DISCUSSION PAPER
Can Turkey Emerge
from Covid-19 as a
‘Developmental State’?
Mustafa Metin Başbay
DISCUSSION PAPER
Can Turkey Emerge
from Covid-19 as a
'Developmental State'?
Mustafa Metin Başbay
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
© TRT WORLD RESEARCH CENTRE
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
WRITTEN BY
Mustafa Metin Başbay
PUBLISHER
TRT WORLD RESEARCH CENTRE
June 2020
TRT WORLD İSTANBUL
AHMET ADNAN SAYGUN STREET NO:83 34347
ULUS, BEŞİKTAŞ
İSTANBUL / TURKEY
TRT WORLD LONDON
PORTLAND HOUSE
4 GREAT PORTLAND STREET NO:4
LONDON / UNITED KINGDOM
TRT WORLD WASHINGTON D.C.
1819 L STREET NW SUITE 700 20036
WASHINGTON DC
www.trtworld.com
researchcentre.trtworld.com
The opinions expressed in this discussion paper represent the views of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the TRT World Research Centre.
4
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
Introduction
R
Recently, talk of Turkey moving towards a new economic
model is becoming louder. This has been the main
theme of the current economic administration since it
came to power in August 2018. At the time, Turkey was struggling with economic turbulence
caused by the country’s accumulated debts
and increasing geopolitical risks. Since then,
the government has been pursuing its ambition to move towards a more resilient economic
structure predicated upon a more sophisticated,
high-value-added production sector, and a larger exports sector. With the Covid-19 crisis causing upheavals in economic and political orders
worldwide, Turkey’s endeavour seems to have
taken a more serious turn. The government has
announced it will be restricting imports in strategic sectors to protect its domestic producers.
This is a crucial and necessary step for realising
its agenda, but fine-tuning trade regulations and
targeting them efficiently are equally challenging and important.
Beginning in the early 2000s, Turkey experienced a growth miracle that improved income
levels substantially and removed millions of
people out of poverty. The main factors of this
success were the country’s improving macroeconomic fundamentals and development of
country-wide infrastructure, which boosted
capital inflows and private sector productivity. The government effectively dealt with the
country’s chronic problems, such as high public
debt and inflation, through a more disciplined
approach to government budgeting and monetary policy. However, the limits of this approach
have arguably been reached; the more recent
rise in the country’s income levels has been
sustained via sharply increasing external debt,
mostly channelled to consumption rather than
productivity-increasing investments. Accordingly, the government needs to adopt a different
approach and assume a more proactive role in
changing the sectoral composition of the economy towards higher value-added production
and high-tech industries.
The radical move to impose higher tariffs on the
country’s imports should also be interpreted in
the context of the government’s changing policy
approach to the economy. Upon his announcement of higher import tariffs, Finance Minister
Berat Albayrak said, “domestic production will
be pushed forward”, and “importing will not be
easy” anymore. Furthermore, Albayrak openly
criticised the previous policy approach, and indicated a change of paradigm in policymaking.
According to him, “Turkey had been turned into
an import heaven” by previous administrations.
This clear criticism of free trade fundamentalism, accompanied with the government’s repeated emphasis on its new agenda of moving
towards higher value-added industries, shows a
serious paradigm change in the AKP’s approach
to economic policy. Also, considering the timing
of it, rising criticism of neoliberal globalisation in
the context of the Covid-19 crisis seems to have
been critical vis-à-vis this policy move.
This paper introduces the recent history of the
Turkish economy, and explains the main dynamics that led to high-income growth since
the early 2000s. This involves the claim that the
limits of the government’s non-interventionist
and more market-based approach to the economy have been reached, and are unlikely to bring
about similar success in the future. Secondly, it
describes the nature of change in the government’s approach to the economy and explains
why government interventionism, including
trade regulations, is required for changing the
sectoral composition of production towards
more sophisticated, high-value-added industries. Finally, it reflects on how trade regulations
should be applied and the missteps that should
be avoided on the ground. This paper concludes that the deep transformations caused by
the Covid-19 crisis provide developing countries
like Turkey with more space and flexibility for
policymaking. This enables Turkey to take bold
steps in realising its ambitions. Overall, this is a
positive development, but it should be well-designed to reap the maximum benefits.
