Research Paper No. 2006/102
Stock Market Development
and Economic Growth
Salvatore Capasso*
September 2006
Abstract
Since the 1990s economists have devoted considerable attention to the study of the
relationship between financial markets development and economic growth. In
particular, the emergence of stock markets with economic development is an intriguing
and interesting aspect of such a relationship, and yet relatively unexplored. This paper
examines the most recent findings in the theoretical and empirical literature trying to
determine the rationale behind the development of stock markets along the path of
growth and the nature of the interrelationship between real and financial variables.
Keywords: financial markets development, economic growth, economic development,
stock markets development
JEL classification: O16, O40, G10
Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2006
*University of Naples ‘Parthenope’ and IDEGA, University of Santiago de Compostela.
This study has been prepared within UNU-WIDER’s research on Globalization, Finance and Growth,
linked to the project on Financial Sector Development for Growth and Poverty Reduction.
UNU-WIDER gratefully acknowledges the financial contributions to the research programme by the
governments of Denmark (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Finland (Ministry for Foreign Affairs),
Norway (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Sweden (Swedish International Development Cooperation
Agency—Sida) and the United Kingdom (Department for International Development).
ISSN 1810-2611
ISBN 92-9190-886-X (internet version)
The World Institute for Development Economics Research (WIDER) was
established by the United Nations University (UNU) as its first research and
training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland in 1985. The Institute
undertakes applied research and policy analysis on structural changes
affecting the developing and transitional economies, provides a forum for the
advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable and environmentally
sustainable growth, and promotes capacity strengthening and training in the
field of economic and social policy making. Work is carried out by staff
researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through networks of
collaborating scholars and institutions around the world.
www.wider.unu.edu
[email protected]
UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER)
Katajanokanlaituri 6 B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland
Camera-ready typescript prepared by Lorraine Telfer-Taivainen at UNU-WIDER
The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s). Publication does not imply
endorsement by the Institute or the United Nations University, nor by the programme/project sponsors, of
any of the views expressed.
1
Introduction
In the wake of substantial empirical evidence, recent decades have seen economists
devoting considerable attention to the study of the interrelationship between financial
variables and the processes of real resource allocation. These studies have directed their
efforts towards challenging the idea of an existing dichotomy between the real and
financial worlds, which has long been assumed by a large part of the literature and
which has found strong theoretical support in the Modigliani and Miller theorem.
Indeed, the real world seems to depict a quite different state of affairs. As the data show,
the structure of financial markets, far from being stable and static, moves along with
economic growth and capital accumulation in many economies. Furthermore, the comovements of financial markets and economic systems appear to display significant
regularities. At low stages of economic development, when economies are relatively
poor, financial systems are very rudimentary: financial intermediation is scarce and
financial instruments are very simple and basic. At these stages stock markets are
completely absent. As economies develop, financial intermediation grows, more
complex and articulated financial instruments appear in the market, and stock markets
emerge. These represent very general regularities and describe in broad terms the
development of financial markets and the interrelationship of financial development and
capital accumulation. However, the data also provide other more specific features of the
co-movements between financial and real variables. These features might differ from
county to country and from period to period, but they still say a lot about the relevance
of financial variables in the process of real resource allocation.
Until now, the literature has mainly focused on the role of financial intermediation in
the process of economic growth and capital accumulation. Indeed, many studies have
analyzed the channels through which banks and other financial intermediaries may help
to increase, for example, the saving rate or the average productivity of capital and, in
turn, growth. Recently, however, a new wave of interest on a specific aspect of financial
market development has occupied economists’ investigative activity. This is the role
played by stock market development in the process of economic development.
The renewed interest, which is predominantly theoretical, stems from the fact that
despite the large body of empirical evidence, many questions remain unanswered. Why
do stock markets develop relatively late in the process of economic development? Why
do firms change corporate financing decisions, preferring debt over equity in richer
countries? Is it economic development that engineers transformations in financial
systems and determines the emergence of stock markets, or, rather, is it stock market
development that spurs economic growth? These, together with other questions, have
been extensively analyzed by a large number of recent theoretical and empirical studies.
1
Significantly, the evolution of financial markets does not appear to be a straightforward
and linear phenomenon. A complex bundle of connections between the relevant
variables makes it difficult to uncover, and replicate through modelling, the real
dynamics of the economic systems. Among these empirical facts, one surfaces as a
particularly interesting one. The emergence and expansion of stock markets does not
usually give rise to the simple substitution of financial intermediation with equity
financing in the economy. Rather, the expansion of stock markets always appears to be
followed by an initial expansion of debt and bank financing, to such an extent that the
equity/debt ratio in the economy first decreases and only increases with further
economic development. Figure 1 provides a description of the evolution of financial
markets in a sample of countries including advanced OECD economies and some major
emerging markets.
Figure 1: Domestic credit provided by bank sector and stock market capitalization
120
100
80
Dom es tic credit provided by
banking s ector (% of GDP)
60
Market capitalization of lis ted
com panies (% of GDP)
40
20
0
1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
Source: World Bank Economic Indicators 2004.
Note: The data are annual averages of the values in the following sample countries: Australia, Belgium,
Canada, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Norway, Portugal, Spain, United Kingdom,
United Status, Rep. Korea, China, Malaysia, India, Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, South Africa, Turkey,
Russian Federation.
Although the objective of previous studies has been generally the same, the
methodological approach has not. In fact, in order to explain the emergence and
evolution of stock markets, and to take account of the impact of such modifications in
financial markets on economic development, the literature has followed different routes.
Despite the differences, these studies can be clustered into two major groups. The first
group deals with the emergence of stock markets as a pure macroeconomic
phenomenon. For these studies the modifications in financial systems are the result of
changing costs associated with different financial institutions. The second group is more
interested in analysing the corporate financing decisions of individual firms. These
studies try to verify how firms’ financing choices change with capital accumulation. We
will refer to the approach followed by the first group as the ‘institutional approach’ and
to the second as the ‘instrumental approach’.
2
Our main objective is to critically examine the current state of the theoretical literature
which, although substantial, has left space for further investigation. The aim is to
organize and manage the main results of these studies in order to shed light on the issue
of stock market development and economic growth and to open new avenues for a
different approach to the empirical evidence. And it is from the empirical evidence that
it is necessary to start in order to understand the evolution of the theoretical literature.
2
Empirical evidence
A large body of empirical studies clearly shows that the development of stock markets
is strongly and positively correlated with the level of economic development and capital
accumulation. This is a solid and uncontroversial result, and it appears to be true across
time and for many countries. Indeed, the data confirm that as economies develop equity
markets tend to expand both in terms of the number of listed companies and in terms of
market capitalization (Atje and Jovanovich 1993; Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine 1996a,
1996b; Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic 1996; Korajczyk 1996; Levine and Zervos
1996, 1998). This result, however, does not suggest a direct and monotonic expansion
of the share of equity markets in the financial system. In reality, the expansion of equity
markets always appears to be preceded and accompanied by the general expansion of
the overall financial system. And to a careful observer, far from being a simple and
straightforward fact, the co-evolution of real and financial variables is a complex and
multifaceted phenomenon. Indeed, the expansion of stock markets generally follows the
development of commercial banks and other financial intermediaries which, in many
cases, continues as equity markets expand. This process produces an apparently
puzzling situation: an expanding equity market together with a financial system
persistently dominated by banks and their financial products. Even if the evidence often
appears to be bewildering, and in many circumstances difficult to interpret, some simple
general stylized facts about the relationship between financial development and
economic growth can be drawn from the empirical literature (De Gregorio and Guidotti
1995; King and Levine 1993a, 1993b; Levine and Renelt 1992; Roubini and Sala-iMartin 1991). These facts are summarized in the following points:
—
In the early stages of economic development, financial markets are very thin
and very rudimentary. During these stages, financial markets are dominated by
banks, or similar types of financial intermediaries. Stock markets are
completely absent or, if they exist in any form, their size is negligible.
