E C O N O M I C
I S S U E S
15
Inflation Targeting
as a Framework
for Monetary Policy
Guy Debelle
Paul Masson
Miguel Savastano
Sunil Sharma
I N T E R N A T I O N A L
M O N E T A R Y
F U N D
E C O N O M I C
15
I S S U E S
Inflation Targeting
as a Framework
for Monetary Policy
Guy Debelle
Paul Masson
Miguel Savastano
Sunil Sharma
I N T E R N A T I O N A L
M O N E T A R Y
W A S H I N G T O N ,
D . C .
F U N D
©1998 International Monetary Fund
Production: IMF Graphics Section
Cover design: Massoud Etemadi
Typesetting: Victor Barcelona, Julio R. Prego
ISBN 1–55775–761–5
ISSN 1020–5098
Published September 1998
To order IMF publications, please contact:
International Monetary Fund, Publication Services
700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A.
Tel: (202) 623-7430
Telefax: (202) 623-7201
E-mail:
[email protected]
Internet: http://www.imf.org
Preface
The Economic Issues series aims to make available to a broad
readership of nonspecialists some of the economic research being
produced on topical issues by IMF staff. The series draws mainly
from IMF Working Papers, which are technical papers produced by
IMF staff members and visiting scholars, as well as from policyrelated research papers.
This Economic Issue draws on material originally contained in
IMF Working Paper 97/35, “Inflation Targeting in Practice,” by Guy
Debelle, and Working Paper 97/130, “The Scope for Inflation
Targeting in Developing Countries,” by Paul R. Masson, Miguel A.
Savastano, and Sunil Sharma. This version was prepared by David
D. Driscoll. Readers may purchase the Working Papers ($7.00) from
IMF Publication Services, or view them in full text on the IMF’s website (http://www.imf.org).
iii
Inflation Targeting as a
Framework for Monetary Policy
I
nflation is bad news. Besides distorting prices, it erodes savings,
discourages investment, stimulates capital flight (into foreign
assets, precious metals, or unproductive real estate), inhibits growth,
makes economic planning a nightmare, and, in its extreme form,
evokes social and political unrest. Governments consequently
regard inflation as a plague and try to squelch it by adopting conservative and sustainable fiscal and monetary policies. Experience
and convenience have induced most of them to conduct their monetary policy by relying on intermediate targets such as monetary
aggregates or exchange rates. During the past decade, however,
seven small and medium-sized advanced economies have broken
with this tradition of using such intermediate targets and have begun
to focus on the inflation rate itself. This new approach to the ageold problem of controlling inflation through monetary policy is
known as inflation targeting.
Why did these countries choose inflation targeting over alternative policy frameworks? First, the authorities in these countries have
decided that achieving price stability—a low and steady inflation
rate—is the major contribution that monetary policy can make to
economic growth. Second, practical experience has demonstrated
that short-term manipulation of monetary policy to achieve other
goals—higher employment or perhaps enhanced output—may conflict with price stability. Some economists believe that an attempt to
1
achieve several economic goals gives monetary policy an inflationary bias. Central banks certainly appear to get more public criticism
for raising interest rates (a customary anti-inflationary tactic) than for
lowering them, and they are subject to constant pressure to stimulate economic activity. Inflation targeting in principle helps redress
this asymmetry by making inflation—rather than employment, output, or some other criterion—the primary goal of monetary policy.
It also forces the central bank to look ahead, giving it the opportunity to tighten policies before inflationary pressures become intense.
Inflation targeting is straightforward, at least in theory. The central bank forecasts the future path of inflation; the forecast is compared with the target inflation rate (the inflation rate the government
believes appropriate for the economy); the difference between the
forecast and the target determines how much monetary policy has
to be adjusted. Countries that have adopted inflation targeting
believe it can improve the design and performance of monetary policy compared with conventional procedures followed by central
banks.
This pamphlet addresses three issues in inflation targeting. First,
it explains the requirements for putting such a policy in place.
