Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
1. Introduction
It is now an economic fact that, the spectre of the European Monetary Union (EMU)
crisis is looming substantially and scaring potential monetary zones. With renewed interest in
the economics of monetary union following this EMU crisis, very few papers have recently
examined the feasibility of the proposed African monetary zones (Tsangarides & Qureshi,
2008; Asongu, 2012ab; Alagidede et al., 2011). Moreover, studies on the proposed West
African Monetary Zone (WAMZ) (Debrun et al., 2005; Celasun & Justiniano, 2005) and the
embryonic East African Monetary Zone (EAMZ) (Mkenda, 2001; Buigut & Valev, 2005) over
the past decade are scarce. Hitherto, the focus of these studies has been on the optimality of the
proposed currency areas (Mkenda, 2001; Asongu, 2012a; Buigut & Valev, 2005), costs and
benefits of candidate countries (Debrun et al., 2005) and adjustments to shocks (Celasun &
Justiniano, 2005; Alagidede et al., 2011; Asongu, 2012b). Results of the works are broadly
consistent with one fact: the need for greater improvements in structural and institutional
characteristics (that will facilitate convergence) in light of a paramount lesson of the EMU
crisis1 (Willet, 2011; Willet & Srisorn, 2011).
In spite of the substantially documented role finance plays in the economic growth of a
monetary union (De Avila, 2003), little (if nothing) is known about evidence of the financegrowth nexus in the proposed WAMZ and EAMZ. According to De Avila, the analysis of the
main channels through which policy changes may affect growth indicate that, the
harmonization process has impacted growth (via increase in the level of efficiency of financial
intermediation) and the liberalization of capital controls has principally affected growth
through improvements in the degree of efficiency in financial intermediation (p.4). In the
experience of the EMU (Vickers, 2000), embryonic African monetary zones constitute ideal
scenarios to analyze the finance-growth nexus. They also present the opportunity of shedding
light on some of the unresolved issues on causality between finance and growth in sub-Saharan
Africa (SSA)2. In light of the above, this study is a short-run trip to the proposed monetary
unions in Africa. We assess the Schumpeterian thesis for the positive spillovers of financial
services on growth. Causality analysis is performed on seven financial development and three
growth indicators. Schumpeter postulated that an efficient financial system greatly helps in
economic prosperity. As emphasized by King & Levine (1993), Schumpeter disputed that,
well-functioning banks spur technological innovation by offering funding to entrepreneurs that
have the best chances of successfully implementing innovative products and production
process.
Opposed to this mainstream consensus are sympathizers of Andersen & Tarp (2003)
who have concluded that, contrary to what Schumpeterian authors claim, the positive link
between financial development and growth has not been sufficiently documented in recent
empirical works. Andersen & Tarp have vehemently argued that, turning to the empirical
evidence, the alleged first-order effect whereby financial development causes growth is not
adequately supported by econometric work. Hence, they conclude that the empirical evidence
on the finance-growth nexus does not yield any clear-cut picture (p. 1). This second school of
thought has recently been supported by Asongu (2011a) in a meta-study of 186 papers on the
finance-growth nexus. It will therefore be interesting to examine the positions of the embryonic
African monetary zones in light of the above debate. The rest of the paper is organized as
follows. Section 2 presents the data and discusses the methodology. The empirical analysis is
covered in Section 3. Section 4 concludes.
1
Serious disequilibria in a monetary union result from arrangements not designed to be robust to a variety of
shocks.
2
See “Finance and Growth: A Schumpeterian Trip to Africa” by Baonza (2011) for more details.
860
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
2. Data and Methodology
2.1 Data
We examine a sample of 4 West and 5 East African countries with data from African
Development Indicators (ADI) and the Financial Development and Structure Database (FDSD)
of the World Bank for the period 1980-2010. Guinea is left-out of the WAMZ due to data
constraints. The summary statistics of the variables and details on the countries investigated are
presented in Panel A and Panel B respectively of Appendix 1. Variable definitions and
corresponding sources are presented in Appendix 2.
