NOTA DI
LAVORO
01.2011
Residential Consumption of
Gas and Electricity in the
U.S.: The Role of Prices and
Income
By Anna Alberini, AREC, University of
Maryland and CEPE, ETH Zürich
Will Gans, AREC, University of
Maryland
Daniel Velez-Lopez, AREC, University
of Maryland
SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Series
Editor: Carlo Carraro
Residential Consumption of Gas and Electricity in the U.S.:
The Role of Prices and Income
By Anna Alberini, AREC, University of Maryland and CEPE, ETH Zürich
Will Gans, AREC, University of Maryland
Daniel Velez-Lopez, AREC, University of Maryland
Summary
We study residential demand for electricity and gas, working with nationwide householdlevel data that cover recent years, namely 1997-2007. Our dataset is a mixed panel/multiyear cross-sections of dwellings/households in the 50 largest metropolitan areas in the
United States as of 2008. To our knowledge, this is the most comprehensive set of data for
examining household residential energy usage at the national level, containing the broadest
geographical coverage, and with the longest longitudinal component (up to 6 observations
per dwelling). We estimate static and dynamic models of electricity and gas demand. We
find strong household response to energy prices, both in the short and long term. From the
static models, we get estimates of the own price elasticity of electricity demand in the -0.860
to -0.667 range, while the own price elasticity of gas demand is -0.693 to -0.566. These
results are robust to a variety of checks. Contrary to earlier literature (Metcalf and Hassett,
1999; Reiss and White, 2005), we find no evidence of significantly different elasticities
across households with electric and gas heat. The price elasticity of electricity demand
declines with income, but the magnitude of this effect is small. These results are in sharp
contrast to much of the literature on residential energy consumption in the United States,
and with the figures used in current government agency practice. Our results suggest that
there might be greater potential for policies which affect energy price than may have been
previously appreciated.
Keywords: Residential Electricity and Gas Demand, Price Elasticity Of Energy Demand,
Static Model, Dynamic Panel Data Model, Partial Adjustment Model
JEL Classification: Q4, Q41, Q48, Q54, Q58
We wish to thank Chuck McCormick for his help with the data, and seminar participants at WCERE
Montreal and ETH-Zurich for their helpful comments. Any errors remain our own.
Address for correspondence:
Anna Alberini
University of Maryland
AREC Department
Rm. 2200 Symons Hall
College Park, MD 20742-553
Phone: 301 105 1267
Fax: 301 314 9091
E-mail:
[email protected]
The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the position of
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei
Corso Magenta, 63, 20123 Milano (I), web site: www.feem.it, e-mail:
[email protected]
Residential Consumption of Gas and Electricity in the U.S.:
The Role of Prices and Income
by
Anna Alberinia,b,*, Will Gansa and Daniel Velez-Lopeza
Abstract
We study residential demand for electricity and gas, working with nationwide household-level
data that cover recent years, namely 1997-2007. Our dataset is a mixed panel/multi-year crosssections of dwellings/households in the 50 largest metropolitan areas in the United States as of
2008. To our knowledge, this is the most comprehensive set of data for examining household
residential energy usage at the national level, containing the broadest geographical coverage,
and with the longest longitudinal component (up to 6 observations per dwelling).
We estimate static and dynamic models of electricity and gas demand. We find strong
household response to energy prices, both in the short and long term. From the static models, we
get estimates of the own price elasticity of electricity demand in the -0.860 to -0.667 range,
while the own price elasticity of gas demand is -0.693 to -0.566. These results are robust to a
variety of checks. Contrary to earlier literature (Metcalf and Hassett, 1999; Reiss and White,
2005), we find no evidence of significantly different elasticities across households with electric
and gas heat. The price elasticity of electricity demand declines with income, but the magnitude
of this effect is small.
These results are in sharp contrast to much of the literature on residential energy consumption in
the United States, and with the figures used in current government agency practice. Our results
suggest that there might be greater potential for policies which affect energy price than may
have been previously appreciated.
Keywords: residential electricity and gas demand; price elasticity of energy demand; static
model; dynamic panel data model; partial adjustment model.
JEL Classification: Q4, Q41, Q48, Q54, Q58.
Affiliations
a
AREC, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742, and
b
CEPE, ETH Zürich
*
Corresponding author,
[email protected] (Tel): 301.105.1267 (Fax):301.314.9091
University of Maryland / AREC Department / Rm. 2200 Symons Hall / College Park, MD 20742-5535
Acknowledgements
We wish to thank Chuck McCormick for his help with the data, and seminar participants at WCERE Montreal and
ETH-Zurich for their helpful comments. Any errors remain our own.
1
Residential Consumption of Gas and Electricity in the U.S.:
The Role of Prices and Income
1. Introduction
In the United States and in other developed countries, buildings account for over 40% of
total annual energy use. Despite many recent policies that either mandate or promote energy
efficiency among residential energy users,1 U.S. residential energy demand has grown over the
last three decades, and projections suggest that it will continue to do so for the foreseeable
future (EIA, 2010).
Recently, there has been considerable debate in academic and policy circles as to
whether retail energy prices, including those charged to the residential sector, will increase or
decrease as a result of deregulation (Fabrizio et al., 2007, Showalter, 2007a,b, Carlson and
Loomis, 2008), establishment of emissions trading markets (e.g., Frondel et al., 2008, Burtraw
et al., 2002, Smale et al., 2006), and imposition of renewable portfolio standards, which is
usually done at the state level (Fischer 2010). More stringent environmental regulations on
emissions and pollutants from power plants (e.g., nitrogen and sulfur oxides, and mercury) and
tightened ambient air quality standards are also expected to increase cost of energy to
consumers.2
1
The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (the Stimulus Bill) of 2009, for instance, allocated some $27.2
Billion for energy efficiency and renewable energy R&D. Yet, despite many cost-effective opportunities for energy
efficiency improvement, projects often go unpursued. In principle, were homeowners aware of the future energy
savings, they would spontaneously undertake energy efficiency investments in their homes. In practice, consumers
and homeowners have often been observed to pass up opportunities to make energy-efficiency investments.
Possible explanations for the so-called “energy paradox” (Jaffe and Stavins, 1994) include liquidity constraints,
limited information, uncertainty about future energy prices (Hassett and Metcalf, 1993), high rates of intertemporal
preferences, disbelief in engineering estimates of the cost savings themselves (Metcalf and Hassett, 1999), and
institutional disincentives (see Golove and Eto, 1996).
2
Financing costs from investments to electricity transmission and distribution infrastructure, volatility and rising
scarcity in feedstocks such as coal, propane, natural gas, and petroleum, and the establishment of a price on carbon,
are all possible mechanisms which would increase the price of energy [Basheda et al. (2006)].
2
For the purpose of forecasting demand and planning for generation, transmission and
distribution capacity, and for energy policy purposes, it is important to measure the
responsiveness of residential energy demand to the prices of electricity and gas, the two major
sources of residential energy in the U.S. Earlier research has examined household demand for
energy and its responsiveness to price, but these analyses i) used old data (Quigley and
Rubinfeld, 1989, Metcalf and Hassett, 1999), ii) are restricted to limited geographical areas
(e.g., Garcia-Cerrutti, 2000; Reiss and Weiss, 2005), so that it is difficult to extrapolate their
results to other areas with different climates, housing stock and electricity suppliers, or iii) were
based on cross-sections or extremely short panels of data (with a maximum of two observations
per household) (e.g., Metcalf and Hassett, 1999), and did not fully address issues of unobserved
heterogeneity and endogeneity. In some cases, responsiveness to price was inferred from supply
shocks so severe and geographically circumscribed (e.g., Bushnell and Mansur, 2005; Reiss and
White, 2008) as to render them inapplicable for broader areas and more gradual price changes.
For these reasons, in this paper we wish to ask three research questions. First, what are
the (nationwide) price elasticities of residential electricity and gas demand? Second, is such
responsiveness sensitive to equipment and energy choices that are not easily reversed (e.g.,
using gas or electricity for heating or cooling)? Third, how does household income influence
demand and the price elasticities?
To answer our research questions we have assembled a large and comprehensive dataset
that documents energy usage data for over 69,000 dwellings (74,000 households) in the United
States. Specifically, we have household utility bills as reported in six nationwide waves of the
American Housing Survey (AHS: 1997, 1999, 2001, 2003, 2005, and 2007) plus three metro-
3
area waves of the same survey (2002, 2004 and 2007).3 Our dataset is a panel that follows
dwellings (not households) in the 50 largest metropolitan areas in the U.S. as of 2008 (54 cities)
in the even years of this decade, augmented with cross-sectional observations from the metro
surveys (2002, 2004 and 2007). The AHS contains extensive information about the structural
characteristics of the dwelling, renovations and retrofits, utility bills, fuels used, appliances and
heating/cooling systems, and socio-demographic and economic circumstances of the occupants.
Attention is focused to single-family homes and duplexes, and to electricity and gas
consumption. We merge these data with electric and gas utility company data (including price
and demand-side management policies), and climate data. Since the dataset has a longer
longitudinal component than any previous nationwide household-level study on these issues, we
are able to control for aspects of, and any changes in, the household, the housing unit, and the
energy prices faced by that household. We estimate static and dynamic models, with and
without controls for the current stock of appliances.
One important feature of our work is that we can control for unobserved heterogeneity in
a number of different ways. We use dwelling-specific fixed effects (a natural candidate given
the sampling frame of the AHS), but we also experiment with dwelling-household fixed effects,
and city-specific fixed effects. The latter give us a good sense of how electricity and gas usage
vary with the size and age of the home, and with income (for which there is wide variation
across homes, but not much at all within homes or households).
Briefly, we find that electricity use is responsive to the price of electricity (with an
elasticity that ranges from -0.67 to -0.86) and increases with the price of gas, indicating that the
latter is a substitute for electricity. The demand for gas is only slightly less responsive, with
3
Quigley and Rubinfeld (1989) used AHS to estimate their hedonic model of residential energy demand, but use
only the 1980 survey year.
4
own-price elasticities ranging from -0.565 to -0.693. The elasticities are highest in the models
with city-specific effects, and lowest in the models with dwelling-specific effects, but stay
within a limited range. (Accounting for unobserved heterogeneity reduces the elasticities by
15% to 32% relative to a model that does not include any effects at all, where the own price
elasticity of electricity demand is -1.)