—
As capital accumulates financial intermediaries develop, the number of
financial instruments increases, as does the level of sophistication and
complexity of financial contracts and the flow of resources and funds accruing
to the financial market increases its size. Stock markets start developing both
in terms of the number of listed firms and market capitalization.
—
As the economy continues to grow, equity markets develop further and so do
banks and other financial intermediaries.
3
—
Stock markets appear to develop in a non-monotonic ways. In economies
where stock markets are relatively small, capital accumulation seems to be
followed by a relative increase in banks’ share in the financial system. In
economies where the stock market has already reached a reasonable size,
further development of the market causes an increase in the equity markets’
share. In other words, evidence shows that the equity/debt ratio first decreases
and, only with further development of the stock market, increases.
The co-evolution of equity markets and capital accumulation is only one aspect of the
more general interrelationship between economic growth and the expansion of the
financial system. Since the seminal contributions by Goldsmith (1969) and McKinnon
(1973), economists have devoted considerable attention to the study of the role played
by financial intermediation in the process of real resource allocation and capital
accumulation. Only very recently have economists specifically focused their attention
on the role of stock markets in the process of economic development. Interestingly,
these recent studies have not only revealed novel theoretical and empirical aspects of the
channels of interaction between real and financial variables, they have also been able to
shed light on individual firms’ optimal financial choice in connection with economic
development.
Before turning to a synthetic description of these studies, it is necessary to agree, at the
onset, on a definition of equity markets’ development, and to specify a measure of such
development. In doing so, it is useful to observe that the development of a stock market
can be identified by means of quantitative or qualitative measurements or by a
combination of the two. Different routes can be pursued. The primary route to follow in
order to assess the expansion of a stock market is to look at changes in its dimension. A
simple measure of a stock market’s size is the total value of all the shares in the market
at each point in time (market capitalization) or the average of this value over a period.
Market size is important because the level of savings mobilization and risk
diversification depend strongly on this indicator. Of course, a measure of a stock
market’s size needs to take into account the dimension of the economic system overall.
For this reason, the typical measurement employed in empirical analyses is the ratio of
market capitalization to gross domestic product (GDP) (market capitalization/GDP).
Stock market size can also be measured by the number of listed companies in the stock
exchange in each period. Although market size is an important indicator of stock market
development, this measurement by itself does not capture all the relevant features of a
financial markets’ development. Indeed, a developed market is also an efficient and
liquid market in which financial funds can be mobilized at low cost and can move easily
from one investment to the other. These qualitative features of market development can
be captured by indicators such as the volume of shares traded in each period and the
degree of concentration. While the former of these indices measures the level of
liquidity in the market, the latter takes into account the level of risk diversification.
Finally, in order to capture the main features of financial market development, one
cannot fail to take into account the institutional and regulatory framework which
4
represents the basic organization of the market. It is useful to provide a brief and
schematic description of such indicators:
—
Market capitalization ratio: this is calculated by dividing the value of listed
companies (market capitalization) by GDP. It gives a measure of the size of the
stock market relative to the size of the economy. It is a good measure of the
relative size of the stock market in the economy.
—
Number of listed companies: this specifies the number of all companies listed
in the country’s stock exchange at any point in time. This indicator is also a
measure of stock market size.
—
Total value traded: this gives the total value of shares traded during the
period. Total value traded divided by GDP gives a measure of the liquidity in
the market. Market liquidity measures how easily securities can be bought and
sold. This indicator complements the market capitalization ratio and signals
whether market size is matched by trading activity.
—
Turnover ratio is the total value of shares traded during the period divided by
the average market capitalization for the period. Average market capitalization
is calculated as the average of the end-of-period values for the current period
and the previous period.
—
Institutional and regulatory framework: the degree of development of a
market is strongly influenced by the regulatory system. Differences in
regulatory systems, for example, are often used to explain the great differences
in equity market development between countries such as the UK, the USA, and
Canada on one side and Japan, Germany, France, and Italy on the other,
despite their similar level of economic development.
—
Concentration: the degree of market concentration is important to show how
well a market really works. A very high degree of concentration signals a
heavy and illiquid market. In such circumstances, the benefits of risk
diversification in markets are very low. A measure of concentration could be
provided, for example, by the average size of firms listed in the stock market
(see Figure 2).
Tables 1a and 1b describe some of these indicators of stock market development for two
groups of countries: a sample of advanced OECD countries and some major emerging
economies. Significantly, for almost all of these countries, the market capitalization
ratio and the number of listed firms show that the size of stock markets has increased
over time. Furthermore, as witnessed by the total stock traded over GDP indicator, stock
markets have been increasingly active, showing an increase in the level of liquidity in
recent decades. Through these and other indicators, empirical studies have provided
hard evidence of the co-evolution of stock market development and economic growth
and highlighted the most relevant features of this interrelationship.
5
Figure 2: Average firm size listed on the stock market
2500,00
2000,00
1500,00
1988-92
1000,00
1998-02
500,00
Au
st
ra
Be lia
lg
iu
Ca m
na
d
Fr a
a
G nce
er
m
an
G y
re
ec
Ire e
la
nd
Ita
ly
Ja
pa
No n
rw
Po a y
rtu
ga
Un
ite
Sp l
d
K ai
Un ing n
ite d o
m
d
St
at
es
0,00
Source: World Bank Economic Indicators 2004.
Note: The average firm size in the reference period is calculated on the basis of the average market
capitalization and the average number of listed firms over the same period.
Table 1a: Stock market development indicators: sample of advanced OECD countries
Market capitalization of
listed companies
(% of GDP)
Number of listed
Total value of stocks
domestic companies
traded (% of GDP)
1988-92 1993-97 1998-02 1988-92 1993-97 1998-02 1998-02 1993-97 1998-02
Australia
44.99
68.59
96.90
1143
1157
1280
14.13
30.50
57.36
Belgium
36.40
42.05
75.34
181
149
163
4.03
7.59
18.84
Canada
46.52
69.89 102.66
1128
1226
1862
14.07
35.42
64.34
France
28.51
37.75
87.51
646
550
810
9.12
21.27
64.99
Germany
21.48
27.38
55.85
549
580
880
29.55
23.69
54.02
Greece
11.60
18.04
91.98
128
205
307
2.06
7.44
66.16
49.32
71.54
80
74
16.15
33.20
14.63
20.17
53.88
220
233
277
3.31
10.27
50.76
105.39
66.39
67.68
2056
2269
2595
55.78
24.78
41.02
Norway
18.99
32.28
37.31
118
151
193
9.46
16.64
31.03
Portugal
13.49
21.62
49.63
181
171
106
3.02
8.29
34.07
Spain
24.39
36.00
76.17
410
372
1333
7.80
30.74 143.43
United Kingdom
91.74 131.27 164.21
1853
2024
1912
40.39
48.90 121.74
United States
62.70
6689
7988
7133
34.31
77.43 242.59
Ireland
Italy
Japan
98.07 146.77
Source: World Bank Economic Indicators 2004.