A number of theoretical papers on finance and growth that emerged following the
insights of the early endogenous growth models (Romer, 1990; Grossman & Helpman, 1991;
Lucas, 1988) have documented three main channels to growth: 1) the rise in the rate of private
savings; 2) increase in the efficiency of the financial intermediation process and; 3) the rise in
the social productivity of capital (Pagano, 1993). Within the framework of our study, only the
first two points are taken into consideration. For organizational purposes, the financial variables
are presented in terms of financial intermediary dynamics of depth (money), activity (credit),
efficiency and size. Firstly, from a financial depth standpoint, we are consistent with the FDSD
and recent African finance literature (Asongu, 2012c) in measuring financial depth both from
overall-economic and financial system perspectives with indicators of broad money supply
(M2/GDP) and financial system deposits (Fdgdp) respectively. Whereas the former represents
the monetary base plus demand, saving and time deposits, the latter denotes liquid liabilities of
the financial system. It is interesting to distinguish between these two aggregates of money
supply because, since we are dealing exclusively with African countries, a great chunk of the
monetary base does not transit through the banking sector. Secondly, financial activity is
appreciated in terms of credit allocation. Thus, the paper seeks to appreciate the ability of banks
to grant credit to economic operators. We use measurements of both banking-system-activity
and financial-system-activity in terms of “private domestic credit by deposit banks: Pcrb” and
“private credit by deposit banks and other financial institutions: Pcrbof” respectively. Thirdly,
financial intermediary size is measured in terms of deposit bank assets as a proportion of total
assets (deposit bank assets plus central bank assets). Fourthly, financial efficiency3 appreciates
the ability of deposits (money) to be converted into credit (financial activity). This fourth
measure appreciates the fundamental role of banks in transforming mobilized deposits
(savings) into credit for businesses or the private sector (Asongu, 2011b). Accordingly, we
adopt indicators of banking-system-efficiency and financial-system-efficiency (respectively
‘bank credit on bank deposits: Bcbd’ and ‘financial system credit on financial system deposits:
Fcfd’). The correlation analysis presented in Appendix 3 shows that, employment of two
variables in almost every financial dynamic category is a form of robustness check. Hence, we
are able to cross-check financial system results with those of the banking system for the most
part. Three measures of economic growth are employed: GDP growth, GDP per capita growth
and real GDP output. While the first two are in growth rate, the last is in natural logarithm.
2.2 Methodology
The estimation technique typically follows mainstream literature on testing the short-run
effect of financial variables on economic activity (Starr, 2005). The approach entails unit tests
to examine the stationarity properties of the variables before a Granger causality approach is
used to examine the short-term effects (Engle & Granger, 1987). Impulse response functions
are used to further assess the tendencies of significant Granger causality results.
3
By financial efficiency here, we neither refer to the profitability-related concept (notion) nor to the production
efficiency of decision making units in the financial sector (via Data Envelopment Analysis).
861
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
3. Empirical analysis
3.1 Unit root tests
The assessment of stationarity is based on two types of first generational panel unit root
tests. When the variables exhibit unit roots in levels, we accordingly test for stationarity in
their first differences. Employment of the Granger causality approach requires that the
variables do not have a unit root (or are stationary). Two main types of panel unit root tests
have been documented: first generational (that is based cross-sectional independence) and the
second generational (which supposes cross-sectional dependence). A necessary condition for
the employment of the latter generational test is a cross-sectional dependence test which is only
applicable if the number of cross-sections (N) in the panel is above the number of periods in the
cross-sections (T). Given that we have 31 periods (T) and 5(or 4) cross-sections (N), we are
limited to the first generational type. Therefore, both the Levin, Lin & Chu (LLC, 2002) and
Im, Pesaran & Shin (IPS, 2003) tests are employed. While the former is a homogenous based
panel unit root test (with a common unit as null hypothesis), the latter is a heterogeneous
oriented test (with individual unit roots as null hypotheses). In case of conflicting results, IPS
(2003) takes precedence over LLC (2002) in decision making because, consistent with Maddala
& Wu (1999), the alternative hypothesis of LLC (2002) is too powerful. In line with Liew
(2004), goodness of fit (or optimal lag selection) for model specification is ensured by the
Hannan-Quinn Information Criterion (HQC) and the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) for
the LLC (2002) and IPS (2003) tests respectively.
