International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
Equity Capital-Structure-Based Evaluation Method
Hassan El Ibrami (Corresponding author)
Department of Accounting
University of Quebec in Montreal
PO Box 8888, MontrealH3C 3P8, Canada
E-mail :
[email protected]
Tel:1 (514) 987 3 000 (ext 1818)
Ahmed Naciri
Department of Accounting
University of Quebec in Montreal
PO Box 8888, MontrealH3C 3P8, Canada
E-mail :
[email protected]
Tel :1 (514) 987 3 000 (ext 7765)
Received: October 15, 2012 Accepted: December 05, 2012 DOI: 10.5296/ijafr.v2i2.2537
Abstract
The main purpose of this paper is to theoretically compare three structural models presenting
several similarities and using financial statements within the context of real options theory. The
models are those suggested by i) Leland (1994); ii) Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) and iii)
Sarkar and Zapatero (2003). The analysis emphasizes convergence conditions of the three
models based on their respective dynamic equations. The results show that the first two models
represent special cases of the third one. The paper also presents a new equity and debt valuation
method.
Keywords: CSR Structural model, F230inancial statement, Equity, EBIT, Mean reversion,
Contingent claim, Convergence
299
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
1. Introduction
Very few capital-structure-based models can be used to evaluate companies. Also, most of
them assume no correlation between the market and the companies’ financial statements,
which we believe explains the market inefficiency. Our paper presents a new structural
evaluation model based on mean reversion assumptions and using financial statements
information. That being said, we start by comparing three existing structural models, namely i)
Leland (1994), ii) Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) and iii) Sarkar and Zapatero (2003).
Although these models present some discrepancies, they also have some similarities and this
is what makes the investigation of their convergence conditions very interesting. While
Leland (1994) and Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) use log normal processes for their
respective state variables, Sarkar and Zapatero(2003) suggest a mean reversion process. In
our paper, we emphasize the conditions that make their contingent claims expressions similar.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section II presents a literature review. Section
III focuses on our methodology. Section IV discusses the convergence between the three
models analyzed. Section V emphasizes our new evaluation method. Section VI presents our
conclusions. Proofs will be supplied upon request.
2. Literature Review
Very few capital-structure-based models can be used to assess securities. Some emphasize
debt evaluation and others the contingent claims approach by using the arbitrage between tax
shields and bankruptcy costs. Merton (1974) was actually the first author to consider equity
as an option. The underlying asset of this option is the firm’s value while debt represents its
strike price. Using a dynamic lognormal process equation, the author obtains a closed form
solution for his partial differential equation (PDE), similar to the Black-Scholes (1973)
equation.
Black and Cox (1976) reexamineMerton’s model but address subordinated debt and the
company’s solvency relationship issue, in order to better control a possible future financial
distress with regard to jump processes and bankruptcy threshold.
In the same vein, Zhou (2001) suggests a hybrid model that includes both continuous and
jump diffusion processes, in order to instantaneously capture new information that could
allow for an instantaneous bonds and equity evaluation with regard to bankruptcy threshold.
Long staffand Schwartz (1995) also use a process similar to Merton’s (1974), with the same
state variable; however, they propose a term structure of interest following a mean reversion
process like Vasicek(1977) and a non-zero-correlation between interest rate and assets value.
Their closed form solution is applicable for both fixed and variable rates of debt interest.
Brennan and Schwartz’s (1978) PDE closed form solution is also similar to Merton’s one but
can only be solved numerically because of its finite life debt. The two authors argue that debt
should be renewable and that its net effect on the company value is a consequence of the
arbitrage between tax shields and bankruptcy costs.
Brennan and Schwartz (1984) add that for solvency, debt should have a net positive effect on
the company value but a negative one in the case of distress, due to agency costs that
eliminate tax shields benefits should this last situation occur. Similarly, Ju et al. (2005) use
assets value as a state variable that follows a lognormal process and show that the company
300
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
can target a capital structure level that allows it to choose the best time to refinance the debt.
Leland and Toft (1996) extend the debate by considering that under a finite debt assumption,
time becomes important when determining the optimal capital structure and the arbitrage
between tax shields, bankruptcy costs and agency costs.
According to Sarkar and Mauer (2005), these agency costs emanate from conflicts between
equity holders and creditors about the best time to invest. Indeed, equity holders always
choose the timing that maximizes their wealth and by doing so, they transfer the risk to
creditors, which contributes to raising agency costs and diminishing company value.
