Is Consensus an Appropriate Basis for Regulatory Policy?
Cary Coglianese
April 2001
RPP-2001-02
Regulatory Policy Program
Center for Business and Government
John F. Kennedy School of Government
79 John F. Kennedy Street, Weil Hall
Cambridge, MA 02138
Citation
This paper may be cited as: Coglianese, Cary. 2001. “Is Consensus an Appropriate Basis
for Regulatory Policy?” Regulatory Policy Program Working Paper RPP-2001-02.
Cambridge, MA: Center for Business and Government, John F. Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University. Comments may be directed to the author at Weil Hall,
Center for Business and Government, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard
University, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138; Email
[email protected].
Regulatory Policy Program
The Regulatory Policy Program at the Center for Business and Government provides an
environment in which to develop and test leading ideas on regulation and regulatory
institutions. RPP’s research aims to improve the global society and economy by
understanding the impacts of regulation and creating better decisions about the design
and implementation of regulatory strategies around the world. RPP’s efforts are
organized around the following three core areas: regulation, markets, and deregulation;
regulatory instruments; and regulatory institutions and policymaking.
The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not imply endorsement
by the Regulatory Policy Program, the Center for Business and Government, the John F.
Kennedy School of Government, or Harvard University.
For Further Information
Further information on the Regulatory Policy Program can be obtained from the
program’s director, Jennifer Nash, Center for Business and Government, John F.
Kennedy School of Government, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, telephone (617)
384-7325, telefax (617) 496-0063, Email
[email protected].
Is Consensus an Appropriate Basis for Regulatory Policy?
Cary Coglianese*
April 2001
RPP-2001-02
Abstract
Observers of environmental policy increasingly urge regulators to build consensus before
making policy decisions. By seeking consensus, regulators are supposed to be able to
reduce conflict, increase compliance, improve public policy, and promote public
participation.
Yet consensus-building markedly shifts the prevailing norms of
governance in the United States by de-centering the role of agency officials, making them
facilitators or negotiation partners rather than central, accountable decision makers
charged with seeking solutions that advance the overall public interest. A shift to
consensus as the basis for regulatory policy also creates or exacerbates at least six
pathologies in the policy process: tractability over importance, imprecision, lowest
common denominator, increased time and resources, unrealistic expectations, and
additional sources of conflict. The widespread establishment of consensus as the goal of
regulatory policy making would constitute a shift in the prevailing mode of governance
that is neither necessary nor wise.
*Associate Professor of Public Policy and Chair of the Regulatory Policy Program
This paper is forthcoming in Eric W. Orts and Kurt Deketelaere, eds., Environmental
Contracts: Comparative Approaches to Regulatory Innovation in the United States and
Europe, Kluwer Law International, 2001.
Is Consensus an Appropriate Basis for Regulatory Policy?
Cary Coglianese
Harvard University
Regulators in the United States are increasingly urged to build consensus before
making policy decisions. The process of consensus-building aims to create an explicit
agreement over the substance of regulatory policy among the individuals and groups who
will be affected by the policy. This craving for consensus was institutionalized in 1990
with the passage of the Negotiated Rulemaking Act1 which authorizes agencies to
establish formal negotiation processes over the terms of proposed regulations. Since that
time, more than two dozen other federal statutes either compel or strongly encourage
agencies to use consensus-based procedures.2
5 U.S.C. §§ 561-570 (1996). The Negotiated Rulemaking Act was permanently
reauthorized by the Administrative Dispute Resolution Act of 1996, Pub. Law No. 104320 (1996).
1
The number of statutory provisions requiring the use of consensus-based decisionmaking continues to grow. For a list of a selected statutes requiring the use of negotiated
rulemaking proceedings, see Coglianese (1997:1268 n. 75). For additional legislation
requiring or encouraging consensus-based decisions, see the Transportation Equity Act
for the 21st Century, Pub. Law No. 105-178 (1998); Higher Education Amendments of
1998, Pub. Law No. 105-244 (1998); VA, HUD, and Independent Agencies
Appropriations Act, Pub. Law No. 105-276 (1998); Omnibus Supplemental
Appropriations, Pub. Law No. 105-277 (1998); Carl D. Perkins Vocational and Applied
Technology Education Amendments of 1998, Pub. Law No. 105-332 (1998); Traumatic
Brain Injury Programs Authorization, Pub. Law No. 104-166 (1996); VA, HUD, and
Independent Agencies Appropriations Act, Pub. Law No. 104-204 (1996); Sustainable
Fisheries Act, Pub. Law No. 104-297 (1996); Omnibus Parks and Public Lands
Management Act of 1996, Pub. Law No. 104-333 (1996); Fisheries Act of 1995, Pub.
Law No. 104-43 (1995); Goals 2000 Educate America Act, Pub. Law No. 103-227
(1994); Marine Mammals Protection Act Amendments of 1994, Pub. Law No. 103-238
(1994); Federal Aviation Administration Authorization Act of 1994, Pub. Law No. 103305 (1994); Federal Acquisition Streamlining Act of 1994, Pub. Law No. 103-355
(1994); Yavapai-Prescott Indian Tribe Water Rights Settlement Act of 1994, Pub. Law
No. 103-434 (1994). In addition, the National Technology Transfer and Advancement
2
The desire for consensus has also taken an especially strong hold in efforts to
adopt new approaches to environmental regulation. Nearly every major commission
report and panel study issued on environmental policy in recent years has called for
greater reliance on consensus-building.3 In recent years, the United States Environmental
Protection Agency has launched several consensus-based projects, such as the Common
Sense Initiative and Project XL. Furthermore, a range of natural resource initiatives in
the areas of ecosystem management and habitat conservation have also relied on
collaborative approaches to policy-making. We are living, some might have it, at the
dawn of an age of consensus.
In the face of a prevailing enchantment with what Louis Jaffe (1937) once called
the 'beauties of co-operation,' it is worth pausing to reflect on whether consensus really is
an appropriate mode of making public policy. Much of what has been written so far on
consensus in regulatory policy-making focuses on its advantages, with comparatively
little attention having been paid to any potential hazards of consensus as a decision rule.
In this chapter, I seek to broaden attention to the implications of efforts to increase the
search for and reliance on consensus in the making of regulatory policy. Drawing on the
Act of 1995, Pub. Law No. 104-113 (1996), declares that 'all Federal agencies and
departments shall use technical standards that are developed or adopted by voluntary
consensus standards bodies...as a means to carry out policy objectives or activities' unless
doing so would be 'inconsistent with applicable law or otherwise impractical.'
Reports issued by the National Performance Review (1993), Carnegie
Commission on Science, Technology and Government (1993), National Academy of
Public Administration (1995), President's Council on Sustainable Development (1996),
Joint Presidential/Congressional Risk Commission (1997), and the Enterprise for the
Environment (1998) -- to name just a few -- all recommend expanding the use of various
forms of consensus-building.
3
experiences of several recent consensus-building processes, I examine what is to be
gained from the institutionalization of consensus-building -- as well as what is to be lost.
Even though I seek to raise questions about consensus in this chapter, I recognize
that it does, in principle, hold a certain allure. Reaching consensus implies that people
have worked out their differences and come to a collective decision. Consensus conjures
up notions of teamwork, community, and harmony, all attractive ideas in themselves.
