Octagon Capital Limited
Registered Office: Villa 7, Millennium Village, Stand 6953, Birdcage Walk, Long Acres, Lusaka, ZAMBIA
Postal Address: Private Bag 442X, Ridgeway, Lusaka, ZAMBIA
Resource Nationalism
The Zambian Perspective
By
Mwiza Mbewe1
This paper discusses resource nationalism with specific reference to Zambia. The
country has in the recent past displayed tenets of resource nationalism in relation to the
mining sector. The paper examines the reasons for resource nationalism on a broader
basis and provides cases from different countries. Zambia’s history with resource
nationalism is discussed. The paper proposes several measures as a means to
minimising the adversarial environment that tends to prevail within the context of
resource nationalism.
October 2020
1
The author is founder and Chief Executive Officer for Octagon Capital Limited, a boutique advisory and investments
firm. He has previously worked for Premier Rating Services Limited, ZCCM Investments Holdings Plc and the Bank of
Zambia. The views expressed in this paper are solely his own.
0
Introduction
During the month of August 2020, the local and international media was inundated with
news that Glencore would sell its entire 73.1% stake in Mopani Copper Mines (MCM) to
the Zambian government’s mining investment arm, ZCCM Investments Holdings plc
(ZCCM-IH). Glencore decided to withdraw from its investment after the Zambian Mines
Minister, Richard Musukwa, announced that ZCCM-IH would increase its shareholding
to at least 51% from 10%. The Minister’s announcement was in reaction to MCM’s
intention to place mining operations under care-and-maintenance due to the negative
effects on operations and incomes arising from the COVID-19 pandemic.
Placing the operations under care-and-maintenance implied that approximately 11,000
direct employees would be placed on forced leave. With general elections approaching in
August 2021, MCM’s intensions were received with consternation by the Government.
The Mines Minister labelled the care-and-maintenance application to Government illegal
and threatened to have the company’s mining licence revoked2.
Meanwhile on another front, the Government was in the midst of a legal battle with
Vedanta Resources which owns 79.4% equity in Konkola Copper Mines plc (KCM). On 21
May 2019, a provisional liquidator for Konkola Copper Mines (KCM) was appointed by
Zambia’s High Court after receiving a petition from ZCCM-IH under the corporate
insolvency act3. In a Ministerial Statement to Parliament, the Mines Minister stated that
the action taken against KCM was necessitated by the operational challenges it was facing
as evidenced by the declining mineral production at its various operations and the failure
to meet its obligations to employees, contractors and suppliers 4. What is notable is that
the liquidation process only commenced after the President’s declaration that the
Government planned to cancel the company’s mining licence and to bring in a new
investor.
Earlier still in 2017, the government through the Zambia Revenue Authority undertook a
mining industry tax audit that resulted in Kansanshi Mining plc, which is 80% owned by
First Quantum Minerals Limited, being slapped with a $7.9 billion tax bill. The
government also announced new fiscal measures for the mining industry that included a
new 5% import duty on concentrates, increasing royalties by 1.5% and making them no
longer tax-deductible, plus replacing value-added tax with a non-refundable sales tax.
Analysts attribute the introduction of these new measures to the ruling party’s decline in
political support as well as the country’s dire finances as external debts piled up5.
While all the developments mentioned above can be broadly described as ‘resource
nationalism’, the KCM development has been defined as outright appropriation and
hence ‘nationalisation’, rather than the Government’s preferred term of ‘liquidation’.
2
https://www.mining.com/zambia-government-in-talks-to-increase-stake-in-mopani/
https://africanminingmarket.com/zambian-court-appoints-provisional-liquidator-of-vedantas-konkola-copper-mines/3965/
4http://www.parliament.gov.zm/sites/default/files/images/publication_docs/MinisterialStatementontheStatusofKCM.pdf
5 https://issafrica.org/iss-today/is-zambia-defaulting-to-nationalisation
3
1
Zambia, of course, has a history with nationalisation of mining companies. In 1969, the
then President, Kenneth Kaunda, announced that arrangements had been completed for
government acquisition of a controlling interest in each mining company in Zambia6.
The consequences arising from the 1969 decisions on nationalisation are well
documented. The purpose of this particular discussion is to examine the broader concept
of ‘resource nationalism’ and Zambia’s experience. The paper proposes policies for
consideration by Zambia, before concluding by linking resource nationalism with
sustainable development.