5
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
1. Time to move on for Turkey
Turkey experienced very high growth rates in the last
two decades. In nothing short of a growth miracle, between 2002 and 2018, Turkey’s annual per capita income growth rate averaged around 4.2%, which is significantly above its historical average and the growth
rates of other developing countries in Turkey’s income
range (World Bank, 2020; Figures 1 & 2). Consequently,
the average citizen’s purchasing power multiplied, and
millions of people moved out of poverty. The critical
factors behind this success story were the swift im-
provement in Turkey’s macroeconomic fundamentals,
such as concerning public debt and inflation records
(following the government’s disciplined approach to
public budget and monetary policy), as well as aggressive investments in the country’s physical infrastructure. This facilitated the private sector then taking the
lead in the country’s investment drive, and increasing
Turkey’s trade volume with the rest of the word.
Figure 1: GDP per capita in constant 2010 dollars, 2000-2018
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000 2001
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
World
Argentina
2010
Turkey
2011
2012
2013
Brazil
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Mexico
Source: World Bank
Figure 2: GDP per capita, Turkey 1960-2018, constant 2010 US dollars
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Source: World Bank
6
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
After coming to power in 2002, one of the main tenets
of the AKP’s approach to the economy was maintaining a disciplined stance on the government’s budget.
This is understandable, considering that public debt
had been the most vulnerable aspect of the Turkish
economy for decades and the main cause of several
major crises. In fact, at the time, the country was just
coming out of another one of such debt crises in 2001.
In the following decade, Turkey’s public debt to GDP ratio has drastically declined from 70% to 30%. Currently,
Turkey ranks as the 4th least indebted country among
OECD countries in terms of public debt (OECD, 2020).
Furthermore, improved monetary discipline solved
another one of Turkey’s chronic problems: inflation.
Although it is still quite high compared to other OECD
countries, and has recently surged, when compared
to Turkey’s historical records Turkey’s inflation rates
were largely taken under control in the early 2000s,
and have remained within reasonable levels since then
(World Bank, 2020).
The government’s efforts also focused on improving
the country’s infrastructure. Transportation systems,
as well as communication networks, have been enhanced with more ports, airports, and trainlines, as
well as extensive road and bridge projects across the
country. Consequently, private sector productivity increased, capacity in domestic and international trade
multiplied, and foreign direct investments to the country soared. Labour-intensive manufacturing industries,
such as textile, construction, or automotive industries,
have flourished, and various aspects of service industries have expanded. Indeed, this expansion in economic activities went hand in hand with a substantial
urbanisation process. Millions moved to urban areas
and were incorporated into manufacturing and service
industries. In fact, as pointed out by economic historians, throughout Turkey’s economic history the transfer
of population from agriculture to urban industries has
always been the main channel through which economic growth has been sustained (Pamuk, 2012).
However, according to many, this story has mostly ended. As the country’s gradual transition from a largely
agricultural economy to an urban one is finalising, the
possibilities of increasing income levels via labour-intensive manufacturing are also being depleted (Basbay, 2019a). In other words, in order to maintain the income rise, Turkey needs to find other ways to increase
its productive capacity. Otherwise, when growth does
not come from increasing productivity, it is maintained
via increasing external debt. Indeed, during the last
decade, while public debt has been largely kept under
control, Turkey’s total external debt, inclusive of private
sector debt, has steadily increased (Figure 4). This foreign capital has gone to domestic companies that are
driven by internal demand, rather than exports, and
continued to boost consumption levels in Turkey. This
trend is clearly visible in Turkey’s current account deficit (Figure 3).
Furthermore, Turkey’s geopolitical risks have been on
the rise recently due to confrontations with its longtime ally, the US, on regional issues as well as rising political tensions with its neighbours. This is significant,
because with increasing political risks comes economic risks. These risks are exemplified by US President
Trump’s repeated threats of sanctions against Turkey
in recent years. In fact, this threat was partly realised
in August 2018 when President Trump imposed sanctions on Turkey’s exports, which started a massive capital outflow. This process has not been fully reversed
since then, and Turkey is still under the pressure of a
drought of foreign funds (even if gold reserves are at
a record high). Moreover, the tensions between the US
and Turkey have still not been fully resolved on all issues, and Washington continues to show the stick of
economic sanctions. Therefore, Turkey’s reduction of
its dependence on foreign capital is critical not only for
increasing its economic resilience, but also for its political resilience (Başbay, 2019b).
In sum, both the long-run dynamics of Turkey’s development path and the more recent geopolitical problems force Turkey to reformulate its growth strategy.
Turkey has to deal with its long-prevailing account deficit problem, and reduce its accumulated debt volume.