Table 1: Panel unit root tests
Panel A: Unit root tests for the WAMZ
F. Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Level
First
difference
Finance
Fin. Efficiency
F. Activity (Credit)
F. Size
BcBd
FcFd
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Dbacba
LLC tests for homogenous panel
c
ct
c
ct
0.879
-0.828
-5.01***
-3.58***
1.252
0.200
-2.81***
-4.14***
-0.738
0.691
-6.65***
-6.20***
-2.89***
-0.125
-3.80***
-3.46***
c
ct
c
ct
0.103
-0.828
-6.47***
-5.54***
0.647
-0.121
-4.71***
-5.52***
0.101
1.616
-6.79***
-6.42***
-1.52*
-1.34*
-4.10***
-3.86***
2.150
2.390
-2.10**
-2.82***
2.142
2.612
-1.130
-2.30**
3.028
0.047
-8.82***
-4.57***
Economic Growth
GDP growth rates
Real
GDPg
GDPpcg Output
-6.24***
-6.23***
n.a
n.a
-6.16***
-6.71***
n.a
n.a
3.229
-1.024
-6.61***
-6.49***
-5.77***
-5.89***
n.a
n.a
-5.62***
-6.10***
n.a
n.a
3.865
-0.159
-7.36***
-7.93***
IPS tests for heterogeneous panel
Level
First
difference
2.513
3.685
-3.33***
-3.15***
2.398
3.840
-2.39***
-2.98***
1.844
-0.799
-9.36***
-9.05***
Panel B: Unit root tests for the EAMZ
F. Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Level
First
difference
Finance
Fin. Efficiency
F. Activity (Credit)
F. Size
BcBd
FcFd
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Dbacba
LLC tests for homogenous panel
c
ct
c
ct
4.969
3.126
-3.36***
-3.74***
5.386
2.463
-2.86***
-3.08***
-0.461
0.304
-9.25***
-9.10***
c
ct
c
ct
4.028
2.126
-3.71***
-3.29***
5.061
2.289
-3.66***
-3.20***
-1.324*
0.002
-8.73***
-8.94***
-0.774
1.517
-1.86**
1.054
2.478
2.778
-0.135
-0.888
2.009
2.631
-2.80***
-6.60***
Economic Growth
GDP growth rates
Real
GDPg
GDPpcg Output
0.912
0.566
-9.67***
-4.63***
-5.25***
-5.17***
n.a
n.a
-6.26***
-0.861
n.a
n.a
1.459
1.730
-7.03***
-5.40***
1.192
0.260
-10.7***
-6.15***
-4.94***
-4.54***
n.a
n.a
-6.09***
-3.15***
n.a
n.a
2.358
-0.026
-6.88***
-4.80***
IPS tests for heterogeneous panel
Level
First
difference
-1.70**
-2.49***
n.a
n.a
2.234
-0.227
-3.16***
-3.26***
1.817
-0.430
-3.62***
-4.95***
Notes: ***, **, *denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. ‘c’ and ‘ct’: ‘constant’ and ‘constant and trend’ respectively.
Maximum lag is 8 and optimal lags are chosen via HQC for LLC test and AIC for IPS test. LLC: Levin, Lin & Chu (2002). IPS: Im, Pesaran
& Shin (2003). M2: Money Supply. Fdgdp: Liquid Liabilities. BcBd: Banking System Efficiency. FcFd: Financial System Efficiency. Pcrb:
Banking System Activity. Pcrbof: Financial System Activity. Dbacba: Deposit Bank Assets on Total Assets. GDP: Gross Domestic Product.
GDPg: GDP growth. GDPpcg: GDP per capita growth. WAMZ: West African Monetary Zone. EAMZ: East African Monetary Zone.
862
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Table 1 above shows results for the panel unit root tests. While Panel A presents the
findings for the WAMZ, those of Panel B are of the EAMZ. For both monetary zones, while
the financial variables are overwhelmingly integrated in the first order (i.e: they can be
differenced once to be stationary), the economic variables are stationary in levels (with the
exception of real output).
3.2 Granger causality for finance and growth
Let us consider the following basic bivariate finite-order VAR models:
Growthi ,t ijGrowthi ,t j ijFinancei ,t j i i ,t
(1)
Financei ,t ijFinancei ,t j ijGrowthi ,t j i i ,t
(2)
p
q
j 1
j 0
p
q
j 1
j 0
where, Growth denotes economic prosperity (GDP growth, GDP per capita growth or real GDP
output) while, Finance represents financial development dynamics (of depth, efficiency,
activity and size).
Simple Granger causality is based on the assessment of how past values of a financial
indicator could help past values of a growth indicator in explaining the present value of the
growth indicator (Eq. 1). In the same vein, it also implies investigating how past values of
growth variables are significant in helping the past values of financial variables to explain the
present value of financial variables (Eq. 2). In mainstream literature, this model is applied on
variables that do not exhibit unit root (in levels for the most part). Within our framework, we
are applying this test to all ‘finance and growth’ pairs in both ‘first difference’ and levels for
three reasons: (1) ensure comparability; (2) consistency with application of the model to
stationary variables and; (3) robustness checks in case we might have missed-out something in
the unit root test specifications.
In light of the above, the resulting VAR models in first difference are the following:
Growthi ,t ijGrowthi ,t j ijFinancei ,t j i i ,t
(3)
Financei ,t ijFinancei ,t j ijGrowthi ,t j i i ,t
(4)
p
q
j 1
j 0
p
q
j 1
j 0
The null hypothesis of Eq. (4) is the position that, ‘Growth does not Granger cause
Finance’. Accordingly, a rejection of the null hypothesis is captured by the significant Fstatistics, which is the Wald statistics for the joint hypothesis that estimated parameters of
lagged values equal zero. Optimal lag selection for goodness of fit is in accordance with Liew
(2004).