Resource Nationalism Explained
The literature is in consensus that there is no agreed definition for ‘resource nationalism’
(Monaldi, 2020; Ward, 2009). Rather what is consistent is the understanding that it
loosely refers to a situation in which governments seek greater control of or benefits from
their country’s natural wealth7. For others, resource nationalism is explicitly
conceptualised as “the complete set of strategies that a host state uses to increase control
over natural resource wealth at the expense of foreign participation and investment.”8
Resource nationalism is generally understood to undergo through a cycle. The way it
works is that when resource prices are low, governments seek private investors to explore,
identify and develop oil, gas and minerals projects. This is because the governments have
limited financing for such undertakings compared to large mining companies. However,
once prices for the resources begin to rise, the governments seek to benefit from the
higher prices by adjusting taxes to higher levels or outright ownership of the projects.
When the resource prices decline, the governments then reduce their taxes or sell their
shareholdings to private companies, while waiting for an uptick in the future which would
induce them to once again increase their interests (Monaldi, 2020; Pryke, 2017; Ward,
2009).
While the upsurge in resource prices appears to be the primary factor for resource
nationalism, it is certainly not the only consideration. The government must have a
stronger bargaining position for negotiation. The stronger bargaining position generally
arises for projects where there has been significant sunk cost with decreased geographical
risk as the project progresses. In such a situation, it is unlikely that the investor would
withdraw from the venture. These two factors, together with rising resource prices
effectively makes the initial development contract between the government and the
mining company obsolete; and hence the instigations for renegotiation of previous
development agreements (Monaldi, 2020).
The lack of institutional government capacity to deal with revenue collections from a
privatised natural resource sector also provides fertile grounds for resource nationalism.
6
Mwanakatwe, John, M. (1994); End of Kaunda Era, Multimedia Zambia, Lusaka, Zambia, P.60
https://africanbusinessmagazine.com/sectors/commodities/whats-so-bad-about-resource-nationalism/
8 Monaldi, F.J. (2020); The Cyclical Phenomenon of Resource Nationalism in Latin America, Oxford University Press, USA, Page 3
7
2
The understanding is that there is an inherent expectation by the government and its
people of the benefits that are to accrue from the mining of resources. These benefits are
assumed to be equal whether they are obtained through taxes or whether they are
obtained through direct ownership of the mining projects. In the event that the tax system
lacks capacity to collect the supposed appropriate level of benefits from the mines, then
nationalisation becomes the option to obtain what is deemed to be the fitting national
return (Ward, 2017).
The motivation for nationalisation is even more probable in an environment where there
is fierce political competition, low government revenues and a dependence on extractive
industries. Political credibility is often obtained by targeting foreign interests in the
national resources with the usual reasoning that the national wealth can now be used to
fighting poverty within the country. Examples include Mexico’s nationalisation of the oil
industry in 1938, Iran’s nationalisation of the Anglo-Iranian Oil Company in 1951 and
more recently the same type of events in Venezuela, Bolivia and Ecuador (Sainsbury,
2018).
It must be noted that the policies for resource nationalism go beyond nationalisation.
Other forms of resource nationalism include higher royalties and taxes, increased
government free-carry participation, requirements for in-country beneficiation and
retention of profits, and participation of local employees and businesses in the value
chains of the resources9.
Large mining companies with projects across the continents tend to denigrate resource
nationalism as the enemy of trade, investment, and energy security. Governments have
in turn defended their resource nationalism policies arguing that they simply want to
ensure that the foreign businesses do not unfairly benefit from their resources. If
anything, the countries contend that while companies seek to position themselves as
victims, the reality is that many mineral producing countries, especially in Africa, have
signed deals that disproportionately favour the mining conglomerates10.
What is interesting is that often times, resource nationalism is associated with less
developed countries in Africa, Asia and Latin America. However, it is actually also
employed by developed countries. The policy statements are made to sound palatable and
politically correct but when considered in a comprehensive context as italicised below,
the negative connation of resource nationalism becomes more pronounced:
•
•
To protect or promote domestic industry (at the expense of foreign competition);
To lower costs for the domestic market (via market distortion for a specific
product); and
9 Toroskaninen, K. and Olan’g, S. (2019); Governments, Companies find a bit of Common Ground in Resource Nationalism at Indaba
https://resourcegovernance.org/blog/governments-companies-find-bit-common-ground-resource-nationalism-indaba
10
https://africanbusinessmagazine.com/sectors/commodities/whats-so-bad-about-resource-nationalism/
3
•
To create a competitive advantage for exports (at the expense of domestic
production in the countries with open markets).