Note: The data are author’s calculation of averages over five year periods.
6
Table 1b: Stock market development indicators: sample of major emerging countries
Market capitalization of
listed companies
Number of listed domestic Total value of stocks traded,
companies
(% of GDP)
(% of GDP)
1988-92 1993-97 1998-02 1988-92 1993-97 1998-02 1998-02 1993-97 1998-02
Korea, Rep.
China
Malaysia
India
43.62
32.30
55.90
667
730
1228
37.71
48.07
162.31
2.46
12.06
38.54
33
416
1056
2.11
21.53
39.88
111.42 248.99 143.10
292
549
791
21.66
162.22
44.06
14.83
34.87
29.56
3204
4983
5821
6.85
17.24
50.06
Argentina
5.46
16.85
55.11
178
154
116
2.59
5.92
2.60
Brazil
9.00
27.57
33.00
579
545
458
3.76
16.79
15.08
19.92
36.76
22.37
202
194
179
6.58
14.65
6.84
123.16 161.71 148.44
721
639
584
6.54
16.35
59.30
3.12
22.00
52.12
1.24
6.19
Mexico
South Africa
Turkey
7.39
19.74
32.93
98
204
295
Russian Federation
0.05
9.03
23.96
20
115
225
Source: World Bank Economic Indicators 2004.
Note: The data are the author’s calculation of averages over five year periods.
By studying a relatively large set of 40 countries in the period 1979-88, and focusing on
the dynamics of market size, Atje and Jovanovich (1993) have found a strong positive
correlation between the level of financial development and stock market development
and economic growth. In a more recent study, Levine and Zervos (1998) obtain similar
results on a larger set of observations. They sample 47 countries from 1976 to 1993, and
find that stock market liquidity measured as the value of stock traded relative to the size
of the market and the size of the economy is strongly and positively correlated to the
rate of economic growth. They also observe that the level of banking development,
measured as the ratio of bank loans to the private sector to GDP, is positively correlated
with the level of economic growth. The significance of stock market development in the
process of economic growth is also confirmed by Beck and Levine (2001) who, by
applying novel econometric procedures, test for the independent impact of banks and
stock markets on growth. Again, Beck and Levine find that the expansion of both banks
and stock markets significantly affects growth.
As already outlined, beyond this apparently clear and general result, the dynamic
interaction between financial and real variables is an articulated and multifaceted
phenomenon which can differ greatly from country to country. In order to get an idea of
these differences in the evolution of the financial systems, it is useful to mention the
contraposition between the so-called bank-based financial system predominant in
continental Europe and Japan, and the so-called market-based system predominant in
the Anglo-Saxon countries. In the former countries, in which the banking sector
strongly dominates the financial sector, economic growth and capital accumulation have
7
involved a significantly less perceptible development of equity markets despite these
countries displaying similar levels of capital accumulation to Anglo-Saxon countries.
Although the dynamic patterns of financial systems can differ greatly from country to
country, some general stylized facts about the development of equity markets can be
drawn from the literature. As outlined by Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (1996),
stock markets do not develop in a monotonic way, neither, as one might wrongly
deduce, does the development of equity markets directly crowd out the banking sector
and other financial intermediaries. Rather, the dynamics of equity markets seem to
depend on the level of economic development and on the level of the stock market
development itself. In specific terms, when economies have thin and underdeveloped
stock markets, capital accumulation leads to an increase in the share in the economy of
debt and bank financing. As economies grow and stock markets develop more, further
development of stock markets leads to a relative increase of equity financing in the
economy. In other words, given that stock market development depends on growth, the
bank debt/equity ratio in the economy tends to increase at low levels of capital
accumulation and to decrease only when stock markets have reached a reasonable size.
Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic provide an explanation for this finding based on the
effect of equity market development on the cost of access to credit. The idea is that in
the initial stages of economic development, the expansion of stock markets increases
both the opportunity for risk sharing and the flow of information in the market. These,
in turn, allow firms to access bank loans more easily and cheaply and to increase the
level of leverage. However, as stock markets develop further, issuing equity becomes
more convenient because of the falling costs of going public, and firms substitute equity
for debt. In line with these ideas, Pagano (1993) shows more formally that because of
trading externalities in the market and the strategic behaviour of listing companies, the
size of the stock market is crucial in explaining its own development. Indeed, a firm that
goes public increases the risk sharing opportunities for investors through portfolio
diversification.
The idea is simple. Assume a situation where borrowing constraints and lack of liquidity
force entrepreneurs to go public. The price they get from floatation depends on the
behaviour of other entrepreneurs and on the size of stock market. Indeed, if few
entrepreneurs decide to list their companies, the gains from portfolio diversification are
low and few investors will demand shares in the market. As a consequence, the share
price will be kept low, and so will the return on floatation. Therefore, the return on
floatation for each entrepreneur strategically depends on what all other entrepreneurs
do. If many entrepreneurs decide to go public, the return on flotation will be higher and
equity issue will be relatively more convenient. A thicker equity market makes equity
issue less costly. Extending this idea into a dynamic framework, one could infer that
strategic complementarities in the stock market could well explain the non-monotonic
behaviour of the debt/equity ratio along the path of capital accumulation.
8
Volatility of stock prices is another empirical aspect of stock market development which
has received considerable attention in the literature. By itself, volatility of stock returns
is not an indicator of stock market development. However, high levels of volatility, by
affecting average portfolio risk, can significantly affect the return on investment and
growth. There are a variety of channels through which high volatility can have a
negative impact on investment and growth:
—
It may cause great instability of the financial system as a whole.
—
It can decrease the supply of financial funds, and raise the cost of access to
capital by discouraging savings from risk averse individuals.
—
To the extent that equity markets help to channel resources towards the most
profitable investment through price signalling, highly volatile stock prices
cause misallocation of resources because prices do not correctly indicate return
on investments.
These arguments would suggest that high volatility should negatively affect growth and
capital accumulation. Along this line of reasoning, Singh (1997) sustains that because of
high volatility, the large expansion of stock markets in developing countries, far from
helping industrialization and fostering capital accumulation, can hamper economic
growth. Indeed, according to Singh, the expansion of stock markets in developing
countries since the beginning of the 1980s has not been caused by the endogenous
evolution of financial systems, as described above, but by means of ad hoc
governmental programmes of privatization and financial liberalization. This financial
‘de-repression’, as denoted by Singh, however, has occurred without a change in the
regulatory system or infrastructure, which remain inadequate to support well
functioning equity markets. The result is very volatile stock markets that are unable to
carry out the roles they play in advanced economies such as monitoring, screening, and
information gathering—which is how they enhance growth.
Although the arguments on the potential negative impact of volatility on growth appear
to be very convincing, Levine and Zervos (1998) do not find any significant relationship
between volatility and growth in the sample countries over the period considered. They
measure volatility as a 12-month rolling standard deviation estimate on stock returns
and regress this estimate on the rate of growth and obtain no significant results.