Simply put, Turkey needs to move towards high-technology, high-value-added manufacturing industries
and boost its export levels so that the economy can
maintain its high growth trajectory while limiting its account deficit. However, such strategic sectors, though
have much higher potential for productivity improvements over time, are largely capital-intensive, and involve huge fixed costs and require substantial investments at the initial stage. Moreover, it takes time and
continued investment to acquire the know-how and
expertise in building capacity in such sophisticated industries (Cherif & Hasanov, 2019). Therefore, the prize is
great, but so are the costs and risks involved.
7
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
Figure 3: Current Account Deficit vs. -3% Maastricht criterion,
% of GDP, 2000-2018
4
2
0
2005
2000
2010
2015
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
Source: World Bank
Figure 4: Turkey's Debt to GDP ratio, 2000-2019
65,0
60,0
55,0
50,0
45,0
40,0
35,0
30,0
25,0
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Central Bank of Turkey
8
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
2. There is an Opportunity in every Crisis
Arguably, the ambitious attempt to move Turkey towards more high-tech industries requires more government activism, or what economists call an industrial policy. Even if the private sector would be the main
actor in this endeavour, without government support,
it is unlikely that private businesses will move towards
these highly risky, costly, and long-term investments in
high-tech industries. As a result, Turkey’s government
needs to switch gears and move beyond simply assuring that macroeconomic fundamentals are in place, and
provide the legal and physical infrastructures to meet
this challenge. It should support and protect strategic
industries via financial support, direct involvement in
R&D, building sector-specific infrastructure and so on.
This major transformation is akin to a ‘developmental
state’ that facilitates and leads the way for private businesses (Başbay, 2019a). Intriguingly, the Covid-19 crisis
opens a new phase in this change of paradigm in the
Turkish government’s role in the economy.
It can be said that, in the first half of AKP rule in Turkey,
the governments’ ‘hands-off approach’ to the economy brought about the intended results. A developing
country’s transition from a pre-modern agricultural basis to low-value-added urban industries may be
somewhat spontaneous, because these countries have
a comparative advantage in such labour-intensive industries thanks to their large populations and cheap labour force. Hence, as long as the government provides
a favourable macroeconomic environment and assures
the legal and physical infrastructure for the smooth
functioning of the economy, private businesses lead
the way in economic growth. As more people migrate
to cities, more employment is supplied to labour-intensive production, which allows for keeping wages and
profits fairly stable while businesses expand. However,
when this transition is completed, and income levels
reach around 10-12 thousand dollars, countries begin
to lose this advantage. This makes it the time for improving the technological sophistication of productive
capacity, such as moving from textiles to electronics or
from construction to auto-production (Aiyar et al. 2013).
Selective policy interventions by the government are
vital, because in a liberal economy, private businesses
normally do not get involved in what is best for the national economy in the long run but rather what is best
for their rather narrowly defined interests. For instance,
a private firm would prefer to invest in businesses with
less risk, smaller fixed costs, and a shorter gestation period. Even if a firm decided to embark on investments
in more sophisticated industries, it would find it difficult to access credit for such a risky business venture.
Consequently, developing countries are stuck with
low-value-added, non-sophisticated sectors – although
they need investments in high-tech industries in order
to move towards high-income levels and become developed countries themselves. As a result, the government’s involvement in the economy becomes rather a
requirement than an adventurous initiative (Amsden,
1989, 1997; Wade, 1990; Chang, 2002).
The case can be made that this shift in the government’s
approach to the economy has already taken place
(Yağcı, 2017). In recent years, particularly since the new
cabinet came to power after the 2018 elections, the
economic administration under the AKP government
clearly declared their intention to change the country’s
sectoral composition towards high-value-added export
industries. Accordingly, the government moved beyond paying only lip service and, although with gradual steps, adopted a holistic industrial policy (Basbay,
2019a). Turkey has been investing in various areas,
such as electric cars, renewable energy technologies,
the defence industry, and more recently pharmaceuticals. Moreover, the government has been providing
low-cost, long-term credit support to export-led manufacturing industries, while state banks have employed
their arsenal to provide credit to boost domestic investments in strategic sectors (Ergöçün & Şahin, 2019).
Still, the most dramatic move came in the middle of the
Covid-19 crisis. In May, Finance Minister Berat Albayrak
declared that the country would be restricting its imports in strategic sectors by imposing higher tariffs in
order to protect domestic production. After preferential credit support and subsidies, trade regulations tick
another box for what development economists would
consider a standard industrial policy package. In many
cases, restrictions on imports are critical, because they
protect newly emerging high-tech industries in developing countries (Chang, 2002). In these highly sophisticated sectors, it often takes years for newly emerging
companies to acquire the necessary know-how and
improve their competitiveness via learning-by-doing.