The price elasticities are stable across specifications, and similar for homes with electric
and gas heat. Our checks suggest that the effect of mismeasuring energy prices is small. The
price elasticities are slightly higher among the poorest households (those that fall in the bottom
25% of the distribution of household income in our sample), and decline monotonically with
income, but in practice this effect is not important. Our dynamic models produce short-run
own-price elasticities equal to -0.736 and -0.572 for electricity and gas, respectively. Their longrun counterparts are -0.814 and -0.647, respectively. These figures are virtually unchanged
whether or not we control for difficult-to-reverse choices of heating/cooling technologies.
In sum, we exploit a nationwide sample with unprecedented detail and breadth of
coverage to study residential energy consumption in the United States since 1997. In contrast to
previous studies, we find strong responsiveness to energy prices, both in the short and long
term, and across homes with electric or gas heating, or air conditioning. These findings are
robust to state, city, dwelling, and dwelling-family fixed effects, and different price formulations
employed to correct for measurement error.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We offer a brief literature review in
section 2. We describe the models and econometric issues in Section 3 and the data in Section 4.
Section 5 presents the results, and Section 6 offers concluding remarks.
5
2. Previous Literature
A. Response of Energy Use to Price
Knowing the responsiveness of energy demand to the price allows analysts to predict the
effects of price changes or policies that result in price changes—for example, taxes on carbon
emissions, or mandates on the share of renewable energy. Earlier research has produced a wide
range of estimates of the price elasticity of demand in the residential sector, possibly because of
the diverse types of data used (time- series, cross-sections and panel), level of geographical and
jurisdictional aggregation (local, state, or national), extent of the observed variation in price, and
time periods covered.
Dergiades and Tsoulfidis (2008) use annual data for the U.S. from 1965 to 2006, and
estimate the short- (long-) run own-price elasticity of residential electricity consumption to be 0.386 (-1.06). Coefficients are assumed to be constant across locales and over the study period,
despite a time span of 41 years. Using a similar time series to study average consumer behavior,
Kamerschen and Porter (2004) employ a simultaneous equations approach with aggregate
annual U.S. energy data from 1973 to 1998, and obtain likewise high elasticities that range from
-0.94 to -0.85.
Bernstein and Griffin (2005) use a panel of state-level data covering 1997-2004, and
estimate that during that period the short-run (long-run) own-price elasticity of electricity
demand is -0.243 (-0.32). They conclude that these elasticities are similar to the ones estimated
in studies 20 years earlier. Paul et al. (2008) use monthly price and electricity demand data at
the state level for 1990-2006, but allow for the price elasticity of demand to vary across regions.
They find, after averaging across locales, that the own price elasticity is -0.13 in the short run
and -0.36 in the long run, and conclude that the demand is inelastic. Alberini and Filippini
6
(2010) likewise focus on annual state-level data in the U.S. from 1995 to 2007, but attempt to
get consistent estimates of the long-run elasticity by using a bias correct “within” estimator
(Kiviet, 1995) and the Blundell-Bond (1998) approach. The short-run own price elasticities of
electricity range from -0.15 to -0.08, and their long-run counterparts range from -0.78 to -0.44.
Hsing (1994) estimates the own-price elasticity of electricity demand in five Southern
states to be -0.24 in the short run and -0.54 in the long run. Garcia-Cerutti (2000) uses countylevel data from 44 California counties for 1983-1997 and random-coefficient models to examine
both electricity and gas demand. The own-price elasticity of electricity demand is -0.17 in the
short run and -0.19 in the long run, with significant variation between counties. Natural gas is
concluded to be a complement of, rather than a substitute to, electricity.
Studies that have focused on household-level data have likewise found a wide range of
price elasticities. Quigley and Rubinfeld (1989) use a cross-section from the 1980 American
Housing Survey and unit price data from the Bureau of Labor and Statistics, and find evidence
of low elasticity of energy demand (-0.1 in the short run). Metcalf and Hassett (1999) use the
1984, 1987 and 1990 waves of the Department of Energy’s Residential Energy Consumption
Survey to examine insulation investments by homeowners, and find price elasticities of
electricity ranging from -0.73 to -1.16 for that households that use electricity for space heating,
whereas those who use gas for space heating are not sensitive to the price of electricity.
Bernard et al. (2010) have multi-year cross-section data about electricity and gas
consumption and prices in Quebec from 1989-2002, and their analysis is based on constructing
pseudo-panels, i.e., relatively similar groups for which the relevant variables are the group
7
averages.4 Reasons for focusing on Quebec households include the facts that electricity is
inexpensive and in large supply, and households rely heavily on electric heat, despite the
extremely cold climate. Bernard et al. estimate the short-run and long-run elasticity to be -0.51
and -1.32, respectively, and conclude that electricity and natural gas are substitutes.5
One concern when examining the responsiveness of electricity use with respect to price
is that the data contain sufficient price variation. Such variation is usually attained by selecting
a broad geographic area and/or a sufficient long period of time. In some cases, identification is
made possible by abrupt changes in prices due to supply conditions. Reiss and White (2008)
and Bushnell and Mansur (2005) exploit the energy crisis and rapidly growing electricity rates
in California in 2000 and 2001, and document relatively large reductions in energy usage
induced by such price increases.
Attention has also been paid to the possible heterogeneity in the response to electricity
rates across households, depending on age, race and ethnicity. Poyer and Williams (1993)
examine whether electricity demand is different for different ethnicities and races, and find that
while the demand is inelastic for all groups, blacks appear to be more sensitive to short-run
price variations than Hispanics and whites. Based on discrete/continuous models of appliance
choice and energy use, Liao and Chang (2002) find that the elderly require more natural gas and
4
The groups are the 27 potential cohorts obtained by forming all of the possible combinations of the 9
administrative regions and 3 house size classes. Two cohorts were collapsed together with others because of too
few observations.
5
Studies outside of North America tend to be produce price elasticity ranges similar to those for North America.
Nesbakken (1999) focuses on the choice of heating and residential energy consumption in Norway, reporting that
short- and long-term price elasticities (in the range of -0.33 to -0.66) are remarkably stable across the 1990-1995
period, with the only exception of 1993. In contrast to other papers, responsiveness to price is more pronounced at
higher levels of income. Meier and Rehdanz (2010) use a 15-year panel of residential heating expenditures in
Great Britain. Using a log-linear specification with year and regional effects, they obtain gas price elasticities
between -0.4 and -0.49, which fall in the range of -0.2 to -0.57 from the comparable literature. They obtain
different elasticities for homeowners and renters. Leth-Petersen and Togeby (2001) find much lower price
elasticities in heating fuels (on the order of -0.1) based on a panel dataset from Denmark and a conditional logit
fixed-effect model.
8
fuel oil but less electricity, the demand for space heating increases as the elderly get older, and
the demand for energy for heating water decreases with age.
B. Which Price?
Standard economic theory posits that what matters in the household’s energy demand is
marginal price. If price is constant with respect to quantity and there is no fixed fee, the
marginal price is constant and equal to the average price. In practice, this is seldom the case. For
starters, many utilities charge a fixed fee in each billing period on top of the metered amount,
which makes the marginal and average price per unit of energy different. Moreover, most
utilities apply (increasing) block pricing schemes, which result in marginal prices that depend on
the quantity consumed, but do not vary smoothly with it. The budget constraint will be
piecewise linear, and for all households not at the beginning of the first block of consumption,
the marginal and the average price will, clearly, be different. Even more important, marginal
block price and consumption are simultaneously determined (Burtless and Hausman, 1978).
In the presence of block pricing, which should be entered in the econometric model of
consumption—marginal or average price? Howe and Linaweaver (1967) argue that the relevant
variable is marginal block price. Taylor (1975) and Nordin (1976) include marginal price and a
“difference” variable meant to account for the lump sum transfers implied by block rates, and
propose ways to test the marginal price v. average price model. Later studies used instrumental
variable estimation techniques to address the simultaneity of marginal price, quantity consumed,
and “difference.”6
6
See McFadden et al. (1977) and Wilder and Willenberg (1975) for two different IV approaches, Hewitt and
Hanemann (1995) for maximum likelihood estimation in the presence of block pricing.
9
Reiss and White (2005) focus on the California households in the Residential Energy
Consumption Survey (RECS), match each household with the block pricing structure applied by
the utility that serves the area, and estimate a model of choice of block and consumption levels
by GMM. Their price elasticity of electricity consumption is between -0.85 and -1.02,
depending on the subsample and the exact specification of the model. They also find a strong
negative correlation between income and price elasticity.
For lack of exact information about the block rates faced by the consumers, however,
many studies (including Metcalf and Hassett, 1999, and ourselves, as we explain below) are
forced to use average price. This is reasonable in light of much evidence that households
respond to the average, rather than marginal, price. Shin (1985) argues that households will
respond to average price, which is easily calculated from the electricity bill, rather than to actual
block marginal price, which is costly to determine, and develops an empirical strategy for
testing this conjecture.7 Borenstein (2008, 2009) likewise finds that consumers respond to an
average price, rather than marginal price or expected marginal price.
When the average price is computed from the consumer’s bill divided by quantity, as is
the case in RECS, it is endogenous with quantity. In our case, as we explain below, we impute
each household the average price per unit of electricity or gas charged by the utilities in the area.
This measure of price is exogenous to the household, but is affected by measurement error. We
discuss this issue in section 3.C below. An additional concern is whether usage decisions
depend on the price in the current (billing) period, on that of earlier periods, or a moving
average of the prices of recent periods (Poyer and Williams, 1993). For good measure, in what
follows we experiment with current price, as well as price of the previous period.
7
Typically, U.S. electric utilities utilize a block rate design. This implies that the marginal price for each household
varies with the quantity of electricity consumed, and can vary from season to season, making it difficult for a
household to monitor.
10
3. The Models and Econometric Estimation Issues
A. Two Models of Residential Energy Demand
Individuals and households do not derive utility directly from energy: They demand
electricity and gas because they use them to produce goods (e.g., a warm home, meals, lighting,
etc.) that enter as arguments in their utility function. Standard economic theory posits that the
demand for energy at the residential level depends on energy prices, the prices of other goods,
income, and other characteristics of the household (see Deaton and Muellbauer, 1980).
In this paper, we focus on the demand for gas and electricity, because they are the most
important fuels used by households in the U.S. Electricity is used by virtually 100% of the
households, and gas serves 60% of the households. Fuel oil (7% of the households), LPG
(1.5%) and kerosene (1.5%) are less important.8
We estimate two sets of models. In the first set, our regression equations are variants
of the static energy demand model:
(1)
ln Qit( j ) 0( j ) 1( j ) ln PE ,it 2( j ) ln PG,it x it γ ( j ) z it δ ( j ) t it( j ) ,
where j=E, G for electricity and gas, respectively, i denotes the dwelling, and t denotes the time
period. Q is consumption, P denotes price, and the coefficients on the log prices are the shortterm own- and cross-price elasticities.