Open economies with deeply integrated financial markets can benefit from cross-border
capital flows and from larger flows of financial resources pouring into the market. As
theory suggests, international financial integration, by bringing about a greater degree of
portfolio and risk diversification, may boost the propensity to save and invest and,
through this channel, can foster growth (Obstfeld 1994; Devereaux and Smith 1994). In
other words, internationally integrated financial markets can potentially be associated
with higher rates of growth and capital accumulation. There is no doubt that financial
globalization can benefit stock markets more than other financial institutions because
the former can mobilize financial resources at low cost. One can therefore argue that
9
although financial globalization is not a direct indicator of stock market development,
the international integration of financial markets would increasingly be expected to be
accompanied by expanding stock markets and higher rates of economic growth.
Following these theoretical suppositions, Korajczyk (1996) investigates whether
internationally integrated stock markets are positively correlated with capital
accumulation and economic growth. In order to measure international market
integration Korajczyk adopts an International Arbitrage Pricing Model for 24 national
markets. This gives a benchmark equilibrium model which gives stock returns in
hypothetical fully integrated markets. Deviation of effective stock returns from these
benchmark values gives a measure of the distance of these economies from full
integration. In line with the theory, Korajczyk finds that market segmentation is higher
for developing than for developed countries. Moreover, market integration tends to
increase as capital accumulates, showing a positive correlation between stock market
integration and economic growth.
3
Theoretical issues
Despite this overwhelming empirical evidence, a number of questions remain
unanswered. Why do stock markets develop later than other financial institutions in the
process of capital accumulation? How can the apparent complementarity between the
equity market and the banking sector be explained? Why do some countries have
overdeveloped stock markets while others have very thin stock markets
(notwithstanding their level of economic development)? Finally, is it the development
of stock markets that spurs economic growth, or is it the process of capital accumulation
and growth that transforms the financial system and causes the development of stock
markets? These are among the questions that a growing body of theoretical studies has
recently tried to answer. It is clear that in order to address these issues, it is first
necessary to understand the exact role of the stock market in the process of real resource
allocation and how the financing decisions of firms affect investments. Second, it is
necessary to determine the possible channels of interaction between real and financial
variables.
The literature on this issue can be categorized as having followed two main routes: the
institutional approach and the instrumental approach. The institutional approach focuses
on the macroeconomic role of stock markets. By identifying and understanding the
working of stock markets, and the main differences between the functioning of financial
intermediaries, it is possible to understand why equity markets emerge at the advanced
stage of economic development and the correlation of stock market development with
the evolution of the banking system. The instrumental approach focuses, instead, on the
microeconomic aspect of the optimal financial choice of the firm. It typically studies the
differences between equity financing and debt financing and how corporate finance
affects the investment decisions of firms. The objective of these studies is to understand
why, depending on the level of capital accumulation in the economy, firms change their
10
preferred source of external funds and switch from debt financing to equity issue. These
analyses, in turn, also need to explain the reverse causal relationship and to establish
how the above changes in the financial system affect the process of economic growth.
3.1 Institutional approach
Modern financial systems pivot on two main financial institutions: one is commercial
banks, the other is stock markets. Although these institutions have the same ultimate
aim, which is conveying financial funds from lenders to final borrowers, they do so
through very different channels, and play very different roles. Understanding these
different roles can help us to shed light on the mechanisms through which financial
variables can influence resource allocation and, in turn, economic growth. Indeed, as the
theory has exhaustively established, the functioning of financial markets can determine
the flow of resources channelled to investment as well as the optimal choice of the type
of investments and projects to be financed.
In order to understand the process through which financial intermediation emerges and
changes along the path of capital accumulation and, most importantly for our purposes,
in order to understand why as capital accumulates, banks and financial intermediation
are substituted with stock markets, it is necessary to focus on the specific functioning of
these institutions and to look for the main differences which might influence the process
of economic growth.
For a long time the literature has thoroughly studied the functional activities of financial
intermediaries. Despite this, only recently have economists focused specifically on the
role of financial intermediation in the process of economic development.1 The results of
these studies are quite clear. Banks and other financial intermediaries can influence the
process of resource allocation and investments through the following channels:
—
Financial intermediaries free resources in the economy by reducing transaction
costs through the economies of scale involved in their activity. Moreover, they
supply specific services, such as brokerage, which reduce frictions and let
financial flows move more easily and at lower cost through the system.
—
Banks and financial intermediaries bring about significant improvements in
risk diversification by supplying a wide array of financial assets with very
specific features. This should increase the propensity of risk averse agents to
save and invest.
—
One of the main functions of financial intermediaries is the maturity
transformation of financial assets. The consequent increase in the array of
1 Battacharia and Thakor (1993) develop a broad survey on the most relevant studies on financial
intermediation. Levine (1997) presents a large survey on the latest literature on financial intermediation
and economic growth.
11
financial assets stimulates the supply of financial funds and of savings and
investments.
—
Banks collect and produce a large amount of information. This reduces the
intensity of information asymmetry between lenders and borrowers and
improves the allocation of resources.
—
Banks facilitate long-term relationships and commitments. Long-term
relationships are very important, particularly when firms have no established
long-term track records and reputation problems are, therefore, severe. Under
these circumstances, long-term relationships may decrease the amount of credit
rationing which otherwise would be very high given the reputation problems.
While progress in the literature on financial intermediation and economic growth has
been quite substantial, the literature on the specific role of stock markets in the process
of economic development is still quite thin and many aspects of this matter remain to be
explored. Despite this, a number of interesting features of the interrelationship between
equity market development and growth have been already disclosed. Stock markets can
support resource allocation and spur growth through very different channels. Below we
try to summarize the results:
—
Reduction in transaction costs and liquidity costs. By reducing transaction
costs and liquidity costs, stock markets can positively affect the average
productivity of capital (Levine 1991; Bencivenga et al. 1996).
—
Resource pooling and saving mobilization. By pooling resources on larger
projects which would otherwise have difficulty accessing finance, stock
markets can mobilize savings and spur the rate of investment (Greenwood and
Smith 1997).
—
Acquisition of information about firms. By promoting the acquisition of
information about firms, stock markets may promote and improve resource
allocation and the average productivity of capital (Grossman and Stiglitz 1980;
Kyle 1984; Allen 1993; Holmstrom and Tirole 1993).
—
Corporate control. By exerting a continuous and strict control over the
management of firms, stock markets positively affect firms’ investment
decisions and the average return on investments (Diamond and Verrecchia
1982; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Laffont and Tirole 1988; Scharfstein 1988).
—
Risk diversification. By improving risk diversification through internationally
integrated stock markets and increasing the array of possible investments,
stock markets can augment the rate of saving and the rate of investment (SaintPaul 1992; Devereux and Smith 1994; Obstfeld 1994).
The duration of investment projects—in conjunction with the expected rate of return
and the relevant risk—is a very important variable for investors. Investors, who strictly
prefer shorter-term assets, might find investments with particularly long maturities
unattractive. Moreover, disrupting an investment project before it has reached maturity
12
can be very costly in terms of missed profit and lower rates of return. Following this
line of arguments, Levine (1991) builds a theoretical model which shows that by
reducing these liquidation costs, and increasing the average productivity of capital and
the rate of savings, stock markets can foster capital accumulation and growth. In fact, by
their nature equity markets make it possible to transfer the ownership of investment
projects that are already running before their final realization and without disrupting
physical production. This feature of stock markets has two effects: (a) it attracts more
resources into long-term investments from investors who would not have committed
their finances for long periods of time; (b) it reduces the loss of resources which would
have occurred with disruption of physical production. Both these effects will spur
growth. The first does this by increasing the saving rate, the second by reducing actual
resources lost by the premature liquidation of investments.