Yet as alluring as consensus may be in principle, any widespread institutionalization of
consensus-building as a basis for policy-making would mark a significant shift in
prevailing modes of governmental decision-making in the United States. Such a shift, I
argue here, appears neither necessary nor wise. It is not necessary because the benefits
attributed to consensus-based processes can be obtained from other forms of public
participation which do not revolve around a quest for consensus. It is not wise because
reliance on consensus as a decision rule exposes policy-making to new sources of failure
and fosters unrealistic expectations for governance in a complex political system.
I.
Consensus and Regulatory Policy
At the outset, it is important to be clear about what consensus means.
Contemporary policy lingo can create confusion about the different ways to involve nongovernmental actors in policy-making. A host of related terms are casually tossed about:
'stakeholder involvement,' 'outreach,' 'partnerships,' 'consultation,' 'public participation,'
'constructive engagement,' 'collaboration,' 'regulatory negotiation,' 'policy deliberation,'
'consensus.' Far too seldom are these terms defined with any precision. In order to
evaluate the relative contribution of consensus, it is necessary to clarify what it means
and how it might differ from other, related terms.
Consensus commonly means unanimity or, at a minimum, something that
everyone can 'live with,' even if it is not the ideal policy that everyone would want. The
Negotiated Rulemaking Act defines 'consensus' as a 'unanimous concurrence' of the
interests represented on a negotiated rulemaking committee, or any lesser agreement that
has been unanimously agreed to by the committee.4 The achievement of such a
unanimous agreement is the defining feature of negotiated rulemaking. Before convening
a negotiated rulemaking committee, agencies are required to consider whether a
committee could be formed consisting of 'persons who. . .are willing to negotiate in good
faith to reach a consensus.'5 Once formed, the committee is legally obligated to 'attempt
to reach a consensus.'6
Outside of federal negotiated rulemaking, 'consensus' has also been stipulated by
statute and practice to mean unanimity.7 The EPA established the Common Sense
Initiative (CSI) in 1994 as a vehicle for 'reinventing' environmental regulation in six
industrial sectors. The Initiative, which ran until 1998, was overseen by an advisory
4
5 U.S.C. § 582.
5
5. U.S.C. § 583 (a)(3).
6
5 U.S.C. § 586 (a).
See Omnibus Consolidated Appropriations Act of 1997, Pub. Law. No. 104-208 §
201(a)(6) (1996) (defining 'consensus' in the procedures for the Upper Klamath Basin
Working Group to mean 'unanimous agreement by the Working Group members
present'). Where 'consensus' has been defined in state negotiated rulemaking legislation,
unanimity has also been the characteristic feature. See Mont. Code Anno. § 2-5-103
(1995); Tex. Govt. Code § 2008.056 (1997); Neb. Rev. Stat. § 84-923 (1994).
7
committee comprised of representatives from the various industrial sectors,
environmental groups, and federal, state, and local government. The operating principles
of the advisory committee, called the Common Sense Initiative Council, declared that the
Council would 'operate by consensus decision-making,' which meant that decisions were
'reached when all Council members at the table can accept or support a particular
position' (US EPA 1996). In a similar way, some of the EPA's Project XL initiatives
have conceived of consensus in terms of the unanimous agreement of interests involved
in the consultation processes that accompany these projects. Under Project XL, the EPA
may waive certain regulatory requirements for individual firms that can demonstrate that
alternative technologies or processes would allow them to achieve superior
environmental performance. The EPA will approve Project XL waivers only after
negotiating an agreement with the regulated firm and gaining the support of local
community and environmental groups.8
Understood to require unanimity among designated interests, consensus specifies
a decision rule. It therefore can be distinguished from other terms -- such as 'stakeholder
involvement,' 'constructive engagement,' and 'public participation' -- which describe
deliberative efforts that are not dependent on a particular decision rule. Stakeholders can
be 'involved' by giving them a chance to be heard, giving them a vote, or giving them a
veto. Only the last of these involves consensus. Consensus-based processes are those
deliberative efforts that seek an agreement among all the participants. Conceived this
The EPA has not required formal unanimity among affected parties for all of its
XL projects; however, serious opposition to an XL proposal will usually mean EPA will
not approve it. For a description of the consensus-based endorsement processes used in
the Intel and Merck XL projects, see US EPA (1998a).
8
way, the term 'collaboration' can be used synonymously with consensus. For example,
the Environmental Protection Agency, in a recent draft manual, defined collaboration as
'a joint endeavor, a sharing in the process, and its goal is working together towards an
agreement -- consensus' (US EPA 1998b:8).9
Unfortunately, consensus is sometimes characterized in such a way that it might
appear to be the only alternative to governmental fiat. Such characterizations are
obviously misleading. Regulatory agencies can (and do) incorporate extensive public
consultation into their decision-making processes without needing to strive for
consensus.10 Regulators can infuse the regulatory process with public deliberation in
three conceptually distinct ways:
•
Feedback. When public participation serves as a check on decisionmaking that the government has already initiated, we can consider
such public involvement to be a form of feedback. The bare bones,
notice-and-comment rulemaking procedures of the Administrative
Somewhat confusingly, 'collaboration' is also sometimes used to refer to
meaningful deliberation. For example, the Presidential/Congressional Commission on
Risk Assessment and Risk Management (1997:17) has stated that in its view
'[c]ollaboration does not require consensus, but it does require that all parties listen to,
consider, and respect each other's opinions, ideas, and contributions.'
9
Policies based on consensus are certainly responsive to public input, but policies
can be equally responsive -- if not more so -- without being based on consensus. Since it
is normally impossible for policy-makers to secure the agreement of all the firms and
individuals affected by a policy, especially in the area of environmental policy,
consensus-based processes are inherently limited in terms of who participates. To the
extent that agencies base their decisions solely on agreements reached between a limited
segment of the affected public, consensus-based policy may very well turn out to be less
responsive than decisions that follow a wide-ranging, open deliberation which is
unconstrained by the need to reach agreement.
10
Procedure Act11 reflect this notion of public involvement. The Act
merely requires agencies to provide notice of a regulatory proposal and
to give members of the public an opportunity to comment on it before
a regulation becomes final.
•
Input. Unlike feedback, input occurs before or contemporaneously
with governmental decision-making. Members of the public provide
their views as the problem is being framed and possible policy
solutions are being developed. Such input can be sought by the
government itself or it can be initiated by the parties. It can also be
collected individually from each interested party in one-on-one
conversations with government officials. Or it can be gathered
collectively, in roundtables or dialogue sessions which allow multiple
parties to engage each other in a conversation. However conducted,
input processes aim to help government officials make more informed
decisions.
•
Consensus. A consensus-based process will typically involve
collective input, but the ultimate aim of the conversation is different.
With consensus, the goal is to establish agreement among all of the
participants, with the expectation that the government will use that
agreement as the basis for its policy decision.
11
5 U.S.C. § 553.
In questioning consensus, I am not challenging the idea that public feedback or input is
desirable. Rather I am asking whether we should design policy-making in such a way as
to seek agreement before setting public policy. Should we, in other words, structure
domestic regulatory policy-making along the lines of NATO or UN Security Council
decision-making?
