Economics of Transition
Volume 19(3) 2011, 611–637
DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2011.00412.x
The demand for skills and
labour costs in partner
countries
Evidence from the enlarged EU1
Alessia Lo Turco* and Aleksandra Parteka**
*Department of Economics, Polytechnic University of Marche, Ancona, Italy. E-mail: a.loturco@
univpm.it
**Department of Economics, Gdansk University of Technology, Gdansk, Poland. E-mail:
[email protected]
Abstract
We analyse the consequences of trade integration in Europe (1995–2005) detecting
how the labour costs in partner countries affect the domestic demand for
high- and low-skilled labour in ‘Old’ (EU-15) and five ‘New’ EU member states.
In general, independently of the skill level of workers, the results suggest complementarity between domestic and foreign labour. However, when we take into
account the typology of sectors, the demand for the high skilled in low skill intensive sectors in ‘New’ EU members is boosted by the increase of the average labour
Received: November 5, 2009; Acceptance: December 9, 2010
1
A previous version of the paper was circulated under the title: EU enlargement, economic interdependence and
the labour markets in old and new member states. We thank the participants of the conference organized by
the National Bank of Poland (Warsaw, 2008), PUE-PIEC Workshop (Università Roma Tre, Rome, 2009), the
SMYE Conference (Istanbul, 2009), Aarhus Business School Departmental Seminar (Aarhus, 2009), and EEA
Conference (Barcelona, 2009) for valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank Stefano Staffolani for
his help. Financial support received from the Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research (Scientific Research Programs of National Relevance 2007 on European Union policies, economic and trade integration processes and WTO negotiation) is gratefully acknowledged. Aleksandra Parteka acknowledges the
financial support from the Foundation for Polish Science. The two authors contributed equally to this paper.
Any remaining errors are ours.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA 02148, USA
612
Lo Turco and Parteka
cost in ‘Old’ EU members. Thus in low skill intensive sectors, the high skilled in
‘New’ member countries can substitute for employment in EU-15 countries.
JEL classifications: F15, F16, J31.
Keywords: Labour markets, trade, EU integration.
1. Introduction
The effects of trade integration on the labour market are among the most debated
consequences of globalization. In particular, the widespread feeling that increases
in the cost of labour in developed countries can be offset through imports from low
labour cost countries implies that the foreign labour force can become a substitute
for the domestic labour force.
For Europe, in particular, the 1990s brought the intensification of links between
Eastern and Western European countries and the general opening up toward economies previously hidden behind the Iron Curtain. Increasing economic integration,
initiated by trade agreements in the mid-1990s and completed by the enlargements
in 2004 and 2007,2 has boosted the intensification of mobility of production factors
and trade across Europe, especially in the form of outward processing trade (OPT).
Wage differentials have influenced the location of separate phases of production
processes, and by the 1990s, ‘New’ member states (NMS) (mainly Central and Eastern European countries, CEECs) were already important hosts of outsourcing practices for the EU-15 (Baldone et al., 2001). The importance of the processing trade in
CEECs rose considerably in the 1990s – between 1988 and 1999 outward processing
exports to (imports from) CEECs increased by approximately 12.4 (17.1) percent
annually (Egger and Egger, 2005a). Now, the CEECs’ total exports to the EU are
linked strongly to the fragmentation of production (de Benedictis and Tajoli, 2008).
Following the political worries about the implications of trade integration with
transition and developing economies resulting from possible damage to low skilled
labour in developed countries, the empirical literature is concerned mainly with
the labour markets in advanced countries. Research has focused particularly on the
effects of imported intermediate inputs on the structure and/or level of demand for
labour. At the same time, with a few exceptions3 little empirical research has been
dedicated to the trade–labour markets interactions at the industry level, especially
for the ‘New’ EU members.
Within this framework, we focus on the EU case and try to answer a simple and
straightforward question: does the cost of labour in partner countries affect the
2
Ten countries (Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovenia
and Slovakia) joined the EU in 2004 while Bulgaria and Romania acceded in 2007.
3
See Section 2.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
613
demand for domestic high and low skilled labour? Several features distinguish our
work from existing contributions. The recent increased accessibility of detailed
sector-level labour statistics for separate EU countries (also NMS) allows us to shed
new light on the interaction mechanisms between the labour markets of ‘Old’ and
‘New’ members. Based on data availability we focus on EU-15 and NMS-5 economies (the five being the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovenia and Slovakia),
analysing the interactions between the domestic and partners’ sector labour market
conditions. In this respect our work extends existing research on the labour market
effects of European trade integration because it considers ‘Old’ and ‘New’ members
together, allowing also for some heterogeneity across the subgroups. Furthermore,
taking into account that a part of trade integration in the enlarged EU also concerns
some service sectors, we extend the traditional focus of the empirical analysis
beyond manufacturing and include business services among the sectors exposed to
international competition.
Moreover, an important novelty lies in the fact that the demand for labour is
assumed to be affected not only by its own price and other domestic input prices
but also by labour costs in partner countries: ceteris paribus, if an increase in foreign
wages positively/negatively affects the domestic demand for labour, we interpret
this as a hint of substitutability/complementarity between home and foreign labour
inputs. The key idea is that deep trade integration can bring about fragmentation of
production. If this is the case, the domestic demand for labour is also related to the
cost of labour abroad.
We consider employment by skill category and, contrary to the traditional
manual/non-manual worker dichotomy, we define skills according to the workers’
education level. This allows for an interpretation of the results in terms of the
relationship between the skill upgrading of a sector in one country and the
skill upgrading in the same sector abroad, and therefore in terms of convergence/
divergence of skill structures of industries across Europe.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: in the next section, we review the
theory and the empirical literature presenting alternative views on the labour market
effects of increased trade integration. In Section 3 we describe the data and present
descriptive statistics on trade intensification between EU-15 and NMS in the years
1995–2005, along with a description of changes in employment structure in these two
groups of countries. In Section 4 we focus on revealing the degree of ‘Old’–’New’
members’ sectoral interdependency. To this aim an empirical model of sector labour
demand for the high- and low-skilled is estimated. Subsequently, we present the
elasticities of labour demand with respect to domestic and foreign wage conditions.
2. Literature review
The main issue raised by our analysis is the interdependence of labour markets within the EU manifested through the impact of wage conditions in partner
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
614
Lo Turco and Parteka
countries on the domestic demand for labour. Whether domestic and foreign labour
input, in terms of labour in general as well as its different types (that is skilled,
unskilled), are complements or substitutes is a question that theory has addressed
in several ways, but only indirectly. On the other hand, in the burgeoning literature
on the role of globalization (Feenstra, 1998; Hummels et al., 2001; Krugman, 2008)
and the increasing inequality between skilled and unskilled workers, the final effect
of trade in intermediates on the wages of the unskilled depends very much on the
initial hypothesis of the model.
Assuming a single final good, Feenstra and Hanson (1996, 1999, 2003) show that
trade in the low skill intensive parts of the production process reduces the relative
demand for and wages of unskilled workers in advanced countries. These unskilled
workers are replaced by skilled workers in developing countries. In a specific factor
model Kohler (2001) reinforces this view and shows that when FDI takes place
together with outsourcing, labour always loses and when arm’s length transactions
are the only possibility, the intensity of the fragment outsourced is relevant for the
final impact on wages.
On the contrary, Arndt (1997) shows that, within a framework with two final
goods, the more labour intensive parts of production may be sent to labour abundant countries, but wages and employment may increase in the labour intensive
sectors of advanced countries because of regained competitiveness. In this respect
an increase in employment/wages abroad need not be related to a reduction at
home. The new paradigm of the unbundling of tasks around the world (Grossman
and Rossi-Hansberg, 2006, 2008) recalls this theoretical suggestion, finding that low
skilled labour need not be a loser from globalization because of increased productivity following the unbundling. However, when the prices of final goods change,
this conclusion can be challenged, especially if the unbundling does not concern
the offshoring of a single type of task but instead a complete bundle of tasks involving different types of labour (Kohler, 2004, 2009).