Second, it reviews the experience of the seven industrial countries
that have actually tried it. And third, it discusses whether inflation
targeting has a wider applicability to developing countries.
What Is Required?
Inflation targeting requires two things. The first is a central bank
able to conduct monetary policy with some degree of indepen-
2
dence. No central bank can be entirely independent of government
influence, but it must be free in choosing the instruments to achieve
the rate of inflation that the government deems appropriate. To
comply with this requirement, a country cannot exhibit symptoms of
“fiscal dominance”—that is, fiscal policy considerations cannot dictate monetary policy. Freedom from fiscal dominance implies that
government borrowing from the central bank is low or nil, and that
domestic financial markets have enough depth to absorb placements
of public debt, such as treasury bills. It also implies that the government has a broad revenue base and does not have to rely systematically and significantly on revenues from seigniorage—revenues that accrue to the government from having the monopoly on
issuing domestic money (the difference, for example, between the
cost of paper and printing and the face value of a $100 bill, which
can represent perhaps as much as $99.95 profit for the government).
If fiscal dominance exists, inflationary pressures of a fiscal origin will
undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy by obliging the central bank to accommodate the demands of the government, say, by
easing interest rates to achieve fiscal goals.
The second requirement for inflation targeting to work is the willingness and ability of the monetary authorities not to target other
indicators, such as wages, the level of employment, or the exchange
rate. A country that chooses a fixed exchange rate system, for example—which is useful in certain situations—subordinates its monetary
policy to the exchange rate objective and will be unable to operate
an inflation-targeting system, especially when capital can move
freely in and out of the country. Since the public will have no assurance that the authorities will give the inflation target precedence
over the exchange rate target or vice versa, neither policy will enjoy
the credibility needed for success.
Having satisfied these two basic requirements, a country can, in
theory, conduct a monetary policy centered on inflation targeting. In
practice, the authorities also have to take certain preliminary steps.
They must establish explicit quantitative targets for inflation for
some periods ahead. They must indicate clearly and unambiguously
to the public that hitting the inflation target takes precedence over
all other objectives of monetary policy. They must set up a model
3
or methodology for inflation forecasting that uses a number of indicators containing information on future inflation. Finally, they must
devise a forward-looking operating procedure in which monetary
policy instruments are adjusted (in line with the assessment of future
inflation) to hit the chosen target. The monetary authorities must
have the technical and institutional capacity to model and forecast
domestic inflation, know something of the time lag between the
adjustment of the monetary instruments and their effect on the inflation rate, and have a well-informed view of the relative effectiveness
of the various instruments of monetary policy at their disposal.
Distinguishing Characteristics
What distinguishes inflation targeting from other ways of controlling inflation is that the adjustment of policy instruments relies on a
systematic assessment of future (rather than past or current) inflation
and not on an arbitrary assumption about future inflation. Inflation
targeting means that monetary authorities explicitly specify the inflation target and establish precise institutional arrangements to reach
this target.
Specifying the inflation target involves selecting a price index to
define the target, setting the target in terms of either the price level
or the rate of inflation, giving the target a numerical value, deciding
whether to define the target as a point or a band, and determining
possible escape clauses or exemptions to the inflation target under
specific circumstances. Establishing the institutional arrangements
involves deciding whether to make compliance with the inflation
4
target a formally mandated objective or simply an operational
requirement of monetary policy, determining how best to integrate
inflation targeting into the overall macroeconomic policy, and developing procedures to ensure its transparency and accountability.
These issues generally imply a trade-off between credibility and
flexibility. Making inflation targeting credible typically diminishes
the authorities’ short-term flexibility and policy discretion although,
in the long run, credibility, once acquired, may give the authorities
more scope to be flexible. A consensus may be emerging on the
advantages of specifying the target in terms of the inflation rate
rather than the price level and on defining the target in terms of a
well-known and widely used price index, such as the CPI (consumer price index), perhaps purged of a few items not linked to
domestic demand pressures. The jury is still out on other issues.