As I have already noted, it is increasingly suggested that we should. A recent
report by the Keystone National Policy Dialogue on Ecosystem Management (1996), for
example, asserted that '[c]learly, consensus is the most desirable outcome of a
collaborative process.' A US EPA (1997) paper describing the Common Sense Initiative
stated that the initiative's 'first priority is to craft agreements that parties support, accept,
or are neutral on.' Yet giving high priority to consensus as a prerequisite to policymaking would markedly shift the prevailing norms of governance in two ways. First, an
emphasis on consensus would 'de-center' the state. The government would no longer be,
in practice or in theory, the central, accountable decision-maker but instead would
become just a facilitator of bargaining between interest groups, or at most just another
player in that bargaining game (Werhan 1996).12 Second, a focus on consensus would
shift the aim of policy-making away from that which will serve the public interest to that
which will be agreeable to those interests that are well represented in the political process
(Funk 1997). Negotiators and facilitators, after all, are not analysts seeking to craft the
To be sure, policy-making in the United States has long involved bargaining
(Dahl 1956) and much regulatory litigation is resolved through negotiated settlement
agreements (Coglianese 1996). However, the reliance on formal agreements to develop
and implement regulatory policy has at least until now remained rather limited.
12
best solutions to public problems. Indeed, sometimes they are skeptical of whether
policy-makers ought to strive to make correct decisions at all.13 As a result, when
reformers describe consensus as 'the most desirable outcome' and speak of securing
agreement as 'the first priority,' they signal a significant shift away from norms which
heretofore have made the development of sound public policy and the advancement of
social values the most important priorities for government decision-makers.
II. Is Consensus Necessary?
Since the frequent pursuit of consensus would mark a shift in the prevailing
practice of governance in the United States, it is helpful to consider first whether making
such a shift is even necessary. The argument for making such a shift hinges on various
claimed benefits that consensus can bring to policy-making, namely that consensusbuilding holds instrumental advantages over processes based on feedback or input. Philip
Harter (1997), for example, has argued for consensus over what he calls 'consultative
processes' -- that is, deliberative processes which do not seek consensus. The crux of his
argument is that processes of consultation lack many of the benefits attributed to
consensus.14 Consensual processes, it is often claimed, will reduce conflict, increase
For example, Philip Harter (1983:475) has suggested that agencies should not
think of themselves as seekers of correct decisions: 'The agency retains a wide range of
discretion and is called on to make choices that are inherently political. Political choices,
however, have no "right" or "wrong" or even "rational" answer.'
13
Harter (1997:1411,1420) has argued that 'the dynamics of the process change
markedly if either the definition of consensus is modified to require less than unanimity
14
compliance, improve public policy, and promote public participation. In this section, I
consider whether the goal of reaching a consensus is necessary in order to achieve these
principal benefits attributed to consensus-building. For each advantage attributed to
consensus-building, I conclude that the same benefits come from (or can come from)
something other than a quest for consensus.
A. Reduced Conflict
Perhaps the most intuitive benefit attributed to consensus is the reduction of
conflict. If all the interested parties can come to an agreement, or at least commit not to
disagree, then it would appear that conflict should be eliminated. The intuition is that
affected organizations will not subsequently challenge a policy with which they have
concurred.
Coming to a consensus, however, is certainly not the only way to avoid conflict.
A potential conflict arises, by definition, when a policy does not satisfy the interests of
affected individuals and groups. Government officials can avoid conflict by learning the
interests of the various parties and seeking to craft a policy that addresses these interests.
Most sophisticated government officials already do this all the time. That helps explain
or, if no attempt is made to reach full closure, to require a commitment to adhere to the
agreement' and that 'many of the benefits of the process are lost' by a reliance on
consultation instead of consensus. Cornelius Kerwin (1999:183) has similarly noted that
'advocates of negotiated rulemaking are skeptical of partial substitutes and decry the loss
of commitment that goes with them.'
why, contrary to popular conceptions, most policy decisions are not challenged in court.15
To avoid litigated conflict, government officials need not fully satisfy all the interests of
all affected individuals and organizations. Such a task is almost always impossible
anyway. Rather, they need only design a policy that those affected are willing to 'live
with.'
Proponents of negotiated rulemaking have pointed to the averaging provision in
EPA's reformulated gasoline regulation as an example of a key conflict-avoiding
innovation that came about because of a pursuit for consensus (Weber 1998).16 The
provision gave refiners more flexibility by allowing them to meet fuel standards on
average over entire stocks of fuel rather than gallon by gallon. In return for this
flexibility, refiners were required to meet average standards that were 10 percent more
stringent, thus allaying some environmentalists' concerns. Philip Harter, one of the
leading defenders and practitioners of negotiated rulemaking, has argued that the
averaging approach, combined with a somewhat more stringent standard, was a
significant innovation that EPA would not have developed had it not needed to find
consensus.17 Environmental regulators, though, did not need a consensus-driven process
to lead them to conceive or adopt this averaging plan. The emissions trading policies that
Despite assertions made by many knowledgeable observers that almost all EPA
regulations are challenged in court, only a minority ever are (Coglianese 1997).
15
16
For the text of the reformulated gasoline rule, see 54 Federal Register 7716
(1994).
Harter advanced this argument in remarks delivered to the administrative law
section of the Association of American Law Schools at its meeting on January 9, 1998, in
an effort to continue to advocate the use of negotiated rulemaking notwithstanding
research showing that negotiated rulemaking has failed to achieve its purposes of saving
time and reducing litigation.
17
EPA adopted more than a decade before the reformulated gasoline rule all relied
essentially on averaging.18 The EPA used averaging for fuel standards at least since the
1970s, and such an approach was integral to the EPA's phasedown of leaded gasoline in
the 1980s (Hahn & Hester 1989). Moreover, agency officials hardly needed to conduct
formal negotiations to realize that environmentalists would more readily support
averaging if it was accompanied by lower standards. The EPA had adopted essentially the
same kind of averaging approach, with a corresponding 20% reduction for the
environment, four years earlier in its regulations governing the trading and banking of
emissions from heavy duty diesel engines.19 In this earlier case, as with other marketbased policies, EPA officials developed the averaging policy through routine, informal
consultations with industry and environmental groups, not through any formal
negotiation that sought consensus. Attentive and savvy government officials pursue such
innovative arrangements and other strategies to reduce conflict even without formally
negotiating agreements. Having groups sign on to an agreement may well be one way to
determine what the parties can accept and to design policies that resolve conflicts, but it
is by no means the only way.
Moreover, in the normal course of policy-making interest groups do not pursue
every potential conflict they may have with an agency. A considerable amount of
'lumping it' always occurs and parties will often forgo their opportunity to contest each
minute aspect of a policy with which they might disagree (cf. Felstiner, Abel, & Sarat
For a review of emissions trading and other market-based policies, see Hahn &
Stavins (1991). Administrative lawyers should already be quite familiar with emissions
averaging, as such an approach undergirded the EPA's 'bubble' rule which was challenged
in Chevron v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837 (1984).
18
19
55 Federal Register 30,584 (July 26, 1990)
1980-81). An organization's disagreement with an agency must be sufficiently great to
justify the costs of a subsequent challenge as well as the risks of creating an adverse
decision or prompting those with opposing interests to raise challenges of their own
(Cooter & Rubinfeld 1989). For this reason, consensus is not only unnecessary for
avoiding conflict, but it can be counterproductive as well. Processes that seek out
consensus can actually make conflict more protracted. In order for representatives of
industry and citizen groups to 'sign on' to a policy they need to achieve an outcome which
is tangibly better than what they would otherwise have received. All things being equal,
it is always harder to convince representatives of constituent-based organizations that
they should affirmatively endorse a policy rather than simply forego raising objections or
legal challenges to that same policy. Thus, it is not surprising that conflicting views have
arisen over the meaning of 'superior environmental performance' in EPA's Project XL,
with environmentalists insisting that to gain their support firms must achieve
performance superior to what their facilities have already achieved (which is often
cleaner than the regulations allow) and not merely performance superior to what is
legally allowable. Industry also finds it harder to make affirmative endorsements than to
offer tacit acceptance. Representatives of a utility trade association pursued difficult
negotiations to secure a preliminary agreement with the Nuclear Regulatory Commission
on proposed regulations, only later to balk at formally 'signing on' to the agreement in the
face of objections from some of the trade association's corporate members (Harrington
1994).