It is evident that the literature on the trade–wage nexus has focused mainly on
the labour markets in advanced countries. The main concern has been whether low
skilled workers in these countries (for example in the UK and USA) are negatively
or positively affected by the fragmentation of the production process. Furthermore,
it should be noted that so far the empirical evidence on the relationship between
delocation of production phases and the composition of employment in European
countries has been in the form of country-specific studies.4 Among the great number of works dealing with this issue in general, there is only a limited number of
contributions implicitly concerning the recent experience of European integration.
In general, in the literature on European integration issues, so far little emphasis
has been put on a parallel assessment of the importance of trade intensification
between EU-15 and NMS for employment structures in both groups of countries.
4
The only exception is the work by Hijzen and Swaim (2007) that explores the relationship between overall
employment and offshoring for 17 high-income OECD countries.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
615
In reality, Central Europe is already well integrated into EU-based networks
(Kaminski and Ng, 2005); therefore, the relative demands for different types of
labour (in terms of skill content) in ‘Old’ and ‘New’ member states are likely to be
strongly interdependent.
Egger and Egger (2003) argue that the increase in outsourcing to Central and
Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union has shifted manufacturing employment in Austria considerably in favour of high-skilled labour while a moderate
increase in the skill premium took place.5 Another example is the study by Helg
and Tajoli (2005) who analyse the experience of Italy and Germany and find that
the increase of the skilled-to-unskilled labour ratio in Italy was caused by international fragmentation of production (IFP) while in Germany IFP appears to have no
influence on changes in the relative demand for skilled labour. Geishecker (2006)
finds that outsourcing to Central and Eastern Europe reduced the relative demand
for unskilled workers in Germany.
As far as labour market developments in NMS are concerned, within the
EU-focused research there is only limited evidence of the impact of trade integration
on changes in average wages in NMS from Central and Eastern Europe (Egger, 2006;
Egger and Egger, 2002, 2005b; Egger and Pfaffermayer, 2004). However, since European data availability has been limited to recent years, there is very little evidence
on the effects of trade on the evolution of wages of different skill categories of labour
in NMS, especially using disaggregated data and not limited to country-specific
studies. Egger and Stehrer (2003) analyse specific developments of the wage bill
between non-manual and manual workers in the Czech Republic, Hungary, and
Poland in 14 manufacturing sectors, finding a negative impact of intermediate goods
trade on the skilled to unskilled wage bill ratio.6 A noticeable gap in the research in
this field can now be challenged with the recent data we describe below.
3. Data description
In order to address directly the relationship between the economic structures of
EU-15 countries and NMS resulting from trade integration, we use disaggregated
trade and industrial statistics for former EU-15 member countries (the ‘Old’ members group)7 and five out of ten NMS which joined the EU in 2004 (the Czech
5
Egger and Kreickemeier (2008) provide a theoretical basis for this result in a model where the interactions
between relative factor endowments and the skill intensity of the domestic production is explored in a setting with imperfect labour markets.
6
Also Esposito and Stehrer (2009) focus on different skill categories; however they analyse the sector bias of
the skill biased technological change (SBTC) hypothesis, which appears to play an important role in rising
skill premiums in Hungary and Poland, but is not confirmed in the Czech Republic.
7
Depending on the year, the statistics for Belgium (BEL) and Luxembourg (LUX) are available for both
countries separately or aggregated together; therefore we aggregated the data that were reported separately
for BEL and LUX, treating them jointly throughout the analysis (BLX).
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
616
Lo Turco and Parteka
Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovenia and Slovakia, from now on called NMS-5 and
included in the ‘New’ group).8 Unfortunately, detailed industrial statistics (especially those needed for calculation of skill specific wages) are not available yet for
the remaining NMS.
Growth and Productivity Accounts9 is our primary source for data on the labour
markets in EU countries (employment levels in each sector, sector specific skill
intensity, that is, the share of hours worked by workers with different skill levels10).
These variables are needed for the calculation of medium wages (labour compensation of different categories of workers employed within each sector and their time
of work), as well as for sector specific value added and intermediate input price
indices. Statistics reported in national currencies were recalculated into euros using
bilateral exchange rates from Eurostat.
Trade statistics (the volume of bilateral exports and imports within the same
sector between NMS and EU-15 members and the volume of total trade with all
world partners) were obtained from the UN Comtrade Database (United Nations
Statistics Division, 2008) through the WITS retrieval system11 which allowed us to
obtain recalculated series of trade data following the industry list consistent with
NACE division (a basic classification of the industrial statistics).
We focus on manufacturing and business services and, to match trade and
industrial statistics at the sectoral level, we reorganized the original data and aggregated all available statistics into 13 sectors.12 Complete labour market data for NMS
8
EU-20 is composed of EU-15 and NMS-5. Throughout the study the following abbreviations have been
adopted: EU-15 (‘Old’) – Austria (AUT), Belgium and Luxembourg (BLX), Denmark (DNK), Spain
(ESP), Finland (FIN), France (FRA), Germany (GER), Greece (GRC), Ireland (IRL), Italy (ITA), Netherlands
(NLD), Portugal (PRT), Sweden (SWE), United Kingdom (UK). NMS-5 (‘New’) – the Czech Republic (CZE),
Hungary (HUN), Poland (POL), Slovakia (SVK), Slovenia (SVN).
9
We used the data from the latest release EUKLEMS Database, 2008 (http://www.euklems.net). All the series in the EUKLEMS database were created based on statistics provided by National Statistical Institutes
(NSIs), but a particular emphasis has been put on the harmonization of the basic data, ensuring cross sample
comparability. Since data by labour types (according to the skill level) are not part of standard statistics
reported by NSIs, EUKLEMS uses survey data as background sources (See Timmer et al., 2007 and
EUKLEMS, 2007 for details).
10
Skills are defined on the basis of educational level. We use statistics originally classified according to the
international ISCO classification into workers with high skills (HS – higher/tertiary education), medium
skills (MS – secondary education) and low skills (LS – basic education) which are combined into two skill
groups (h = HS, l = MS + LS) for this study. See Section 3.2.
11
World Integrated Trade Solutions (http://www.wits.worldbank.org).
12
Sectors A–M included into the analysis have been divided into two groups according to their skill typology from EU KLEMS. Low skill intensive sectors: A. Food, beverages and tobacco; B. Textiles, leather and
footwear; C. Wood and products of wood and cork; D. Pulp, paper, printing and publishing; F. Rubber and
plastics products; G. Other non-metallic mineral products; H. Basic metals and fabricated metal products;
L. Manufacturing, nec; recycling. High skill intensive sectors: E. Chemicals and chemical products; I. Machinery,
nec; J. Electrical and optical equipment; K. Transport equipment; M. Renting of machinery and equipment,
other business services. We eliminate agriculture, mining, and public services from the analysis in order
to focus on manufacturing and IT services.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
617
are not available prior before 1995; therefore our analysis covers the period 1995–
2005 which is an important decade for the observation of the increased interdependence within an integrating Europe after the Europe Agreements.
3.1 Changes in trade relations between ‘Old’ and
‘New’ member states
The progressing economic integration in Europe has intensified trade relations
between Western Europe and countries which joined the EU in 2004 and 2007. Our
main interest is to focus on the transmission mechanism via trade from partner
countries; therefore we concentrate on import flows which were coming to ‘New’
partner countries from EU-15 and vice versa.13 Table 1 presents the first insight
into the dynamics and significance of trade flows between NMS-5 and EU-15. The
first set of columns presents the importance of EU-15 countries as a source of
imports for NMS-5, the next three columns present analogous figures measuring
the importance of imports from NMS-5 for EU-15 countries and the final two columns show the normalized trade balance (where positive value is a sign of being a
net exporter).