Nevertheless, the experience of industrial countries that have begun
to target inflation directly is instructive in analyzing the wider applicability of this approach.
Industrial Country Experience
During the past decade, inflation targeting has been adopted (in
chronological order) in New Zealand, Canada, the United Kingdom,
Finland, Sweden, Australia, and Spain. Unsatisfactory experience
with setting intermediate monetary targets or with maintaining a
fixed exchange rate prompted this innovation in most of these countries. In New Zealand and Canada, the governments initially introduced the targets to help with disinflation. The success of these two
countries in taming relatively high inflation (by industrial country
5
standards) spurred in part the adoption of similar policies by the
other five countries, where, in contrast, the inflation rate was already
comparatively low.
These seven countries shared a relatively poor record in fighting
inflation over the past 30 years in comparison with Germany, Japan,
Switzerland, and the United States. Moreover, market participants
generally perceived the seven as lacking monetary policy credibility. In one sense, inflation targeting was the foundation on which
these countries sought to build a record of both low inflation and
monetary policy credibility. In these countries, the inflation rate was
the overriding objective of monetary policy and was given precedence over other objectives, such as the exchange rate or the level
of employment.
The focus on the inflation rate highlights the paramount role that
inflation forecasts play in this approach. Since the forecast dictates
how monetary policy should respond, the structure of the economy
must be stable and easily modeled to ensure an accurate forecast.
Assignment of the Inflation Target
The announcement of the inflation target varied across the countries. In Australia, Finland, and Sweden, the central bank originally
announced the inflation target without explicit endorsement from
the government. In Canada and New Zealand, the target resulted
from a joint agreement between the minister of finance and the governor of the central bank. Where the inflation target was originally
announced by the central bank, in most cases the inflation-targeting
approach has been subsequently endorsed by the government.
Although no central bank charter explicitly mentions an inflation target, the target has been justified as an operational interpretation of
the ultimate goal of currency or price stability.
Definition of the Target
The definition of the inflation target also varied across the seven
countries. The main differences concerned the time horizon specified (how long it would take to reach the goal and how long the tar-
6
get would prevail), how the price level was measured, and whether
the target was specified in terms of a point or a band.
Horizon of the Target. The horizon of the inflation target
depended in part on the inflation rate at the time the policy was
adopted. In Canada and New Zealand, authorities used inflation targets to encourage disinflation, allowing about 18 months for reaching the initial target. Thereafter, they set targets for further step
reductions in the inflation rate at 12-month intervals in New Zealand
and 18-month intervals in Canada. Once inflation was reduced to
the desired level, targets in both countries were set for five years. In
the United Kingdom, the authorities first set the horizon as the end
of the parliamentary term (mid–1997). During the period until
mid–1997, inflation was to reach a band of 1–4 percent; then it was
to be stabilized below 2.5 percent indefinitely. In contrast to the
other six countries, in Australia the time horizon for the inflation target was to be the length of the business cycle.
Price Level. Biases in the calculation of the CPI (owing, for
example, to the introduction of new goods or to higher demand for
better-quality goods) imply that, in practice, price stability is likely
to be associated with a small positive rate of CPI inflation rather than
a zero rate. These and other considerations have caused the inflation targets to center on a rate of about 2 percent a year. At such
low levels, targeting an even lower inflation rate is unlikely, according to existing empirical evidence, to yield significant benefits.
Width of the Target Band. A major difference in the definition
of inflation targets across countries was the width of the band
around the central target. In both Australia and Finland, the framework focused on a particular point target for the inflation rate, while
Canada, New Zealand, Sweden, and the United Kingdom all specified a range for the inflation target. In Spain, authorities specified the
target in terms of a ceiling for the inflation rate.