The pioneer of the second structural models generation is Leland (1994) who proposes a new
approach based on the arbitrage between tax shields and bankruptcy costs. He argues that
these last two variables should be considered as contingent claims for his model’s PDE.
Consequently, a relationship between optimal capital structure and market value could be
established. Thus, equity holders continue holding company shares while reimbursing debt
and by doing so, they actually hold a call option whose underlying asset and strike price are,
respectively, the company value and the perpetual debt that pays a continuous coupon as long
as the company remains solvent. Indeed, in the case of bankruptcy, debt holders take
possession of company assets.
Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) find that Leland’s (1994) model is static and presents some
uncertainty induced by the non-negotiability of the assets value. According to the three
authors, the latter assumes a positive relationship between taxes and tax shields, presumed to
increase equity value. That implies a positive relationship between taxes and equity, which is
aberrant. Hence, a static capital structure overestimates the instantaneous growth of the
company value, which implies an unrealistic low threshold of bankruptcy probability. The
three authorssuggest that taxes be considered as contingent claims to be handled like equity
and debt. Hence, their value becomes proportional to the company’s. Considering a
lognormal process and EBIT as state variable, they derive a dynamic equation and obtain a
closed form solution for their PDE.
Similarly, Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) use an EBIT state variable that, however, follows a
mean reversion process, which helps to avoid the ambiguity surrounding the relationship
between taxes and the company value. They also point out the irrelevance of Leland’s (1994)
proportionality assumption between the continuous coupon and the company value, which
implies a non-constant value of the former. The two authors assume a constant perpetual
coupon that is insensitive to company earning variations but not to the company’s capital
structure.
Hackbarth, Henessy and Leland (2007) extend Leland (1994) and Goldstein, Ju and Leland
(2001) by considering two debt categories: bank debt and market debt. According to them,
the flexibility offered by banking debt reduces bankruptcy costs and then helps to optimize
the arbitrage relationship between those costs and the tax shield. Thus, small firms should use
bank debt to finance their projects while large firms that are looking for an optimal leverage,
should use a combination of bank debt and market debt while prioritizing the first one1.
1
This priority is respected in the case of default.
301
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
3. Methodology
First of all, we will investigate the convergence conditions of Leland (1994), Goldstein, Ju
and Leland (2001) and Sarkar and Zapatero (2003).To achieve this objective, we will use the
contingent claims closed form expressions, as obtained by the authors, to identify these
conditions analytically. We think that the first two models are just special cases of the third
one. We will then compare them separately with this last model. To do so, we will pay special
attention to the speed of mean reversion parameter value and use mathematical evidence to
obtain similar solutions for contingent claims. In fact, the three models present some
similarities but are also different in some respects.
We will also extend Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) by presenting a new computable valuation
method for contingent claims, mainly equity and debt, based on financial statements
information. We will again use mathematical evidence to obtain finite solutions for
contingent claims expressions and then avoid the computation problem caused by the
confluent hyper-geometric function present in all the contingent claims expressions of SZ.
This will make these contingent claims assessable, which will allow us to determine the
company value. Further analyses will help to extend the use of our new model to CEO
compensation, mergers and acquisitions, debt cost and cost of capital, stock-options and other
assets valuations.
4. Convergence Conditions of Three Structural Models
We examine the Leland (1994), Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001), and Sarkar and Zapatero
(2003) models. We begin by investigating the convergence between the Leland (1994) and
Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) models. Then, we check for convergence conditions between the
two EBIT models.
4.1. Leland (1994) model vs. Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) model
According to the Leland (1994) model2, equity value can be expressed as follows:
(1)
Where:
C represents the consolidated coupon;
represents assets volatility;
V represents the company’s assets value;
2
According to this model, the dynamic equation fulfilled by a contingent claim can be presented as follows:
dV = µVdt + σVdz
Where:
represents the company’s instantaneous growth rate;
represents assets volatility;
V represents the company’s assets value;
dz is a Wiener process.
302
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
VB represents the value of a company going bankrupt;
r represents the free rate of return;
τ represents the tax rate;
On the other hand, by solving the dynamic equation of the Sarkar and Zapatero(2003) model 3,
we obtain the following expression for equity:
(2)
Where:
V represents the company value;
VB represents the value of a company going bankrupt;
k represents the speed of mean reversion;
r represents the free rate of return;
C represents the bond value;
X represents the EBIT;
XL represents the EBIT value in the case of bankruptcy.