However, these ‘infant industries’ are often driven out
of the market by established foreign companies before
they can increase their scale and complete their learning process. As a result, import tariffs can be useful to
temporarily shield them from foreign competition, providing them with the chance to improve their competitive muscle without getting crushed in global markets.
9
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
This is a fairly radical move which would not have
been expected to occur just a few months ago. After
four decades of hyper-globalisation, liberal trade had
become the unquestioned norm both in academia
and policymaking circles. The Covid-19 crisis seems
to have served as a revelatory moment, providing a
more flexible policy environment for developing countries such as Turkey without facing too much pressure
from the gatekeepers of the free-trade order. In fact, a
revision of the neoliberal approach was already taking
place, especially since the 2008 global financial crisis.
Then came the Trump Presidency and the trade wars
between the US and China. Finally, Covid-19 has ostensibly been the last nail in the neoliberal globalisation’s
coffin. Now, across the globe, governments are assuming more power and responsibility in economies and,
willingly or not, intervening into the way international
trade functions (Basbay, 2020).
In sum, the Covid-19 crisis, while possibly causing a
major transformation in the global economic order,
has offered a moment of reflection on decades of hyper-globalisation and neoliberal fundamentalism.
Major disruptions in trade relations and the economy
force governments to think outside the box, and citizens, even in developed economies, are questioning
the benefits of unfettered markets. In this environment,
Turkey seems to have found more space for manoeuvring and an opportunity to further its agenda of boosting domestic production. The government underlines
that it is committed to the ambitious plan. However, we
are still at the beginning of this new endeavour. Trade
regulations can bring about the intended results, but
such deep structural transformation requires an elaborate and long-term plan.
Figure 5: High-technology Exports, % of Manufactured Exports
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2007
2008
Turkey
2009
2010
Mexico
2011
Chile
2012
2013
Indonesia
2014
China
2015
2016
2017
Brazil
2018
Argentina
Source: World Bank
Figure 6: Total Factor Productivity at Constant National Prices, 2011=1
1,1
1,05
1
0,95
0,9
0,85
0,8
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
Source: Penn World Tables
10
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
3. Challenges Ahead
For the Turkish government’s developmental agenda,
there are many lessons in the other notable success
stories of the 20th century. The academic literature
analysing successful and failed cases of government
interventionism in the economy has accumulated
substantial information and insight from throughout
the 20th century. A handful of countries, mostly concentrated in East Asia, have been successful in moving
beyond middle-income levels and becoming fully industrialised, high-income countries. These examples
include: Japan, South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and
more recently China. Countries that exhibit how selective government policies, including but not restricted
to trade protections, may be utilised to enable the private sector to drive investments in strategic industries
and facilitate economic transformation. There are several major conclusions to be drawn from these success
stories.
First, governments should avoid populist temptations
such as building self-sufficiency or producing most
of what the country needs. As pointed out by many,
adopting a wholesome approach to trade protections
usually creates more problems than it solves (Chang,
2008). We have witnessed in countries like India, Brazil,
and Argentina, how a closed economy can lead to inefficiency and welfare-loss in the name of self-sufficiency.
Free trade is basically a cooperative mechanism which
enables a country to take advantage of specialisation
and division of labour across countries. Thanks to international trade, a country does not need to spread
its limited resources, such as labour and capital, over
a wide variety of productive activities and instead concentrate on what it is best. It allows for improvements in
the welfare of all countries involved via exchange. As a
result, it is fundamentally an efficient tool.
Therefore, the government’s intervention should involve protecting only a few strategically selected sectors that require ‘short-term’ insulation from foreign
competition until they develop their own capacity. It is
illogical and unmanageable for a developing country,
or any country for that matter, to protect all its industries
from competition and preserve efficiency. This will likely lead to a substantial loss of welfare. A country should
continue taking part in free trade and importing a wide
variety of products from other countries while trying to
develop its own capacity in just a few strategic sectors.
The phrase ‘short-term’ should also be underlined. The
government should not protect the selected sectors for
too long, but only until they develop sufficiently to be
able to compete in global trade on their own. If protection from competition is excessively lengthy, it limits
productivity growth rather than enabling it.