The need to specify a bandwidth results from the imperfect control of monetary policy over the inflation rate. The choice of a bandwidth reflects a trade-off between announcing a tight, hard-edged
band, which may occasionally be breached, and announcing a wide
band, which may be regarded as “softness” on the part of the central bank. Market participants may interpret a narrower band as indi-
7
cating a stronger commitment to the inflation target. If remaining
inside a narrow band proves difficult in practice, however, frequent
breaches could undermine any credibility gain.
Accountability
Inflation targets provide a yardstick against which central bank
actions may be judged; authorities can be asked to justify their monetary policy decisions. Transparency, or openness, is closely linked
to accountability. To increase the effectiveness of monetary policy
under inflation targeting, the authorities must announce policy
changes and make the reason for these changes as explicit as possible. This increased transparency reinforces the impact and reduces
the lag of monetary policy changes on price and wage decisions.
In general, central banks with inflation targets are directly
accountable to the government. Regular testimony to parliament and
the publication of annual reports have been the main vehicles of this
accountability. Since 1989, the governor of the Reserve Bank of New
Zealand has also been required to publish every six months a
Monetary Policy Statement that discusses whether the bank has
achieved the inflation targets during the previous six months and
what its strategy will be for the next six months. This statement has
served as a prototype for similar publications elsewhere. The Bank
of England and the Riksbank of Sweden have for some time been
issuing inflation reports focused uniquely on the recent history of
and outlook for inflation, and the Bank of Canada and the Bank of
Spain have begun publishing similar documents. In these documents, officials discuss monetary policy solely in terms of the inflation target. In addition, the Bank of England increases the transparency of monetary policy by publishing (with a five- to six-week
lag) the minutes of meetings of its Monetary Policy Committee.
Inflation Forecasts
Given the lags in the effect of monetary policy, an inflation target
must be forward-looking. Preemptive strikes are necessary: action
8
must be taken before the inflation rate begins to rise. Consequently,
the central bank’s forecasts of inflation are critical.
A number of criteria underpin an inflation forecast. There must be
sufficient historical data to estimate reliable relationships, and forecasters must be reasonably confident that these relationships will
remain stable under the new regime. The authorities should base
their monetary policy decisions on a projection for the future path
of inflation, although this expectation need not be based on a particular model. In fact, experience in all the inflation-targeting countries has shown that using the input from many different models
tends to give policymakers the most useful information.
Economic Performance Under Inflation Targeting
In general, inflation remained within or close to the target range
in the countries where the target specified a band (Canada, New
Zealand, Sweden, and the United Kingdom) or near the target rate
(Australia, Finland, and Spain). Still, it is probably too early to
declare that the inflation-targeting approach has succeeded in delivering lower inflation, given that inflation has also generally declined
in many industrial countries that have not adopted inflation targeting. During 1988–92, however, inflation-targeting countries reduced
their inflation rates more than the major industrial countries and
since then have remained at levels of inflation comparable to those
of the major industrial economies. This performance suggests that
the inflation-targeting approach has been useful for those countries
that lacked anti-inflation credibility.
Although inflation has fallen, it has been accompanied in most of
the seven countries by higher unemployment. Only in New Zealand
has there been a systematic decline in unemployment in the 1990s,
but even there, unemployment remained significantly above its level
of the second half of the 1980s. Comparing unemployment in the
inflation-targeting countries with that in other major industrial countries shows that the average unemployment rate rose significantly in
the early 1990s in the inflation-targeting countries, but since 1994
has tended back toward the level of the major industrial countries.
9
The experience through mid-1998 is that most countries that have
announced target bands have successfully maintained inflation
within the target, although recently Swedish inflation has been
slightly below its band. In New Zealand, underlying inflation
remained inside the band from 1992 to early 1995, but then
breached the 2 percent band twice, though only by very small
amounts. Initial indications from the New Zealand experience suggest that breaches of a narrow band may not be all that costly, since
financial markets and inflation expectations seemed little perturbed
by the small breaches that have occurred and by the subsequent
raising of the band ceiling to 3 percent.