In 2005, depending on the sector, imports from EU-15 amounted to between
47.7 percent to 75.3 percent (the maximum was reached in the renting of machinery
and equipment and other business services sector) of total imports reported by
NMS-5. However, between 1995 and 2005 the share of import flows from EU-15
countries had diminished in most sectors as a percentage of total imports reported
by NMS-5. The relative importance of imports from EU-15 in trade structures in
‘New’ countries increased considerably in such sectors as ‘Wood, products of wood
and cork’, ‘Chemicals and chemical product’, ‘Basic metals and fabricated metal
products’ and ‘Renting of machinery and equipment and other business services’.
On the other hand, if we consider the importance of NMS as partners for EU-15,
the shares of import flows from NMS-5 as a percentage of total imports reported by
EU-15 are quite low (in 2005 up to 8.1 percent of total imports directed to EU-15
from the world), but since 1995 NMS-5 as importers have gained importance in the
overall EU-15 structure of imports in all but three sectors (in one of these ‘Textiles,
leather and footwear’, the drop in the share of imports from CEECs may reflect
increasing competition from low labour cost Asian countries). Importantly, NMS-5
improved their position as a source of EU-15 imports in more advanced sectors
such as ‘Electrical and optical equipment’, ‘Transport equipment’ and ‘Renting of
machinery and equipment and other services’. In the case of these sectors the share
of import flows from NMS-5 as a percentage of total EU-15 imports more than doubled between 1995 and 2005. Therefore, it is clear that, independently of the sector
13
For Western European partners, trade with NMS-5 represents the bulk of trade flows coming from/sent
to NMS in general; therefore, we present statistics concerning countries from our panel (NMS-5) and analogous figures referring to all 12 NMS are available on request.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
618
Table 1. Trade patterns: share of import flows from EU-15 countries to NMS-12 and NMS-5 (and vice versa)
and normalized trade balance (by sector)
Imports from
EU-15 to NMS-5
(% total NMS-5 imports)
Notes: NMS-5: CZE, HUN, POL, SVK, SVN.
EXPfromNMS5toEU15 IMPtoNMS5fromEU15 100%
*Calculated as:EXP
þIMP
fromNMS5toEU15
toNMS5fromEU15
Source: Own elaboration with UN Comtrade data.
NTB (NMS-5
vs. EU-15)*
1995
2005
D
1995
2005
D
1995
2005
57.3
72.7
50.6
72.0
62.6
75.6
69.2
59.2
79.9
63.7
76.2
67.9
66.2
56.2
58.9
52.8
70.6
68.6
75.0
62.1
64.5
72.7
47.7
71.1
52.4
75.3
)2.0
)18.9
4.3
)2.0
9.6
)0.8
)10.3
9.0
)9.0
)25.1
)6.7
)22.8
13.7
1.4
5.2
8.6
1.8
1.5
2.3
6.0
4.4
2.4
1.6
2.1
5.3
0.6
2.9
3.5
7.7
4.2
1.4
6.4
6.3
5.4
6.0
6.0
6.8
8.1
2.1
102.9
)32.2
)10.5
141.6
)3.3
177.3
5.2
22.2
150.8
281.8
218.0
51.7
228.9
)9.7
15.5
69.3
)33.5
)35.9
)29.8
14.8
20.0
)41.5
)23.9
)9.5
36.3
)37.3
)2.2
2.6
42.8
)15.3
)48.9
)16.8
2.7
)2.4
)7.7
18.9
19.1
52.2
)15.5
Lo Turco and Parteka
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
A. Food, beverages and tobacco
B. Textiles, leather and footwear
C. Wood and products of wood and cork
D. Pulp, paper, printing and publishing
E. Chemicals and chemical products
F. Rubber and plastics products
G. Other non-metallic mineral products
H. Basic metals and metal products
I. Machinery, nec
J. Electrical and optical equipment
K. Transport equipment
L. Manufacturing, nec; recycling
M. Renting of machinery and equipment,
other services
Imports from
NMS-5 to EU-15
(% total EU-15 imports)
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
619
taken into consideration, trade with EU-15 is still much more important for NMS
than trade with NMS is for the EU-15. A very large proportion of total imports to
NMS come from EU-15 countries while the reverse is not true.14
Analysing the changes in sector specific normalized trade balances in trade
flows between ‘New’ member states and the EU-15 (last two columns of Table 1),
we can confirm that the NMS-5 as a group still tends to occupy the position of a net
exporter in sectors requiring rather low skilled labour, such as ‘Textiles, leather and
footwear’ and ‘Wood and products of wood and cork’, but are net importers of food
products, pulp and paper, chemicals, rubber products, machinery, and business
services. However, between 1995 and 2005, NMS-5 managed to pass from the position of net importer to net exporter in such advanced sectors as ‘Electrical and optical equipment’ and ‘Transport equipment’. This may be caused by increasing FDI
activity in these fields (for example car factories located in CEECs).
3.2 Changes in employment patterns in ‘Old’ and ‘New’ members
Having seen the major characteristics concerning trade patterns within the enlarged
EU, we now turn toward the presentation of sectoral patterns of employment in
EU-15 and NMS-5 countries (complete labour statistics for the remaining NMS are
unavailable). Importantly, the information on sector specific skill content permits
us to trace the dynamics of skill structures in ‘Old’ and ‘New’ member states.
We use the information on the share of hours worked in single sectors by persons
with high, medium, and low skills,15 where skills in EUKLEMS are defined according to the worker’s education level – workers with a tertiary education degree or
more are classified as high skilled (HS), with a secondary school degree as medium
skilled (MS), and with a primary school degree or less as low skilled (LS). The information contained within the EUKLEMS is consistent over time for each country,
but it might differ across countries. Therefore, full comparability is assumed only
across the bachelor degree educational level (EUKLEMS, 2007). In order to preserve
comparability and provide easier legibility of the results, throughout the whole
analysis we consider two types of workers – high skilled (h) and less/low skilled
(l): h = HS are workers with tertiary education and l = MS + LS are workers with
secondary education or less.
14
A similar pattern is confirmed in export shares – the predominant share of NMS exports is directed to the
EU-15. For example, in 2005 up to 78.7 percent of total exports from the NMS-12 textiles, leather and
footwear sector and 72.6 percent of NMS-5 transport equipment exports were sent to the EU-15 market.
In comparison, in 2005 the great majority of EU-15 exports (approximately 90 percent) was still directed to
non-NMS markets. Detailed data are available on request.
15
In general, EUKLEMS distinguishes between employees and persons engaged – the difference between
the two are the self-employed and family workers; therefore the discrepancy may be considerable in sectors
with a large proportion of self-employed such as agriculture or retailing. However, specific labour statistics
by skill groups are available only for persons engaged.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
620
Lo Turco and Parteka
In Table 2 we present sector specific high skill content (the share of hours
worked by highly skilled persons engaged – share(Lh) – in the EU-15 and NMS-5 in
1995 and 2005. Additionally, we present percentage changes between 1995 and
2005 in overall employment in single sectors (measured by the change in total hours
worked, DL) and in the number of hours worked by highly skilled workers, DLh.
How important is highly skilled labour in the employment structures in ‘Old;
and ‘New’ members? On average by sector, in NMS-5 in 1995 10 percent of total
hours were worked by highly skilled workers with a tertiary education; in EU-15
the figure was 11.6 percent; in 2005 the corresponding shares had risen to
16.5 percent and 18.2 percent, a sign of movement toward a larger share of highly
educated workers (an overall skill upgrading of employment structures) in both
groups. Between 1995 and 2005 share(Lh) increased in all sectors both in the
EU-15 and in NMS-5, indicating a more intensive use of skills in the tradable
economy.