863
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Table 2: Short-run Granger causality analysis for the WAMZ
Panel A: Finance and GDP growth
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause GDP growth
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Levels
1st Difference
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
0.331
0.378
0.152
0.185
0.628
0.623
1.044
D[M2]
D[Fdgdp]
D[BcBd]
D[FcFd]
D[Pcrb]
D[Pcrbof]
D[Dbacba]
0.108
0.030
1.050
0.893
0.988
0.963
0.016
Null Hypothesis: GDP growth does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Levels
st
1 Difference
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
0.392
0.365
0.808
1.177
0.912
0.793
3.324**
D[M2]
D[Fdgdp]
D[BcBd]
D[FcFd]
D[Pcrb]
D[Pcrbof]
D[Dbacba]
0.405
0.302
1.418
1.738
0.017
0.027
2.160
Panel B: Finance and GDP per capita growth
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause GDP per capita growth
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.171
0.222
0.054
0.031
0.331
0.341
0.880
1st Difference
D[M2]
0.134
D[Fdgdp]
0.029
D[BcBd]
0.839
D[FcFd]
0.631
D[Pcrb]
0.934
D[Pcrbof]
0.904
D[Dbacba]
0.015
Null Hypothesis: GDP per capita growth does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.291
0.249
1.024
1.341
1.024
0.909
3.405**
1st Difference
D[M2]
0.412
D[Fdgdp]
0.305
D[BcBd]
1.431
D[FcFd]
1.825
D[Pcrb]
0.019
D[Pcrbof]
0.029
D[Dbacba]
2.233
Panel C: Finance and Real GDP Output
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause Real GDP Output
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.242
0.115
0.068
0.032
0.210
0.197
0.952
1st Difference
D[M2]
0.118
D[Fdgdp]
0.054
D[BcBd]
0.120
D[FcFd]
0.033
D[Pcrb]
0.112
D[Pcrbof]
0.156
D[Dbacba]
2.151
Null Hypothesis: Real GDP Output does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
1.531
1.512
8.126***
9.216***
9.742***
10.35***
0.779
1st Difference
M2
1.215
Fdgdp
1.297
BcBd
2.370*
FcFd
2.675*
Pcrb
7.351***
Pcrbof
8.01***
Dbacba
2.070
M2: Money Supply. Fdgdp: Liquid liabilities. BcBd: Bank credit on Bank deposit (Banking System Efficiency). FcFd: Financial credit on
Financial deposits (Financial System Efficiency). Pcrb: Private domestic credit from deposit banks (Banking System Activity). Pcrbof: Private
domestic credit from deposit banks and other financial institutions (Financial System Activity). Dbacba: Deposit bank assets on Total assets
(Banking System Size). Fin: Financial. WAMZ: West African Monetary Zone.
864
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Table 3: Short-run Granger causality analysis for the EAMZ
Panel A: Finance and GDP growth
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause GDP growth
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Levels
st
1 Difference
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
0.021
0.074
3.732**
7.306***
1.174
1.912
1.404
D[M2]
D[Fdgdp]
D[BcBd]
D[FcFd]
D[Pcrb]
D[Pcrbof]
D[Dbacba]
0.032
0.052
0.571
2.864*
2.801*
2.088
0.015
Null Hypothesis: GDP growth does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Levels
1st Difference
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
1.249
1.333
0.048
3.050*
2.399*
2.506*
0.695
D[M2]
D[Fdgdp]
D[BcBd]
D[FcFd]
D[Pcrb]
D[Pcrbof]
D[Dbacba]
0.172
0.042
0.522
2.319
2.175
1.311
0.617
Panel B: Finance and GDP per capita growth
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause GDP per capita growth
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.258
0.087
6.269***
8.292***
2.227
3.551**
1.245
1st Difference
D[M2]
0.248
D[Fdgdp]
0.297
D[BcBd]
0.891
D[FcFd]
2.810*
D[Pcrb]
3.715**
D[Pcrbof]
3.042*
D[Dbacba]
0.082
Null Hypothesis: GDP per capita growth does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
1.589
1.675
0.016
2.342
3.232**
2.935*
0.797
1st Difference
D[M2]
0.211
D[Fdgdp]
0.146
D[BcBd]
0.416
D[FcFd]
2.040
D[Pcrb]
1.671
D[Pcrbof]
0.937
D[Dbacba]
0.926
Panel C: Finance and Real GDP Output
Null Hypothesis: Finance does not cause Real GDP Output
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.175
0.163
3.387**
4.183**
0.368
1.338
0.581
1st Difference
D[M2]
1.486
D[Fdgdp]
1.357
D[BcBd]
0.764
D[FcFd]
3.256**
D[Pcrb]
0.949
D[Pcrbof]
1.516
D[Dbacba]
0.390
Null Hypothesis: Real GDP Output does not cause Finance
Financial Depth (Money)
M2
Fdgdp
Financial Efficiency
BcBd
FcFd
Fin. Activity (Credit)
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Fin. Size
Dbacba
Levels
0.608
0.675
0.707
1.368
0.359
0.143
3.055*
1st Difference
M2
0.279
Fdgdp
0.464
BcBd
1.687
FcFd
1.809
Pcrb
0.472
Pcrbof
0.415
Dbacba
3.764**
M2: Money Supply. Fdgdp: Liquid liabilities. BcBd: Bank credit on Bank deposit (Banking System Efficiency). FcFd: Financial credit on
Financial deposits (Financial System Efficiency). Pcrb: Private domestic credit from deposit banks (Banking System Activity). Pcrbof: Private
domestic credit from deposit banks and other financial institutions (Financial System Activity). Dbacba: Deposit bank assets on Total assets
(Banking System Size). Fin: Financial. Fin: Financial. EAMZ: East African Monetary Zone.