Following Levine, Bencivenga et al. (1996) maintain that equity markets can increase
the average productivity of capital and, in turn, positively affect growth by decreasing
liquidity costs. The idea is that projects which require longer periods of time to
complete are usually also investments with a higher expected return. These projects,
however, will not be taken on by investors who do not want to tie up their financial
resources for a long time. Therefore, assets with long maturities will never be
demanded, unless these can be liquidated easily and at low cost. Again, equity markets
make these projects attractive to investors by allowing the trading of all or part of
project’s ownership at any time. The channels of interaction between stock markets and
capital accumulation and growth are quite clear. As equity markets develop, longer
maturity projects with higher rates of return become more attractive, the average
productivity of capital increases, and so does the rate of growth.
In a framework where agents face liquidity and productivity shocks, financial markets
can help to reallocate resources towards the most productive investments by reducing
idiosyncratic risks. Indeed, by considering an economy in which both banks and stock
markets coexist, Greenwood and Smith (1997) show that financial markets, by
decreasing liquidity risk, increase savings and pool resources towards larger, more
productive projects. The average productivity of investment increases and so does the
rate of growth. However, while equity markets always increase the growth rate relative
to the case of autarky, equity markets increase the growth rate relative to banks only if
agents are relatively risk averse.
For Allen (1993) the emergence of equities primarily depends on the degree of
complexity of the production structure, and on information gathering costs. One of the
advantages of stock markets is that they allow for efficient risk sharing by providing
incentives for investors to search for information. The basic idea is well known in the
literature. Grossman (1976, 1978), Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), and Diamond and
Verrecchia (1982) build theoretical models in which stock markets efficiently cluster
together very different investors’ information. Stock prices, therefore tend, in efficient
13
markets, to reflect the true valuation of underlying investment projects and constitute a
clear signal for the actual rates of return on capital. As a consequence, stock prices are
an efficient instrument for correct resource allocation. It is for this reason that they can
boost economic development and growth. It is clear that where the production system is
more complex, as Allen outlines, the process of information acquisition is more difficult
and the working of equity markets in the process of capital accumulation will be more
effective. Although, at first sight, this explanation appears to be fully satisfactory, two
questions remain. What is the difference between equity markets and banks given that
banks also help in providing information through monitoring and screening? And, why
do stock markets appear only at an advanced stage of economic development, and only
in some countries and not in others?
The answers to these two questions are to be found in the processes of information
transfer between firms’ management and the market, and in the possibility of
identifying optimal investment strategies. In the presence of very simple productive
systems, when optimal investment opportunities and management policies can be easily
identified—for example, because these policies are limited in their number or because
the feasible options do not change very rapidly over time—the banking system can
gather enough information for optimal resource allocation. A typical example of a
productive system in which simple production processes prevail is one dominated by the
agriculture sector. Determination of optimal investment opportunities and control of
management strategies are not difficult to carry out in such a framework. However, as
the number of firms’ investment opportunities increases, and the production processes
become more and more difficult to control (not only by external observers, but also by
firms’ management), continuous monitoring becomes essential for the efficient
allocation of resources. Stock markets, under such circumstances, become the best
instrument for optimal investment control and risk diversification. Stock markets are
more costly for the system overall than banks. However, they become more convenient
when the production system becomes more complex. Banks and financial intermediaries
in general do not allow for continuous monitoring. This explains why banks prevail in
economies with simpler production structures, for example economies dominated by the
agricultural sector, and stock markets become increasingly important as economies
grow and display more articulated and complex productive systems.
One final observation on the market structure is necessary. The hypothesis of complete
and efficient markets throws up some theoretical puzzles over the existence of
incentives for information production. As pointed out by Grossman and Stiglitz (1980),
if markets are complete and perfect, then prices will reflect all available information in
the market. Therefore, given that collecting information is costly, nobody will have any
incentive to collect information and monitor firms. This paradox is solved by Grossman
and Stiglitz by assuming incomplete markets and by assuming variables which are
unobservable to participants.
14
Another channel through which stock markets can positively affect growth is the
continuous monitoring on firms’ management which greatly improves resource
allocation. Indeed, continuous monitoring and control can provide the most effective
incentives for mangers to choose investment projects which maximize firms’ market
value and, therefore, increase the average return on capital and investment. The interests
of firms’ management do not coincide with the interest of firms’ shareholders and
owners and, as a consequence, managers’ decisions might be in contrast with firms’
interest and profitability. Such a potential conflict of interests generates a typical agency
problem which can be solved by means of credible threats and incentive-compatible
contracts. Incentives for managers to act in the best interests of firms come from two
main sources: one is the threat of possible takeover, the other is the introduction of
effective incentive-compatible payment schemes.
Quotation in the stock market might potentially force managers to try to maximize the
value of the firm, since publicly quoted firms which perform poorly may become the
target of possible takeovers which, usually, entail the removal of the management. This
threat can be sufficient for managers to act in the interest of the firm (Laffont and Tirole
1988; Sharfestein 1988, Stein 1988). From a different perspective, but with similar
effects, the continuous monitoring of firms’ performance following quotation on the
stock market makes it possible to build optimal compensation schemes which can force
managers to put in high levels of effort and take the best resource allocation decisions
(Diamond and Verrecchia 1982; Jensen and Murphy 1990).
Despite the success of the above arguments in clearly highlighting the benefits of the
stock markets and providing a satisfactory description of the channels through which
quotation on the stock market can affect investment decisions and the growth rate of the
economy, some interesting questions remain unanswered. If the continuous monitoring
from stock markets is so valuable, why don’t all firms decide that being publicly quoted
is best? The answer to this question is essentially that monitoring is costly for firms
(Holmstrom and Tirole 1993). As Holmstrom and Tirole argue, monitoring is valuable
because it gives speculators information advantages which can be turned into profits.
The higher the value of the information, the higher the value of monitoring will be.
However, information advantages are strictly linked to the share price. Only if the actual
share price is far from the fair value, and someone knows it, is there the possibility of
profit. Information and monitoring costs result in a lower share price and a loss for the
owner.
Finally, another channel through which stock markets may positively affect capital
accumulation and economic growth is the improvement of risk diversification through
international financially integrated markets. Indeed, as shown by Obstfeld (1994), an
increase in the degree of international integration of stock markets reduces the level of
average investment risk through diversification and leads to a shift in the global
portfolio from safe low-yield projects to riskier high-yields projects. This shift induces
15
an increase in capital productivity and in the saving rates, both of which should boost
growth. However, it is also necessary to recognize that portfolio diversification,
depending on agents’ degree of risk aversion, can decrease the level of savings and
negatively affect growth (Devereux and Smith 1994).