Second, the government should fine-tune its interventions in foreign trade in a way which does not disadvantage domestic producers by imposing tariffs on
intermediate goods or raw materials used in production. This is more complex than it sounds, because
most products are outputs of certain sectors while the
inputs of others. Occasionally, governments, while trying to protect the former, damage the latter. Admittedly,
there will be trade-offs involved in the government’s decisions. Thus, the government should carefully weigh
the benefits and costs of protecting the certain sectors
for the overall economy and target them accordingly.
It should also be noted that this would involve redistributive effects between businesses and potentially
between different geographies and segments of society. Accordingly, there is a political dimension to this as
well, which is beyond the scope of this paper.
Third, the government’s plan should be pragmatist
and flexible. As Alice Amsden stated, it should “let go
of losers”. Namely, if a specific sector does not seem to
be improving its productivity level, trade protections
provided for the sector or the company should be
lifted. Unpromising sectors which appear to have no
prospects should be let go (Amsden, 1997). Otherwise,
protecting non-dynamic sectors for too long leads to efficiency loss without bringing about any positive consequences. In that respect, Brazil’s computer industry
in the late 80s provides a good example. Even though
it was protected from global competition and made
substantial profits in the domestic market, the Brazilian
computer industry failed to advance its technological
basis enough to be able to export its product. Eventually, the government admitted that the protectionist
policy failed to elevate the industry to international
standards. In contrast, East Asian countries were quite
good at detecting non-dynamic sectors and letting go
of them from their protectionist agenda.
Fourth, the administration needs to step up its fight
against economic fraud and deception. Private sector
actors are usually tempted to cash in on the protected
domestic market rather than investing in productivity
enhancements. For instance, the protective tariffs are
11
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
meant to provide the domestic entrepreneur with a
price advantage, in the hope that they will use this opportunity to improve efficiency and eventually become
able to produce the product independently in a cost-effective manner. However, unless the entrepreneur actually invests in R&D and technology development, this
expectation will not materialise. Also, trade protections
often go hand in hand with subsidies, which makes
the intentions of the investor even more crucial. If government support is being wasted on investments that
are more profitable in the short-run, rather than being
invested in long-run improvements in technological
sophistication, the government’s plan to develop domestic industries will fail. In fact, both Korea and Japan
not only monitored the financial accounts of protected
companies but also employed government officials
within these companies to keep them at arm’s length.
Companies, which did not invest in technological improvements, were cut from support.
Finally, it is imperative to put in place severe measures
against favouritism. Businesses always try to lobby the
government. They may endeavour to persuade authorities to expand protections towards their sectors and
extend them for much longer than needed. However,
this practice risks generating the problems mentioned
above, namely trying to protect too many sectors for
too long. Then, what starts as a well-planned protective scheme for a few strategic sectors may turn into a
mechanism to favour an inordinate number of companies and sectors at the cost of social welfare. Therefore,
the government should put in place well-defined criteria and a transparent procedure in determining which
sectors will be protected through tariffs or supported
with subsidies. Furthermore, monitoring and reporting
a technocratic bureaucracy should continue in a disciplined and transparent manner to prevent abuse of the
system.
Conclusion
Turkey is rightly celebrated as a success story for its
growth record in the 2000s. Impressive improvements
in the country’s economic fundamentals, such as its
public debt record and inflation rate, were accompanied by vast investments by the government in physical infrastructure across the country. These have enabled private industries to lead the way in a massive
expansion of labour-intensive manufacturing as well
as various service industries and multiply the average
citizen’s income level. However, in recent years, Turkey
has faced the pressure of rising external private sector
debt due to the country’s high account deficit. Moreover, Turkey faces a dearth of foreign capital inflows in
the wake of rising geopolitical tensions with the US and
other major powers over a number of regional issues.
Indeed, the rising risk premium associated with the
threat of sanctions by the US against Turkey has diverted some foreign investors from investing in Turkey.
Under these conditions, Turkey seems compelled to
change its approach to the country’s economic growth.
As discussed by many economists, increasing income
levels beyond middle-income range via labour-intensive manufacturing is mostly not possible. In order
to maintain a high growth trajectory and become a
high-income country, developing countries need to
transform their sectoral composition towards high-value-added, high-tech, and sophisticated industries with
12
higher export potential. Failing to accomplish this leads
to either growth slow-downs or rising external debt, as
has happened in Turkey. Therefore, Turkey’s economy
needs to transform towards sophisticated sectors with
better prospects for economic growth, which arguably
requires strategic leadership from the government and
its direct involvement through subsidies and trade protection.