Conflict can best be avoided if state officials listen carefully to the concerns of
affected parties and craft policies that address these concerns. Once organizations are put
on the spot and expected to affirm a policy, they will likely demand an even better
outcome for their interests. If many of the participants in a negotiation act in this way, it
will prove still more difficult under a consensus process to resolve the conflicts between
groups. This helps explain why consensus-based processes tend to consume more time
and resources for everyone involved.
B. Increased Compliance
A related benefit sometimes attributed to consensus-building is that it will
increase compliance by the regulated industry. People tend to be more likely to follow
through on those things for which they claim ownership. So if a regulated industry signs
onto a consensus policy, it would be predicted to be more likely to comply with that
policy, as well as to comply more quickly and more fully than it otherwise would.
The existence of subsequent litigation over negotiated rulemakings seems to draw
this prediction into question, for it shows that a 'buy in' to a consensus agreement does
not necessarily mean complete 'buy in' to the final policy. Environmental regulations
developed using consensus-based procedures have resulted in more litigation than have
comparable regulations promulgated using other forms of public participation
(Coglianese 1997). Of course, litigation is not direct evidence of the specific compliance
effects of a consensus decision rule, but unfortunately researchers have yet to study
systematically whether consensus-based policies elicit greater compliance. That said,
there are plausible grounds to question whether consensus is all that significant in
promoting industry compliance with a policy decision.
Compliance rates are affected by any number of factors, such as industry
knowledge of a standard, the cost of complying with the standard, the probability that
noncompliance will be detected, and the penalties for noncompliance. When a regulation
is backed by effective monitoring and the possibility of penalties of ten to twenty-five
thousand dollars per day (as are many environmental regulations), it is not unreasonable
to ask whether the mere fact that the policy emerged from a consensus process should
matter at all. Lead has been phased out of gasoline, passive restraints have been installed
in cars, and cigarette smoking in some states has been virtually eliminated from public
buildings, all without attempts at consensus-building preceding the policy decision.
Effective compliance can certainly be achieved without efforts at building consensus.
At most, the 'buy in' that accompanies consensual decision-making process may
increase compliance at the margins. Yet we still have to wonder whether even this
marginal effect exists. The 'buy in' that some consensus processes require, after all, is
simply a willingness to let the policy move forward. A decision that an industrial sector
can 'live with' is not the same as a decision it affirmatively likes. It is not altogether clear
why organizations which are simply willing to 'live with' a policy developed through
negotiation would have all that much more incentive to comply with it than with a policy
that was not negotiated.
It is also far from clear that any effects of a 'buy in' by those sitting around the
table in Washington, D.C., will necessarily carry through to the individuals across the
country who have, at the ground level, the day-to-day responsibility for complying with
government regulation. When consensus is used as the basis for industry-wide or sectorwide regulation, can we expect that the plant-level managers who carry out the
implementation and monitoring of the regulation will take 'ownership' of that regulation?
Will they even know that the regulation was negotiated with representatives from their
industry's trade association in Washington? More empirical research obviously needs to
be done to answer these questions, but it clearly is not self-evident that the 'buy in' to a
consensus regulation will have any substantial effect on compliance.
C. Improved Policy
Even if the 'buy in' prediction does not hold, consensus might still affect
compliance indirectly by the kind of policy that is likely to emerge from a consensus
process. Perhaps consensus-based policies are simply better and more sensible because
they are based on better information and a more realistic understanding of the specific
demands of an industry and concerns of affected citizens. Proponents of consensusbuilding have increasingly argued that such processes will lead to better policy
decisions.20 The intensive discussions with regulated industry, as well as the give-andtake dialogue with the other parties, brings detailed information to the table that should
lead to a better policy decision. A consensus-based process, it is argued, takes advantage
of the collective wisdom of those who are sitting around the negotiating table, as opposed
to relying mainly on agency staff's best guess of plant conditions or other technical
Harter (1997:1418) has asserted that '[a] negotiated rulemaking forces the parties
to bring an enormous amount of practical information to the table and hence expands the
data base on which to build a regulation. The practical insight contributed by those with
first-hand experience also allows agency staff to focus resources on areas with the
greatest potential payback.'
20
aspects of industry operations. Consensus-building efforts are therefore thought to
promote learning and yield more informed decisions.
Empirical evidence to sustain the claim that consensus-based processes yield
systematically better policies has yet to emerge.21 Moreover, as I discuss in Part III of this
chapter, several pathologies can afflict consensus-based processes which will lead to
inferior policy results. The existence of these pathologies alone provides reason to doubt
whether consensus-based processes will tend to lead to better policies. Yet there are still
other reasons to question whether structuring a dialogue around a quest for consensus
will indeed yield full disclosure and debate of policy issues. The fact that the group is
charged with the task of achieving a consensus may actually inhibit some participants
from raising important issues which seem at the time likely to hinder consensus-building.
In his study of groupthink in government, Paul 't Hart (1994:293) writes that when policy
decisions are based on consensus some participants 'may refrain from voicing their
concerns, either by self-discipline and a desire not to shatter group harmony (suppression
of doubts) or following direct hints by the leader (compliance) or by fellow group
members (mindguards; peer pressure). When consensus is no longer required, group
discussion can be more open.' In regulatory negotiations, such inhibition does occur. In
one case, for example, an EPA official told me that he knew industry was overlooking an
entire category of equipment in setting consensus-based standards for equipment leaks,
Langbein and Kerwin (1998) report findings that show participants in negotiated
rulemakings tend to rate the quality of the final outcome higher than do participants in
other rulemakings. However, it is far from clear that ratings by participants are unbiased
measures of the actual quality of the policy outcomes achieved in these cases. Cognitive
dissonance seems likely to explain the favorable outcome ratings participants give to
negotiated rulemakings, as these proceedings involve considerably more time and effort
on their part.
21
but that he never said a word about it during the negotiations. In another illustrative case,
a citizen member of the Intel Project XL negotiation group reportedly signed the final
agreement, but only reluctantly after 'feeling pressure from all sides' (US EPA
1999:Appendix 1). Often what decision-makers need is conflict to illuminate policy
issues most fully. The full articulation of opposing views may provide more useful
information on which to construct public policy than the truncated discussion that can
develop when individuals feel pressured to achieve consensus.
Nevertheless, even if consensus-building processes do yield better, more informed
decisions, the question remains whether this benefit derives from, or depends on,
consensus itself. On its face, it is the deliberation -- not the consensus -- which advocates
claim yields the additional information needed to craft better policy decisions (Freeman
1997:40). Consensus-based procedures certainly can demand a lot more time and
resources on the part of participants than other procedures. If this same amount of time
and effort were devoted to policy deliberations that did not aim at consensus, it seems
quite plausible that the informational benefits would be the same, if not better. As we
know, alternatives which do not aim at consensus do exist. To the extent that public
officials employ deliberative processes that lead interested parties to identify their areas
of agreement and disagreement, this kind of intensive deliberation can provide
comparable, if not even superior, results in terms of contributing to better public policy
(cf. Reich 1985).