Instances of the many forms of resource nationalism by different countries across
continents abound. The cases are provided below:
1. In the early 1970s, the resource networks between Japanese steel and Australian
mining industries were largely under Japanese control. These networks ensured
that Japan’s need for low-cost minerals supply was ensured. Meanwhile, the
Australians felt that their industry and economy were not attaining satisfactory
returns.
In 1973, the Australian government adopted a series of aggressive state
interventions aimed at reducing Japanese control and increasing the share of value
generated in the Australian production networks. By the early 1980s, the measures
were deemed successful (Wilson, 2013)
2. In 2010, as commodity prices rose and governments struggled with low returns
and reduced corporate activity due to the global financial crisis, Australia proposed
the Resources Super Profits Tax (RSPT). The RSPT which failed was replaced by
the Minerals Resources Rent Tax (MRRT) which was also later repealed (Grimley,
2015).
3. From 2005, increased Chinese investments in the Australian iron ore and coal
mining sectors raised concern with regard to the state-owned and strategic nature
of the investors. As a result, in February 2008 the Australian government declared
its intention to more closely screen foreign direct investment from state-owned
entities. This action was seen as a defensive move against state-owned Chinese
companies (Wilson, 2011).
4. In the United States of America, the Washington State and local officials restrict
the export of coal to China and elsewhere on the basis of climate change impacts
despite the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change calling for
an open international economic system that would lead to development in all
parties (Banks, 2015).
5. China produces 80% of the rare earth elements global output and controls 85% of
the processing capacity. This means some of the rare earths mined outside of China
have to be sent to China for processing. The Chinese have thus started to reorganise
the industry so as to have more control of the industry. This has caused prices for
rare earths to rise (Cobb, 2020).
4
6. In 2018, the Tanzanian President oversaw the export ban of copper, silver, iron
and nickel ore in a bid to promote local value-added industries (African Business
Magazine, 4 June 2018).
7. In the Democratic Republic of Congo, some resources were declared strategic
assets, particularly cobalt which is a key ingredient in electric car and smart phone
batteries (African Business Magazine, 4 June 2018).
8. In 1994, after apartheid ended, the South African government introduced
regulations requiring local black-owned businesses participation in the
development of mines (Tobita and Takahashi, 2018).
9. In 2012, Botswana insisted on the domestic sorting and processing of diamonds.
In addition, all diamonds are sold through the Diamond Trading Corporation
Botswana (Grynberg, R, 2013)
From the foregoing, it is evident that the resource nationalism policies are undertaken for
purposes of national interest. However, it is important to note that resource nationalism
can impose costs on the country that has initiated the nationalism in the first place. These
costs include:
•
•
•
Retaliatory resource nationalism by other countries. This may negatively affect
the processing and use of specific resources which are of necessity in the country
that initiated restrictions;
Increased investment risks on account of the instability in minerals and metals
market. This inhibits foreign investment in the long term; and,
It can make mines and reserves in other countries more attractive due to rising
prices which eventually go down in the medium term.
In view of the foregoing, it is important for the national leadership to undertake a
comprehensive evaluation of the potential costs to the domestic economy before
commencing resource nationalism policies. What may appear as a domestic issue for the
country to resolve within its jurisdiction may actually cost the country more than the
expected benefits. Zambia’s experience with resource nationalism attests to this notion.
Resource Nationalism in Zambia
In 1969, the President of Zambia, Kenneth Kaunda announced that the country would
acquire 51% shareholding in the two main copper producing companies: Roan Selection
Trust and Anglo-American Corporation. The President justified Government’s decision
on the basis that the two companies had ceased to undertake meaningful mining
developments after the country obtained its independence. In their defence, the two
companies contended that the royalty system impeded their capacity to undertake new
developments. The Government did not accept this defence because the royalties
5
remained unchanged from those paid to the British South Africa Company when it
controlled the mineral rights before independence and during which period the same
companies developed the existing mines (Sardanis, 2003).