However, skill patterns are very different across sectors. Not surprisingly, the
biggest proportion of hours worked (approximately one-third in EU-15 and
one-fourth in NMS-5) by employees with a tertiary education level is in the services
sector. A much lower proportion of time worked by people with the highest
educational levels is typical for more traditional, labour intensive activities. Interestingly, both in 1995 and 2005, the NMS-5, compared to the EU-15, employed
more higher-skilled workers in almost all sectors but not in those typically defined
as ‘high-skill’, such as ‘Electrical and optical equipment’ and ‘Transport equipment’, indicating the within-sector differences in tasks performed in ‘Old’ and
‘New’ member states.
As far as changes in total hours worked are considered (DL), between 1995 and
2005 in EU-15 the business services sector expanded noticeably (by more than
50 percent), but all other sectors, except ‘Basic metals and fabricated metal products’, registered a drop in the number of hours worked (it was most pronounced,
by 31 percent, in ‘Textiles, leather and footwear’). In NMS-5 the picture is more
complicated – among sectors that contracted we may find both traditional ones,
such as ‘Food, beverages and tobacco’ or ‘Textiles, leather and footwear’ (hours
worked fell by more than 40 percent), but also the more advanced chemical and
machinery manufacturing sectors. Apart from service sectors, where the number of
hours worked in 2005 was 66 percent higher than in 1995, employment in NMS-5
grew most in ‘Rubber and plastics products’ and in ‘Electrical and optical equipment’ sectors. In brief, while ‘Old’ members were moving labour from manufacturing to services, ‘New’ members were still experiencing labour force movements
within manufacturing.
The general tendency of skill upgrading is confirmed when we look at changes
in the number (not share) of hours worked in each sector: Share(Lh) grew in almost
all cases, even in sectors where the overall number of hours worked decreased.
It means that employment structures of both ‘Old’ and ‘New’ EU countries employ
highly educated labour more and more intensively.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
‘Old’ (EU-15)
Share(Lh)
‘New’ (NMS-5)
Share(Lh)
DL
DLh
DL
DLh
1995
2005
1995–2005
1995–2005
1995
2005
1995–2005
1995–2005
A. Food, beverages and tobacco
B. Textiles, leather and footwear
C. Wood and products of wood and cork
D. Pulp, paper, printing and publishing
E. Chemicals and chemical products
F. Rubber and plastics products
G. Other non-metallic mineral products
H. Basic metals and fabricated metal products
I. Machinery, nec
J. Electrical and optical equipment
K. Transport equipment
L. Manufacturing, nec; recycling
M. Renting of machinery and equipment,
other business services
2.7
3.0
5.6
7.0
8.2
6.4
6.0
5.9
6.2
10.1
9.4
4.4
23.6
6.0
4.4
8.8
10.6
12.2
9.1
9.0
8.5
8.7
13.2
12.9
6.7
30.2
)5.4
)31.4
)10.0
)11.1
)10.2
)1.6
)9.9
1.4
)2.2
)12.6
)1.9
)9.4
54.3
50.2
4.5
40.6
33.4
33.4
39.2
32.8
40.3
39.9
19.3
44.0
54.5
99.0
4.2
4.2
8.7
8.8
9.2
8.9
8.7
8.5
7.8
7.9
8.0
4.1
30.3
6.3
6.2
12.8
13.2
13.4
13.0
12.8
12.4
10.2
9.9
10.3
6.3
37.7
)15.8
)43.9
7.1
2.6
)22.2
41.7
)18.7
)5.1
)28.3
33.2
15.8
10.6
66.6
26.6
)20.2
53.4
51.3
11.3
103.4
16.5
34.0
)7.9
62.9
45.0
66.8
113.2
Average
11.6
18.2
18.9
63.3
10.1
16.5
13.2
52.7
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
Table 2. Employment patterns: high skill content of employment structure and changes in hours worked, by
sector, in %
Notes: Weighted averages (by sector size) across countries within each group.
NMS-5: CZE, HUN, POL, SVK, SVN.
Source: Own elaboration with EUKLEMS data.
621
622
Lo Turco and Parteka
4. Modelling the domestic labour demand response to foreign
labour costs
4.1 Empirical model
In order to assess the degree of complementarity/substitutability between domestic
and foreign workers in the EU we focus on the response of domestic employment
in a sector with respect to overall average labour costs in the same sector in partner
countries. We take into account the heterogeneity of tasks performed and disentangle different responses of domestic demand for skilled and unskilled labour.
In order to allow for a flexible technology, we adopt a non-homothetic translog cost
function. Deriving the log of the cost function C with respect to the log of input
prices Px, we obtain cost share equations of the following form (Berndt, 1991,
p. 470):
@ ln C
Px @C
Px Xx
;
¼
¼ Sx ¼
@ ln Px
C @Px
C
ð1Þ
P
where Sx represents the cost share for each input x and x PxXx = C. Then, assuming a production technology with inputs such as: intermediate inputs16 (mat) and
labour (L) – high and low skilled – it is possible to derive the conditional demand
for high and low skilled labour as follows (i denotes countries, j = sectors and
t = time, but apart from the error term we omit i and j subscripts to provide easier
legibility of the formulas):17
~ht ¼ ah S
~ht1 þ
S
l
X
bhk
k¼h
~lt1 þ
~lt ¼ al S
S
l
X
k¼h
wkt
pmat
blk
wkt
pmat
þ chy yt þ
Old
X
dzhL wpzLt þ kt þ eijt ;
ð2aÞ
z¼New
þ cly yt þ
Old
X
dzlL wpzLt þ kt þ eijt ;
ð2bÞ
z¼New
where Sh and Sl respectively measure the cost shares of high and low skilled labour;
represents the deviation from the individual time mean to allow for industrycountry specific unobservable fixed effects and for any time invariant source of
endogeneity. The dependent variable lag is included to control for the persistence
of the labour cost shares. Lack of data on the capital stock for the NMS-5 represents
a limitation for which we control, in a first step, by the within transformation of the
16
Intermediates include energy, material and service inputs. The original cost function then describes the
total variable cost.
17
The exact detailed derivation of the final equations is based on Berndt (1991, pp. 469–476).
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
623
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
variables. The log of domestic hourly wages of skilled and unskilled labour is
represented by wk (for each k = h, l); y is the log of real output and pmat represents
the log of unit price of intermediate inputs. The latter appears in the denominator
because the equation for the conditional demand of materials needs to be dropped
from the system to avoid linear dependency among the left hand side variables and
the singularity of the system variance–covariance matrix. However, we estimate a
model (2) with the Maximum Likelihood estimator which allows for the invariance
of the parameter estimates to the choice of the equation to delete.18 Finally, indexing with q the R partners in the EU and ranking the ‘New’ partners (NMS-5) from
1 to p and the ‘Old’ ones (EU-15) from p + 1 to R,19 wpzL , for z = Old, New, represents the log of the average labour cost in partner countries (WPL), measured as
(time subscripts omitted):
WPNew
Lij
WPOld
Lij
¼
¼
Pp
importiqj wageqj
;
Pp
q¼1 importiqj
q¼1
PR
q¼pþ1 importiqj wageqj
PR
q¼pþ1 importiqj
:
ð3aÞ
ð3bÞ
For each country i and for partners classified as z ¼ Old, New; WPzLij is
obtained as the weighted average of partners’ wage, wageqj, in the same sector j,
with weights equal to country i’s imports from partner q in the same sector j. Such a
18
Actually, the presence of the lagged dependent variable in the model above would call for a GMM estimation technique. However, GMM estimators of dynamic panel data display poor finite sample properties and
the bias of GMM becomes quite severe when the number of instruments is large relative to the number of
groups in the panel. On the other hand, although the maximum likelihood estimator is generally consistent,
the ML principle has not been any help due to the incidental parameter problem. Furthermore, the conditional ML for the AR(1) panel data model with FE equals the LSDV (Least Squares Dummy Variable) estimator, which is inconsistent under traditional large N and fixed T asymptotics (Nickell, 1981) but it has been
shown that the bias is reduced when T grows large (Alvarez and Arellano, 2003; Hahn and Kuersteiner,
2002). In our case the use of GMM is not advisable since the NMS-5 group is very small and we also mean to
explore the response of the demand for labour to foreign wages in the sub-samples of high and low skill
intensive sectors, for which the cross-section dimension shrinks further for the NMS-5 and EU-15. Then,
although our time span covers 11 years we stick to the Within ML to save the property of invariance of the
results with respect to the equation deleted from the system. To determine whether the endogeneity of
the transformed lagged dependent variable affects the consistency of the estimates of the remaining coefficients, for the overall sub-samples of NMS-5 and ‘Old’ members we compare the ML estimates of the system
coefficients with their LSDVC (corrected LSDV) ones (Kiviet, 1995) which, under strict exogeneity of the
remaining regressors, perform substantially well compared to GMM and IV in general in panel structures
like ours (Bruno, 2005a,b).