D. Expanded Participation
It has sometimes been suggested that a consensus rule, along with a commitment
by the agency to implement the consensus decision, is needed in order to attract people to
participate in deliberative processes.22 Consensus, according to this argument, amounts to
something like a 'field of dreams.' If you seek to build consensus, the players will come
to the table. If consensus is not the main goal, few will engage in the sport.
While it is certainly the case that in order to have a policy deliberation individuals
must be motivated to deliberate, a quest for consensus is by no means necessary in order
to achieve that motivation. A few years ago I helped facilitate a pilot workshop convened
by the National Performance Review and EPA's Region 1 office to which members of
industry, the environmental community, and local government were invited. This was to
be the first in a series of workshops across the country through which EPA would 'get in
touch' with the grassroots.23 Although the goals of this particular meeting were not
specified at all, and only short notice was given of the meeting, well more than fifty
participants crowded into the workshop room for the day long event. They needed not
the slightest assurance that they would be there to reach a consensus which the EPA
would implement, but rather took advantage of this opportunity to communicate their
concerns with regulators.
For example, Jody Freeman (1997:92) argues that 'agencies must presumptively
commit to agreements developed in these processes, and courts must presumptively defer
to them. If not, participants will never engage in the prolonged negotiation and planning
required to produce either a consensus rule or an FPA.' In a similar vein, Harter
(1997:1411) claims that '[t]he dynamics of the process change markedly if either the
definition of consensus is modified to require less than unanimity or, if no attempt is
made to reach full closure, to require a commitment to adhere to the agreement.'
22
For a discussion of the lack of focus in the Clinton Administration's early
partnership effort, see Sparrow (2000).
23
The possibility of influencing policy decisions is what drives participation in
policy-making. It is well documented that the past thirty years have seen considerable
growth in interest group representation in Washington, D.C. (King & Walker 1991).
These groups and their representatives have come to play the game even though
consensus has only recently become a trendy -- even though still relatively infrequent -way to play. Interest group representatives already have the incentives to engage in
policy deliberations without a consensus decision rule. It turns out, in fact, that most of
what the EPA considers its 'stakeholder involvement' projects do not formally adopt a
consensus rule. What group representatives need in order to be motivated to play is an
assurance that some decision is going to be made and that their input can help influence
that decision.24 Agencies can provide that assurance without requiring the parties to
search for consensus and agreeing to implement a consensus that develops. Agencies can
-- and do -- show that they have an open mind, that they have a decision yet to be made,
and that they are genuinely interested in learning about the various perspectives
(Applegate 1998).
Participation can be sought in a collective forum which allows for a give-and-take
dialogue as long as the agency demonstrates a willingness to listen and, as best it can
while still pursuing its public mandate, to incorporate what it learns into its decisions. As
I discuss in Part III, consensus rules can sometimes create unrealistic expectations about
what an agency is able or willing to deliver, and when these expectations are dashed it
can actually lead to less willingness in the future to engage in public deliberations.
Ironically, when a consensus decision rule is adopted, it may actually turn groups
away from participating. Some of the sector projects in the Common Sense Initiative
floundered for lack of interest once players saw that little would be accomplished given
the requirement for unanimity imposed on the initiative.
24
Policy-making by consensus can also lead, ironically, to the exclusion of some affected
parties from the decision-making process in order to facilitate agreement (Beardsley,
Davies & Hersh 1997; Rossi 1997; Harrison 1999). The best way for an agency to
motivate outside groups to participate in policy deliberations seems to be to set realistic
expectations, meet them, and demonstrate on a repeated basis that the deliberations have
an impact on -- even if they do not control -- the agency's final decisions. Promises about
consensus cannot stack up against an agency culture that takes deliberation and
consultation with affected parties seriously, even though the agency maintains its position
as the ultimate decision-maker.
When it comes to encouraging public participation -- as with reducing conflict,
increasing compliance, and developing better public policy -- a consensus decision rule
simply is not needed. Alternative forms of engagement with the public can yield the
same benefits that have been attributed to consensual policy processes. Advocates of
consensus-building have overstated the need for consensus by de-emphasizing alternative
forms of public participation that do not depend on consensus.
III. The Pathologies of Consensus
Just as the recent literature on regulatory consensus-building has overstated the
need for consensus, it has also tended to understate the hazards of consensus as a decision
rule. Perhaps this has been because those writing about consensus have largely sought to
convince legislators and regulatory agencies of the value of formal negotiated
proceedings -- and possibly also of the need for professional facilitation services which
some of those writing in this area provide (Rabe 1988). For example, Philip Harter, a
leading advocate for and practitioner of regulatory negotiation, argues that consensusbuilding leads to 'regulatory actions [that] are often simply better by virtually any
measure. These are, indeed, powerful tools' (Harter 1997:1423).
The generally one-sided view that emerges from contemporary advocacy of
consensus-building in the regulatory process, however, is not reflected in the broader
literature on group decision-making and policy deliberation. There is, for instance,
considerable work in social psychology examining both the strengths and weaknesses of
group decision-making, one of the latter being the potential for 'groupthink' (Janis 1972;
Hart 1994). In addition, the work of Jane Mansbridge (1980:163-82,252-69) on
democratic decision-making illuminates certain strengths of consensus decision-making
for small groups with relatively homogeneous interests, but also stresses substantial
disadvantages of consensus-building used more widely. Mansbridge studied
participatory decision-making in both a small workplace and the government of a small
New England town and found that decision-making by consensus presented numerous
disadvantages. It demanded considerably more time, opened decisions up to more
frequent revision, generated ambiguity and imprecision, and sometimes resulted in
deadlock or social coercion. She also confirmed that consensus tended to bias decisions
in favor of the status quo and strengthened those who were already powerful.
Mansbridge (1980:293) concluded that even though consensus may be suitable for the
governance of small groups of individuals who have ongoing relationships and common
interests, it is not suitable for governance of large nation-states or in highly conflictual
settings.
The disadvantages of consensus in the context of regulatory policy have not
received comparable consideration in the literature. However, experience is showing that
the same kinds of pathologies elsewhere associated with consensus decision-making also
find their way into the regulatory process. Even those who otherwise support consensusbuilding acknowledge that decisions agreed to by select groups of policy actors need not
necessarily comport with the public interest (e.g., Langbein & Kerwin 1998; Weber
1998). A consensus decision rule can create or exacerbate at least six pathologies in the
policy process: (a) tractability having priority over public importance; (b) regulatory
imprecision; (c) the lowest common denominator problem; (d) increased time and
expense; (e) unrealistic expectations; and (f) new sources of conflict. To be sure, not
every consensus-based process will suffer from these pathologies, and just as surely some
non-consensual processes will. Nevertheless, each of these problems, elaborated in the
sections that follow, derive from a quest for consensus and their risk is increased when
decision-making procedures effectively hand each participant a veto over the policy
decision.
A. Tractability over Importance
The first pathology created by a focus on consensus relates to the nature of the
issues selected for consideration. Consensus-based processes increase the likelihood that
the wrong issues will receive attention. Instead of devoting time and resources to the
issues of most importance to the public, a focus on consensus tends to lead to the
selection of the most tractable issues, the ones most amenable to agreement.