Vectors x and z are dwelling and household characteristics thought to influence the
consumption of energy. Vector x includes weather, size and age of the home, heating and
cooling equipment dummies, and appliances. For example, a house heated only with an electric
heater would have a higher electricity demand than an identical home with gas heat. Household
characteristics (z) include the number and age of occupants, income, the presence of children or
8
EIA, http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/energyexplained/index.cfm?page=us_energy_homes (last accessed 28 Sept. 2010)
11
elderly persons, and a homeownership dummy. Equation (1) includes year effects (the s), and
is easily amended to include dwelling or city-specific effects to account for unobserved
heterogeneity.9
It is of interest to assess how consumption changes if individuals are allowed to adjust
their stock of appliances and make energy efficiency and conservation investments. A partialadjustment model (Houthakker, 1980) lets individuals adjust their stock of appliances and
energy-efficiency investments. This model assumes that the change in log actual demand
between any two periods ( t−1 and t ) is only some fraction (λ) of the difference between log
*
actual demand in period t−1 and the log of the long-run equilibrium demand in period t, Qt .
Formally,
(2)
ln Qt ln Qt 1 (ln Qt* ln Qt ) ,
where 0<λ<1. The dwelling subscript i is omitted to avoid clutter. This implies that given an
optimum, but unobservable, level of energy consumption, demand only gradually converges
towards that optimum level between any two time periods.
Assume that desired energy use (for example, desired electricity consumption) can be
*
expressed as Qt PE PG exp(Xγ) , where and are the long-term elasticities with
respect to the price of the electricity and that of gas, and X is a vector of variables influencing
demand for energy, including income, climate, characteristics of the stock of housing, income,
etc. On inserting this expression into (2), we get
9
A special case of this situation is when the dwelling-specific effects are suppressed, but the error terms in the
demand for electricity and gas equations are correlated within the same dwelling unit in the same period (but
uncorrelated in different period and across dwellings). If so, the equations for log Q(E) and log Q(G) are part of a
system of seemingly unrelated regression equation. Since the regressors are the same in the equations for log
electricity and gas consumption, the most efficient estimation technique (GLS) is simplified to OLS applied
separately to each equation.
12
(3)
ln Q t ln Q t 1 ln ln PE ln PG Xγ ln Q t 1 .
On re-arranging and appending an econometric error term, we obtain the regression equation:
(4)
ln Qt ln ln PE ln PG X γ (1 ) ln Qt 1 .
Equation (4) shows that the short-run elasticities are the regression coefficients on the
log prices, whereas the long-run elasticities can be computed by dividing these short-run
elasticities (i.e., the coefficients on the log prices) by the estimate of . In turn, the latter is
easily obtained as 1 minus the coefficient on ln Qt 1 .
B. Estimation of the Dynamic Model
We wish to estimate the partial adjustment model (equation (4)) with fixed, dwellingspecific effects. One concern with this specification is that the lagged dependent variable in the
right-hand side may be serially correlated and hence correlated with the error term, which
makes the LSDV and GLS estimators biased and inconsistent, since ( y i , t 1 y i , 1 ) , where
y it ln Qit , is correlated with ( it i ) (see Baltagi, 2001). The bias vanishes as T gets large,
but the LSDV estimator remains biased and inconsistent for N large and T small, as is the case
here, since we have tens of thousands of homes but the maximum length of the longitudinal
component of the sample is 6.10
Kiviet (1995) derives an approximation for the bias of the LSDV estimator when the
errors are serially uncorrelated and the regressors are strongly exogenous, and proposes an
estimator that is derived by subtracting a consistent estimate of this bias from the LSDV
10
We remind the reader that, when attention is restricted to those dwellings that appeared in more than one round of
AHS survey, we have an unbalanced panel with T ranging from 2 to 6. A similar argument applies if we use
dwelling-household effects instead of dwelling effects.
13
estimator. An alternative approach is to first-difference the data, thus swiping out the statespecific effects:
(5)
y it y i , t 1 w it β it
where w denotes all exogenous regressors in the right-hand side of equation (4), and to use
y i ,t 2
and w it as instruments for y i , t 1 (Anderson and Hsiao, 1982).
Arellano and Bond (1991) point out that the latter approach is inefficient and argue that
additional instruments can be obtained by exploiting the orthogonality conditions that exist
between the lagged values of y i , t and the disturbances. The Arellano-Bond procedure is a
generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator that is implemented in two steps. In practice,
the Arellano-Bond estimator has been shown to be biased in small samples, and the bias
increases with the number of instruments and orthogonality conditions. Moreover, Arellano and
Bond (1991) show that the asymptotic approximation of the standard errors of their two-step
GMM estimator is biased downwards, and they, as well as Judson and Owen (1999), find that
the one-step estimator outperforms the two-step estimator.
Under the additional assumption of quasi-stationarity of y i , t , y i , t 1 is uncorrelated with
it , and Blundell and Bond (1998) suggest a “system” GMM estimation where one stacks the
model in the levels and in the first differences, imposes the cross-equation restriction that the
coefficients entering in the two models be the same, and uses the full set of instruments
(corresponding to the full set of orthogonality conditions for both models). Blundell and Bond
report that in simulation the “system” GMM estimator is more efficient and stable than the
Arellano-Bond procedure. This is the approach we adopt for the partial adjustment model.
C. Mismeasured Prices
14
As we explain in more detail in section 4, in this study the price of energy is measured
with an error, because we do not know the exact price(s) faced by the household and impute the
average price paid by residential customers in that area.
Standard econometric theory shows when a regressor is mismeasured, and the
measurement error is classical, the estimated regression coefficient is downward biased (Greene,
2008, page 325-326). In our case, we must keep in mind that the mismeasured price enters in the
construction of the dependent variable as well as in the right-hand side of the model as a
regressor. Omitting for simplicity all other regressors and the cross price, we estimate the
regression equation:
(6)
pit*
ln * i ln
it ,
CPIit
pit
Ait
Where subscript i denotes the dwelling A is the utility bill at time t, p it* is nominal price, and
CPI is the CPI index that converts nominal prices to real prices.11 In this simplified model, the
own price elasticity is . Variable p it* is mismeasured. Specifically, we assume that
p * p exp( e) , so ln p * ln p e .
Equation (6) can be re-written as
(7)
ln Ait i (1 ) ln pit* ln CPIit it i 1 ln pit* 2 ln CPIit it ,
where 1 1 and 2 . The elasticity with respect to price is thus the LSDV coefficient
on log price, ˆ1 , minus 1.
Is this estimate consistent or biased? Suppose that the measurement error is
approximately constant within a dwelling over time. If this is the case, then the measurement
11
City-level Consumer Price Indices are taken from the Bureau of Labor and Statistics (BLS) at
http://www.bls.gov/data/ by selecting “urban consumer series” for all items. Prices are then divided by the ratio of
the annual CPI to the year 2007 CPI, to convert to constant 2007 dollars.
15
error is swiped out by the LSDV procedure, which produces consistent estimates of the slopes in
equation (1).
Consider now the situation where the measurement error is completely uncorrelated
within and between the units in every period. If the measurement error is classical, then it can be
shown that
(8)
p lim ˆ1 1
Var (ln p) Var (ln CPI ) Cov 2 (ln p, ln CPI )
,
Var (ln p) Var (ln CPI ) Cov 2 (ln p, ln CPI ) Var (e) Var (ln CPI )
where plim denotes the probability limit, and variances and covariances are computed using the
deviations from the dwelling means. Clearly, ˆ1 underestimates the true 1 , and so, since is
negative and = 1 -1, the price elasticity will be overstated (i.e., the absolute value of the
estimated coefficient will be greater than | | ).
Equation (7) also shows that the price elasticity is the negative of the coefficient on ln
CPI. Unfortunately, this coefficient is estimated consistently using LSDV only if ln CPI is
uncorrelated with the log price of electricity, or (as shown in expressions (9)-(10) below), =-1.
In our case, ln CPI is positively correlated with the log price of electricity (correlation
coefficient 0.37), and is likely different from -1, and so the bias induced by the measurement
error on price is propagated to the coefficient on ln CPI. For large samples,
(9)
p lim ˆ2 2 1 m (1 ) m ,
where
(10)
m
Var (e) Cov (ln p, ln CPI )
.
Var (ln p ) Var (ln CPI ) Cov 2 (ln p, ln CPI ) Var (e) Var (ln CPI )
Again, in expression (10) variances and covariances are based on deviations from the
dwelling means. It is difficult to sign the bias, because it depends on the magnitude of the true
16
elasticity. In our case, term m in expression (10) is clearly positive. Term (1 ) is positive if
the true price elasticity is negative but small (i.e., | | 1 ), in which case ̂ 2 is biased away
from zero, and its opposite ( ̂ 2 ) overstates the true elasticity. If the true elasticity is large
(i.e., greater than 1 in absolute value), then term (1 ) is negative, ̂ 2 is biased towards zero
and its opposite understates the true elasticity.
How can one get around the mismeasurement problem? One approach is to restrict
estimation to areas where mismeasurement is likely to be less severe (e.g., areas with only one
utility). Another is to instrument for ln pit* , which we do using state-level electricity and gas
prices, or, in alternate runs, lagged electricity prices. The results obtained in this fashion can be
compared with those from equation (1) directly, and with those from equation (7).
4. The Sample and the Data
In addition to data provided by individual utilities for their service territories (e.g.,
Borenstein, 2008, 2009) or otherwise geographically circumscribed areas (e.g., Shin, 1985;
Garcia-Cerrutti, 2000, Bushnell and Mansur, 2005), earlier research has used the Department of
Energy’s Residential Energy Consumption Survey to examine energy use patterns at the
household level (e.g., Metcalf and Hassett, 1999, Reiss and White, 2005). Despite its national
coverage, we were dissatisfied with this dataset, because it does not lend itself to panel data
modeling (the length of the longitudinal component is at most 2), and the geographical
17
identification is at too coarse a level to link each household with the relevant utilities (or to
state-level or local policies or incentives).12
For these reasons, we assembled a large and comprehensive dataset that merged several
sources of data. We use the American Housing Survey, a longitudinal study conducted by the
Department of Housing and Urban Development where the cross-sectional units are dwellings
(not households). The AHS contains extensive information about the structural characteristics
of the dwelling, renovations and retrofits, home ownership and its financial aspects (mortgages,
maintenance costs, etc.), appliances and heating/cooling systems, socio-demographic and
economic circumstances of the occupants, and their assessment of the quality of the home and
the neighborhood.