Table 2 and Table 3 above present Granger causality results for the WAMZ and the
EAMZ respectively. Regardless of tables, Panel A, Panel B and Panel C show ‘Finance and
GDP growth’, ‘Finance and GDP per capita growth’ and ‘Finance and real GDP output’
865
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
causality estimations respectively. The Schumpeterian thesis is based on the top-half of each
panel which has a null hypothesis of: ‘Finance does not Granger cause Growth’. The bottom
halves (with null hypotheses: ‘Growth does not Granger cause Finance’) are relevant
complementary assessments of tendencies in the finance-growth nexus.
From the results in Table 2, the following could be established: (1) there is
overwhelmingly no evidence of finance causing growth; (2) real GDP output causes financial
allocation efficiency and financial activity and; (3) the scanty evidence of GDP growth and
GDP per capita growth causing financial size is not very robust because of ‘level significance’4.
The following conclusions could be derived from Table 3: (1) financial allocation efficiency is
instrumental in GDP growth, GDP per capita growth and real GDP output, while financial
activity causes only GDP growth and GDP per capita growth and; (2) the evidence of growth
causing financial development can only be validated for financial size (Panel C) with respect to
real GDP output because it is both significant in levels and first difference5. The simple fact
that we have seen evidence of Granger causality flowing from some financial variables to
growth dynamics is not enough to draw any economic inferences. Hence, the impulse-response
functions (IRFs) of such relationships should provide additional material on the scale and
timing of a one standard deviation shock in the financial variables and the responses of the
growth dynamics.
3.3 Impulse response for the EAMZ
Using a Choleski decomposition on a VAR with ordering: 1) financial variable, 2)
growth dynamic; we compute IRFs for the finance-growth nexus. We know from intuition that
the Schumpeterian thesis advocates for positive spillovers of financial services on growth.
Hence, we expect positive shocks in financial services (financial system efficiency, banking
system activity and financial system activity) to improve growth dynamics at least in the shortrun because of the long-run neutrality of money. Appendix 4-9 show graphs corresponding to
the IRFs. The dotted lines are the two standard deviation bands, which are used to measure the
significance (Agénor et al., 1997, p. 19). It could be observed that, but for the responses of
GDP growth (GDP per capita growth) to financial system efficiency in Appendix 4 (6)6, there
is an overwhelming significant positive short-run impact on the temporary components of the
growth dynamics. Convergence of the effect to zero towards the 10th year confirms the longrun neutrality of monetary policy variables on real output (growth).
3.4 Robustness checks
In order to ensure that our results and estimations are robust, we have checked and
performed the following. (1) For almost every financial variable (depth, efficiency or activity),
two indicators have been used. Hence, the findings have broadly encapsulated measures of
financial development dynamics both from banking and financial system perspectives. (2)
Three measures of economic growth have been employed as well to capture growth both from
overall economic, per capita and real output standpoints. (3) Both homogenous and
heterogeneous assumptions have been considered in the unit root tests. (4) Optimal lag
selection for model specifications has been consistent with the goodness of fit
4
It should be recalled that financial size for the WAMZ is stationary only in first difference (see Panel A in Table
1).
5
Financial size for the EAMZ is also stationary only in first difference (see Panel B of Table 1).
6
A possible explanation for these initial negative responses is the substantially documented evidence of surplus
liquidity issues in African financial institutions (Saxegaard, 2006; Fouda, 2009).
866
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
recommendations of Liew (2004)7. (5) Granger causality has been performed both in level and
first difference equations. (6) Impulse response functions have been used to further assess the
tendencies of significant Granger causality results and correspondingly, the Schumpeterian
thesis.
3.5 Monetary policy implications
The traditional discretionary monetary policy arrangement favors a short-run effect of
changes in monetary policy variables on economic activity (especially real output). This favors
arrangements such as international economic integration (monetary unions and inflation
targeting for example). Results of the EAMZ are broadly consistent with this traditional strand.
The significant absence of any short-run effect of monetary policy on output in the WAMZ is
consistent with the non-traditional strand of policy regimes that limit the ability of monetary
authorities to use policy to offset output fluctuations. Thus, the inability of monetary policy to
affect short-run real GDP is in line with the stance of Week (2010) who views this International
Monetary Fund (IMF) oriented approach as absurdly inappropriate because a vast majority of
SSA countries lack the instruments to make monetary policy effective. Hence, the monetary
authority in the potential WAMZ may not use policy instruments in the short-run to offset
adverse shocks to output by pursuing either an expansionary or a contractionary policy.