That such a selection process occurs is evident in the paucity of cases in which
consensus has been used to develop federal regulations. Proponents of negotiated
rulemaking have never claimed that consensus-building would be appropriate for more
than about five percent of all agency rulemakings, and in practice the use of the
procedure has been exceedingly rare (less than one-tenth of one percent of all
regulations). The small fraction of rules that agencies have selected for negotiated
rulemaking has not been comprised of the rules with the largest impact on the public. For
example, only five negotiated rulemakings have been classified as 'major' or 'significant'
rules according to the standards set forth by executive order (Coglianese 1997). The
Negotiated Rulemaking Act sets forth standards for selecting rules for negotiation, most
of which guide agency officials to select rules that are most likely capable of resulting in
a consensus. Among other things, agency officials contemplating negotiated rulemaking
are required to determine that there is '[a] reasonable likelihood that a committee will
reach a consensus on the proposed rule within a fixed period of time.'25 Standards such as
these place a primacy on tractability over social importance.
An emphasis on consensus not only leads to the selection of more tractable policy
matters for negotiation to begin with, it also leads to a selection of the more tractable
issues within the negotiating proceedings themselves. The Quincy Library Group, a high
profile group organized to develop a consensus over forest policy in California, focused
on those issues where agreement was possible. As two participants acknowledged, 'true
consensus' as a decision rule 'greatly limits the range of issues the group can take on'
25
5 U.S.C. § 563(a)(4) (1994).
(Terhune & Terhune 1998). The subset of issues addressed in consensus-building are
typically tractable ones, not necessarily the ones that are most important.
The problem with tractability is also evidenced in the recent report of the
Enterprise for the Environment (1998) initiative. In 1996, former EPA Administrator
William Ruckelshaus convened this initiative, dubbed 'E4E' for short, in order to bring
together leaders from industry, government, and the environmental community to forge a
consensus about how to improve environmental policy in the United States. The project
initially sought agreement on a diagnosis of the problems in the current system of
environmental protection and on a set of concrete legislative solutions. Not long into the
discussions, however, it became apparent to the participants that consensus would never
be achieved on either the specification of current problems or the precise form of
legislative proposals. Even though an illumination of existing problems and specific
legislative fixes was surely what was needed, the group shifted its goals to what was
more attainable (but ultimately less valuable): agreement on a broad 'vision' of an ideal
environmental protection system.26
It seems a truism that consensus will be more difficult to achieve on the most
vexing problems. In evaluating policy 'experiments' which rely on consensus-building,
one therefore needs to be mindful of potential selection bias. This is especially true with
initiatives that rely on volunteers. Not only are the firms that volunteer for initiatives
such as Project XL already likely to be ones that have better-than-average relationships
with their communities, the types of problems that they initially choose to address are not
26
For a discussion of the E4E process and report, see Coglianese (1999).
likely to tend towards the most complex or challenging.27 This raises a question. If sitespecific regulation of the kind envisioned by proponents of Project XL really can
improve efficiency and innovation, should resources go to projects based on whether they
do (or do not) draw initial support (or lack opposition) from various citizen groups? At
least in the early years of the XL initiative, a community group could write a strongly
worded three-paragraph letter asking the EPA 'to scratch this company from the list
immediately'28 -- and the project would never go forward. The EPA now assures XL
applicants that a single community group cannot kill an application, but the agency
nevertheless maintains that stakeholder support is a critical criterion for selecting
projects.29 Certainly there will still be opportunities to make cost-saving environmental
improvements in the projects that garner community support and are selected for Project
XL or other reform efforts. However, to the extent that consensus (or even just the
absence of controversy) drives decision-making, it is likely that the opportunities for
gains will be smaller than if other selection criteria were used.30
Blackman and Mazurek (1999) have noted that the EPA's Project XL has been
biased against the most complex and innovative projects.
27
The quoted language comes from a letter from Denny A. Larson, Communities
for a Better Environment, to President William Clinton, dated Oct. 26, 1995, in which
Larson expressed his organization's opposition to an XL proposal submitted by Citgo
Corporation. The EPA did not pursue Citgo's proposal.
28
29
Notice of Modifications to Project XL, 62 Fed. Reg. 19872 (April 23, 1997).
Of course, in saying this, I am mindful that community support (or lack of
significant opposition) could be thought necessary given the legal vulnerability of XL
agreements and site-specific rulemakings (Caballero 1998). However, I am also mindful
of a small survey of participants in four XL projects which resulted in at least one
interesting finding: nearly half of the respondents thought that the deliberation process
neglected issues that should have been addressed (US EPA 1998a:32). Had the EPA not
30
B. Imprecision
Just as a focus on tractability makes consensus easier to achieve, so too does
imprecision or ambiguity. In her study of democratic decision-making, Mansbridge
(1980:167) found that '[c]onsensual decision making. . .generates imprecision. In order
to reach unanimous agreement, groups formulate their collective decision so as to blur
potential disagreements.'
The E4E process, mentioned earlier, is a stark example of the pathology of
imprecision that comes from a quest for consensus. The final Enterprise for the
Environment (1998:3) report described the project's resulting consensus in terms with
which no one could seriously disagree: '[T]he environmental protection system of the
next century must become as efficient and low cost as possible without compromising
environmental progress.' Elsewhere the report offered other platitudes as
recommendations: policy-makers should 'adapt and adjust policies, strategies, and
systems based on experience and new information;' they should 'generate, disseminate,
and rely on the best-available scientific and economic information;' and society should
'place authority, responsibility, and accountability at the appropriate level of government.'
Of course, no one would seriously urge otherwise, although different people do disagree
about specifically how best to achieve better environmental protection at lower cost.
Rather than seek consensus for its own sake, what was needed was to illuminate areas of
disagreement and to conduct further analysis that might better inform decision-making.
placed such a priority on securing stakeholder support, there would presumably have
been less pressure to truncate the deliberative processes in these cases.
Admittedly, the language found in a consensus-based policy report reflects an
extreme case, and the regulations and environmental agreements that have been crafted
using consensus-based processes have been clearer and more specific. However, the
pressure always exists that, in order to secure an agreement, negotiators will adopt
abstract or unclear language. It will usually be easier to achieve consensus at higher
levels of abstraction, and it is always less time-consuming and less controversial to adopt
imprecise language (Diver 1983). Adopting abstract principles and vague standards may
serve to secure agreement in the face of conflict, but doing so will constrain the
usefulness of the public policy that emerges from consensual processes.
C. Lowest Common Denominator
By handing each participant a veto, consensus-based processes also make it more
likely that the final outcome will amount to no more than the lowest common
denominator acceptable to all the parties. Consensual decision rules have the effect of
giving domestic policy-making the same structural form as international policy-making.
It is common for multilateral international agreements to require no more than what is
acceptable to the state with the most objections to regulation. For example, initial drafts
of the ISO 14001 environmental management system standards would have required
public accessibility of environmental data, third party certification, and sector-specific
pollution standards -- requirements that some have argued are needed to make
environmental management systems credible. However, these requirements were
dropped in response to objections from the United States and Japan (Roht-Arriaza 1995).
The problem with the lowest common denominator, of course, is that such a minimallyacceptable outcome will not be enough when a more dramatic decision is needed. In a
recent study of negotiated rulemaking, Caldart and Ashford (1999:201) concluded that
because industry representatives will not likely 'sign on' to any regulations that would
force dramatic changes upon business, 'negotiated rulemaking's focus on consensus can
effectively remove the potential to spur innovation.'
