,” IMF Working Paper 05/218 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
63
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Heller, Peter, 1974, “Public Investment in LDCs with Recurrent Cost Constraint:
The Kenyan Case,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 88, pp. 251–72.
———, 1979, “The Underfinancing of Recurrent Development Costs,” Finance
and Development, Vol. 16 (March), pp. 38–41.
———, 2002, “Considering the IMF’s Perspective on a Sound Fiscal Policy,” IMF
Policy Discussion Paper 02/8 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2003, Who Will Pay? Coping with Aging Societies, Climate Change, and
Other Long-Term Fiscal Challenges (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
———, 2005a, “Understanding Fiscal Space,” IMF Policy Discussion Paper 05/4
(Washington: International Fund).
———, 2005b, “Pity the Finance Minister: Issues in Managing a Substantial Scaling-Up of Aid Flows,” IMF Working Paper 05/180 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Hemming, Richard, 2003, “Policies to Promote Fiscal Discipline,” paper presented
at the Conference on Political Economy of Policy Transfer, Learning, and
Convergence, Tulane University, April 11–12.
———, 2004, “Promoting Fiscal Discipline,” paper presented at APEC Deputies
Meeting, Santiago, September.
Hemming, Richard, Michael Kell, and Selma Mahfouz, 2000, “The Effectiveness of
Fiscal Policy in Stimulating Economic Activity—A Review of the Literature,”
IMF Working Paper 02/208 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Hemming, Richard, and Murray Petri, 2000, “A Framework for Assessing Fiscal
Vulnerability,” IMF Working Paper 00/52 (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
International Monetary Fund, 1986, A Manual on Government Finance Statistics
(Washington).
———, Fiscal Affairs Department, 1997, Guidelines for Fiscal Adjustment, IMF
Pamphlet Series, No. 49 (Washington).
———, 1997, “IMF Adopts Guidelines Regarding Governance Issues,” IMF
Survey, Vol. 26, No. 15, August 15.
———, 2001a, Government Finance Statistics Manual (Washington).
———, 2001b, Manual on Fiscal Transparency (Washington). Available via the
Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/fad/trans/manual/index.htm.
———, 2002, Fiscal Dimensions of Sustainable Development, IMF Pamphlet
Series, No. 54 (Washington).
———, 2003, “Public Debt in Emerging Markets: Is It Too High?” World
Economic Outlook, September 2003, World Economic and Financial Surveys
(Washington).
———, forthcoming, Promoting Fiscal Discipline (Washington).
———, 2004a, “Public Investment and Fiscal Policy” (Washington). Available via
the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/fad/2004/pifp/eng/pifp.pdf.
64
Bibliography
———, 2004b, “Rebuilding Fiscal Institutions in Post-Conflict Countries”
(Washington). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/
fad/2005/022505.htm.
———, 2004c, “IMF Discusses Operational Debt Sustainability Framework for
Low-Income Countries,” IMF Press Information Notice No. 04/119. Available
via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pn/2004/pn04119.htm.
———, 2005a, “Dealing with the Revenue Consequences of Trade Reform”
(Washington). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/
eng/2005/021505.pdf.
———, 2005b, “The Macroeconomics of Managing Increased Aid Inflows—
Experiences of Low-Income Countries and Policy Implications” (Washington). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/
080805a.pdf.
———, 2005c, “Review of PRGF Program Design—Overview” (Washington).
Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/
080805r.htm.
———, 2005d, “Monetary and Fiscal Policy Design Issues in Low-Income Countries” (Washington). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/
np/pp/eng/2005/080805m.pdf.
———, and World Bank, 2001, Guidelines for Public Debt Management
(Washington).
International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office, 2003, “Evaluation of
Fiscal Adjustment in IMF-Supported Programs” (Washington). Available via
the Internet: http://www.imf.org/External/NP/ieo/2003/fis/index.htm.
Ivanova, Anna, Michael Keen, Alexander Klemm, 2005, “The Russian ‘Flat Tax’
Reform,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, Vol. 43 (July), pp. 397–444.
Keen, Michael, 2003, Changing Customs: Challenges and Strategies for the Reform of Customs Administration (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, and Jenny Ligthart, 2002, “Coordinating Tariff Reduction and
Domestic Tax Reform,” Netherlands Journal of International Economics,
Vol. 56 (March), pp. 489–507.