We focus on “national” survey AHS data for 1997, 1999, 2001, 2003, 2005, and 2007,
which means that we can follow homes for up to T=6 periods. We augment this sample with
observations from the AHS “metro”13 surveys, which are conducted in even years in specific
areas. We use the 2002, 2004 and 2007 metro surveys. Homes in the metro surveys are
surveyed only once, so our sample is a mix of panel data plus multi-year cross-sections.
Because of privacy concerns, the AHS discloses the location of the dwelling only if the
area has a population of 100,000 or more. We selected dwellings in the 54 cities corresponding
to the 50 largest metropolitan areas in the U.S. as of 2008, unless the AHS SMSA identification
makes it impossible to identify unambiguously which state the dwelling is located in. Table 1
lists the “candidate” metro areas (the 50 largest in the U.S. as of 2008) and indicates which are
12
RECS provides the Census Region for each household. It provides the state identifier only if the household
resides in one of the four most populous states (California, New York, Texas and Florida). HDD and CDD
information is provided, but the true figures at the household’s location are masked to ensure confidentiality.
13
The Nationwide AHS sample returns to the same homes for every survey, and adds some newly constructed
homes to keep the sample representative of the housing stock in the U.S.. The metro surveys are conducted on a
representative sample of homes in different cities every two years, but in the metro surveys different homes are
selected in different waves for the same city.
18
included in our study. These locations should ensure considerable variation in climate, age of
the stock of housing and construction materials (which may affect efficiency of space heating
and cooling), and utility prices.
Table 1. Metropolitan areas selected for the study.
metro area
Included?*
metro area
Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Marietta, GA
yes
Austin-Round Rock, TX
yes
Minneapolis-St. Paul-Bloomington, MN-WI
Nashville-Davidson--Murfreesboro--Franklin,
TN
Baltimore-Towson, MD
yes
New Orleans-Metairie-Kenner, LA
Birmingham-Hoover, AL
yes
New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island,
NY-NJ-PA
yes
yes (New
York,
Northern
New Jersey)
Boston-Cambridge-Quincy, MA-NH
yes
Oklahoma City, OK
yes
Buffalo-Niagara Falls, NY
yes
Orlando-Kissimmee, FL
yes
Philadelphia-Camden-Wilmington, PA-NJ-DEMD
no
Chicago-Naperville-Joliet, IL-IN-WI
yes
(Charlotte)
yes
(Chicago)
Phoenix-Mesa-Scottsdale, AZ
yes
Cincinnati-Middletown, OH-KY-IN
no
Pittsburgh, PA
yes
Cleveland-Elyria-Mentor, OH
yes
Portland-Vancouver-Beaverton, OR-WA
yes
Columbus, OH
yes
Providence-New Bedford-Fall River, RI-MA
yes
(Providence)
Dallas-Fort Worth-Arlington, TX
yes
Raleigh-Cary, NC
yes
Denver-Aurora, CO \2
yes
Richmond, VA
yes
Detroit-Warren-Livonia, MI
yes
Riverside-San Bernardino-Ontario, CA
yes
Hartford-West Hartford-East Hartford, CT
yes
Sacramento--Arden-Arcade--Roseville, CA
yes
Houston-Sugar Land-Baytown, TX
yes
St. Louis, MO-IL \3
no
Indianapolis-Carmel, IN
yes
Salt Lake City, UT
yes
Jacksonville, FL
yes
San Antonio, TX
yes
Kansas City, MO-KS
no
San Diego-Carlsbad-San Marcos, CA
yes
Las Vegas-Paradise, NV
yes
San Francisco-Oakland-Fremont, CA
yes
Los Angeles-Long Beach-Santa Ana, CA
yes
San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, CA
yes
Louisville/Jefferson County, KY-IN
not there
Seattle-Tacoma-Bellevue, WA
yes
Memphis, TN-MS-AR
no
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater, FL
yes
Miami-Fort Lauderdale-Pompano Beach, FL
yes
Charlotte-Gastonia-Concord, NC-SC
Virginia Beach-Norfolk-Newport News, VA-NC
Washington-Arlington-Alexandria, DC-VA-MDMilwaukee-Waukesha-West Allis, WI
yes
WV
* Eligible because of unambiguous state identification in the AHS
Included?*
yes
(MinneapolisSt Paul)
yes
no
no
19
Our sample is restricted to single-family homes and duplexes. We further restrict
attention to homes that are owner-occupied or occupied by a tenant, and where these persons
actually are responsible for paying the utility bills.14 These criteria yielded a sample size of
120,333 observations. We deleted observations where i) the home was occupied as a residence
for only part of the year, ii) the utility bills had been imputed using “hot deck” procedures, iii)
the square footage (which should be an important determinant of energy usage) had been
imputed using “hot deck” procedures, and/or iv) large and implausible changes in size where
observed from one time period to the next.15 This left us with 98,774 observations, which are
further reduced to 98,772 when we further exclude residences where the heating equipment is
shared with other units (2 observations).
Table 2 displays the distribution of this final sample by city. Table 3 summarizes
information about the longitudinal component of our sample, examining the case where the
cross-sectional units are the dwellings, and that where the cross-sectional units are dwellingfamilies. We have a total of 69,169 homes and 74,697 households (because families may move
into and out of any given home during the study period).
14
In other words, we exclude tenants where the utilities are included in the rent. Incentives to save on utilities may
be different in this case.
15
Specifically, we excluded observations with a change in the amount of energy or gas used that changed by more
than 500% from one period to the next, while at the same time no renovation in the home and no square foot
change was reported. Homes that experienced a change in square footage of more than 1000% from one period to
the next, or with a change in square footage of more than 100% without a reported renovation to the home, were
also discarded.
20
Table 2. Distribution of the sample by city. N=98,772.
City
Nobs
Percent
City
Anaheim
3,618
3.66
Minneapolis
Atlanta
3,335
3.38
193
0.2
1,522
1.54
Bergen-Passaic
428
Birmingham
Nobs
Percent
2,112
2.14
Monmouth
339
0.34
Nashville
275
0.28
New Orleans
2,387
2.42
0.43
New York
2,585
2.62
343
0.35
Newark
612
0.62
1,754
1.78
Northern New Jersey
659
0.67
91
0.09
Oakland
793
0.8
Buffalo
1,739
1.76
Oklahoma City
2,752
2.79
Charlotte
2,681
2.71
Orlando
434
0.44
Chicago
4,306
4.36
Phoenix
3,665
3.71
Cleveland
3,137
3.18
Pittsburgh
3,313
3.35
Columbus
3,315
3.36
Providence
271
0.27
Dallas
3,488
3.53
Raleigh-Durham
280
0.28
Denver
2,415
2.45
Riverside San Bernardino
3,883
3.93
Detroit
3,467
3.51
Sacramento
2,584
2.62
Ft. Worth
2,992
3.03
Salt Lake
532
0.54
Hartford
2,010
2.03
San Antonio
2,781
2.82
Houston
2,430
2.46
San Diego
2,978
3.02
Indianapolis
2,908
2.94
San Francisco
502
0.51
Jacksonville
357
0.36
San Jose
579
0.59
Jersey City
91
0.09
Santa Rosa
90
0.09
Las Vegas
453
0.46
Seattle
2,706
2.74
Los Angeles
4,870
4.93
Tacoma
224
0.23
Miami
4,115
4.17
Tampa
2,089
2.11
300
0.3
Tucson
355
0.36
2,295
2.32
West Palm Beach
339
0.34
Austin
Baltimore
Boston
Boulder
Middlesex County
Milwaukee
Table 3. Distribution of the sample by length of the longitudinal component. N=98,772.
capitalT (length of the panel)
1
2
3
4
5
6
Unit: dwelling‐family
Unit: dwelling
Freq.
Percent Freq.
Percent
58,088
58.81
63,916
64.71
7,094
7.18
9,616
9.74
5,315
5.38
6,126
6.2
8,232
8.33
6,236
6.31
10,905
11.04
6,740
6.82
9,138
9.25
6,138
6.21
21
B. Energy Consumption and Utilities’ Rates
The AHS reports the average monthly utility bill (and annual payments on heating oil
fuel for those households that use heating oil) in the survey year, but does not report the
electricity or gas tariffs, nor the actual energy consumption (in kilowatt-hours [kWh] or
thousand cubic feet [MCF]).
We must therefore construct consumption by taking the bills and dividing them by unit
price. Unfortunately, the names of the utilities and the rate structure are not identified in the
AHS either, so we were forced to impute average tariffs per KWh and cubic foot of gas for each
dwelling in a number of ways.
For each metropolitan area, we identified the relevant gas and electric utilities using the
listings provided by the state public utility commission, and a variety of on-line city services.
We also consulted the list of counties covered by each utility, as documented in the EIA 861
forms database. We obtained utility-level price information from the Energy Information
Agency (EIA) 861 forms (for electricity) and EIA 176 forms (for gas), which the utilities are
required to file every year with the agency. Next, if the area was supplied by a single utility, we
computed the average price per kWh (MCF) as the utility’s annual revenue from sales to
residential customers divided by the kWhs (MCFs) sold to residential customers.16
If the area was supplied by more than one utility, we first computed the average price
charged by each of them in the aforementioned fashion, and then constructed three alternative
measures of price to use in our regressions. One, which we dub “residential price 1,” is a
weighted average of each utility’s average tariff per KWh, where the weights are proportional
to the utility’s customer base. The next, which we dub “residential price 2,” is also a weighted
16
We note here that the EIA computes state-level electricity prices and gas prices exactly in this fashion—by taking
the revenues of all utilities and dividing by all kWhs (or gas) served to residential households.
22
average, with weights assigned to represent the utility’s dominance of the market.17 The final
constructed price (“residential price 3”) is a simple average of the individual utilities’ average
tariffs.18 We followed a similar approach for gas utilities.
We use the prices of electricity and gas in two ways. First, we use them to create the
dependent variables in our regressions: Consumption of electricity and gas are obtained as the
amount on the bill divided by (nominal) price. Second, (real) prices enter in the right-hand side
of the demand equations.