3.2 Instrumental approach
The most recent literature on stock markets development and economic growth has
shifted the focus from the role of markets and institutions to the nature of the underlying
financial contracts. The objective of this literature is to explain the emergence and
evolution of stock markets by analysing how capital accumulation affects firms’ optimal
financing choice and, in turn, how firms’ corporate financing decisions affect
investments and capital accumulation. Evidently, this kind of analysis needs to
investigate in detail the main features of the optimal financial contracts available to
firms: costs, benefits, and possible impacts on the production process. Although
intuitively straightforward and apparently simple, this type of investigation faces
theoretical obstacles. In a standard Arrow–Debreu framework, in which markets are
perfect, agents are fully informed and there are no transaction costs, the ModiglianiMiller theorem holds and the value of a firm is unaffected by how that firm is financed.
In this framework, whether the firm issues equity or takes on debt in order to raise
money is completely irrelevant to the firm’s investment decisions as well as to its
market valuation. Under these conditions, a firm’s financial capital structure is
completely irrelevant for real resource allocation. As a consequence, the frictionless
Arrow–Debreu setup needs to be modified in order to develop a theory which can
explain the connections between financial and real variables. Economists have modified
this framework in different ways, for example by introducing different kinds of market
frictions, such as liquidity costs and transaction costs, or by assuming imperfect
information between borrowers and lenders. Thus, the arguments are that financial
markets can affect growth through the reduction of liquidity risks, or because they can
increase the flow of savings and channel such resources towards more productive
alternatives (Greenwood and Jovanovich 1990; Levine 1991; Bencivenga and Smith
1991; Saint-Paul 1992; Blackburn and Hung 1998; among others).2
Similar arguments have been put forward to explain the dynamic role of stock markets
in the process of real resource allocation. However, only recent developments in the
literature on optimal financial contracts under information asymmetry have provided
significant insights for new avenues of investigation on the co-evolution of equity
market development and economic growth. These recent studies on stock market
development integrate microeconomic models of optimal financial contracts under
information asymmetry into dynamic general equilibrium models.
2 Levine (1997) and Becsi and Wang (1997) provide a very broad review of this literature.
16
In the presence of information asymmetries between lenders (typically households) and
borrowers (typically firms) different informational problems might arise and the
exchange of resources can become costly, sometimes to such an extent as to prevent
capital markets from functioning at all. For example, problems of adverse selection
might arise when firms have the possibility of hiding their expected profits or their level
of efficiency. Problems of moral hazard might arise because of the incentive for firms to
misreport the actual return on their investments. These informational problems generate
agency costs, and the financial contract is the result of agents’ attempts to reduce these
costs. The financial contract, as well as the financial market, is, therefore, endogenously
determined. The link between growth and finance arises because growth can affect the
level of agency costs and hence financial arrangements, while the structure of the credit
market affects growth because it determines the amount of resources invested and the
allocation of capital.
The optimal financial contract, depending on the nature of information asymmetries and
on agents’ endowments, might display very different features. Typically, financial
contracts take only two forms: one is equity, the other debt. The differences between the
two are quite sharp. Equity entails a repayment which depends on firm’s profits (or
losses) and, in specific terms, it entails a repayment which is directly proportional to
firm’s investment returns. While debt involves a fixed, pre-determined repayment which
does not depend on firm’s profits, up to the point that profit is enough to repay the
lender what has been contractually promised. Therefore, while debt involves
bankruptcy, equity does not. Despite these clear differences, the literature on corporate
finance has found it difficult to justify the issue of equity even in a framework with
information asymmetries. In fact, debt always dominates equity repayment. Intuitively,
if the firm-borrower has private information of very high rates of return on the project in
need of external finance, it is not going to choose a repayment which involves sharing
proportionally the return on those projects with others (equity repayment). If debt is
available, the firm is always going to choose this form of repayment even in the
presence of very high bankruptcy costs. Indeed, the issue of equity very often involves
sending negative signals to the market (Leland and Pyle 1977; Myers and Majluf 1984)
and results in a negative appraisal of the firm. Equity is treated as a residual alternative
and as a suboptimal choice compared with debt.
The most recent studies have moved away towards a different approach which
essentially hinges on a very simple consideration. Equity and debt involve very different
financial costs and the issue of only equity, of only debt, or of a combination of the two,
is simply the result of a firm’s optimal investment decision which is taken in order to
minimize those financial costs. As can be easily understand, these studies on a firm’s
optimal financial structure are strictly related to the literature on Initial Public Offerings
(IPOs). The decision to go public and to issue shares is a complex one and it depends on
institutional factors as well as on the economic environment. In practice the decision to
enter the stock market involves the comparison of a wide array of costs and benefits.
17
Pagano et al. (1998) provide detailed empirical analysis of the major determinants of
IPOs. Using a large database of Italian firms, they find that ultimately three major
factors determine the decision of a firm to go public: (a) the stock market valuation of
other firms in the same industry; (b) the company’s size; and (c) the destination of the
raised funds, that is, how firms employ these resources.
Very simple and intuitive reasons lie behind these results. The higher the valuation of
firms in a given sector, the more probable it is that a firm operating in the same sector
will go public. This finding confirms the arguments of Pagano (1993) that the issue of
new equity is essentially a matter of strategic complementarities in the market, and the
optimal solution to problems of information asymmetries. The probability of going
public is also positively affected by a company’s size. The larger the firm, the more
convenient quotation on the stock market will be. This evidence seems to confirm the
existence of fixed costs of listing and of economies of scale. Finally, the results of this
study suggest that firms do not usually issue equity to finance expansionary investments
but rather to repay outstanding debt or to reduce negative financial positions.
Interestingly, Pagano et al. (1998) also find support for the existence of a kind of
complementarity between equity and debt. Indeed, they find that going public enables
companies to borrow more cheaply: equity reduces the cost of debt. Although Pagano et
al. do not explicitly consider the impact of IPOs on capital accumulation, their results
provide very interesting insights into the issue.
Recent studies explain the emergence of equity markets by analysing the optimal
financial contract under information asymmetry and by investigating the changes
involved because of capital accumulation. Information asymmetries can strongly modify
agents’ incentives and, therefore, contractual agreements between borrowers and
lenders. A typical incentive problem, for example, arises when lenders are unable to
observe directly the outcomes of the projects to be financed and, therefore, face moral
hazard problems. The implication of such problems is that lenders must monitor, or
verify, the claims of borrowers about projects’ returns. However, since verification is
costly, lenders find it optimal to verify only in a limited set of possible contingent states.
Typically, the optimal solution to a standard costly state verification (CSV) problem,
under the assumption that agents are risk neutral and monitoring costs do not depend on
project returns, is always a debt contract. In other words, the loan repayment is
predetermined and independent of the actual outcome of the investment (Townsend
1979; Diamond 1984; Gale and Hellwig 1985; Williamson 1986, 1987a, 1987b). The
reason being that debt, which involves a fixed repayment, does not require costly
monitoring providing that the contractual repayment is honoured. This would not be
feasible if the loan repayment were a function of the project’s return, like for example
equity, and monitoring would be required in all states.
Boyd and Smith (1996, 1998) modify the standard CSV framework in order to provide
an account of why equity might dominate debt at least in some circumstances. In Boyd
18
and Smith, borrowers have access to two alternative projects for producing capital. The
first project has a higher expected return which is known to the lender. The actual return
on the project, however, is unobservable to outsiders. If the lender wants to verify the
result of production, they must incur a cost which is decreasing in the price of capital
(the interest rate). The second project has a lower expected return, but the actual return
on this project is costlessly observable to lender. Interestingly, Boyd and Smith show
that the way the lender optimally finances the two projects are different. In specific
terms, while the unobservable project is optimally financed through a debt contract, the
observable project is optimally financed through equity issue. The dependence of the
equity-debt choice on growth is easily explained. For a low level of capital
accumulation, when the interest rate is high, monitoring costs are relatively low. As a
consequence, agents tend to use the unobservable technology. This, in turn, implies that
debt finance is more widespread than equity finance. As capital accumulates, and the
price of capital decreases, monitoring costs increase, and the unobservable technology
becomes less and less profitable. As a result, equity finance will make up a larger share
of the economy. This process explains the emergence of stock markets at later stages of
economic development.