Keen, Michael, and Alejandro Simone, 2004, “Tax Policy in Developing Countries:
Some Lessons from the 1990s, and Some Challenges Ahead,” in Helping
Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by Sanjeev Gupta, Benedict Clements, and Gabriela Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Khan, Mohsin S., and Abdelhak S. Senhadji, 2001, “Threshold Effects in the Relationship Between Inflation and Growth,” Staff Papers, International Monetary
Fund, Vol. 48, No. 1, pp. 1–21.
Kopits, George, and Steven Symansky, 1998, Fiscal Policy Rules, IMF Occasional
Paper No. 162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
65
FISCAL ADJUSTMENT FOR STABILITY AND GROWTH
Mackenzie, George A., and Peter Stella, 1996, Quasi-Fiscal Operations of Public
Financial Institutions, IMF Occasional Paper No. 142 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Mackenzie, George A., David W.H. Orsmond, and Philip R. Gerson, 1997, The
Composition of Fiscal Adjustment and Growth: Lessons from Fiscal Reforms
in Eight Economies, IMF Occasional Paper No. 149 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Martin, Philippe, and Carol Ann Rogers, 1997, “Stabilization Policy, Learningby-Doing, and Economic Growth,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 49, No. 1,
pp. 152–66.
McLure, Charles E., 1999, “Tax Holidays and Investment Incentives: A Comparative Analysis,” Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, pp. 326–39.
Mintz, Jack M., 1990, “Corporate Tax Holidays and Investment,” The World Bank
Economic Review, Vol. 4 (Washington: World Bank), pp. 81–102.
Norregaard, John, 1997, “Tax Assignment,” in Fiscal Federalism in Theory and
Practice, ed. by Teresa Ter-Minassian (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Ortiz, Guillermo, 2002, Recent Emerging Market Crises: What Have We Learned?
Per Jacobsson Foundation Lecture (Basel: Bank for International Settlements
and Per Jacobsson Foundation, July 7).
Pattillo, Catherine, Hélène Poirson, and Luca Ricci, 2004, “Through What Channels Does External Debt Affect Growth?” Brookings Trade Forum 2003, ed.
by Susan M. Collins and Dani Rodrik (Washington: Brookings Institution
Press), pp. 229–78.
Perotti, Roberto, 1996, “Fiscal Consolidation in Europe: Composition Matters,”
American Economic Review, Vol. 86 (May), pp. 105–10.
Petri, Murray, 2003, “Promoting Fiscal Transparency: The Complementary Roles
of the IMF, Financial Markets, and Civil Society,” IMF Working Paper 03/199
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Potter, Barry H., and Jack Diamond, 1999, Guidelines for Public Expenditure
Management (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Prud’homme, Remy, and Anwar Shah, 2002, “Centralization v. Decentralization:
The Devil Is in the Details” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).
Sargent, Thomas, and Neil Wallace, 1981, “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, Vol. 5, No. 3.
Schadler, Susan, and others, 1995, IMF Conditionality: Experience Under StandBy and Extended Arrangements, Part I, Key Issues and Findings, IMF Occasional Paper No. 128 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Silvani, Carlos, and Katherine Baer, 1997, “Designing a Tax Administration
Reform Strategy: Experiences and Guidelines,” IMF Working Paper 97/30
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
66
Bibliography
Tanzi, Vito, 1998, “Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope
and Cures,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 45 (December),
pp. 559–94.
———, and Howell Zee, 1996, “Fiscal Policy and Long-Run Growth,” IMF Working Paper 96/119 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2000, “Tax Policy for Emerging Markets: Developing Countries,” IMF
Working Paper 00/35 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Ter-Minassian, Teresa, ed., 1997, Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 1997, “Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in a Macroeconomic Perspective: An Overview,” in Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice, ed. by
Teresa Ter-Minassian (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, and Jon Craig, 1997, “Control of Subnational Government Borrowing,” in Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice, ed. by Teresa
Ter-Minassian (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
von Hagen, Jürgen, 1998, “Budgeting Institutions for Aggregate Fiscal Discipline”
(unpublished; Bonn: Center for European Integration Studies, February).
Available via the Internet: http://www.zei.de/download/zei_wp/B98-01.pdf.
Zee, Howell H., 2004, Taxing the Financial Sector: Concepts, Issues, and Practices (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, Janet G. Stotsky, and Eduardo Ley, 2002, “Tax Incentives for Business
Investment: A Primer for Policy Makers in Developing Countries,” World
Development, Vol. 30, No. 9, pp. 1497–516.
67