19
The definition of partner countries adopted here refers to partners in the EU in our restricted sample composed of 20 countries, therefore every ’New’ member state has four ’New’ partners and 15 ‘Old’ partners,
while every ‘Old’ member state has five ‘New’ partners and 14 ‘Old’ partners.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
624
Lo Turco and Parteka
weighting scheme allows us to consider trade-based interactions between labour
markets at home and abroad – foreign wage conditions in partner q can matter as
long as trade is present and we assign major importance to the evolution of wage
conditions in partner countries from which imports are particularly intense. Similar
approaches in the empirical literature have concerned mainly the elasticity of substitution of labour between domestic parents and foreign affiliates, estimated with
both firm- and sector-level US data (Brainard and Riker, 1997; Lawrence, 1994;
Slaughter, 2000).
In our case, the use of sector level data allows for a more general approach not
limited to the multinationals’ activity. Following Feenstra (2004)20, the foreign
labour cost is modelled as exogenous technology shocks affecting the sector cost
function and the demand for skills, possibly in a non-neutral way so it is treated as
any other structural variable. Although, due to data limits we cannot consider
wages from trading partners outside the EU, any other source of foreign competition is meant to be captured by the within transformation of the variables and by
the inclusion of time fixed effects. Allowing for common time shocks across the
countries we control for the influence of globalization on our countries’ labour
markets.
Finally, the own and cross price elasticities are calculated as follows:
enn ¼
enm ¼
bnn þ S2n Sn
; n ¼ h; l;
Sn
bnm þ Sn Sm
; n; m ¼ h; l and
Sn
ð4aÞ
n 6¼ m;
ð4bÞ
so that, for example, ehl denotes the elasticity of the demand for skilled labour with
respect to the wage of the low skilled, and so on. The elasticities of demand for high
and low skilled labour with respect to real output (y) and foreign wages (wpzL ) are
obtained as:
eny ¼
eznm ¼
cny
Sn
; n ¼ h; l;
dznm
; n ¼ h; l and
Sn
z ¼ New, Old:
ð5aÞ
ð5bÞ
4.2 Results
Summary statistics of model 2 estimates are shown in Table A1 in the Appendix.
Table 3 shows the elasticities of skilled and unskilled labour (Lh and Ll) with
20
Chapter 4.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
625
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
Table 3. Elasticities of high and low skilled labour with respect
to output and wages
‘New’(NMS-5)
wh
wl
y
wpOld
L
wpNew
L
‘Old’ (EU-15)
Lh
Ll
Lh
Ll
)0.15
[0.15]
)0.68***
[0.15]
)0.11
[0.1]
)0.28***
[0.05]
)0.12***
[0.04]
)0.19***
[0.04]
)0.21***
[0.05]
)0.07
[0.06]
)0.11***
[0.03]
)0.22***
[0.02]
)0.35***
[0.04]
)0.28***
[0.04]
0.04
[0.03]
)0.05***
[0.02]
)0.13***
[0.02]
)0.06***
[0.01]
)0.41***
[0.02]
0.04***
[0.02]
)0.04***
[0.01]
)0.13***
[0.01]
Source: Own calculations.
Note: *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Standard errors are given in
brackets.
respect to domestic wages (wh and wl) and foreign labour costs (wpOld
and wpNew
),
L
L
calculated according to the formulas in Equation (4). The table should be read as a
matrix with columns denoting the type of labour demand and rows referring to
the price of the factor of interest and output; the cell on the intersection between the
two contains the estimated elasticity. The first two columns contain elasticities
calculated over the sub-sample of domestic labour in ‘New’ members and the
remaining ones refer to the estimated elasticities for labour in ‘Old’ members.
All the results include common time effects.
The coefficient estimates for the elasticities in Table 3 are shown in Table A2 in
the appendix, along with the Breusch–Pagan test for independence between the
two equations and the test for strict exogeneity of the regressors for the LSDVC
(corrected Least Square Dummy Variable) estimator.21 We failed to reject the null
of strict exogeneity for the right hand side variables; therefore, once controlled for
time invariant unobservables, no other source of endogeneity is at work for our
right hand variables. Furthermore, as shown by comparing the coefficient estimates
obtained with WG-ML (Within Group Maximum Likelihood) and LSDVC, the endogeneity of the lagged dependent variable does not affect the estimate of the
remaining coefficients, so we continue with the system’s Within ML estimator.
In general, the regularity conditions implied by the theory are respected since
domestic price elasticities (Lh with respect to wh and Ll with respect to wl) are nega21
The test is performed according to Wooldridge (2002, p. 285).
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
626
Lo Turco and Parteka
tive. They also are negative for material inputs as shown in Table A3 in the Appendix. Furthermore, the average prediction for the share of skilled and unskilled
labour is positive as shown in Table A4 in the Appendix, along with the test for the
symmetry cross-equation restrictions. The negative domestic cross price elasticities
of Lh with respect to wl and Ll with respect to wh in Table 3 reveal a certain degree
of complementarity between domestic low and high skilled labour.
Turning to the elasticities of domestic labour with respect to foreign wages, the
general result we obtain is the fact that independently of the skill level there are
complementarity relations between domestic and foreign labour force in our sample of EU countries. NMS-5 domestic labour with tertiary education completed
(Lh in Table 3, first column) is a complement to the labour force in partner countries, both those belonging to the EU-15 and NMS-5 group (negative and significant
New
). Similarly, the second column reveals that
elasticities between Lh and wpOld
L wpL
the foreign labour force from both ‘Old’ and ‘New’ partner countries is complementary to domestic low skilled labour from NMS-5, Ll. When looking at the third and
fourth columns, referring to domestic high and low skill domestic labour in EU-15
countries, it turns out that the internal demand both for more and less educated
workers in EU-15 countries diminishes when wages rise in partner countries.
Therefore, in EU-20 an increase in the average wage in partner countries is
related to a decrease in the average labour share ‘at home’. This is true in general,
but the highest estimated elasticity is for the response of demand in the NMS-5 for
high skilled labour with respect to average wage changes in ‘Old’ members – 1 percent rise in wages in EU-15 is linked to a 0.28 percent drop in domestic demand for
high skill workers in NMS-5. Also the response of the domestic demand for low
skilled workers in NMS-5 countries to changes in wage conditions in other NMS-5
economies is relatively strong (elasticity equal to )0.22).