Applicability to Developing Countries
Under what conditions might developing countries adopt inflation
targeting? These countries represent a mixed group, particularly in
their monetary policy and financial markets. Despite a general trend
toward greater reliance on indirect instruments of monetary policy,
increased access to international capital markets, and financial sector reform, few generalizations can be made about the degree of
financial development in these countries. Standard indicators of
interest rates, financial deepening, and the level of income have not
yet yielded a widely accepted classification or ranking of developing countries. As a result, it is extremely difficult to evaluate the benefits for these countries of adopting inflation targeting. The analysis
therefore remains largely exploratory and argumentative rather than
based on firm empirical evidence.
10
Basic Requirements
Recall that the basic prerequisites for adopting inflation targeting
in any country are freedom from the dominance of fiscal policy and
the absence of a firm commitment by the authorities to other, perhaps conflicting, targets such as the exchange rate.
In a few developing countries, the basic requirements for adopting inflation targeting are clearly not satisfied. In economies with
chronic high inflation (above 30–40 percent a year), monetary policy will be largely accommodative and will generally have only
short-lived and unpredictable effects on the inflation rate. The priority for economic policy in these countries should be a lasting
reduction in inflation through a comprehensive program comprising
a lower budget deficit, a break in borrowing from the central bank
to finance government operations, and the targeting of one or more
indicators to anchor inflationary expectations. For these countries,
conducting monetary policy in a manner consistent with inflation
targeting may be an option, but only after the fiscal roots of the
problem are eradicated and the rate of inflation falls to manageable
levels.
For most developing countries, however, assessing the degree of
compliance with the basic prerequisites is more difficult. Studies of
central bank independence in these countries suggest, with some
notable exceptions, that the central bank’s scope for conducting an
independent monetary policy tends to be hampered by heavy
reliance on seigniorage, shallow financial markets, and fragile banking systems.
Reliance on Seigniorage. Reliance on seigniorage is perhaps the
simplest and most common indication of fiscal dominance. The link
between a government’s inability to raise the revenue it needs from
conventional sources and its recourse to seigniorage is well documented. In developing countries, this link is often strong because of
structural features (concentrated and unstable sources of tax revenue, poor tax collection procedures, and skewed income distribution) and a proclivity to abuse seigniorage, particularly in times of
crisis.
11
Financial Markets. Shallow capital markets are also a common,
though more subtle, indication of fiscal dominance. They are often
a by-product of government schemes to extract revenue from the
financial system through various forms of financial repression,
including interest rate ceilings, high reserve requirements, sectoral
credit policies, and compulsory placements of public debt. In some
low-income countries, undeveloped capital markets may be as
much a cause as a consequence of fiscal dominance, leaving
seigniorage and other forms of fiscal repression as the only options.
Regardless of the cause, however, evidence of an adverse relationship between financial repression and the development of domestic
capital markets is indisputable.
Banking Systems. Fragile banking systems are an obvious consequence of prolonged periods of financial repression. In the aftermath of financial sector reforms, however, the banking system can
impart an independent influence on the conduct of monetary policy, but in this context conflicts can arise between the goals of
attaining price stability and restoring banking sector profitability.
Recent studies have found that banking crises have been more
severe in developing than in industrial countries. Evidence suggests
that, in the early stages of financial liberalization, policy goals must
be clearly ranked and followed in order of priority.
General Characteristics
A statistical analysis of the relative importance of these three factors in developing countries reveals several regularities. First, as
expected, reliance on seigniorage is considerably higher in developing countries than in industrial economies. In developing countries, annual revenues from seigniorage average 1.4–3.0 percent of
GDP, depending on the region, while in advanced economies
annual revenues from this source in the last 16 years have consistently averaged less than 1 percent of GDP.