4. Conclusion
With the spectre of the Euro crisis looming substantially large and scaring potential
monetary unions, this study has been a short-run trip to embryonic African monetary zones to
assess the Schumpeterian thesis for positive spillovers of financial services on growth.
Causality analysis has been performed with seven financial development and three growth
indicators in the proposed West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ) and East African Monetary
Zone (EAMZ). The journey has been promising for the EAMZ and lamentable for the WAMZ.
Results of the EAMZ are broadly consistent with the traditional discretionary monetary policy
arrangements while those of the WAMZ are in line with the non-traditional strand of regimes in
which policy instruments in the short-run cannot be used to offset adverse shocks to output.
Acknowledgement
The author is highly indebted to the editor and referees for their useful comments.
“The major findings in the current simulation study are previewed as follows. First, these criteria managed to
pick up the correct lag length at least half of the time in small sample. Second, this performance increases
substantially as sample size grows. Third, with relatively large sample (120 or more observations), HQC is found
to outdo the rest in correctly identifying the true lag length. In contrast, AIC and FPE should be a better choice
for smaller sample. Fourth, AIC and FPE are found to produce the least probability of under estimation among all
criteria under study. Finally, the problem of over estimation, however, is negligible in all cases. The findings in
this simulation study, besides providing formal groundwork supportive of the popular choice of AIC in previous
empirical researches, may as well serve as useful guiding principles for future economic researches in the
determination of autoregressive lag length” (Liew, 2004, p. 2).
7
867
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Appendices
Appendix 1: Summary Statistics and Presentation of Countries
Panel A: Summary Statistics
Economic
Growth
Finance
Growth
Rates
Real Output
Fin.
Depth
Fin.
Efficiency
Fin.
Activity
Fin. Size
GDPg
GDPpcg
M2
Fdgdp
BcBd
FcFd
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Dbacba
West
Mean
3.459
0.740
9.521
0.226
0.154
0.625
0.629
0.096
0.099
0.502
African Monetary Zone (WAMZ)
S.D
Min.
Max.
Obser.
5.499
-19.01
27.462
124
5.108
-18.63
22.61
124
0.855
8.248
11.31
124
0.116
0.091
0.796
114
0.093
0.045
0.600
114
0.347
0.173
2.103
117
0.326
0.209
1.812
114
0.066
0.014
0.350
114
0.068
0.014
0.368
114
0.273
0.054
1.350
117
East African Monetary Zone (EAMZ)
Mean
S.D
Min.
Max.
Obser.
4.077
6.606
-50.24
35.22
143
1.208
6.246
-46.89
37.83
143
9.581
0.456
8.774
10.49
147
0.224
0.118
0.046
0.498
134
0.171
0.110
0.026
0.414
134
0.676
0.282
0.070
1.609
146
0.819
0.357
0.139
1.968
134
0.112
0.074
0.011
0.255
134
0.137
0.097
0.011
0.349
134
0.628
0.198
0.110
0.999
141
Panel B: Presentation of countries
West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ)
East African Monetary Zone (EAMZ)
The Gambia, Ghana, Nigeria, Sierra Leone
Burundi, Kenya, Rwanda, Uganda, Tanzania
S.D: Standard Deviation. Min: Minimum. Max: Maximum. Obser : Observations. Fin: Financial.
Appendix 2: Variable Definitions
Variables
Signs
Variable Definitions
Sources
Economic Prosperity
GDPg
GDP Growth (Annual %)
World Bank (WDI)
Per Capita Economic Prosperity
GDPpcg
GDP Per Capita Growth (Annual %)
World Bank (WDI)
Real Output
Output
Logarithm of Real GDP
World Bank (WDI)
Economic financial depth
(Money Supply)
M2
Monetary Base plus demand, saving and time
deposits (% of GDP)
World Bank (FDSD)
Financial system depth (Liquid
liabilities)
Fdgdp
Financial system deposits (% of GDP)
World Bank (FDSD)
Banking system allocation
efficiency
BcBd
Bank credit on Bank deposits
World Bank (FDSD)
Financial system allocation
efficiency
FcFd
Financial system credit on Financial system deposits
World Bank (FDSD)
Banking system activity
Pcrb
Private credit by deposit banks (% of GDP)
World Bank (FDSD)
Financial system activity
Pcrbof
Private credit by deposit banks and other financial
institutions (% of GDP)
World Bank (FDSD)
Banking System Size
Dbacba
Deposit bank assets/ Total assets (Deposit bank assets
plus Central bank assets)
World Bank (FDSD)
Infl: Inflation. M2: Money Supply. Fdgdp: Liquid liabilities. BcBd: Bank credit on Bank deposits. FcFd: Financial system credit on Financial
system deposits. Pcrb: Private domestic credit by deposit banks. Pcrbof: Private domestic credit by deposit banks and other financial institutions.