We note here that, technically speaking, these average prices are not necessarily equal to
the prices faced by the households. The majority of the utilities apply block pricing, but with
such a geographically broad sample and such a long study period, it would be unfeasible to
obtain the block pricing schemes used by each utility in each period. The only remaining
econometric concern is that the price we use in our regression is measured with error. With our
model and data construction, as explained in section 3.C, this would make the household
demand appear to be more elastic than it truly is.
We display descriptive statistics about prices and energy use in table 4. Attention is
restricted to the “price 1” variables because the others were very close to them.19 Every home
is served by electricity, and, as shown in table 4, on average our households use about 930
KWh per month. This is in line with nationwide estimates collected by the Department of
Energy using a dedicated survey (RECS). Just over three-quarters of the sample (76.6%) use
natural gas as well, and almost 88% of such natural-gas connected households use gas heat. In a
typical month, gas usage is 7.27 MCF.
17
If a utility dominates the market completely, despite the nominal existence of other utilities, that utility received a
weight of ones and the others weights equal to zero. If two utilities were perceived to share the market in the area in
a relatively equitable fashion, we assigned weights of 0.5 to each.
18
Clearly, if there is a single utility, residential price 1, 2 and 3 are all identical.
19
The correlation coefficients between the “price 1” variables and the others were generally higher than 0.97.
23
Over the study period, the average price of electricity is about 11 cents per kWh
(2007$). We found, however, evidence of considerable variation across states. The state with
the lowest prices is Indiana (about 6.8 cents per kWh on average over the study period) and that
with the highest prices is New York, where a kWh averaged almost 18 cents over the study
period (2007$). The price of natural gas exhibits similar variability across locales. The average
price per MCF is $11.41 (2007$), with Georgia exhibiting the lowest prices ($6.10, 2007$, on
average) and Florida the highest ($17.83, 2007$).
Table 4. Prices and monthly consumption of electricity and natural gas.
Variable
kwh1 (monthly electricity usage, KWh)
gasuse1 (monthly gas usage, MCF)
residentialprice1_r (price of electricity per
kWh, 2007 dollars)
gasprice1_r (price of natural gas per MCF,
2007 dollars)
Log kwh1
Log gasuse1
Log residentialprice1_r
Log gasprice1_r
Obs
Mean
Std. Dev. Min
Max
97344
930.39
654.09
11.06 5697.54
67154
7.27
5.50
0.23
71.86
98487
0.11
0.03
0.05
0.22
94315
11.42
3.10
3.90
22.89
97344
67154
98487
94315
6.61
1.75
‐2.23
2.40
0.70
0.68
0.26
0.26
2.40
‐1.49
‐2.92
1.36
8.65
4.27
‐1.49
3.13
Since we exploit the longitudinal feature of our data, it is important to check the extent
of the variation in prices across and within units. In what follows, the units are the dwellings.
We computed the total variation of real electricity prices and of log real electricity prices, and
found that in each case the variation within dwellings accounted for only 4% of the total
variation.20 Gas prices are more variable over time: the “within” dwelling variation accounts for
20
Our measure of variation is the sum of square deviations from the grand mean.
24
about 14% of total variation in real gas prices, and 15% of the total variation for log real gas
prices.
C. Other Key Regressors
The weather is an important determinant of energy use. We computed heating and
cooling degree-days (HDDs and CDDs) in the year prior to the date of the AHS survey using
the T3 Global Summaries of the Day from NOAA’s National Climatic Data Center. We
matched each metro area with the T3 monitors in that area, computed the average of the mean
temperatures for each day of the year prior to the date of the survey, created the HDD (CDD)
for that day as 65F minus the average temperature (average temperature minus 65F), and
summed over the year prior to the survey. This construction is the same as that used by the
U.S. Department of Energy. The average HDDs and CDDs are 3450 and 1658 degree-days,
respectively.
Our regressions control for dwelling characteristics, such as the age and size of the
home, number of rooms, and number of floors, which come from the AHS. We enter all
continuous variables in log form in the regression. Descriptive statistics for these variables are
displayed in table 5. The average size of the home is about 2000 square feet. This figure
matches up nicely with the nationwide estimates for single-family homes and homes that are
part of a two-unit building from the 1997, 2001, and 2005 RECS.
25
Table 5. House characteristics.
Variable
Unitsf (square footage)
basement
Floors
Rooms
House age
all observations
Obs
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min Max
91254
2073.96
1615.04
99 18083
98772
0.37
0.48
0
1
98772
1.83
0.96
1
21
98772
6.42
1.86
1
21
98772
38.69
23.27
0
88
more than 400 sq ft and less than 10,000 sq ft, no more than 4 floors
Unitsf
88732
1950.42
1141.95 400
9911
basement
88732
0.35
0.48
0
1
Floors
88732
1.77
0.83
1
4
Rooms
88732
6.47
1.83
1
21
Houseage
88732
37.64
22.84
0
88
Despite removing observations with imputed square footage and implausible changes in
square footage from one survey wave to the next, our sample does contain some observations
with extremely small and extremely large values for size and the number of floors, so in our
regressions we further restrict attention to homes no smaller than 400 square feet and no larger
than 10,000. We also delete from the usable sample homes with more than 4 floors (single
family homes are unlikely to have 5 or more floors).
Descriptive statistics for this cleaned sample are reported in the bottom panel of table 5.
The average square footage, house age and number of rooms are virtually unchanged. We note
that a value of zero for the age of the house is correct: it means that the home was built in the
same year of the survey. (The AHS does add new dwellings to mirror the stock of housing and
new constructions. Homes with age 0 account for less than 1% of the sample.)
We report descriptive statistics about heating and cooling equipment, as well as
appliances that use energy, in table 6. All of this information comes from the AHS. Briefly, in
terms of heating, about 67% of the sample has a gas heating system, 26% relies on electricity
26
for heating, and about 5% on heating oil as the main source of heat. Homes with electric heat
are located primarily in states with mild or warm climates, such as Arizona (66% of all Arizona
homes), Florida (93.80%), Louisiana (43%), Tennessee (59%) and Texas (43.76%), or cheap
electricity (e.g., Washington, 29%).
About 84% of the sample has some type of air conditioning, and about 67% has central
air conditioning. Window units are used by 20% of the sample, sometimes alongside with
central air conditioning. Only 2% of the observations have gas-powered heat pumps.
Turning to appliances, virtually all homes have a fridge, almost 72% a dishwasher, 32%
use gas-powered clothes dryers, and a little more than half of the sample has an electric stove.
Table 6. Heating and cooling equipment and appliances.
Variable
gas_heat (gas heat)
el_heat (electric heat)
fueloil_heat (heating
oil heat)
Windowac (window
A/C units)
Numair (number of
rooms with A/C)
Centralac (central A/C)
gasAC (gas heat pump
for A/C)
Anyac (any type of A/C
present)
Fridge (refrigerator)
Dishwasher
g_dryer (gas powered
clothes dryer)
e_stove (electric
stove)
Obs
Std.
Mean
Dev.
Min
98772
0.67
0.47
98772
0.26
0.44
0
0
1
1
98772
0.05
0.23
0
1
98772
0.21
0.40
0
1
20251
98772
1.78
0.67
1.02
0.47
1
0
8
1
98772
0.03
0.16
0
1
98772
0.84
0.37
0
1
98772
98772
0.9981
0.72
0.04
0.45
0
0
1
1
98772
0.32
0.47
0
1
98772
0.53
0.50
0
1
Max
27
Summary statistics of household characteristics are shown in table 7. Briefly, we find
that the average household income over the study period is about $88,000 (2007$). There are a
small number of households (93, or 0.09%) that report negative income. When these persons
are removed, the distribution of household income is essentially unchanged: The new sample
average is still $88,000 (2007$).21 The average household size is 2.8, 31% of the sample has
small children, 22% has at least one person aged 65 or older living in this house, and almost
84% owns the home.
Table 7. Household characteristics.
Variable
Household income in thou. 2007$
Number of household members
Young child (12 or less) lives in this
house
Elderly person (65+) lives in this house
Owner
Obs
Mean
Std. Dev. Min
Max
98772
87.92
115.49
‐42.33 11473.2
98772
2.81
1.52
1
17
98772
98772
98772
0.31
0.23
0.84
0.46
0.42
0.37
0
0
0
1
1
1
5. Results
A. Static Models
Results for several specifications of the static model (see equation 1) are reported in
table 10 for log electricity consumption, and in table 11 for log gas consumption. The runs differ
for the type of effects we include to account for unobserved heterogeneity.
We choose to report results for fixed city-, dwelling- and dwelling-family specific effects. We
include city-specific effects because 1) the coefficients on most regressors are similar to those
from a random effects model with dwelling-specific effects (estimated using GLS), 2) it stands
21
In our regressions, which use log income, we will simply recode log income to zero when income is negative.
28
to reason that homes and residents might share similar unobservable characteristics as other
homes and residents in the same metro area, 3) we do not lose the observations with T=1, and 4)
we are able to assess the impact on consumption of factors that vary widely across locales (e.g.,
home size, income, etc.) but little within a house over time. Finally, 5) assigning average prices
at the metro-area level to each dwelling likely produces errors that are correlated within the
metro area, biasing standard error estimates downward (Moulton, 1990). For this reason, we
cluster the standard errors at the city level.
Fixed dwelling effects are a natural candidate, since the AHS follows a dwelling over
time, while dwelling-family effects allow for unobservable heterogeneity to depend on the
household as well as the home.22 We prefer fixed effects because Hausman tests indicate that if
the unobserved heterogeneity is modeled using random effects, these are correlated with the
included regressors, which makes the GLS estimates inconsistent. For good measure, the
standard errors are clustered at the city level (in specifications with city effects) or at the
dwelling level (in specifications with dwelling and dwelling-household effects).
Starting with table 10, most of the coefficients are significant and have the expected
sign. Importantly, column (A)—the results of a model with city-specific effects—shows that the
elasticity of electricity use with respect to the price of electricity is -0.860, and the crosselasticity with respect to the price of gas is positive and equal to 0.117, indicating that the two
are substitutes.23
Consumption of electricity increases by 22% for every 10% increase in the square
footage of the home, is 16% higher if the home has air conditioning, and about 15% higher if the
22
The fixed effects also account for any selection of households into cities or homes.
It is useful to compare these figures with their counterparts in an OLS regression that ignores unobserved
heterogeneity. The own price elasticity when the city effects are suppressed is -1. Adding state effects (but no city
effects) makes it -0.894.