D. Time and Resources
The lowest common denominator problem, along with the pathologies of
tractability and imprecision, arise because it takes time and resources to achieve
consensus. Deliberation takes time for everyone to present their concerns and for others
to respond, and consensus demands that the deliberation continue until everyone agrees
(or at least agrees to 'live with' a decision). Time, in itself, is not inherently a pathology,
at least not if the additional time yields valuable information and better results. All things
being equal, though, the additional time it takes to develop a decision through consensus
is certainly an important drawback, especially when it takes longer to reach closure on
only the most tractable issues.
Those who have participated in consensus-building processes complain about the
amount of time and effort they take. In one study, participants in negotiated rulemakings
were three times more likely to complain that the process took too much time, effort, and
resources than were those respondents who participated in conventional rulemakings
(Kerwin & Langbein 1997). One of the most common complaints about the EPA's now-
defunct Common Sense Initiative was that it took a frustratingly long time to accomplish
anything (Todd 1997). EPA's Project XL has generated similar reactions.31 Studies of
negotiated rulemaking confirm that consensus-building fails to save time (Coglianese,
1997; Balla & Wright 1999). No one should expect that decision-making by consensus
will help speed up the policy process.
E. Unrealistic Expectations
By making consensus the goal of participatory processes, public officials can give
rise to unrealistic expectations about how much any agreement will affect the ultimate
policy decision. Even though widespread reliance on consensus would have the effect of
'de-centering' the state by making it more of a player and facilitator than a decisionmaker, the agreements made through collaborative partnerships are usually not selfimplementing statements of policy. Government officials must still formally enact and
implement these agreements. In so doing, the policy may change -- even slightly -- from
the proposal on which the parties thought they had agreed. After a consensus is forged,
maintaining that consensus throughout the remaining steps of the policy process can
prove difficult. Other actors not party to the agreement, such as legislators, other interest
According to the US EPA's (1998a:41) review of Project XL, '[m]ost stakeholders
commented the process was too long or much longer than they expected or felt was
warranted.' To be sure, not all of the time and expense associated with developing XL
agreements have been due to the pursuit of consensus, and only some XL projects have
sought to achieve consensus from a broad range of affected parties. However, the need to
reach an agreement with EPA and other governmental agencies has still contributed to a
more costly and time-consuming process than participants would like.
31
groups, and executive branch officials, may also try to take another bite at the apple
(Kagan 1997).
When this happens and the policy outcome diverges from the agreement,
participants in the consensus proceeding will undoubtedly have certain expectations
disappointed, expectations that would have been much less likely to have developed had
the process simply sought public input to assist the agency in reaching its decision. In a
study of several consensus-building initiatives at the National Marine Fisheries Service,
sixty percent of the participants who were surveyed reported that they were dissatisfied
with the results of the process (RESOLVE 1999). The study's authors found that much of
the dissatisfaction arose because participants expected to control the outcomes much
more than was realistically possible. It was also precisely such a case of dashed
expectations that led to the underlying litigation in the first major appellate decision to
interpret the Negotiated Rulemaking Act. In USA Group Loan Servicers, Inc. v. Riley,32
participants in a Department of Education negotiated rulemaking sued the agency
claiming that it had reneged on commitments made during the negotiated rulemaking.
The Seventh Circuit held that federal agencies could not be compelled to adopt a
consensus agreement nor held to positions taken during negotiations because the agency
retains the ultimate decision-making authority. To the extent that it will remain possible
for government officials to enact policies that depart from the precise (or perhaps not-soprecise) understandings of those involved in policy negotiations, a process centered on
the quest for consensus only sets up expectations that in the end probably cannot help but
32
82 F.3d 708 (7th Cir. 1996).
be somewhat unfulfilled. In this way, an increased reliance on processes that aim for
consensus could very well undermine trust and increase cynicism in the policy process.
F. Additional Sources of Conflict
The case of USA Group Loan Servicers shows that conflicts not only persist
following consensus-building, but that they can even be engendered by the expectations
such processes create. Consensus is not always attainable, and even when it is it may
only temporarily hide underlying conflicts. Perhaps the most notable disappointment in
terms of avoiding conflict has been the EPA's reformulated gasoline regulation. Heralded
by some as a 'successful collaboration' (Weber 1998), this negotiated rulemaking hardly
succeeded at all in eliminating conflict. The final rule elicited extensive criticism in the
press and from the public, prompted four legal challenges and a petition for
administrative review, and resulted in an adverse ruling by the World Trade Organization
(Coglianese 1997). The reformulated gasoline regulation is not unique. As noted earlier,
environmental regulations developed through consensus-based processes overall end up
being challenged in court more frequently than do comparable regulations formulated
through procedures that do not depend on consensus.
Consensus-based processes create new sources of conflict that do not exist with
other methods of policy-making. Conflicts first arise over who participates in the
negotiations. A recent set of negotiated rulemakings at the Department of Housing and
Urban Development (HUD) spawned what appears to be the first legal action filed to
secure a spot on a negotiated rulemaking committee.33 HUD had originally named four
public housing organizations to participate on negotiated rulemaking committees for
regulations addressing subsidies and capital funds. After the housing organizations
subsequently filed a petition against the agency over a separate matter, HUD officials
declared that the organizations could no longer bargain in good faith and removed them
from the negotiated rulemaking committees. The organizations filed for a court order
reversing the agency's decision to remove them from the committee, claiming that HUD's
action discriminated against them for exercising their fundamental right of petition.
HUD subsequently capitulated and reinstated the organizations to the negotiated
rulemaking committees, but the experience demonstrates one significant new source of
conflict caused by a process designed around the search for consensus.
In addition to conflicts over who gets to participate, processes structured around
consensus can create conflicts over the meaning of any agreements that are reached and
over whether final government decisions comport with those agreements. Disagreements
also arise over the meaning of terms in consensus statements as well as over the
implications of terms or issues that are absent from these statements.34 Just as with
disputes over membership in the consensus process, neither of these additional sources of
conflict arise outside the context of consensus-based processes.
Council of Large Public Housing Authorities, Inc. v. US Department of Housing
and Urban Development, No. 1:99CV00634 (Dist. D.C. March 25, 1999) (motion for a
temporary restraining order).
34
For examples of the range of conflicts engendered by attempts to build consensus,
see Coglianese (1997).
33
Conclusion
A reliance on consensus, I have argued, introduces new sources of conflict and
creates additional problems in the policy process. It leads to unrealistic expectations,
increased time and resources, lowest common denominators, imprecision, and a focus on
tractability over importance. We should therefore not engage in any wishful thinking
about consensus-based processes. Even though public officials, scholars, and policy
advocates seem to be converging on a new vision of policy-making based on consensus,
we should not expect that simply by organizing policy around consensus, defined
variously as requiring either unanimity or a decision everyone 'can live with,' we will
indeed achieve a more timely, less conflictual, and higher quality system of regulation.
The widespread establishment of a consensus-based approach to regulation would
constitute a shift in the prevailing mode of governance in the United States, amounting to
a 'decentering' of the state and a retreat from the public interest as the primary goal of
government officials. In this chapter, I have argued that such a shift is neither necessary
nor wise. All the purported benefits of consensus-building can be achieved through other
participatory processes which do not aim for consensus. Moreover, basing decisionmaking on a search for consensus introduces new pathologies into the policy process.