We conduct another check estimating the empirical model (2) on subgroups of
sectors; we distinguish between low and high skill-intensive sectors according to
the taxonomy adopted within the EUKLEMS database.22
In Table 4 we focus on the elasticities with respect to foreign wages for ease of
presentation; the same elasticities for material inputs are shown in Table A5 in the
appendix. The first two columns refer to high skill-intensive sectors and the second
pair to the low skill-intensive sectors. Two panels contain the results obtained
within the subgroups of domestic labour from NMS-5 and ‘Old’ members.
The results give us the whole set of possible interactions across sectors and
countries, but given our interest in the interdependency between ‘Old’ and ‘New’
members, we first focus on cross elasticities between workers from these two
groups of countries. In most cases cross-border labour complementarity is confirmed (negative elasticities), but the important difference with the previous table
mainly concerns low skill-intensive (more traditional) sectors. In such sectors wage
increases in partners from ‘Old’ group is associated with the rise in the demand
22
See footnote 12 for the list of sectors classified as high skill-intensive.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
627
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
Table 4. Elasticities of high and low skilled labour with respect to wages
by sectors typology
High skill intensive sectors
‘New’ (NMS-5)
wh
wl
y
wpOld
L
wpNew
L
‘Old’ (EU-15)
wh
wl
y
wpOld
L
wpNew
L
Low skill intensive sectors
Lh
Ll
Lh
Ll
)0.647***
[0.193]
)0.26
[0.190]
)0.05
[0.044]
)0.458***
[0.116]
)0.409***
[0.075]
)0.109
[0.079]
)0.305***
[0.087]
)0.133***
[0.030]
)0.206***
[0.070]
)0.267***
[0.046]
)0.011
[0.199]
)0.718***
[0.197]
)0.208***
[0.054]
0.422**
[0.175]
)0.174**
[0.071]
)0.138***
[0.038]
)0.240***
[0.057]
)0.278***
[0.031]
0.043
[0.100]
)0.042
[0.040]
)0.219***
[0.049]
)0.386***
[0.045]
)0.148***
[0.028]
)0.004
[0.043]
)0.069***
[0.020]
)0.135***
[0.016]
)0.322***
[0.029]
)0.189***
[0.018]
0.028
[0.025]
)0.078***
[0.012]
)0.597***
[0.046]
0.103**
[0.052]
)0.155***
[0.030]
0.135**
[0.055]
)0.003
[0.024]
0.016**
[0.008]
)0.479***
[0.019]
)0.109***
[0.013]
0.049**
[0.022]
)0.012
[0.010]
Source: Own calculations.
Note: *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Standard errors are given in
brackets.
for highly skilled labour in NMS-5, thus there may be a sign of possible competition between high skilled workers in ‘New’ EU member states and workers from
EU-15, but only within less skill-intensive sectors. On the other hand, independent
of the typology of sectors, we did not find any signs that NMS-5 workers could
pose a threat to the high or low skilled domestic EU-15 labour force (workers
employed in EU-15 are not significantly affected by NMS-5 wage conditions).
EU-15 workers employed in less skill-intensive sectors should not especially fear
competition with NMS-5, since they could also be substituted by workers from
other EU-15 countries.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
628
Lo Turco and Parteka
Table 5. Overall growth (1995–2005)
‘New’ (NMS-5)
High skill intensive sectors
Low skill intensive sectors
‘Old’ (EU-15)
High skill intensive sectors
Low skill intensive sectors
Sh
Sl
wpOld
L
wpNew
L
0.03
0.22
)0.25
)0.10
0.31
0.20
0.63
0.59
0.31
0.48
)0.16
)0.10
0.36
0.26
0.58
0.59
Source: Own calculations.
Trying to quantify the importance of these elasticities and determine the
strength of cross-border labour interdependency, we report in Table 5 the overall
growth of cost shares and foreign wages between 1995 and 2005.
Wages in partner countries grew in all cases, but more in partners belonging to
the ‘New’ group. Both in NMS-5 and in EU-15, shares of high skill labour grew
(especially in less skill-intensive sectors) while shares of low skilled labour declined
(especially in more advanced sectors). We can combine these growth rates with the
estimated elasticities from Table 4. For example, in the case of low skill-intensive
sectors (typically perceived as more vulnerable to foreign competition) the increase
in labour cost in the ‘Old’ member partners could have accounted for approximately 8 percentage points (=0.20 · 0.422) of the overall increase in the demand for
high skilled employees in NMS-5 in the same sectors.
4.3 Robustness checks
In order to check the robustness of the results, we also tested a final specification by
including in model (2) average wage in the rest of the economy, wo, and a measure
of capital services, cap (due to data availability in this case the number of NMS
drops to three and the group of ‘Old’ members does not include Greece). The main
findings from the previous tables are confirmed.23
Then, a further check was accomplished. To determine whether our results are
driven by the measure of average labour cost adopted (3), we first substituted it
with the average labour cost for the high and the low-skilled in partner countries
(wpzh and wpzl respectively with z = Old, New). Next, we examined whether the
significance of our elasticities is driven by the use of imports as a weight of the
importance of partners’ labour markets in the domestic economy. To do so, we calculated the unweighted average labour cost and another measure of weighted
labour cost where, in the spirit of Frankel and Romer (1999), we substituted imports
23
Detailed results available from the authors upon request.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
629
from the partners with their geographical prediction.24 Then, we checked whether
our results hold in general (in other word when considering all the countries in the
larger EU as potential competitors regardless of their trade relations with the country under analysis), or when measuring the extent of potential competition by their
actual distance from their own market.
Consequently, we compared the benchmark results with those obtained when
we used no weighting scheme or with imports predicted by distance as a weight
for the average labour cost in the formulas in Equation (3). Our results in general
remain robust, aside from the response of labour in ‘Old’ members which is not significant when the weight is removed or substituted. Furthermore, when average
partner wages wpOld
are substituted for the average wage of the high
and wpNew
L
L
and low skilled an interesting result appears: the demand for the highly skilled
workers employed in NMS-5 low skill intensive sectors is stimulated particularly
by the increase in the wages of the low skilled workers in ‘Old’ member states.
In fact, the elasticity of NMS-5 low skilled labour with respect to the average wage
of the ‘Old’ members’ low skilled labour (wpOld
l ) is 0.42 while the elasticity with
respect to the wage of the EU-15 high skilled labour (wpOld
h ) is 0.28. This could
mean that the high skilled labour in NMS-5 is a better substitute for low-skilled
labour in the EU-15 than for highly skilled labour in the EU-15 in ‘Old’ members’
low skill-intensive sectors.25
5. Summary of the findings and conclusions
This paper has focused on the interdependence between labour markets in ‘Old’
and ‘New’ member states of the integrating European Union. The evidence of the
recent boost in trade between the two groups of European countries, together with
the overall skill upgrading registered in the employment structures in ‘Old’ and
‘New’ member states, suggests that the two phenomena may be related through the
thoroughly documented process of production fragmentation. With respect to the
previous limited evidence on the trade–labour nexus in the EU, the increased accessibility of detailed sector-level data on labour markets in separate EU member
countries (EU-15 and selected NMS, namely, Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic,
Slovakia and Slovenia) allowed us to shed new light on the interactions between
labour markets in ‘Old’ and ‘New’ member states. We add to the existing empirical
literature considering ‘Old’ and ‘New’ EU members at the same time in a homogeneous empirical setting, including the business service sector in the analysis and
24
We ran a regression of bilateral imports on bilateral distances (from CEPII) and a full set of pair, reporter,
and partner fixed effects, along with time dummies and their interaction with reporter and partner dummies
and with the distance. Ceteris paribus, the interaction of time dummies with the distance is meant to represent
the ease of improved communication and transportation infrastructure through time.
25
Detailed results available from the authors upon request.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
630
Lo Turco and Parteka
covering the 1995–2005 time span, which is convenient for observing the effects of
EU progressive enlargement. Finally, our main contribution concerns the detection
of the effect of the average evolution of labour costs in partner countries on the
domestic demand for skills.