The acquisition of majority shareholding in the mining companies was part of an already
existing framework developed to expand the state’s presence into enterprise. The
government’s main objective was that of improving the conditions of the rural poor and
reducing unemployment in the urban areas. However, the objectives were not achieved
as the largely foreign-owned private sector which was expected to take the leading role in
the economic development did not do so. Meanwhile the indigenous private sector’s
growth was slow and thus unable to take on the mantle of development and job creation.
The Government thus saw the acquisition of controlling stakes in the foreign-owned
companies as the only means to modify the behaviour of the leading foreign-owned
companies (Craig, 1999).
Before resorting to majority ownership of the mines, the government had tried other
measures which it hoped would encourage investment in Zambia. One such measure was
limiting the proportion of net profit that could be declared and remitted externally as
dividends. The idea was that holding excess cash in the banks would compel the
companies to seek other investments with better returns within the country. However,
the companies responded by maintaining their large cash balances of undistributed
profits in their bank accounts and adjusting their accounting policies to enable higher
dividend potential pay-outs (Craig, 1999).
Beyond the investment objective, the acquisition of majority shares also had a political
undertone, particularly with regard to the employment policies of the mining companies.
The employment policies in the mining sector were designed to favour white employees
with generous salaries, lavish accommodation and social facilities, education and training
for their children, and most important of all, job reservation. Meanwhile, the African
employees remained untrained, unskilled and underpaid. This policy ensured that the
indigenous people were kept on the lowest rungs of the employment ladder while the
plum jobs were reserved for the European mineworkers (Sardinis, 2014).
The nationalisation of the mining companies was therefore intended to correct the
systemic employment imbalances that existed in the industry. The correction included
same levels of wages and employment opportunities for indigenous and foreign workers.
In 1974, this culminated in the appointment of David Phiri as Managing Director for the
former Roan Selection Trust and Wilson Chakulya for the former Anglo-American
Corporation (Kaunda, 2002).
The story of Zambia’s nationalisation of the mines and the subsequent failure of
operations over the years is often cited as the lesson against nationalisation of the mining
industry. The Zambian copper mining industry’s downward spiral started in the mid1970s as copper prices collapsed, management focussed on production to ensure
6
employment and social services rather than production for profit, and substantial
payment of dividends to the state hindered its ability to re-invest in production
infrastructure (Limpitlaw, 2011).
By 1990, the UNIP government adopted a limited programme of privatisation as the
country grappled with the underperforming nationalised economy. With specific
reference to the mines, the idea envisaged was for the state-owned Zambia Consolidated
Copper Mines Limited (ZCCM) to continue operating, subject to some structural remedies
having been undertaken while private companies would be issued with licences for new
exploration and exploitation of minerals (Kaunda, 2002).
In 1991, Zambia evolved into a multi-party dispensation and the privatisation concept
gained more impetus. However, for the mining industry the actual privatisation of ZCCM
took a while as there were several key considerations to be made. These included the
company’s bearing on the whole economy as the largest foreign exchange earner and
largest contributor to tax revenues, the historically-known political weight of the mining
towns’ populations, and the debates as regards the mode of entry for the new mining
investors.
By the time the privatisation process for the mines was being completed in 2004, copper
prices had dropped to US$2,500 per tonne thus weakening the Government’s negotiation
abilities. This was in effect the downturn in the resource nationalism cycle.
Within four years, prices jumped to US$8,500 per tonne and bolstered the upturn in the
resource nationalism cycle for Zambia. Rather than nationalisation, the new policies
included the cancellation of all development agreements through a new Mines and
Minerals Act, an increase in corporate tax to 35% from 25%, an increase in mineral royalty
tax to 3% from 0.6% and the introduction of a windfall tax.
The mining companies objected to these changes with claims that the effective tax rate
ranged from 64% to 96% for high cost mines and from 57% to 64% for low cost mines,
much higher than the intended Government effective tax rate of 47% (Ng’ambi, 2015).
Soon enough, the global financial crisis of 2008 led to a fall in copper prices. This together
with the threats by the mining companies to commence massive job reductions, and
general elections approaching in 2011 led to the MMD government withdrawing the
windfall tax policy.
In 2011, a new administration was ushered into government. The Patriotic Front
government won the elections on the back of a pro-poor campaign. It was therefore
inevitable that there would be need for significant funding to achieve the stated objectives;
the easiest target being mineral royalties. The mining companies responded with threats
to suspend operations and projects.