WDI: World Development Indicators. FDSD: Financial Development and Structure Database. GDP: Gross Domestic Product.
868
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Appendix 3: Correlation Matrices
Panel A: West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ)
Financial Depth
Fin. Efficiency
Financial Activity
Economic Growth
GDPg
1.000
GDPpcg
0.985
1.000
Output
0.080
0.124
1.000
GDPpcg
0.951
1.000
Fdgdp
0.109
0.065
-0.105
0.990
1.000
BcBd
0.069
0.055
0.294
0.020
0.062
1.000
FcFd
0.062
0.043
0.238
0.022
0.056
0.966
1.000
Pcrb
0.101
0.057
0.108
0.646
0.682
0.746
0.731
1.000
Pcrbof
0.100
0.057
0.150
0.634
0.675
0.745
0.735
0.994
1.000
Panel B: East African Monetary Zone (EAMZ)
Financial Depth
Fin. Efficiency
Financial Activity
Economic Growth
GDPg
1.000
M2
0.097
0.050
-0.175
1.000
Output
0.205
0.173
1.000
M2
-0.115
-0.150
0.427
1.000
Fdgdp
-0.072
-0.110
0.497
0.989
1.000
BcBd
-0.162
-0.162
-0.447
0.148
0.106
1.000
FcFd
-0.357
-0.344
-0.665
0.010
-0.057
0.870
1.000
Pcrb
-0.199
-0.224
0.215
0.893
0.884
0.450
0.278
1.000
Pcrbof
-0.243
-0.276
0.152
0.912
0.900
0.461
0.344
0.953
1.000
F. Size
Dbacba
0.183
0.127
0.079
0.478
0.537
0.528
0.547
0.780
0.766
1.000
GDPg
GDPpcg
Output
M2
Fdgdp
BcBd
FcFd
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Dbacba
F. Size
Dbacba
0.008
-0.012
0.374
0.583
0.576
0.234
0.079
0.600
0.533
1.000
GDPg
GDPpcg
Output
M2
Fdgdp
BcBd
FcFd
Pcrb
Pcrbof
Dbacba
M2: Money Supply. Fdgdp: Liquid liabilities. BcBd: Bank credit on Bank deposit (Banking System Efficiency). FcFd: Financial credit on
Financial deposits (Financial System Efficiency). Pcrb: Private domestic credit by deposit banks (Banking System Activity). Pcrbof: Private
credit from deposit banks and other financial institutions (Financial System Activity). Dbacba: Deposit bank asset on Total assets (Banking
System Size). Fin: Financial. Fin: Financial.
Appendix 4: Financial System Efficiency and GDP growth (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(FCFD)
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(GDPG)
.08
.08
.06
.06
.04
.04
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
-.04
-.04
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
Res pons e of D(GDPG) to D(FCFD)
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Res pons e of D(GDPG) to D(GDPG)
4
1
3
9
10
1
869
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Appendix 5: Banking System Activity and GDP growth (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(PCRDBGDP) to D(PCRDBGDP)
Res pons e of D(PCRDBGDP) to D(GDPG)
.016
.016
.012
.012
.008
.008
.004
.004
.000
.000
-.004
-.004
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
Res pons e of D(GDPG) to D(PCRDBGDP)
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
9
10
Res pons e of D(GDPG) to D(GDPG)
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Appendix 6: Financial System Efficiency and GDP per capita growth (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(FCFD)
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(GDPPCG)
.08
.08
.06
.06
.04
.04
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
-.04
-.04
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(FCFD)
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(GDPPCG)
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Appendix 7: Banking System Activity and GDP per capita growth (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(PCRDBGDP) to D(PCRDBGDP)
Res pons e of D(PCRDBGDP) to D(GDPPCG)
.016
.016
.012
.012
.008
.008
.004
.004
.000
.000
-.004
-.004
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(PCRDBGDP)
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(GDPPCG)
4
1
2
10
1
870
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Appendix 8: Financial System Activity and GDP per capita growth (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(PCRDBOFGDP) to D(PCRDBOFGDP)
Res pons e of D(PCRDBOFGDP) to D(GDPPCG)
.020
.020
.015
.015
.010
.010
.005
.005
.000
.000
-.005
-.005
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(PCRDBOFGDP)
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Res pons e of D(GDPPCG) to D(GDPPCG)
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Appendix 9: Financial System Efficiency and real GDP output (EAMZ)
Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(FCFD)
Res pons e of D(FCFD) to D(LOGREALGDP)
.08
.08
.04
.04
.00
.00
-.04
-.04
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
Res pons e of D(LOGREALGDP) to D(FCFD)
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Res pons e of D(LOGREALGDP) to D(LOGREALGDP)
.06
.06
.04
.04
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
References
Agénor, P, R., McDermott, C. J., and Ucer, E. M. (1997) “Fiscal Imbalances, Capital Inflows,
and the Real Exchange Rate: The Case of Turkey” IMF Working Paper 97/1.