From the estimates of the conditional labour demand for the high and low
skilled, augmented by the inclusion of a measure of average labour cost in partner
countries, our work leads to plausible results. Unsurprisingly the labour markets in
‘Old’ EU members are much less affected by foreign labour costs than the demand
for skills in ‘New’ EU members. For this reason, our main results concern the latter
group and imply, in general, that labour in NMS-5 is complementary with respect
to labour from partners, both from the ‘Old’ group (EU-15) and from other NMS-5.
This finding confirms Kaminski and Ng’s (2005) evidence of the NMS-5 as locations
interconnected by different phases of a complex EU-based production chain.
However, when looking for possible heterogeneous effects across different
sectors, the demand for high skilled labour employed within low skill-intensive
sectors in NMS-5 is boosted by an increase in average labour costs of ‘Old’ member
partners, especially average low skilled labour costs. Such a result suggests that the
substitutability of NMS-5 high skilled labour for (low skilled) labour in the EU-15
countries seems to characterize the period under analysis and contributes to interpreting the skill upgrading of manufacturing in NMS-5 in line with trade based
explanations (Feenstra and Hanson, 1996).
In conclusion, our analysis shows that EU enlargement has fostered the skill
upgrading of the productive structure in less skill intensive activities in NMS-5
countries possibly leading to convergence with respect to manufacturing structures
in the ‘Old’ EU members. On the other hand, our study does not confirm the fears
that the enlargement process could cause severe adjustments in the labour markets in ‘Old’ EU members considered as a homogeneous group.
References
Alvarez, J. and Arellano, M. (2003). ‘The time series and cross-section asymptotics of
dynamic panel data estimators’, Econometrica, 71(4), pp. 1121–1159.
Arndt, S. W. (1997). ‘Globalization and the open economy’, North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 8, pp. 71–79.
Baldone, S., Sdogati, F. and Tajoli, L. (2001). ‘Patterns and determinants of international
fragmentation of production: Evidence from outward processing trade between EU and
Central Eastern European Countries’, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 1371, pp. 80–104.
de Benedictis, L. and Tajoli, L. (2008). ‘Similarity in trade structures, integration and catching-up’, Economics of Transition, 162, pp. 165–182.
Berndt, E. R. (1991). The Practice of Econometrics, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Brainard, S. and Riker, D. (1997). ‘Are U.S. multinationals exporting U.S. jobs?’ NBER Working Paper No. 5958, Cambridge, MA: The National Bureau of Economic Research.
Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w5958.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
631
Bruno, G. F. S. (2005a). ‘Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models’, Economics Letters, 87, pp. 361–366.
Bruno, G. F. S. (2005b). ‘Estimation and inference in dynamic unbalanced panel-data models
with a small number of individuals’, The Stata Journal, 54, pp. 473–500.
CEPII (Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales) (2006). ‘Bilateral distance data’ (dist_cepii), Available at: http://www.cepii.fr. Last accessed 20 March 2008.
Egger, P. (2006). ‘Intermediate goods trade and international wage convergence in Central
Europe’, Empirica, 33, pp. 181–192.
Egger, H. and Egger, P. (2002). ‘How international outsourcing drives up Eastern wages’,
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 1381, pp. 83–96.
Egger, H. and Egger, P. (2003). ‘Outsourcing and skill specific employment in a small
economy: Austria and the fall of the iron curtain’, Oxford Economic Papers, 55, pp. 625–643.
Egger, H. and Egger, P. (2005a). ‘The determinants of EU processing trade’, The World
Economy, 282, pp. 147–168.
Egger, H. and Egger, P. (2005b). ‘Labour market effects of outsourcing under industrial
interdependence’, International Review of Economics and Finance, 14, pp. 349–363.
Egger, H. and Kreickemeier, U. (2008). ‘International fragmentation: Boon or bane for domestic employment?’ European Economic Review, 52, pp. 116–132.
Egger, P. and Pfaffermayer, M. (2004). ‘Two dimensions of convergence: National and
international wage adjustments effects of cross-border outsourcing in Europe’, Review of
International Economics, 125, pp. 833–843.
Egger, P. and Stehrer, R. (2003). ‘International outsourcing and the skill-specific wage bill in
Eastern Europe’, The World Economy, 261, pp. 61–72.
Esposito, P. and Stehrer, R. (2009). ‘The sector bias of skill-biased technical change and the
rising skill premium in transition economies’, Empirica, 36(3), pp. 351–364.
EUKLEMS (2007). The EUKLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts: Version 1.0; Part I: Methodology, prepared by Timmer M., van Moergastel T., Stuivenwold E., Ypma G., Mahony M.,
Kangasniemi M., on behalf of the EU KLEMS consortium, Available at: http://
www.euklems.net/data/EUKLEMS_Growth_and_Productivity_Accounts_Part_I_Method
ology.pdf. Last accessed 15 February 2008.
EUKLEMS Database (2008). The EUKLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts, University of
Groningen and University of Birmingham, Available at: http://www.euklems.net. Last
accessed 10 October 2008.
Feenstra, R. C. (1998). ‘Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global
economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 124, pp. 31–50.
Feenstra, R. C. (2004) Advanced International Trade. Theory and Evidence, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Feenstra, R. C. and Hanson, G. H. (1996) ‘Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative
wages’, in Feenstra, R. C., Grossman, G. and Irwin, D. (eds), The Political Economy of Trade
Policy: Papers in Honour of Jagdish Bhagwati, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Feenstra, R. C. and Hanson, G. H. (1999). ‘The impact of outsourcing and high-technology
capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, pp. 907–940.
Feenstra, R. C. and Hanson, G. H. (2003) ‘Global production sharing and rising inequality:
A survey of trade and wages’, in Kwan Choi, E. and Harrigan, J. (eds), Handbook of International Trade, London: Basil Blackwell.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
632
Lo Turco and Parteka
Frankel, J. A. and Romer, D. (1999). ‘Does trade cause growth?’ American Economic Review,
893, pp. 379–399.
Geishecker, I. (2006). ‘Does outsourcing to Central and Eastern Europe really threaten manual workers’jobs in Germany?’ The World Economy, 295, pp. 559–583.
Grossman, G. M. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2006). ‘The rise of offshoring: It’s not wine for cloth
anymore’, Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 2006, pp. 59–102.
Grossman, G. M. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). ‘Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring’, American Economic Review, 985, pp. 1978–1997.
Hahn, J. and Kuersteiner, G. (2002). ‘Asymptotically unbiased inference for a dynamic
panel model with fixed effects when both n and T are large’, Econometrica, 70, pp. 1639–
1657.
Helg, R. and Tajoli, L. (2005). ‘Patterns of international fragmentation of production and the
relative demand for labor’, North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 16, pp. 233–
254.
Hijzen, A. and Swaim, P. (2007). ‘Does offshoring reduce industry employment?’ National
Institute Economic Review, 201(1), pp. 86–93.
Hummels, D., Ishii, J. and Yi, K. (2001). ‘The nature and growth of vertical specialization in
world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54(1), pp. 75–96.
Kaminski, B. and Ng, F. (2005). ‘Production disintegration and integration of Central Europe
into global markets’, International Journal of Economics and Finance, 14, pp. 377–390.
Kiviet, J. F. (1995). ‘On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic
panel data models’, Journal of Econometrics, 68, pp. 53–78.
Kohler, W. (2001). ‘A specific factors view on outsourcing’, North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 12, pp. 31–53.
Kohler, W. (2004). ‘International outsourcing and the factor prices with multistage production’, The Economic Journal, 114, pp. 166–185.
Kohler, W. (2009). ‘Offshoring: Why do stories differ?’ European Community Studies Association of Austria Publication Series, 12(1), pp. 17–49.