7
As the dispute raged on, the country went through an unexpected turn with the death of
the national President. By-elections were held in 2015 and soon after the mineral royalties
were revised to lower levels. In the following year, elections for a presidential full-term
were held and the PF administration continued in office.
There appeared a semblance of stability for a while. However, with the next round of
elections fast approaching in 2021, rising national debt levels, and clear challenges as
regards the capacity of the fiscal envelope to meet the nation’s expectations, the evidence
points to rising cases of resource nationalism as evidenced by the actions against the
mines owned by First Quantum Minerals Limited, Vedanta Resources and Glencore.
Drawing from lessons of the past, Zambia’s experience shows that a mine asset that is run
down is very expensive and difficult to get back on track. The new mine owners after
privatisation are said to have invested total of US$1.4 billion from time of purchase to
2004. However, the industry as a whole was only able to restore annual production to
400,000 tonnes, way below the 700,000 tonnes that was achieved in 1969 upon
nationalisation (Limpitlaw, 2011).
Given these lessons, it is important that the government undertakes a critical self-analysis
as regards its application of resource nationalism policies. There must be due
consideration with respect to the short, medium and long-term effects to the sector and
economy as a whole. The next section thus delves into future policy considerations for
Zambia with respect to resource nationalism.
Policy Considerations and Implications
In a posting dated 21 March 2019, Maplecroft, a research firm specialising in global risk
analytics, country risk insight and advisory services, stated that a total of 30 countries
witnessed a significant increase in resource nationalism over the previous year. The
posting noted that outright expropriation is less of a risk than it used be and indirect
forms of resource nationalism are now the most common means; the indirect forms being
increasing tax pressures, changing contractual terms, and stronger local content
requirements. These alongside a worsening of the regulatory climate are said to be raising
the risk environment for corporate resource extractors.
A telling statement in the posting was the declaration that host governments use the
indirect measures to wrestle revenues away from oil, gas and mining operators across
the continents11.
The reference to ‘wrestling revenues away’ aptly confirmed that what lies at the core of
the tension surrounding resource nationalism is the distribution and sharing of revenues.
As highlighted in the previous section, Zambia is a prime example of the tug-of-war for
11
https://www.maplecroft.com/insights/analysis/resource-nationalism-rises-30-countries (italics added for emphasis)
8
revenues that occurs between the Government and the mining companies. The
Government validates its demands for a fair share of the revenues on the basis that while
the country is the second largest copper producer in Africa, the majority of its population
still lives below the poverty line12. The granting of huge tax concessions to the mining
industry has been identified as the reason for the relatively lower tax collections from the
Zambian mining industry.
To illustrate the relatively lower tax collections, a comparative between Chile and Zambia
is provided for the boom period of 2004 to 2007. For Chile, copper contributed 20.7% to
31.1% to total fiscal revenues while in Zambia copper’s contribution to total fiscal revenues
was 1% or below (Meller and Simpasa, 2011). Given the status of Zambia as a developing
country, the lower levels of fiscal revenue contributions by the mining companies indicate
a clear absence of interest to contribute to the development of the country.
In late-September 2020, it was reported that First Quantum Minerals and EMR Capital
were halting their $2 billion expansion plans on account a royalty tax introduced in 2019.
According to the mining companies, the new royalty has made the projects unviable. The
revenue-based royalty increases from a minimum of 5.5% to 7.5% when copper prices are
at $6,000 to $7,000 a tonne. The royalty rises further to 10% when copper prices top
$10,000. The miners contend that this is double taxation since the royalty is not
deductible from profits and they also pay corporate income tax13.
The Finance Minister’s response is that the country does not get enough from its mineral
resources. He is however willing to consider the mining companies’ grievances regarding
the royalty. Any compromise on the part of the Government should be quite an
achievement by the mining companies, given the country’s debt overhang reportedly
around $18.5 billion and a debt-to-GDP ratio of 104%, way above the IMF and World
Bank threshold of 35%14.
In the interim, the mining companies’ decision to halt their expansion programmes is a
clear threat to projected government revenues for the medium-to-long term. More
definitively, the threat negatively affects government’s means to settling the national
debts and funding of its infrastructure projects to which it is contractually committed.