Although the positive correlation between stock market development and economic
growth has been established empirically, the causal relationship between these variables
is still an obscure point. Is it stock market development that spurs economic growth, or
is it capital accumulation that drives the emergence and the development of equity
markets? Blackburn et al. (2005) provide an account of the possible two-way linkages
between stock market development and economic growth, and an alternative
interpretation of the development of equity markets. To these authors, the emergence of
equity contracts is the result of lenders’ attempts to solve multiple enforcement
problems when a firm’s choice of investment project and level of effort devoted to that
project are private information. Capital accumulation can influence the development of
equity markets because it can affect the degree of control that the lender has over these
choices. The analysis is based on a principal-agent framework in which the borrowerfirm (the agent) has access to an array of different projects, each with an expected return
that depends on the risk of the project itself and on the amount of effort that the
borrower exerts. The lender (principal), who has the task of designing the optimal
financial contract, cannot directly control the firm’s effort, but has the option to either
impose their own choice of project at a cost, or to leave this choice up to the borrower.
The optimal financial contracts under these two alternative scenarios are not the same.
When the lender chooses the project, the optimal financial contract is typically a debt
contract. When the firm chooses the project, the optimal financial contract is a mixture
of debt and equity. The reason for this is that when the choice of project is imposed by
the lender, a fixed repayment (debt contract) is sufficient to induce the optimal level of
effort by the firm. By contrast, when the choice of project is left up to the borrower, a
fixed repayment is not enough to induce the best level of effort, nor the best choice of
19
project; in this case part of the payment must be a function of the actual return (equity
payment) in order to induce the borrower to exert the optimal effort.
The optimal choice of contract depends essentially on the cost to the lender of taking
charge of project selection. In Blackburn et al. (2005) this cost is represented by the
wage that the lender is forgoing by not supplying their labour in the market, and by
instead spending their time selecting and imposing the project choice on the borrower.
At low levels of capital accumulation, when the return to labour is relatively low, and
the wage rate is also low, this cost is low and the debt contract dominates. As the
economy develops, and the wage rate prevailing in the market goes up, the cost of
imposing the project choice increases until it eventually becomes optimal for the lender
not to interfere directly in this choice; then the financial contract will involve both debt
and equity. When equity markets appear, the economy jumps from a low capital
accumulation path to a high capital accumulation path so that growth is temporarily
stimulated. The reason being that fewer resources are wasted in the economy for project
selection. This could explain the positive impact of stock market development on
growth.
The role of information asymmetries in financial contract design is extremely important
not only in qualitative but also in quantitative terms. Recently, Bolton and Frexias
(2000) have argued that when firms have superior information about the returns on their
investments, the costs associated with the optimal security used to finance those
investments depend on the degree of informational asymmetry. This is simply because
lenders, who cannot a priori observe project returns, take an average of all possible
outcomes. As in a typical lemon market, owners of projects with high returns will be
penalized since their projects will be valued at a lower average price. This is referred to
as the dilution cost of asymmetric information. Under such circumstances, Bolton and
Frexias (2000) show that firms' optimal capital structure consists of two main forms of
securities: equity and/or debt. The type of security issued depends on the level of
dilution costs, together with the level of bankruptcy costs associated with the loss of
future income following the borrower’s inability to repay debt.
In a dynamic context, the level of information asymmetry does not stay fixed, but
changes over time. It is commonly argued, for example, that in many countries the level
of information available in the market increases considerably with the introduction of
new communication technologies and the diffusion of many sources of information. It is
therefore possible, in the wake of Bolton and Frexias’ arguments, to imagine that
economic growth and capital accumulation, by bringing about an improvement in the
level of information diffusion, engender a modification in financial securities’ costs and
spur the development of equity financing. Following this line of argument, the
emergence and growth of stock markets can be seen as the result of a reduction in the
severity of information problems.
20
This idea can be modelled in a simple way (see Capasso 2004). Assume that different
types of firms have access to different sets of projects with different expected returns.
Assume also that the return on all, or some, of these projects depends on specific market
conditions. The market value of a project reflects the level of information available in
the market. Under the assumption that the same project yields different returns to
different firms (for example, because some firms are more efficient than others), the
value attached by the market to a project will depend on which type of firms find it
optimal to carry out that project. If a project is run only by high productivity firms, then
the market value will be high. On the other hand, if the project is run by less efficient
firms, then its value will be lower, or ‘diluted’. This dilution cost is one of the factors
which can determine the optimal choice of one form of security over another. If lenders
know which firms prefer to operate which project, then the set of projects undertaken
will signal precisely the nature and the type of firms in the market. If, on the other hand,
some firms have access to common projects, then the type of firms in the market can be
inferred only probabilistically by observing the projects. The higher the number of firms
accessing the same sets of projects, the lower the probability of correctly inferring a
firms’ type will be. Now, if the set of ‘common projects’ undertaken becomes smaller
for some reason (for example, because some of these projects become economically
inefficient), then the signal from the market becomes stronger and the possibility of
inferring a firm’s type becomes higher. The link with growth arises from the fact that
capital accumulation reduces the incentive of some low productivity firms to operate
projects that are typical of more efficient firms. Thus, capital accumulation leads to an
improvement in the ‘visibility’ of more efficient firms, it decreases the cost of equity
issue, and it causes an expansion of stock markets.
4
Conclusions
The positive correlation between stock market development and economic growth is a
well known empirical fact. Stock markets appear to emerge and develop only when
economies reach a reasonable size, and the level of capital accumulation is high.
Notwithstanding such uncontroversial empirical evidence, the causal relationship
remains a debated issue in the literature. Is it stock markets that boost growth, for
example by reducing liquidity and monitoring costs, or is it capital accumulation that
induces a modification in the financial system which causes the emergence of equity
financing, for example by engendering modifications in the optimal financial contract?
In recent years, a growing body of theoretical literature has attempted to provide
satisfactory answers to this question. These efforts have given rise to distinct
methodological approaches which have highlighted both the macroeconomic and
institutional aspects of the phenomenon, and its microeconomic roots.
On the one hand, this large body of investigation has disclosed many interesting features
of financial market development and provided new insights on the effects of financial
variables on economic growth, on the other hand, it has raised further questions opening
21
new avenues for further research. In particular, the recent work, by focusing on
individual firms’ optimal financing choice and on the optimal financial contract, have
transferred issues of corporate finance from a purely microeconomic level of discussion
to a macroeconomic one and have raised innovative and exciting questions which
deserve to be dealt with. One of these is the role played by information dynamics and
information technology diffusion on firms’ financing choice and, in turn, on financial
market development and economic growth.
References
Allen, F. (1993). ‘Stock markets and resource allocation,’ in C. Mayer and X. Vives
(eds) Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press: 81-108.