23
29
home is heated using electricity. Dishwashers and electrical stoves increase usage by 8% and
7%, respectively (not displayed in the table). F tests reject the null hypotheses that
heating/cooling systems are jointly equal to zero (F statistic = 37.65, p value less than 0.0001)
and that the appliances are not associated with electricity consumption (F statistic = 38.05, p
value less than 0.0001).
The income elasticity of electricity consumption is only about 0.02. One reason for such
a low elasticity might be the fact that income is highly correlated with characteristics of the
home, such as the size, the number of floors, and the presence of certain appliances. Once we
removed these from the specification, income elasticity of electricity usage increased to almost
0.05.
Column (B) presents the results of a FE specification where the cross-sectional units are
the homes. The own price elasticity is lower (-0.667), as expected, but the cross-price elasticity
is slightly stronger. As expected, the coefficients on most other variables are much smaller than
their counterparts in the city-specific effects specification, because these variables rarely change
within a home over time. In column (C), we present the results of a model with dwellinghousehold specific effects. They are similar to those in column (B), with slightly stronger ownand cross-price elasticities.
In the gas equation, columns (A)-(C) of table 11 show that the own price elasticity
ranges from -0.693 (city-specific effects) to -0.565 (dwelling-specific effects). The model with
dwelling-household effects produces a price elasticity of -0.577. The cross-price elasticity is
positive (0.150) and indicates that gas and electricity are substitutes in the model with cityspecific effects (column (A)), but turns insignificant when we use dwelling-specific effects, and
negative and insignificant in the model with dwelling-family effects.
30
The model with city-specific effects indicates that gas usage increases by 19% for every
10 percentage point increase in the square footage of the home, and is about 24% larger in
homes with gas heating systems. The impact of these variables is small and statistically
insignificant in the variants with dwelling- and dwelling-household effects.
B. Robustness checks
Our first order of business is to examine the size of the potential bias due to
measurement errors in the prices of electricity and gas. To see if such a bias is severe, we began
with regressions where the sample is restricted to metro areas served by one utility. We argue
that the measurement error due to our price imputation procedure is smaller in single-utility
areas. For electricity usage, the results of these runs are reported in columns (D) and (E) of table
10 for the models with dwelling-specific effects and dwelling-family effects. Similar models for
gas usage are displayed in columns (D) and (E) of table 11. Clearly, the own-price elasticities
are very close (and slightly higher than) to their counterparts in columns (B) and (C).
Next, we estimated a log kWh model with fixed dwelling-specific effects, the regressors
as in table 10, and log electricity price (but no gas price). If we do not instrument for electricity
price, the own price elasticity is -0.6794. When we instrument for log electricity price using the
log of the state average prices of electricity and gas as the identifying instruments, the
coefficient on log price is -.67907.24 Using log state-level electricity price as the only identifying
instrument produces an own price elasticity of electricity demand of -0.6584, while replacing
that with the first lag of log price of electricity in the metro area yields an elasticity of -0.6108.
24
Our instruments are in the spirit of Black and Kniesner (2003), who propose using another mismeasured variable
(i.e., state-level annual average prices) to clean out the measurement error in the original mismeasured regressor
(here, average price in the metro area).
31
Finally, we estimated a model similar to equation (7), namely one where the dependent
variable is log electricity bill, the right-hand side includes fixed dwelling-specific effects, all
other controls, the log of nominal electricity price and the log of the CPI (but no gas price). The
coefficient on log nominal electricity price is 0.3223 and that on log CPI is 0.5981. The
corresponding estimates of the elasticity with respect to the price of electricity are -0.6777 and 0.5891 (from the coefficient on log price and log CPI, respectively). Although we argue in
section 3.C that these are both likely to overstate the true elasticity, they are within 10-15% of
the original estimates and of the IV estimates of the price elasticity, suggesting that the impact
of measurement error is modest.
Observers sometimes speculate that high price elasticities might be capturing the effect
of conservation and energy efficiency installations made possible by the utilities' DSM
initiatives.25 We do have the DSM expenditure per customer by the electrical utilities that serve
any given metro area, and, indeed, it is indeed positively correlated with electricity price
(correlation coefficient 0.28). However, when we add DSM expenditure per customer (in real
terms) in the right-hand side of the log KWh model, the coefficient on log electricity price is
virtually unchanged (-0.657).
To check if consumption depends on current or recent prices, we also estimated models
similar to the ones shown in tables 10 and 11, but where we further included lagged prices. We
found that i) the coefficients on contemporaneous price were strongly significant and similar to
their counterparts in table 10 and 11, and ii) the coefficients on lagged prices were very small in
magnitude and insignificant at the conventional levels. This is unsurprising if we recall that the
“previous period” is usually two years prior to the current observations. We would expect
25
We are grateful to Mark Jacobsen, personal communication, 2010, for raising this issue.
32
people to react to changes in recent billing periods, and billing periods are usually one month
(see Reiss and White, 2008).
To make that our results are not driven by outliers, we experimented with trimming the
sample, e.g., we excluded the observations in the bottom and top 1%, 2.5%, etc. of the
distribution of kWhs and MCFs. The elasticities and most other coefficients remained virtually
the same as those in tables 10 and 11.
In columns (F) and (G) of tables 10 and 11, we report regression results for the
subsamples with electric heat and gas heat. We report only the results for the models with cityspecific effects for the sake of brevity, but the same qualitative results hold for the models with
dwelling- and dwelling-households effects (although the magnitude of the coefficients is slightly
smaller). In contrast to earlier literature (Metcalf and Hassett, 1999; Reiss and White, 2005), we
find households with electric heating systems are actually less responsive to the price of
electricity than households that use gas heat. Households with gas heat are slightly more
sensitive to the price of gas than households that use electric heat.
However, Wald tests of the null that the elasticities are the same across the two groups
fail to reject the null. For example, if attention is restricted to the equations in columns (F) and
(G) of table 10, the Wald statistic of the null of identical own price elasticities is only 1.13 (pvalue 0.29).
The Wald statistics are even smaller in runs with fixed dwelling (or dwelling-household)
effects. One possible explanation for this is that the sample size is rather uneven across the
groups of homes served with electric and gas heat. The number of observations with electric
heat is 23542, but drops to 8416 when only true “panels” are used. This is only about 8% of the
33
total sample. The resulting increase in variance may help explain the lack of significant
differences across the two subsamples.
Finally, we estimated models where we allow the responsiveness to energy prices to vary
with the quartile of the income distribution that the household falls in. We find that the
responsiveness to prices is a bit higher in the first quartile, and declines monotonically by
quartile. For example, the elasticity of electricity consumption with respect to electricity price is
-0.681 among households in the first income quartile, -0.673 among those in the second quartile,
-0.663 among those in the third, and -0.645 among those in the fourth. An F test of the null that
these elasticities are all identical rejects the null at the 1% level or better (F statistic=15.96, pvalue less than 0.0001).
C. Dynamic Models and Models with Investments.
Turning to the partial adjustment model, we report results based on the Blundell-Bond
estimation procedure in table 12. Column (A) shows that the short-run own price elasticity of
electricity consumption is -0.736, and the long-run one is -0.814, while the short-run cross-price
elasticity (with respect to gas) is 0.265, and the long-run one is 0.293. For gas consumption,
shown in column (C), the short-run own price elasticity is -0.572 and the long-run one is -0.647.
The price of electricity is not significant in the gas equations. These equations include controls
for the heating and cooling system, and we interpret them to imply adjustment when the current
heating and cooling technology is considered irreversible.
In specifications (B) and (D) for electricity and gas, respectively, we exclude heating,
cooling, and appliance dummies from the regression and interpret the result to apply when the
choice of heating and cooling technology is reversible. It has been argued that durable goods
34
and heating and cooling equipment are variable in the long-run, hence these specifications
should result in a more pronounced response to energy prices. In fact, we do find slightly
elevated price elasticities, but the differences are minor, on the order of 2% for electricity
regressions, and 6% for gas regressions.
35
Table 10. Static Model: Selected Regression Results. Dependent variable: log of electricity
usage (lkWh1)
log elec price
log gas price
log sq. ft.
House Age
Age ^2
Owns the Home
No. of Rooms
No. of Floors
log Hhold Income
youngchild
elderly
lcdd
lhdd
Gas Heat
Electric Heat
fueloil_heat
(A)
(B)
(C)
(D) only one
utility
(E) only one
utility
(F) electric
heat
(G) gas heat
-0.860***
-0.667***
-0.681***
-0.685***
-0.692***
-0.679**
-0.825***
(-9.37)
(-9.69)
(-8.16)
(-8.26)
(-6.82)
(-3.22)
(-8.12)
0.117*
0.122*
0.139*
0.115*
0.107
0.126*
0.102
(2.02)
(2.45)
(2.36)
(1.97)
(1.58)
(2.04)
(1.63)
0.216***
0.0593
0.0522
0.0538
0.0396
0.226***
0.220***
(11.05)
(1.64)
(1.21)
(1.29)
(0.81)
(7.12)
(9.15)
0.00553***
-0.00477
-0.00195
-0.00164
-0.000416
0.00685***
0.00517***
(8.38)
0.0000540***
(-7.56)
(-1.70)
(-0.53)
(-0.48)
(-0.09)
0.0000491
0.0000307
0.0000154
0.00000486
(1.69)
(0.81)
(0.43)
(0.10)
(7.44)
0.0000632***
(-5.19)
(7.39)
0.0000498***
(-6.80)
0.0696***
-0.0558
0.0408
-0.0803
0.0215
0.0899**
0.0518**
(4.86)
(-1.69)
(0.70)
(-1.79)
(0.26)
(3.33)
(3.25)
0.0659***
0.0159***
0.0103
0.0202***
0.0130
0.0701***
0.0626***
(14.74)
(3.42)
(1.94)
(3.39)
(1.91)
(8.14)
(14.07)
-0.0171*
0.0371
0.0297
0.0425
0.0297
-0.0524**
0.00476
(-2.07)
(1.34)
(0.85)
(1.29)
(0.71)
(-3.35)
(0.59)
0.0225***
0.00906*
0.00677
0.0107*
0.00804
0.0251***
0.0208***
(8.83)
(2.30)
(1.49)
(2.12)
(1.38)
(6.10)
(8.08)
0.0963***
0.0721***
0.0353
0.0614**
0.0335
0.0913***
0.0964***
(15.06)
(4.24)
(1.48)
(2.82)
(1.09)
(11.36)
(11.93)
-0.0390***
-0.0204
-0.00932
-0.0137
-0.00911
-0.0154
-0.0400***
(-4.20)
(-0.88)
(-0.32)
(-0.49)
(-0.25)
(-0.95)
(-4.22)
0.0727***
0.0299
0.0250
0.0417
0.0272
0.141**
0.0762**
(3.58)
(1.07)
(0.78)
(1.20)
(0.68)
(3.14)
(3.33)
0.00350
-0.0123
0.00277
-0.0278
-0.0244
0.0393
0.0384
(0.07)
(-0.39)
(0.07)
(-0.58)
(-0.42)
(0.63)
(0.54)
-0.0990**
-0.0152
-0.0183
-0.00105
-0.0704
(-2.79)
(-0.17)
(-0.18)
(-0.01)
(-0.56)
0.0722
0.154***
0.106
0.123
0.117
(4.72)
(1.23)
(1.20)
(1.09)
(0.57)
-0.0971*
0.00475
0.103
0.0230
0.0945
(-2.28)
(0.04)
(0.64)
(0.15)
(0.51)
0.161***
0.0572*
0.0493
0.0566
0.0445
0.0928*
0.176***
(8.00)
(2.21)
(1.61)
(1.71)
(1.15)
(2.63)
(8.61)
1.422**
4.053***
3.861***
4.000***
4.212***
1.510*
1.094
(2.72)
(7.61)
(6.07)
(5.64)
(4.97)
(2.12)
(1.49)
city
dwelling
dwellingfamily
dwelling
dwellingfamily
city
city
R-squared
0.457
0.0557
0.0491
0.0564
0.0481
0.418
0.407
N.of cases
82905
82905
82905
48027
48027
22003
55688
city
dwelling
dwelling
dwelling
dwelling
city
city
A/C
Constant
effects
std. errs. Clustered
36
Table 11. Static Model: Selected Regression Results. Dependent variable: log of gas usage
(lgasuse1)
log elec price
log gas price
log sq. ft.