This adversarial scenario of the Government versus the mining companies obviously
hinders the future revenue plans for both. However, the striking distinction here is that
the mining companies are willing to suspend or halt progress until the situation changes
to suit their preferred outcome or they could even invest elsewhere. It therefore weighs
more on the government than the mining companies to seek grounds for compromise and
revenue enhancement for both parties.
12
https://theconversation.com/is-africas-resource-nationalism-just-big-business-as-usual-41647
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-09-30/zambian-royalty-spat-halts-2-billion-of-copper-mine-investment
14https://www.lusakatimes.com/2020/09/30/we-are-18-5-billion-dollars-in-debt-our-debt-to-gdp-position-is-104-finance-minister/
13
9
The problem for the Government is best defined as the lack of progressive increase in
corporate tax collections from the mining companies when resource prices rise. The
imposition of higher mineral royalties speaks volumes on the Government’s supposition
that the mining companies very likely manipulate their financial statements so as to have
lower profits and hence pay lower corporate taxes.
To resolve this problem, the Zambian Government must institute a mining tax framework
which will facilitate for proportional increases in government revenues when the mining
companies enjoy abnormal profits due to higher resource prices. The framework must be
balanced with the Government’s desire for extended investments and should not hinder
the companies’ abilities to meet their financial obligations to their lenders. With such a
framework, the Government has a long-term interest in the gainful financial performance
of the mining industry as they in essence bear a substantial risk should the mining
industry perform poorly. It is therefore important that there be considerable transparency
between the two parties in determining the appropriate framework.
The new tax framework should remove the need for stability clauses in the development
agreements. The stability clauses become irrelevant on the basis that all benefits from
rising resource prices should ideally be shared proportionally between the government
and the industry.
The formulation of development agreements, however, does not fall out. The
development agreements’ relevance continues with regard to outlining the rules of
engagement for non-fiscal commitments by both the government and by the investor. The
development agreements should continue to outline government’s role to ease
exploration, development, and operations as well as trade and investment. The issue boils
down to the mining companies insisting that the taxes paid should result in the
government undertaking infrastructural investment that facilitates the mine company’s
activities as well as benefits the surrounding communities. This does not absolve the
mining company from undertaking corporate social responsibilities but there should be a
clear distinction between the government’s socio-economic responsibility and that of the
mining companies’ choice for community responsibility.
Given Zambia’s landlocked status and Maplecroft’s recent statement that the country is a
high-risk destination for resource extraction investments,15 the country must develop and
market a medium-to-long term programme that comprehensively details Zambia’s
competitive advantages for energy, transportation, communication and skills availability
for all significant sectors of the economy. For the mining sector, a comprehensive
geological map is required as it minimises the exploration risk and is therefore of
significant value for the industry’s promotion. As at 2016, only 61% of the country had
been geologically mapped, leaving a large portion of 39% unmapped (Kasumba and
Chifwepa, 2016). In terms of labour resource, the government must have a deliberate
15
https://www.maplecroft.com/insights/analysis/africas-rising-resource-nationalism-ups-stakes-for-miners/
10
investment in advanced educational and skills programmes with the understanding that
mining entities now employ far fewer people with advanced skills compared to
experiences of the past.
Undoubtedly, the government investments will require significant financing which the
private mining companies alone cannot fulfil through their tax payments. As with most
governments, the Zambian government does have a proclivity to accuse the mining
companies of lacking transparency. ZCCM-IH, the government’s investment arm in
mining, should therefore be used as the model for government’s intrinsic understanding
of the country’s mining industry for taxation determination. To do this, the company must
evolve from a minority shareholder in the existing mining companies to an owner,
developer, and operator of full-scale mining operations.
With its detailed geological map, the government should reserve geological areas that
exhibit low-risk with high rents potential for ZCCM-IH while leaving areas that have high
geological uncertainties and require large investments for private developers. The
rationale is that private investors have greater access to funding and also have predetermined risk capital, a luxury which ZCCM-IH cannot afford.
Other than serving as a model for tax determination, the ownership, development and
running of mining projects by ZCCM-IH will present the government an opportunity for
direct enhancement of its revenues when resource prices rise; revenues which can be used
for new investments and the creation of jobs, enhanced and efficient mining programs for
greater profitability, beneficiation and diversification programmes, and mentorship
programmes with respect to quality control and marketing for artisanal and small-scale
miners.