;
;
;
;
σ represents the company’s assets volatility;
;
3
The dynamic equation of this model can be presented as follows:
dx = k Θ − x dt + σxdz
Where:
x represents the EBIT;
k represents the speed of mean reversion;
Θrepresents the mean of earnings before interests and taxes;
Σ represents the assets volatility;
dz is a Wiener process.
303
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
;
If we consider the special case where “k” is equal to zero, the term “z” also becomes nil. In
this case, the expression of M(x) becomes equal to 1, regardless to the company’s solvency
level. Note that, under a zero mean reversion speed assumption, the term “ V2 ”becomesnil as
well. By considering this assumption, equation (2) becomes:
(3)
We can easily show that in the case of a nil mean reversion speed, the value of “γ” becomes:
(4)
But when the term “
expression
” is less than 1, which is a strong assumption for volatile assets,
”can be approximated by the following term:
(5)
If we insert this result into equation (4), the latter becomes:
(6)
Finally, by solving equation (6), we obtain the following result:
(7)
We can then conclude that, under a zero mean reversion speed assumption, the two equity
expressions become similar according to Leland (1994) and Sarkar and Zapatero (2003). We
will now determine the convergence conditions of Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) and
Sarkar and Zapatero (2003).
304
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
4.2. Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001) model vs. Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) model
Goldstein, Ju and Leland (2001)4 obtain the following expression for equity:
(8)
Where:
V represents the value of the company’s assets;
VB represents the value of the company going bankrupt;
C represents the consolidated coupon;
r represents the free rate of return;
τ represents the tax rate;
represents the volatility of returns.
If we consider risk neutrality, we can approximate µ as follows:
This hypothesis allows us to express the term “x” as follows:
(9)
Equation (9) is equivalent to equation (10) which can be presented as follows:
(10)
By inserting these results into GJL’s equity equation, its expression becomes identical to the
one of SZ. The results obtained in Section IV show that Leland (1994) and GJL (2001) are
just special cases of SZ (2003) and that the log-normality assumption is pertinent solely in the
absence of mean reversion. That being said, all the contingent claims expressions obtained by
this last model present a confluent hyper-geometric function that makes their computability
4
The dynamic equation of this model can be presented as follows:
Where:
dV + δdt
= rdt + σdz
V
V represents the value of the company’s assets
δ represents the EBIT;
σ represents the volatility of returns;
dz is a Wiener process.
305
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
unsuitable. In Section V, we present a new valuation technique based on finite solutions.
5. A New Capital-Structure-Based Valuation Method
The Sarkar and Zapatero (2003) model is a sophisticated one but cannot be operationalized
for contingent claims evaluation. In this section, we extend Sarkar and Zapatero’s (2003)
theory by presenting a new valuation method based on usual computable functions. We will
proceed by conducting a convergence analysis. So, we know that the term “M(X)” has a
minimum value of 1. We also know that the term “γ” can be presented as follows:
(11)
We also know that the parameter “b” of “M(x)” can be expressed as follows:
(12)
By developing this expression, we obtain the following:
(13)
So, we can easily demonstrate that "-γ = a" never exceeds the value of “b”5. We also know
that the nth term of “M(x)” can be expressed as follows:
(14)
Thus, when n tends to infinity, meaning that the company remains solvent, the expression
tends to 1, representing an upper boundary. We can then approximate “M(x)” as
follows:
(15)
Equation (15) represents the Taylor series expansion of an exponential function. Thus, we can
say that the confluent hyper-geometric function “M(x)” tends to the expression below:
(16)
5b
=1+
1+
2k 2
σ2
+
8r
σ2
≥
1+
2k 2
σ2
+
8r
σ2
≥
1+
2k 2
σ2
306
+
8r
σ2
− 1+
2k
σ2
≥
2k 2
8r
+ 2
σ2
σ
1+
2
2k
σ2
− 1+
= −γ
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
Since "k", "θ" and "σ" are finite terms, “M(x)”obviously converges when "x" becomes very
large. This allows us to express equity, in the case of solvency, as follows:
(17)
This expression represents a finite function that is easy to compute. We can then use it to
determine the fair value of equity.