Second, the relationship among average fiscal deficits, inflation,
and seigniorage varies considerably across regions and country
groups. This apparent lack of association is due partly to measurement problems, but more fundamentally to the ambiguous relation-
12
ship between fiscal deficits and inflation. The size of the fiscal deficit
is, thus, a misleading indicator of the degree of fiscal dominance.
Third, the average reliance on seigniorage for the seven industrial
countries that have adopted inflation targeting was similar to the
average for all advanced economies, but higher than in the United
States and Germany.
Fourth, the average reliance on seigniorage and the recent inflation performance in a number of high-middle-income developing
countries (Israel, Korea, Mexico, and South Africa) do not seem
much different from the averages recorded by the seven inflationtargeting countries immediately before they adopted this approach.
What seems clear from the evidence is that, in a large number of
developing countries, fiscal dominance and a poor financial market
infrastructure severely constrain the scope for independent monetary policy. In fact, for most of these countries, the effective independence of the central bank to use instruments of its own choosing will most likely have to await a comprehensive public sector
reform that broadens the tax base, reduces the government’s
reliance on seigniorage and other revenues from financial repression, lowers inflation at least to low double-digit levels, and revamps
the banking and financial systems.
Nonetheless, it is also evident that the constraints on monetary
policy imposed by fiscal dominance, high inflation, and financial
repression are considerably less severe in the 1990s for some highmiddle-income developing countries. For these countries, the obstacles to conducting monetary policy in a way consistent with inflation targeting seem related less to feasibility than to the authorities’
willingness to give clear priority to inflation reduction over other
objectives of monetary policy and to their ability to convey policy
objectives to the public in a credible and transparent manner.
Conflicts with Other Objectives
In developing countries with reasonably well functioning financial markets, moderate to low inflation, and no clear symptoms of
fiscal dominance, the independence of monetary policy depends
crucially on the exchange rate regime and the mobility of capital.
13
Although fixed exchange rates have become rare, they have given
way in many developing countries to a variety of flexible, but still
managed, exchange rate arrangements, and access to international
capital markets has increased dramatically. Nevertheless, the nominally more flexible exchange rate arrangements that many of these
countries have adopted do not seem to have led the authorities to
attach a much lower weight to exchange rate objectives or to stop
using the exchange rate to guide monetary policy settings. These
developments have further complicated the task of conducting monetary policy in these economies and have an important bearing on
whether these emerging economies can adopt inflation targeting.
The necessary conditions for inflation targeting—the priority of
the inflation target over other policy objectives and a forward-looking operating procedure using inflation forecasts—are difficult to
satisfy in a context where exchange rate stability is a stated or an
implicit objective of monetary policy (as when the authorities adopt
de facto a target level, path, or band for the exchange rate even
when that rate is de jure flexible) or where the understanding of the
empirical links between instruments and targets of monetary policy
is rudimentary. As long as an inflation target coexists with other
objectives of monetary policy, and the central bank lacks the means
to convey to the public its policy priorities and its operating procedures in a credible and transparent way, tension between the inflation target and the other policy objectives is unavoidable. In such
circumstances, the benefits of inflation targeting are lower, and the
difficulties of conducting monetary policy in many emerging market
economies will remain unresolved.
Specification of the Inflation Target
The inflation target should be specified on the basis of an assessment of the effect of different decisions about the level of the inflation target, the time it will take for the target to be reached, exemptions from the price index, and the treatment of administered prices.
A medium-term inflation target implies a consensus about the
appropriate or optimal inflation rate. In most developing countries,
including those with some scope for independent monetary policy,
14
such a consensus simply does not exist. For a variety of reasons, the
benefits of low and stable inflation in these economies have rarely
been quantified or tied to a particular rate of inflation. As long as
this situation persists, any choice of a medium-term inflation target
for these countries is bound to be arbitrary.
Even less can be said about the speed at which the inflation target ought to be attained. Since opinions on this issue are intimately
linked to differences of view about the primary goal of monetary
policy in these economies, there are no grounds to expect that
agreement on the appropriate speed of convergence to the inflation
target can be reached quickly.