Krugman, P. (2008). ‘Trade and wages, reconsidered’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1,
pp. 103–154.
Lawrence, R. Z. (1994). ‘Trade, multinationals and labor’, NBER Working Paper No. 4836,
Cambridge, MA: The National Bureau of Economic Research, Available at: http://
www.nber.org/papers/w4836.pdf.
Nickell, S. (1981). ‘Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects’, Econometrica, 49, pp. 1417–
1426.
Slaughter, M. J. (2000). ‘Production transfer within multinational enterprises and American
wages’, Journal of International Economics, 50(2), pp. 449–472.
Timmer, M. P., O’Mahony, M. and van Ark, B. (2007). ‘Growth and productivity accounts
from EUKLEMS: An overview’, National Institute Economic Review, 200, pp. 64–78.
United Nations Statistics Division (2008). Commodity Trade Statistics Database UNComtrade,
available through World Integrated Trade Solutions (http://www.wits.worldbank.org/
witsweb).
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
633
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
Appendix
Table A1. Summary statistics model 2
Variable
Mean
SD
Min
Max
Observations
0.05
0.06
0.06
0.01
0.00
0.00
)0.04
0.51
0.48
0.17
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)0.78
1.29
1.29
0.12
)3.03
)2.79
)1.38
3.34
2.79
)0.17
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
0.22
0.07
0.07
0.02
0.04
0.07
0.11
0.55
0.47
0.30
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)1.42
1.27
1.27
0.12
)3.68
)3.51
)2.00
2.45
1.87
)0.82
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
4.81
0.29
0.23
0.18
3.91
4.18
3.16
7.20
6.26
5.75
N = 2717
n = 247
T = 11
)1.05
0.27
0.25
0.11
)1.73
)1.63
)1.52
)0.12
)0.45
)0.52
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)1.64
0.27
0.25
0.10
)2.31
)2.15
)2.08
)0.62
)1.10
)1.06
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)3.06
0.30
0.21
0.22
)4.60
)3.64
)4.22
)2.10
)2.70
)2.32
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
Sh
Overall
Between
Within
wh
Overall
Between
Within
Sl
Overall
Between
Within
wl
Overall
Between
Within
y
Overall
Between
Within
wpOld
h
Overall
Between
Within
wpOld
l
Overall
Between
Within
wpNew
h
Overall
Between
Within
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
634
Lo Turco and Parteka
Table A1. (cont) Summary statistics model 2
Variable
Mean
SD
Min
Max
Observations
)3.81
0.32
0.23
0.23
)5.34
)4.42
)4.95
)2.68
)3.32
)2.98
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)0.83
1.28
1.28
0.13
)2.54
)2.40
)1.36
2.75
2.47
)0.35
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
)1.46
1.26
1.26
0.14
)3.45
)3.30
)1.98
1.79
1.49
)0.96
N = 2,717
n = 247
T = 11
wpNew
l
Overall
Between
Within
who
Overall
Between
Within
wlo
Overall
Between
Within
Source: Own calculations.
Table A2. Coefficients estimates for elasticities in Table 3
‘New’ (NMS-5)
ah
bhh
bhl
chy
dOld
dNew
al
blh
‘Old’ (EU-15)
WG-ML
LSDVC
WG-ML
LSDVC
0.53
0.00
0.04
0.00
)0.04
0.00
)0.01
0.00
)0.01
0.00
)0.01
0.00
0.37
0.00
)0.04
0.00
0.65
0.08
0.03
0.01
)0.04
0.01
)0.01
0.00
)0.01
0.01
)0.01
0.01
0.48
0.03
)0.04
0.01
0.73
0.00
0.03
0.00
)0.03
0.00
)0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.51
0.00
)0.03
0.00
0.80
0.02
0.03
0.00
)0.02
0.00
)0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.55
0.03
)0.02
0.00
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
635
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
Table A2. (cont) Coefficients estimates for elasticities in Table 3
‘New’ (NMS-5)
bll
cly
dOld
dNew
N
T
n
‘Old’ (EU-15)
WG-ML
LSDVC
WG-ML
LSDVC
0.11
0.00
)0.04
0.00
)0.01
0.00
)0.02
0.00
650
10
65
0.10
0.01
)0.03
0.00
)0.01
0.01
)0.02
0.01
650
10
65
0.08
0.00
)0.03
0.00
0.01
0.00
)0.01
0.00
1,820
10
182
0.07
0.01
)0.03
0.00
0.01
0.01
)0.01
0.00
1,820
10
182
Breusch–Pagan test of independence
v2(1)
3.66
P-value
0.055
26.6
0.00
F-test of strict exogeneity of all the regressors
1.32
0.22
P-value
1.26
0.27
Source: Own calculations.
Table A3. Calculated elasticities for material inputs
‘New’ (NMS-5)
pmat
wph
wpl
y
wpOld
L
‘Old’ (EU-15)
Smat
Smat
)0.239***
[0.020]
0.050***
[0.003]
0.086***
[0.007]
0.034***
[0.003]
0.023
[0.015]
)0.270***
[0.009]
0.045***
[0.002]
0.152***
[0.005]
0.027***
[0.002]
)0.017***
[0.006]
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
636
Lo Turco and Parteka
Table A3. (cont) Calculated elasticities for material inputs
‘New’ (NMS-5)
‘Old’ (EU-15)
Smat
Smat
0.042***
[0.008]
650
0.017***
[0.003]
1,820
wpNew
L
Observations
Source: Own calculations.
Note: *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Standard errors are given in
brackets.
Table A4. Actual and predicted cost shares of high and low skilled labour
Variable
Mean
SD
Min
Max
‘New’ (NMS-5)
S~h
S~h
S~l
S~l
Observations
650
650
650
650
Cross equation restriction [Sh | wl = Sl | wh]
0.05
0.05
0.17
0.17
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.00
0.01
0.03
0.04
0.31
0.33
0.33
0.35
‘Old’ (EU-15)
S~h
S~h
S~l
S~l
v2(1) = 1.23
0.05
0.06
0.05
0.06
0.23
0.07
0.23
0.07
1,820
1,820
1,820
1,820
Cross equation restriction [Sh | wl = Sl | wh]
v2(1) = 0.97
Prob. v2 = 0.27
0.00
0.49
0.00
0.51
0.05
0.53
0.06
0.55
Prob. v2 = 0.32
Source: Own calculations.
Table A5. Calculated elasticities for material inputs II
Smat ‘New’ (NMS-5)
pmat
wph
Smat ‘Old’ (EU-15)
High skill
intensive sectors
Low skill
intensive sectors
High skill
intensive sectors
Low skill
intensive sectors
)0.229***
[0.035]
0.076***
[0.006]
)0.203***
[0.021]
0.033***
[0.003]
)0.332***
[0.016]
0.064***
[0.005]
)0.190***
[0.010]
0.025***
[0.002]
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
637
The Demand for Skills and Labour Costs in Partner Countries
Table A5. (cont) Calculated elasticities for material inputs II
Smat ‘New’ (NMS-5)
wpl
y
wpOld
L
wpNew
L
Observations
Smat ‘Old’ (EU-15)
High skill
intensive sectors
Low skill
intensive sectors
High skill
intensive sectors
Low skill
intensive sectors
0.083***
[0.009]
0.019***
[0.004]
0.080***
[0.018]
0.088***
[0.012]
250
0.089***
[0.010]
0.046***
[0.005]
)0.029
[0.024]
0.018*
[0.010]
400
0.139***
[0.009]
0.037***
[0.003]
)0.008
[0.009]
0.031***
[0.004]
700
0.152***
[0.006]
0.023***
[0.003]
)0.023***
[0.008]
0.004
[0.004]
1,120
Source: Own calculations.
Note: *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Standard errors are given in
brackets.
2011 The Authors
Economics of Transition 2011 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development