All in all, what is proposed for the mining sector is a hybrid system which allows private
companies to compete with the Government-owned enterprise in the exploration,
development and operation of mining entities. It is proposed that the Government
enterprise be allowed an advantage in the geological locations to ease exploration and
development but the government should still commit to all parties with regard to the
development agenda that ease operations and logistics; and hence create a competitive
advantage for the mining sector as well as other sectors of the economy.
Drawing from the lessons of Chile once again: From producing the same annual quantities
of Copper as Zambia in the 1960s, Chile is now the largest copper producer in the world
as both the state-owned mining company and the private investors have expanded output.
It is also worth noting that in Chile, the participation of copper in the export basket
declined to 35% by 2002; an indication of the success in diversification of the economy
(Meller and Simpasa, 2011).
Acknowledging that mining is a wasting asset and the continuation of operations depend
on the level of resource prices is cardinal. In the event of falling prices, it is not uncommon
11
for mining companies to place the operations under care-and-maintenance with the
entire workforce on unpaid leave for long periods. Having become reliant on wages, to
expect that the workers will simply find their own means of livelihood is a clear recipe for
tension with the local populace. The Zambian Government therefore needs to create
environments for diversification as and when the mining asset wastes away or during
periods of care-and-maintenance.
Furthermore, the Government and the investor need to recognise that incursions into
frontier areas are generally considered to be an intrusion by the local community. Both
the Government and the foreign mining investor will promote the project on the basis of
development and the provision of jobs without due consideration to the notion that the
people are self-employed in whatever has kept them economically engaged for decades, if
not centuries.
The commencement of a mining project can therefore literally mean the destruction of
traditional livelihoods. The compensation by the mining companies is generally through
the construction of ‘modern’ structures, resettlement to other areas which were not of
original interest, and the promise of wages from jobs. In the long term, the negative effects
of pollution and environmental degradation may completely hinder the capacity to return
to the traditional means of livelihood. It is therefore imperative that before any mining
project can commence, issues of sustainable development are addressed.
Conclusion
The United Nations defines sustainable development as ‘development that meets the
needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their
own needs’ (Emas, 2015). This definition highlights the responsibility which
government’s must bear as they consider permitting investors to extract resources from
their peoples’ lands. The responsibility can be well-defined by answering several
questions:
1. Does the resource extracted enhance the lives of the domestic community or that
of foreign communities eg cobalt for electric car batteries?
2. To what extent do revenues from the extraction benefit future generations eg the
creation of Sovereign Wealth Funds (SWFs)?
3. Is the resource extractor committed to protecting the land and the traditional
means of livelihood from the harmful effects of resource extraction eg social and
environmental enabling for hunting, fishing, herding and farming?
4. Is the resource extractor committed to leaving a sustainable socio-economic
system than the one found eg enhanced and diversified opportunities for the
populace?
These questions basically provide for a cost-benefit analysis so as to determine whether
the mining project should go ahead or not. The principle here, although not fully
addressed, is to conceptualise the project in a comprehensive framework for sustainable
12
development. Where questions arise or the answers are incomplete, it means that the
project is not viable from a sustainable developmental perspective. The programme can
therefore be suspended for the future generation who may be in a better position to
manage it. This works in the same manner as managing SWFs for the future generations
except in this case, the resource is left for the future generation to extract and determine
its use. This is also comparable to mining companies’ suspension or halting of projects
because it is not financially viable in the interim.
It must be noted that natural resource extraction and nationalism extend beyond the
traditional minerals such as copper. For Zambia, this has been demonstrated by the rise
in demand for Pterocarpus Chrysothrix tree species (locally known as Mukula), increased
interest for gold extraction, and the chronic demand from the neighbouring countries for
maize produced in Zambia. In all the three cases, the government authorities have
demonstrated forms of resource nationalism through banning of trade, strategic reserves
enforcement and seizure of illegal exports. The underlying theme for all cases has been
that the government does not obtain the appropriate revenues from the trading of these
natural resources.
Given the government’s obvious need for extensive and sustainable funding for its
development agenda, it is cardinal that it establishes a national framework for resource
nationalism. The framework must instil long-term stability in revenue collections by the
government, tackle systemic corruption, and strengthen government institutions to
ensure the protection of investments and the delivery of social justice for the country.