Alagidede, P., Coleman, S., and Cuestas, J. C. (2011) “Inflationary shocks and common
economic trends: Implications for West African Monetary Union membership”, Journal of
Policy Modeling: Forthcoming.
Andersen, T., and Tarp, F. (2003) “Financial Liberalization, Financial Development and
Economic growth in LDCs” Journal of International Development 15, 189-209.
Asongu, S. A. (2011a) “Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be wrong in our era. New
evidence from Meta-analysis” MPRA Paper No. 32559.
871
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
Asongu, S. A. (2011b) “Why do French civil-law countries have higher levels of financial
efficiency?” Journal of Advanced Research in Law and Economics 2(2), 94-108.
Asongu, S. A. (2012a) “Are Proposed African Monetary Unions Optimal Currency Areas?
Real, Monetary and Fiscal Policy Convergence Analysis” African Journal of Economic and
Management Studies: Forthcoming.
Asongu, S. A. (2012b) “REER Imbalances and Macroeconomic Adjustments in the Proposed
West African Monetary Union” African Governance and Development Institute Working
Paper.
Asongu, S. A. (2012c) “African Financial Development Dynamics: Big Time Convergence”
African Journal of Economic and Management Studies: Forthcoming.
Baonza, J. D. (2011) “Finance and Growth: A Schumpeterian Trip to Africa”, Barcelona GSE.
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1898932 (Accessed on: 02/11/2012).
Buigut, S. K., and Valev, N. T. (2005) “Is the Proposed East African Monetary Union an
Optimal Currency Area? A Structural Vector Autoregression Analysis” World Development
33(12), 260-267.
Celasun, O., and Justiniano, A. (2005) “Synchronization of output fluctuations in West Africa:
Implications for monetary unification” IMF Working Paper.
De Avila, D. R. (2003) “Finance and Growth in the EU: New Evidence from the Liberalization
and Harmonization of the Banking Industry” European Central Bank Working Paper No. 266.
Debrun, X., Masson, P., and Pattillo, C. (2005) “Monetary union in West Africa: Who might
gain, who might lose and why?” Canadian Journal of Economics 38(2), 454-481.
Engle, R. F., and Granger, W. J. (1987) “Cointegration and error correction: Representation,
estimation and testing” Econometrica 55, 251-276.
Fouda, O. J. P. (2009) “The excess liquidity of banks in Franc zone: how to explain the paradox
in the CEMAC” Revue Africaine de l’Integration 3(2), 1-56.
Grossman, G. N., and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy The
MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., and Shin, Y. (2003) “Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels”
Journal of Econometrics 115, 53-74.
King, R. G., and Levine, R. (1993) “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics MIT Press 108(3), 717-737.
Levin, A., Lin, C. F., and Chu, C. S. (2002) “Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and
finite-sample properties” Journal of Econometrics, 108, 1-24.
Liew, V. K. (2004) “Which lag selection criteria should we employ?” Economics Bulletin
872
Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 1 pp. 859-873
3(33), 1-9.
Lucas, R. E. (1988) “On the Mechanics of Economic Growth” Journal of Monetary
Economics 22, 3-42.
Maddala, G. S., and Wu, S. (1999) “A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and
a new simple test” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61, 631-52.
Mkenda, B. K. (2001) “Is EA an optimum currency area?” Working Papers in Economics, No.
41 School of Economics and Commercial Law, Goteborg University.
Pagano, M. (1993) “Financial Markets and Growth: An Overview” European Economic
Review 37, 613-622.
Romer, P. M. (1990) “Endogenous Technological Change” Journal of Political Economy
98(5), S71-S102.
Saxegaard, M. (2006) “Excess liquidity and effectiveness of monetary policy: evidence from
sub-Saharan Africa” IMF Working Paper 06/115.
Starr, M. (2005) “Does money matter in the CIS? Effects of monetary policy on output and
prices” Journal of Comparative Economics 33, 441-461.
Tsangarides, C. G., and Qureshi, M. S. (2008) “Monetary Union Membership in West Africa:
A Cluster Analysis” World Development 36(7), 1261-1279.
Vickers, J. (2000) “Monetary union and economic growth”, National Bank of Belgium
Working Paper Research No. 10.
Weeks, J. (2010) “Why Monetary Policy is Irrelevant in Africa South of the Sahara”, School of
Oriental and African Studies, Center for Development and Policy Research, Development
Viewpoint No. 53. http://www.soas.ac.uk/cdpr/publications/dv/file59766.pdf (accessed:
29/10/2012).
Willett, T. D., (2011). “Some Lessons for Economists from the Financial Crisis”. In Indian
Growth and Development Review 3(2), 186-208.
Willett, T. D., and Srisorn, N., (2011, June). “Some Lessons for Asia from the Euro Crisis”,
TheClaremont Colleges, Workshop on Global Growth and Economic Governance Implications
for Asia: George Mason University.
873