The choice of the price index on which to base the inflation target is also likely to be more problematic in developing than in
industrial countries. Although in general using a widely recognized
index such as the CPI enhances the credibility and transparency of
monetary policy, the fact that developing countries tend to be subject to numerous and variable supply shocks argues in favor of
removing some volatile items from the core inflation rate used to
guide monetary policy settings.
In many developing countries, administered or controlled prices
are an important component of aggregate price indices and thus of
the short-run behavior of inflation. A proper inflation forecasting
procedure needs to incorporate explicit assumptions about the
timing and magnitude of changes in these prices. Consequently,
greater coordination between monetary and fiscal authorities would
be demanded than in economies where most prices are market
determined.
15
Summary
The two major prerequisites for adopting inflation targeting are a
degree of independence of monetary policy and absence of commitment to a particular level for the exchange rate. A country satisfying these requirements could choose to conduct its monetary policy in a framework of inflation targeting. Seven industrial economies
have used such a framework and have so far met with apparent success. These countries have adopted inflation targeting from a starting point of low (less than 10 percent) inflation, considerable
exchange rate flexibility, and substantial independence of the central bank—conditions rarely found in developing countries. In many
of the latter, the requirements for an effective inflation-targeting
strategy are absent, either because seigniorage is an important
source of financing or because there is no consensus on making low
inflation the overriding goal of monetary policy.
16
The Economic Issues Series
11. Growth in East Asia: What We Can and What We Cannot Infer.
Michael Sarel. 1996.
12. Does the Exchange Rate Regime Matter for Inflation and Growth?
Atish R. Ghosh, Anne-Marie Gulde, Jonathan D. Ostry, and
Holger Wolf. 1996.
13. Confronting Budget Deficits. 1996.
14. Fiscal Reforms That Work. C. John McDermott and Robert F.
Wescott. 1996.
15. Transformations to Open Market Operations: Developing
Economies and Emerging Markets. Stephen H. Axilrod. 1996.
16. Why Worry About Corruption? Paolo Mauro. 1997.
17. Sterilizing Capital Inflows. Jang-Yung Lee. 1997.
18. Why Is China Growing So Fast? Zuliu Hu and Mohsin S. Khan.
1997.
19. Protecting Bank Deposits. Gillian G. Garcia. 1997.
10. Deindustrialization—Its Causes and Implications. Robert
Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy. 1997.
11. Does Globalization Lower Wages and Export Jobs? Matthew J.
Slaughter and Phillip Swagel. 1997.
12. Roads to Nowhere: How Corruption in Public Investment Hurts
Growth. Vito Tanzi and Hamid Davoodi. 1998.
13. Fixed or Flexible? Getting the Exchange Rate Right in the 1990s.
Francesco Caramazza and Jahangir Aziz. 1998.
14. Lessons from Systemic Bank Restructuring. Claudia Dziobek and
Ceyla Pazarbaşıoǧlu. 1998.
15. Inflation Targeting as a Framework for Monetary Policy. Guy
Debelle, Paul Masson, Miguel Savastano, and Sunil Sharma. 1998.
17
Guy Debelle is Deputy Head, Economic Analysis,
at the Reserve Bank of Australia. He wrote Working
Paper 97/35 when he was an Economist in the
IMF's Asia and Pacific Department. He graduated
from the University of Adelaide and holds a Ph.D.
from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Paul Masson is Senior Advisor in the IMF's
Research Department. He received his Ph.D. from
the London School of Economics. Before joining
the IMF, he worked at the Bank of Canada
and the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development.
Miguel Savastano is a Senior Economist in the
IMF's Research Department and received his Ph.D.
from the University of California, Los Angeles.
Sunil Sharma, a Senior Economist in the
Research Department of the IMF, holds a Ph.D.
from Cornell University. Prior to joining the IMF,
he was a member of the economics faculty at the
University of California, Los Angeles.