13
Bibliography
African Business Magazine (4 June 2018); ‘What’s so bad about resource nationalism?’
https://africanbusinessmagazine.com/sectors/commodities/whats-so-bad-about-resourcenationalism/
Banks, G.D. (2015); U.S. Resource Nationalism: The Impact of Energy Trade Restrictions on
National Security, American Council for Capital Formation
Childs, J. (2015); Is Africa’s ‘resource nationalism’ just big business as usual? National Research
Foundation
Cobb, K. (2020); The return of resource nationalism in Resource Insights
(https://www.resilience.org/stories/2020-02-16/the-return-of-resource-nationaism/
Emas, R. (2015); The Concept of Sustainable Development: Definition and Defining Principles,
United Nations
Export Finance Australia (2018); Ems – Rising resource nationalism frustrates investment
climate;
https://www.exportfinance.gov.au/resources-news/news-events/world-riskdevelopments/2018/world-risk-developments-february-2018/ems-rising-resource-nationalismfrustrates-investment-climate/
Grimley, S. (2015); Resource Nationalism, Ernst & Young
https://www.ausimmbulletin.com/opinion/resource-nationalism/
HM Government (2014); Resource Nationalism, Horizon Scanning Programme
Humphrey-Smith, E. (2019); Africa’s Rising Resource Nationalism Ups Stakes for Miners;
https://www.maplecroft.com/insights/analysis/africas-rising-resource-nationalism-ups-stakesfor-miners/
Kaunda, Francis (2002); Selling the Family Silver: The Zambian Copper Mines Story, Lusaka,
Zambia
Leon, P. (2019); ‘Zambia lured by the siren song of resource nationalism’ in Financial Times,
https://www.ft.com/content/7afe468c-878c-11e9-a028-86cea8523dc2
Limpitlaw, D. (2011); ‘Nationalisation and Mining: Lessons from Zambia in The Journal of The
Southern African Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Vol. 111, Pages 737 - 739
Maplecroft (2019); Resource Nationalism Rises in 30 Countries: DRC Joint Highest Risk with
Venezuela,
https://www.maplecroft.com/insights/analysis/resource-nationalism-rises-30countries/
14
Meller, P. and Simpasa, A.M. (2011); Role of Copper in the Chilean & Zambian Economics: Main
Economic and Policy Issues, Global Development Network Working Paper Series, WP No. 43
Monaldi, F. J. (2020); ‘The Cyclical Phenomenon of Resource Nationalism in Latin America’
printed from The Oxford research Encyclopaedia, Politics, Oxford University Press, USA, Pages
1 - 22
Ng’ambi, S.P. (2015); ‘Mineral Taxation and Resource Nationalism in Zambia’ in Southern
African Journal of Policy and Development, Vol. 2, No. 1, Article 4
Pryke, S. (2017); ‘Explaining Resource Nationalism’ in Global Policy Journal, Vol. 8, Issue 4,
Pages 474 – 482 https://www.globalpolicyjournal.com/articles/global-commons-andenvironment/explaining-resource-nationalism
Sainsbury, P. (2018); What is Resource Nationalism, https://materials-risk.com/what-isresource-nationalism/
Sardanis, Andrew (2003); Africa: Another Side of the Coin, I.B. Taurus, New York, USA
Sardanis, Andrew (2014); Zambia: The First Fifty Years, I.B. Taurus, New York, USA
Tobita, M.S. and Takaha, T. (2018); ‘Resource nationalism’ clouds China’s Africa ambitions in
Nikkei Asian Review, https://asia.nikkei.com/Politics/International-relations/Resourcenationalism-clouds-China-s-Africa-ambitions2
Toroskainen, K. and Olan’g, S. (2019); Governments, Companies Find a Bit of Common Ground
on Resource Nationalism at Indaba, National Resource Governance Institute,
https://resourcegovernance.org/blog/governments-companies-find-bit-common-groundresource-nationalism-indaba
Ward, H. (2009); Resource Nationalism and Sustainable Development: A Primer and Key
Issues, International Institute for Environment and Development
Wilson, J. D. (2013); ‘Resource Nationalism and Australian State Intervention’ in Governing
Global Production, International Political Economy series, Palgrave Macmillan, London
Wilson, J. D. (2011); ‘Resource Nationalism or Resource Liberalism? Explaining Australia’s
approach to Chinese investment in its minerals sector’ in Australian Journal of International
Affairs, Pages 283 - 304
15