In that regard, the paradigm change in the current government’s approach to the economy from a more market-based, liberal framework to a more interventionist
and proactive one becomes increasingly apparent in
recent years. As part of this new agenda, the government has been extending cheap and long-term credit
to strategic manufacturing industries, directly engaging with R&D intensive industries, such as defence or
renewable energy, and providing subsidies to critical
sectors such as electric cars. Most recently, in a momentous decision, the government announced that
it would be imposing higher tariffs on the country’s
imports in order to support domestic production in
strategic sectors. It is fair to say that the extraordinary
circumstances created by the Covid-19 crisis have laid
the basis for and encouraged this bold policy move by
the Turkish government. As globalisation and neo-liberal market fundamentalism are being criticised across
the world, and governments’ taking a more direct role
Can Turkey Emerge from Covid-19
as a 'Developmental State'?
in the economy becomes normalised, the Turkish government also seems encouraged to take this radical
step in line with its new approach.
Overall, Turkey’s growing developmental approach is
to be celebrated as a significant and vital step in order
to sustain the country’s development and become a
fully industrialised nation. Ironically, Covid-19 seems to
have been an enabling and encouraging factor in real-
ising this transition. However, in order for this agenda
to be successful, industrial policy and trade protections
particularly should be designed and implemented in a
pragmatic and sophisticated manner. This process potentially involves a trial-and-error mechanism as well as
constant revisions of government strategy. Although
there are risks involved in such radical policy moves,
they are worth taking to let the Turkish economy grow
and flourish in the long-term.
References
Aiyar, M. S., Duval, M. R. A., Puy, M. D., Wu, M. Y., & Zhang,
M. L. (2013). Growth slowdowns and the middle-income
trap (No. 13-71). International Monetary Fund.
Chang, H-J. (2002). Kicking away the ladder: development
strategy in historical perspective. Anthem Press.
Amsden, A. H. (1989). Asia’s next giant: South Korea and
late industrialisation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Chang, H. J. (2008). Bad Samaritans: The guilty secrets of
rich nations and the threat to global prosperity. Random
House.
Amsden, A. H. (1997). Bringing production back in—Understanding Government’s economic role in late industrialisation. World Development, 25(4), 469-480.
Chang, H-J. (2011). Industrial policy: can we go beyond an
unproductive confrontation? In Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics (pp. 83-109).
Başbay, M. M. (2019a). Turkey’s Economy: The case for
Industrial Policy. TRT World Research Centre. https://
Cherif, R., & Hasanov, F. (2019). The Return of the Policy
That Shall Not Be Named: Principles of Industrial Policy.
researchcentre.trtworld.com/publications/discussion-papers/turkey-s-economy-the-case-for-industrial-policy.
Başbay, M. M. (2019b). ‘Root of Turkey’s economic troubles: US foreign policy.’ Anadolu Agency. 9 May 2019.
https://www.aa.com.tr/en/analysis/root-of-turkeys-economic-troubles-us-foreign-policy/1474346.
Basbay, M. M. (2020). Reordering Capitalism: A New Economic World Order post-Covid-19. TRT World Research
Centre. https://researchcentre.trtworld.com/publications/
discussion-papers/reordering-capitalism-a-new-economic-world-order-post-covid-19.
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (2019). Current
Account Deficit Statistics. Retrieved from September 2019
Report.
Chang, H-J. (1993). The Political Economy of Industrial Policy in Korea, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1993, no.
2 (reprinted in H-J. Chang, The East Asian Development
Experience).
Ergöçün G. & Şahin, T. (2019). ‘Turkey announces $4.9B
financing for strategic sectors’. Anadolu Agency. 23 May
2019. www.aa.com.tr.
Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R., Timmer, M. P. (2015). The next
generation of the Penn World Table. The American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150-3182.
Mazzucato, M. (2013). The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths. Anthem Press.
Pamuk, Ş. (2012). Türkiye’nin 200 Yıllık İktisadi Tarihi.
Türkiye İş Bankası Kültür Yayınları.
Yağcı, M. (2017). The political economy of AK Party rule
in Turkey: From a regulatory to a developmental state?
Insight Turkey, 19(2), 89-114.
Wade, R. (1990). Governing the Market: Economic Theory
and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialisation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
World Bank (2020). Various country statistics on Turkey,
Data. [online] http://data.worldbank.org. [Accessed 10
June 2020].
13