Enthusiastic calls for consensus, and particularly those efforts to compel agencies to
employ consensus-building, are at best premature. Environmental regulators can -- and
many increasingly do -- seek to engage in public deliberation in ways that do not impose
consensus as a constraint on decision-making. In doing so, they can achieve the same
kinds of benefits that have been attributed to consensual decision-making without
introducing the pathologies of consensus as a decision rule.
References
J. Applegate, 'Beyond The Usual Suspects: The Use Of Citizens Advisory Boards In
Environmental Decisionmaking' (1998) 73 Indiana Law Journal 903
S. Balla and J. Wright, ‘Consensual Rulemaking and the Time it Takes to Develop
Rules,’ (1999) (Paper presented at the fifth National Public Management Research
Conference, College Station, Texas).
D. Beardsley, T. Davies, and R. Hersh, 'Improving Environmental Management: What
Works, What Doesn't' (September 1997) 39 Environment 6
A. Blackman and J. Mazurek, The Cost of Developing Site-Specific Environmental
Regulations: Evidence from EPA's Project XL (Resources for the Future Discussion
Paper, Washington, D.C., 1999)
T. Caballero, 'Project XL: Making It Legal, Making It Work' (1998) 17 Stanford
Environmental Law Journal 399
C. Caldart and N. Ashford, 'Negotiation as a Means of Developing and Implementing
Environmental and Occupational Health and Safety Policy' (1999) 23 Harvard
Environmental Law Review 141
Carnegie Commission on Science, Technology and Government, Risk and the
Environment: Improving Regulatory Decision Making (New York, 1993)
C. Coglianese, 'Litigating within Relationships: Disputes and Disturbance in the
Regulatory Process' (1996) 30 Law & Society Review 735
C. Coglianese, 'Assessing Consensus: The Promise and Performance of Negotiated
Rulemaking' (1997) 46 Duke Law Journal 1255
C. Coglianese, 'Limits of Consensus' (April 1999) 41 Environment 28
R. Cooter and D. Rubinfeld, 'Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and their Resolution'
(1989) 27 Journal of Economic Literature 1067
R. Dahl, A Preface to Democratic Theory (The University of Chicago Press, 1956)
C. Diver, 'The Optimal Precision of Administrative Rules' (1983) 93 Yale Law Journal 65
Enterprise for the Environment, The Environmental Protection System in Transition:
Toward a More Desirable Future (The CSIS Press, Washington, D.C. 1998)
W. Felstiner, R. Abel, and A. Sarat, 'The Emergence and Transformation of Disputes:
Naming, Blaming, Claiming...' (1980-81) 15 Law & Society Review 631
J. Freeman, 'Collaborative Governance' (1997) 45 UCLA Law Review 1
W. Funk, 'Bargaining Toward the New Millennium: Regulatory Negotiation and the
Subversion of the Public Interest' (1997) 46 Duke Law Journal 1351
R. Hahn and G. Hester, 'Marketable Permits: Lessons for Theory and Practice' (1989) 16
Ecology Law Quarterly 361
R. Hahn and R. Stavins, 'Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era from an
Old Idea?' (1991) 18 Ecology Law Quarterly 1
C. Harrington, 'Howard Bellman: Using "Bundles of Input" to Negotiate an
Environmental Dispute,' in D. Kolb (ed.), When Talk Works (Jossey-Bass, San
Francisco, 1994)
K. Harrison, 'Talking with the Donkey: Cooperative Approaches to Environmental
Protection' (1999) 2 Journal of Industrial Ecology 51
P. Hart, Groupthink in Government: A Study of Small Groups and Policy Failure (Johns
Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1994)
P. Harter, 'The Political Legitimacy and Judicial Review of Consensual Rules' (1983) 32
American University Law Review 471
P. Harter, 'Fear of Commitment: An Affliction of Adolescents' (1997) 46 Duke Law
Journal 1389
L. Jaffe, 'Law Making by Private Groups' (1937) 51 Harvard Law Review 201
I. Janis, Victims of Groupthink: A Psychological Study of Foreign Policy Decisions and
Fiascoes (Houghton Mifflin, Boston, 1972)
R. Kagan, 'Political and Legal Obstacles to Collaborative Ecosystem Planning' (1997) 24
Ecology Law Quarterly 871
C. Kerwin and L. Langbein, An Evaluation of Negotiated Rulemaking at the
Environmental Protection Agency (manuscript 1997)
B. Kerwin, Rulemaking: How Government Agencies Write Law and Make Policy (2d
edn., CQ Press, Washington, D.C., 1999)
Keystone Center, The Keystone Center National Policy Dialogue on Ecosystem
Management: Final Report (Keystone, Colo., 1996)
D. King and J. Walker, Jr., 'An Ecology of Interest Groups in America,' in J. Walker, Jr.,
Mobilizing Interest Groups in America: Patrons, Professions, and Social Movements
(University of Michigan Press, 1991)
L. Langbein and C. Kerwin, Regulatory Negotiation Versus Conventional Rulemaking:
Claims, Counter-Claims, and Empirical Evidence (manuscript 1998)
J. Mansbridge, Beyond Adversary Democracy (University of Chicago Press, 1980)
National Academy of Public Administration, Setting Priorities, Getting Results: A New
Direction for EPA (Washington, D.C., 1995)
National Performance Review, Improving Regulatory Systems (Washington, D.C., 1993)
Presidential/Congressional Commission on Risk Assessment and Risk Management,
Framework for Environmental Health Risk Management (Washington, D.C., 1997)
President's Council on Sustainable Development, Sustainable America: A New
Consensus for Prosperity, Opportunity, and a Healthy Environment for the Future
(Washington, D.C., 1996)
B. Rabe, 'The Politics of Environmental Dispute Resolution' (1988) 16 Policy Studies
Journal 585
R. Reich, 'Public Administration and Public Deliberation: An Interpretive Essay' (1985)
94 Yale Law Journal 1617
RESOLVE, Inc., The National Marine Fisheries Service Take Reduction Team
Negotiation Process Evaluation (National Marine Fisheries Service, Washington,
D.C., 1999)
N. Roht-Arriaza, 'Shifting the Point of Regulation: The International Organization for
Standardization and Global Lawmaking on Trade and the Environment' (1995) 22
Ecology Law Quarterly 479
J. Rossi, 'Participation Run Amok: The Costs of Mass Participation for Deliberative
Agency Decisionmaking' (1997) 92 Northwestern University Law Review 173
M. Sparrow, The Regulatory Craft: Controlling Risk, Solving Problems, and Managing
Compliance (Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C., 2000)
P. Terhune & G. Terhune, 'QLG Case Study' (workshop paper, 1998)
J. Todd, Review of the Common Sense Initiative (US EPA, Washington, D.C. 1997)
US EPA, Operating Principles of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Common
Sense Initiative Council (Washington, D.C., 1996)
US EPA, Consensus Decision-Making Principles and Applications in the EPA Common
Sense Initiative (Washington, D.C., 1997)
US EPA, Evaluation of Project XL Stakeholder Processes: Final Report (Washington,
D.C., 1998a)
US EPA, Better Decisions Through Consultation and Collaboration: A Manual on
Consultative Processes and Stakeholder Involvement (Washington, D.C., 1998b)
US EPA, Constructive Engagement Resource Guide: Practical Advice for Dialogue
Among Facilities, Workers, Communities and Regulators (Washington, D.C., 1999)
E. Weber, 'Successful Collaboration' (November 1998) 40 Environment 10 E. Weber
K. Werhan, 'Delegalizing Administrative Law' 1996 University of Illinois Law Review
423