House Age
Age ^2
(A)
(B)
(C)
(D) only one
utility
(E) only one
utility
(F) electric
heat
(G) gas heat
0.150*
0.0376
-0.0334
0.0763
0.0192
0.461
0.128*
(2.15)
(0.48)
(-0.36)
(0.78)
(0.16)
(1.49)
(2.12)
-0.693***
-0.565***
-0.577***
-0.583***
-0.587***
-0.634***
-0.693***
(-6.57)
(-9.51)
(-8.21)
(-8.31)
(-7.24)
(-4.52)
(-6.45)
0.189***
0.0524
0.0459
0.0490
0.0439
0.120*
0.201***
(9.88)
(1.26)
(0.89)
(1.03)
(0.76)
(2.33)
(10.25)
0.00383***
0.0000321
0.000597
-0.0000686
-0.000542
0.00252
0.00384***
(5.87)
(0.01)
(0.15)
(-0.02)
(-0.12)
(1.06)
(5.85)
-0.00000911
0.00000684
0.0000168
0.00000619
0.0000201
-0.0000107
-0.00000725
(-1.30)
(0.22)
(0.42)
(0.16)
(0.42)
(-0.47)
(-1.05)
Owns the
Home
0.0322*
-0.0426
-0.00991
-0.0331
-0.00764
0.00436
0.0412**
(2.56)
(-1.08)
(-0.14)
(-0.61)
(-0.07)
(0.15)
(3.28)
No. of
Rooms
0.0549***
0.0149**
0.0125
0.0171*
0.0140
0.0695***
0.0536***
(18.61)
(2.72)
(1.93)
(2.51)
(1.74)
(7.37)
(17.83)
0.00974
0.0573
0.0485
0.0645
0.0673
-0.0224
0.00998
No. of Floors
log Hhold
Income
youngchild
elderly
lcdd
lhdd
Gas Heat
(1.18)
(1.75)
(1.09)
(1.72)
(1.32)
(-0.62)
(1.30)
0.00357
0.00285
0.00298
0.00446
0.00313
-0.00950
0.00497*
(1.61)
(0.60)
(0.55)
(0.74)
(0.47)
(-1.40)
(2.20)
0.0711***
0.0635**
0.0657*
0.0658*
0.0813*
0.0549***
0.0683***
(12.01)
(3.05)
(2.25)
(2.44)
(2.18)
(3.73)
(11.12)
0.0640***
-0.00246
0.00278
-0.00266
-0.000376
0.0574*
0.0659***
(7.23)
(-0.10)
(0.08)
(-0.08)
(-0.01)
(2.53)
(7.40)
-0.00384
-0.0262
-0.00987
-0.0189
0.000143
0.105
0.00162
(-0.13)
(-0.85)
(-0.28)
(-0.49)
(0.00)
(1.24)
(0.06)
0.0991
0.105*
0.114
0.192*
0.198*
-0.0936
0.149**
(1.67)
(1.99)
(1.93)
(2.20)
(2.15)
(-1.15)
(2.83)
0.215***
-0.0797
-0.0890
-0.0855
-0.108
(-0.45)
(4.20)
(-0.55)
(-0.48)
(-0.36)
0.0211
-0.225
-0.226
-0.237
-0.229
(0.47)
(-1.47)
(-1.15)
(-0.95)
(-0.90)
-0.938***
-0.730**
-0.564*
-0.677
-0.506
(-11.47)
(-2.82)
(-1.99)
(-1.91)
(-1.36)
-0.0147
0.0171
0.00614
-0.000232
-0.0155
-0.0348
-0.0154
(-0.94)
0.214
(0.62)
1.931**
(0.18)
1.587*
(-0.01)
1.334
(-0.36)
1.050
(-1.09)
3.746**
(-1.01)
0.206
(0.35)
(2.76)
(1.97)
(1.29)
(0.95)
(2.79)
(0.33)
city
dwelling
dwellingfamily
dwelling
dwellingfamily
city
city
R-squared
0.438
0.0497
0.0465
0.0556
0.0512
0.250
0.429
N.of cases
59492
59492
59492
34371
34371
5176
53027
std. err
clustering
city
dwelling
dwelling
dwelling
dwelling
city
city
Electric Heat
fueloil_heat
A/C
Constant
effects
37
Table 12. Blundell-Bond estimates. Dynamic models. (Model based on dwelling-specific
effects.)
log of energy usage - lkWh
log of energy usage - lMCF
(A) dwelling
effect
(B) no HVAC
(C) dwelling
effect
(D) no HVAC
0.0958***
(6.09)
-0.736***
(-12.26)
0.265***
(5.15)
0.142**
(2.64)
-0.00624*
(-2.04)
0.0000497
(1.63)
-0.0261
(-0.90)
0.0128***
(3.70)
0.00976
(0.45)
0.00935**
(3.09)
0.0725***
(4.89)
-0.00728
(-0.36)
0.0660**
(3.01)
0.0222
(0.95)
0.0939***
(5.83)
-0.743***
(-12.29)
0.283***
(5.56)
0.142**
(2.65)
-0.00699*
(-2.22)
0.0000522
(1.68)
-0.0310
(-1.06)
0.0126***
(3.60)
-0.00316
(-0.14)
0.00925**
(3.05)
0.0714***
(4.80)
-0.00829
(-0.41)
0.0793***
(3.56)
0.00478
(0.21)
0.116***
(6.20)
-0.0716
(-0.91)
-0.572***
(-9.15)
0.140
(1.91)
0.00691*
(2.22)
-0.0000353
(-1.07)
-0.0168
(-0.45)
0.0162***
(3.72)
0.149***
(4.98)
0.00318
(0.93)
0.0574**
(3.01)
0.0160
(0.69)
-0.0297
(-1.21)
0.200***
(5.46)
0.123***
(6.41)
-0.0821
(-1.05)
-0.586***
(-9.32)
0.137
(1.83)
0.00720*
(2.31)
-0.0000365
(-1.11)
-0.0101
(-0.27)
0.0162***
(3.70)
0.164***
(5.40)
0.00425
(1.23)
0.0578**
(2.99)
0.0190
(0.81)
-0.0304
(-1.22)
0.202***
(5.41)
N.of cases
2.389***
(4.06)
24487
2.422***
(4.08)
24487
-0.661
(-0.91)
17679
-0.844
(-1.14)
17679
long term elasticity
-0.8140
-0.8200
-0.6471
-0.6682
Lag Consumption
Log electric price
Log gas price
Log sq. ft
House age
Age ^ 2
Owns the Home
No. Rooms
No. Floors
Log Hhold Income
Youngchild
Elderly
log CDD
log HDD
Constant
38
6. Discussion and Conclusions
The price elasticity of residential energy demand is an important input into assessments
of the effects of energy policies and demand forecasts. In this paper, we have focused on the
residential demand for electricity and gas, working with nationwide household-level data and
covering recent years, namely 1997-2007.
There are reasons to suspect that earlier estimates based on a similar approach but old
data may no longer apply because of well-documented recent trends towards larger homes, more
efficient but more numerous appliances, and more extensive use of air conditioning, which
drives up energy consumption during the summer (EIA, 2010).
With more recent estimates based on abrupt changes in prices due to supply conditions
in geographically limited areas, it is unclear whether they are appropriate nationwide. Matters
are further complicated by the deregulation of the utilities sector and expectations about future
price changes.
To address these external validity limitations, we assembled a mixed panel/multi-year
cross-sectional dataset of households in the 50 largest metropolitan areas in the United States as
of 2008. Our dataset documents utility bills, heating and cooling systems and appliances, and
dwelling and household characteristics for over 69,000 dwellings (over 74,000 households)
from 1997 to 2007, for a total of over 98,000 observations. These data are taken from the
American Housing Survey. We merged this dataset with utility prices and heating and cooling
degree-days at the metro area level. To our knowledge, this is the most comprehensive set of
data for examining household residential energy usage at the national level, containing the
broadest geographical coverage, and with the longest longitudinal component (max T=6).
39
Another important feature of our data is that we can control for unobserved
heterogeneity in a variety of ways. City-specific fixed effects exploit the variation in prices,
dwelling characteristics, and state and local policies between observations, while dwellingspecific and dwelling-household effects rely on variation of prices, weather, and other local
characteristics over time. We estimate static and dynamic models under alternate assumptions
about the difficulty of reversing a home’s heating and cooling system.
We find strong household response to energy prices, both in the short and long term.