Atje, R. and Jovanovic, B. (1993). ‘Stock markets and development’, European
Economic Review, 37: 632-40.
Battacharya, S. and Thakor, A.V. (1993). ‘Contemporary banking theory’, Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 3: 2-50.
Beck, T. and Levine, R. (2001). ‘Stock markets, banks, and growth: correlation or
causality?’, Policy Research Working Paper 2670, Washington DC: World Bank.
Becsi, Z. and Wang, P. (1997). ‘Financial development and growth’, Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 46-62.
Bencivenga, V.R, and Smith, B.D. (1991). ‘Financial intermediation and endogenous
growth’ Review of Economics Studies, 58 (2):195-209.
Bencivenga, V., Smith, B., and Starr, R.M. (1996). ‘Equity markets, transactions costs,
and capital accumulation: an illustration’, The World Bank Economic Review, 10 (2):
241-65.
Blackburn, K. and Hung, V. (1998). ‘A theory of growth, financial development and
trade’, Economica, 65: 107-24.
Blackburn, K., Bose, N., and Capasso, S. (2005). ‘Financial development, financing
choice and economic growth’, Review of Development Economics, 9 (2): 135-49.
Bolton, P. and Frexias, X. (2000). ‘Equity, bonds and bank debt: capital structure and
financial market equilibrium under asymmetric information’, Journal of Political
Economy, 2 (208): 324-51.
Boyd, J. and Smith, B. (1996). ‘The coevolution of real and financial sectors in the
growth process’, The World Bank Economic Review, 10 (2): 371-96.
Boyd, J. and Smith, B. (1998). ‘The evolution of debt and equity markets in economic
development’, Economic Theory, 12: 519-60.
22
Capasso, S. (2004). ‘Bankruptcy costs, dilution costs and stock market development’,
University of Naples ‘Parthenope’ Working Paper 1 (March).
De Gregorio, J. and Guidotti, P.E. (1995). ‘Financial development and economic
growth’, World Development, 23: 433-48.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Levine, R. (1996a). ‘Stock market development and financial
intermediaries: stylized facts’, The World Bank Economic Review, 10 (2): 291-321.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Levine, R. (1996b). ‘Stock markets, corporate finance and
economic growth: an overview’, The World Bank Economic Review, 10: 223-39.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (1996), ‘Stock market development and
financing choices of firms’, World Bank Economic Review, 10: 341-69.
Devereux, M.B., and Smith, G.W. (1994). ‘International risk sharing and economic
growth’, Internationl Economic Review, 35 (4):535-50.
Diamond, D. (1984). ‘Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring’, Review of
Economic Studies, 51: 393-414.
Diamond, D. and Verrecchia, R.E. (1982). ‘Optimal managerial contracts and
equilibrium security prices’, Journal of Finance, 37: 275-87.
Gale, D. and Hellwig, M. (1985). ‘Incentive-compatible debt contracts: the one-period
problem’, Review of Economic Studies, 52: 647-63.
Goldsmith, R.Y. (1969). Financial Structure and Development, New Haven and
London: Yale University Press.
Greenwood, J. and Jovanovic, B. (1990). ‘Financial development, growth, and the
distribution of income’, Journal of Political Economy, 98: 1076-107.
Greenwood, J. and Smith, B. (1997). ‘Financial markets in development, and the
development of financial markets’, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21:
141-81.
Grossman, S. (1976). ‘On the efficiency of competitive stock markets where traders
have diverse information’, Journal of Finance, 31: 573-85.
Grossman, S. (1978). ‘Further results n the informational efficiency of competitive
stock markets’, Journal of Economic Theory, 18: 81-101.
Grossman, S. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1980). ‘On the impossibility of informationally efficient
markets’, American Economic Review, 70: 393-408.
Holmstrom, B. and Tirole, J. (1993). ‘Market liquidity and performance monitoring’,
Journal of Political Economy, 101 (4): 678-709.
Jensen, M.C. and Murphy, K.J. (1990). ‘Performance pay and top-management
incentives’ Journal of Political Economy, 98: 225-64.
23
King, R.G. and Levine, R. (1993a). ‘Finance and growth: Shumpeter might be right’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108: 717-37.
King, R.G. and Levine, R. (1993b). ‘Finance entrepreneurship, and growth: theory and
evidence’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 32: 513-42.
Korajczyk, R. (1996). ‘A measure of stock market integration for developed and
emerging markets’, The World Bank Economic Review, 10 (2): 267-89.
Kyle, A.S. (1984). ‘Market structure, information, futures markets, and price formation’
in G. Storey, A. Schmitz, and A.H. Sarris (eds.) International Agricultural Trade:
Advanced Readings in Price Formation, Market Structure, and Price Instability
Boulder, CO: Westview.
Laffont, J. and Tirole, J. (1988). ‘Repeated auctions of incentive contracts, investment,
and bidding parity with an application to takeovers’, Rand Journal of Economics, 19:
516-37.
Leland, H. and Pyle, D. (1977). ‘Informational asymmetries, financial structure and
financial intermediation’, Journal of Finance (Papers and Proceedings), May.
Levine, R. (1991). ‘Stock markets, growth and tax policy’, The Journal of Finance, 46:
1445-65.
Levine, R. (1997). ‘Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda’,
Journal of Economic Literature, XXXV, 688-726.
Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992). ‘A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth
regressions’, American Economic Review, 82: 942-63.
Levine, R. and Zervos, S. (1996), ‘Stock market development and long-run growth’,
World Bank Economic Review, 10 (2): 223-39.
Levine, R. and Zervos, S. (1998). ‘Stock markets, banks and economic growth’,
American Economic Review, 88: 537-57.
McKinnon, R.I. (1973). Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington,
DC: Brookings Institution.
Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S. (1984). ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions
when firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial
Economics, 13: 187-221.
Obstfeld, M. (1994). ‘Risk-taking, global diversification, and growth’, American
Economic Review, 85 (5):1310-29.
Pagano, M. (1993). ‘The flotation of companies on the stock market: a coordination
failure model’, European Economic Review, 37: 1101-25.
Pagano, M., Panetta, F., and Zingales, L. (1998). ‘Why do companies go public? An
empirical analysis’, Journal of Finance, 53: 27-61.
24
Roubini, N. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1991). ‘Financial development, the trade regime and
economic growth’, NBER Working Paper 3876.
Saint Paul, G. (1992). ‘Technological choice, financial markets and economic
development’, European Economic Review, 36: 763-81.
Scharfstein, D. (1988). ‘The disciplinary role of takeovers’, Review of Economic
Studies, 55: 185-99.
Singh, A. (1997). ‘Financial liberalisation, stock markets and economic development’,
Economic Journal, 107: 771-82.
Stein, J.C. (1988). ‘Takeovers threats and managerial myopia’, Journal of Political
Economy, 96: 61-80.
Townsend, R. (1979). ‘Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state
verification’, Journal of Economic Theory, 21 (2): 265-93.
Williamson, S.D. (1986). ‘Costly monitoring, financial intermediation and equilibrium
credit contracting’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 18: 159-79.
Williamson, S.D. (1987a). ‘Costly monitoring, loan contracts, and equilibrium credit
rationing’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102: 135-45.
Williamson, S.D. (1987b). ‘Financial intermediation, business failures, and real
business cycles’, Journal of Political Economy, 95: 1196-216.
25