From the static models, we get estimates of the own price elasticity of electricity demand in the 0.860 to -0.667 range, while the own price elasticity of gas demand is -0.693 to -0.566. Contrary
to earlier literature (Metcalf and Hassett, 1999; Reiss and White, 2005), we find no evidence of
significantly different elasticities across households with electric and gas heat. The dynamic
models produce estimates similar estimates, with short-run (long-run) own-price elasticity of
demand of -0.736 (-0.814) for electricity and -0.572 (-0.647) for gas.
These results are in sharp contrast with much of the literature on residential energy
consumption in the United States, and with the figures used in current government agency
practice. In its Annual Energy Outlook, for example, the Energy Information Agency (EIA)
historically employed a short-term price elasticity of -0.15 for non-electric energy. In their 2010
report, EIA adopts an electric elasticity of -0.30 in anticipation of improved consumer
awareness resulting from recent smart grid projects.26 Our results suggest that price elasticities
are likely more pronounced than that. Moreover, they suggest that there might be considerable
potential for policies which affect energy price than may have been previously appreciated. We
leave it to future research to explore how people respond to changing energy prices—through
26
The text refers specifically to smart grid projects funded under the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of
2009 http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/assumption/residential.html and EIA (2010)
40
energy efficiency investments, changing the stock of appliances, or merely changing
conservation practices.
41
References
Alberini, Anna and Massimo Filippini (2010), “Response of Residential Electricity Demand to
Price: The Effect of Measurement Error,” CEPE Working Paper 75, Centre for Energy
Policy
and
Economics,
ETH
Zurich,
July
(available
at
http://www.cepe.ethz.ch/publications/workingPapers/CEPE_WP75.pdf )
Arellano, Manuel and Stephen Bond (1991), “Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte
Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations,” Review of Economic
Studies, 58(2), 277–297.
Anderson, T.W. and C. Hsiao (1982), “ Formulation and Estimation of Dynamic Models Using
Panel Data,” Journal of Econometrics, 18, 67–82.
Baltagi, B.H. (2001), Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, Chichester: Wiley and Sons.
Basheda, Gregory, et al. (2006), “Why Are Electricity Prices Increasing? An Industry-Wide
Perspective”, Report Prepared for the Edison Foundation
Berry David (2008), “The impact of energy efficiency programs on the growth of electricity
sales,” Energy Policy, 36(9), 3620-3625.
Bernard, Jean-Thomas et al. (2010), “A Pseudo-Panel Data Model of Household Electricity
Demand,” Resource and Energy Economics, 32 (4)
Bernstein, Mark A., and James Griffin (2005), “Regional Differences in Price-Elasticity of
Demand for Energy,” The Rand Corporation Technical Report.
Black, Dan, and Thomas Kniesner, (2003), “On the Measurement of Job Risk in Hedonic Wage
Models,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27(3), 205-220.
Blundell, R. and S. Bond (1998), “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel
Data Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.
Burtless, Gary, and Jerry A. Hausman (1978). “The Effects of Taxation on Labor Supply:
Evaluating the Gary Income Maintenance Experiment,” Journal of Political Economy,
86, 1101-1130.
Burtraw, Dallas, et al. (2002), “The Effect on Asset Values of the Allocation of Carbon Dioxide
Emission Allowances”, The Electricity Journal, 15(5), 51-62
Bushnell, James and Erin Mansur (2005), “Consumption under noisy price signals: a study of
electricity retail rate deregulation in San Diego,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 53
(4), 493-513
42
Carlson, J. Lon, and David Loomis, (2008), “An Assessment of the Impact of Deregulation on
the Relative Price of Electricity in Illinois”, The Electricity Journal, 21(6), 60-70
Choi-Granade, Hannah et al. (2009), “Unlocking Energy Efficiency in the U.S. Economy,”
McKinsey & Company Report
Deaton, Angus and John Muellbauer (1980), Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge
University Press.
Dergiades, Theologos and Lefteris Tsoulfidis (2008),”Estimating Residential Demand for
Electricity in the United States, 1965-2006,” Energy Economics, 30, 2722-2730
Energy
Information
Agency
(2010)
“Annual
Energy
http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/demand.html accessed November 4, 2010
Outlook”,
Fabrizio, Kira, Nancy Rose, and Catherine Wolfram (2007), “Do Markets Reduce Costs?
Assessing the Impact of Regulatory Restructuring on U.S. Electric Generation
Efficiency”, American Economic Review 97(4), 1250-1277
Fischer, Carolyn (2010), “Renewable Portfolio Standards: When Do They Lower Energy
Prices?,” The Energy Journal, 31(1), 101-120
Frondel, Manuel et al. (2008), “Emissions Trading: Impact on Electricity Prices and EnergyIntensive Industries,” Ruhr Economic Working Paper No. 81
Garcia-Cerrutti. L. Miguel (2000), “Estimating Elasticities of Residential Energy Demand from
Panel County Data Using Dynamic Random Variables Models with Heteroskedastic
and Correlated Error Terms,” Resource and Energy Economics, 22, 355-366
Golove, William H. and Joseph H. Eto (1996), “Market Barriers to Energy Efficiency: A
Critical Reappraisal of the Rationale for Public Policies to Promote Energy
Efficiency,” Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory Report, UC Berkeley.
Greene, W. H., (2008), Econometric Analysis, Sixth Edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson
Prentice Hall.
Greening, Lorna A., et al. (2000), “Energy Efficiency and Consumption – the Rebound Effect –
A Survey,” Energy Policy, 28, 389-401.
Hassett, Kevin and Gilbert Metcalf, (1993), “Energy Conservation Investment: Do Consumers
Correctly Discount the Future?,” Energy Journal, 21(6), 710-716
Houthakker, Hendrik S. (1980), “Residential Electricity Revisited,” Energy Journal, 1(1), 2941.
Howe, Charles W. and F. P. Linaweaver, Jr. (1967), “The Impact of Price on Residential Water
Demand and Its Relation to System Design and Price Structure,” Water Resources
Research, 20, 197-202.
43
Jaffe, Adam B. and Robert N. Stavins (1994), “The Energy Efficiency Gap. What Does It
Mean?” Energy Policy, 22(10), 804-810.
Joskow, Paul and Jean Tirole (2006), “Retail Electricity Competition,” RAND Journal of
Economics, 37(4), 799-815.
Judson, R. A. and A. L. Owen (1999), “Estimating Dynamic Panal Data Models: A Guide for
Macroeconomists,” Economic Letters, 65, 9–15.
Kamerschen, David and David Porter (2004), “The Demand for Residential, Industrial and
Total Electricity, 1973-1998,” Energy Economics 26 (1), 87-100
Kiviet, J.F. (1995), “On bias, Inconsistency, and Efficiency of Various Estimators in Dynamic
Panel Data Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 68, 53–78.
Leth-Petersen, Soren and Mikael Togeby (2001), “Demand for Space Heating in Apartment
Blocks: Measuring Effects of Policy Measures Aiming at Reducing Energy
Consumption,” Energy Economics 23 (4), 387-403
Liao, Hue-Chi and Tsai Feng Chang, (2002), “Space-Heating and water-heating demand of the
aged in the U.S.,” Energy Economics, 24(3), 267-284.
Meier, Helena and Katrin Rehdanz (2010), “Determinants of Residential Space Heating
Expenditures in Great Britain,” Energy Economics, 32, 949-959
Metcalf, Gilbert and Kevin A. Hassett (1999), “Measuring the Energy Savings from Home
Improvement Investments: Evidence from Monthly Billing Data”, The Review of
Economics and Statistics, 81(3), 516-528.
Moulton, Brent R. (1990), “An Illustration of a Pitfall in Estimating the Effects of Aggregate
Variables on Micro Units,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2), 334-338
Nesbakken , Runa (2001), “Energy Consumption for Space Heating: A Discrete-Continuous
Approach”, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103(1), 165-184.
Nordin, John (1976), “A Proposed Modification of Taylor’s Demand Analysis: Comment,” The
Bell Journal of Economics, 7(2), 719-721.
Paul Anthony, Erica Myers, and Karen Palmer (2009) “A Partial Adjustment Model of U.S.
Electricity Demand by Region, Season, and Sector,” Resources for the Future
discussion paper 08-50, Washington, DC, April.
Poyer, David A. and Martin Williams (1993), “Residential Energy Demand: Additional
Empirical Evidence by Minority Household Type,” Energy Economics, 15(2), 93-100.
Quigley, John M. and Daniel L. Rubinfeld (1989), “Unobservables in Consumer Choice:
Residential Energy and the Demand for Comfort,” The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 71(3), 416-425.
44
Reiss, Peter C. and Matthew W. White (2005), “Household Electricity Demand, Revisited,”
Review of Economic Studies, 72, 853-858.
Reiss, Peter C. and Matthew W. White (2008), “What Changes Energy Consumption? Prices
and Public Pressures,” RAND Journal of Economics, 29(3), 636-663.
Scarpa, Riccardo and Kenneth Willis (2009), “Willingness-to-Pay for Renewable Energy:
Primary and Discretionary Choice of British Households' for Micro-Generation
Technologies,” Energy Economics, 32(1), 129-136.
Shin Jeong-Shik (1985), “Perception of Price When Price Information Is Costly: Evidence from
Residential Electricity Demand,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(4), 591-598.
Showalter, Marilyn (2007a) “Price Trends For Industrial Electricity, Regulated versus
Deregulated States,” Power in the Public Interest, Nov. 6.
Showalter, Marilyn (2007b), “Electricity Price Trends in Regulated versus Deregulated States,”
Power in the Public Interest, Nov. 7.
Smale, Robin, et al. (2006), "The impact of CO2 Emissions Trading on Firm Profits and Market
Prices" Climate Policy, 6(1), 31-48.
Taylor, Lester D. (1975), “The Demand for Electricity: A Survey,” The Bell Journal of
Economics, 6(1), 74-110.
NOTE DI LAVORO DELLA FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper Series
Our Note di Lavoro are available on the Internet at the following addresses:
http://www.feem.it/getpage.aspx?id=73&sez=Publications&padre=20&tab=1
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/JELJOUR_Results.cfm?form_name=journalbrowse&journal_id=266659
http://ideas.repec.org/s/fem/femwpa.html
http://www.econis.eu/LNG=EN/FAM?PPN=505954494
http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/handle/35978
http://www.bepress.com/feem/
SD
1.2011
NOTE DI LAVORO PUBLISHED IN 2011
Anna Alberini, Will Gans and Daniel Velez-Lopez: Residential Consumption of Gas and Electricity in the U.S.:
The Role of Prices and Income