6. Conclusion
One of the main purposes of this paper was to investigate conditions under which three
structural models became similar. The models we compared are Leland (1994), Goldstein, Ju
and Leland (2001), and Sarkar and Zapatero (2003). The three models have divergent
dynamic processes and non-identical state variables. The analysis showed that the first two
models were just special cases of the last one. We also established that the log-normality
hypothesis held just in the case of a zero-mean-reversion-speed.
Also, we presented a convenient stakeholders’ shares evaluation method, based on financial
statements information. Further investigations will allow us to measure the performance of
such a technique in evaluating a company’s fair value. The new evaluation method we
presented is equally useful for several other purposes like debt cost and cost of capital
estimation, CEO’S compensation, stock-options fair value determination and mergers and
acquisitions evaluation. Future empirical analyses using this model should be performed to
show the accounting information power in determining the proper value of company assets.
That being said, the model presents some limits. In fact, it is only useful for mean-reversion
companies. Furthermore, it can only be operationalized for companies with a positive EBIT
and a debt value lower than the company value as calculated by the model itself. The opposite
means that the company suffers financial distress.The model represents a first step towards
avoiding the market inefficiency while measuring an asset value. Further structural models
presenting lower restrictions will be performed to determine a company’s fair value.
References
Arnott, R. D., J. Hsu and P. Moore, 2005, Fundamental indexation, Financial Analysts
Journal 62, 83-99.
Black, F., and M. Scholes, 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of
political economy 81, 637-654.
Black, F., and John C. Cox, 1976, Valuing corporate securities: Some effects of bond
indenture provisions, Journal of Finance 31, 351-367.
Brennan, Michael J., and Eduardo S. Schwartz, 1978, Corporate income taxes, valuation, and
the problem of optimal capital structure, Journal of Business 51,103-114.
Brennan, Michael J., and Eduardo S. Schwartz, 1984, Optimal financial policy and firm
valuation, Journal of Finance 39, 593-607.
Briys, E. and F. DeVarenne, 1997, Valuing risky fixed rate debt, Journal of Financial and
307
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
Quantitative Analysis 32, 239-248.
Eom, Young H., J. Helwedge and Jing Z. Huang, 2004, Structural models of corporate bond
pricing: An empirical analysis, The Review of Financial Studies17, 499-544.
Geske, R., 1979, The valuation of compound options, Journal of Financial
Economics 7, 63-82.
Goldstein, R., N. Ju and Hayne E. Leland, 2001, An EBIT-based model of dynamic capital
structure, Journal of Business 74, 483-512.
Hackbarth, D., Christopher A. Hennessy and Hayne E. Leland, 2007, Can the tradeoff theory
explain debt structure?, The Review of Financial Studies 20, 1390-1428.
Hackbarth, D., J. Miao and E. Morellec, 2007, Capital structure, credit risk and
macroeconomic conditions, Journal of Financial Economics 82, 519-550.
Ju, N., R. Parrino, Allen M. Poteshman and Michael S. Weisbach, 2005, Horses and rabbits?
Trade-Off theory and optimal capital structure, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 40, 259 -281.
Leland, Hayne E., 1994, Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure,
Journal of Finance 49, 1213-1252.
Leland, Hayne E., 1998, Agency costs, risk management, and capital structure, Journal of
Finance 53, 12O.1243.
Leland, Hayne E., and Klaus B. Toft, 1996, Optimal capital structure, endogenous bankruptcy,
and the term structure of credit spreads, Journal of Finance 51,987-1019.
Longstaff, Francis A., and Eduardo S. Schwartz, 1995, A simple approach to valuing fixed
and floating rate debt, Journal of Finance 50, 789-819.
Mella-Barral, P., and W. Perraudin, 1997, Strategic debt service, Journal of Finance 52,
531-556.
Merton, Robert C., 1974, On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates,
Journal of Finance 29, 449-470.
Modigliani, F., and M. Miller, 1958, The cost of capital, corporate finance and the theory of
investment, American Economic Review 48, 261-297.
Ranaldo, A., and R. Häberle, 2007, Wolf in sheep’s clothing : The active investment
strategies behind index performance, European Financial Management 14, 55–81.
Sarkar, S., 2003, The effect of mean reversion on investment under uncertainty, Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control28, 377-396.
Sarkar, S., and F. Zapatero, 2003, The trade-off model with mean reverting earnings : Theory
and empirical evidence, Economic Journal113, 834-860.
Sarkar, S., and D. Mauer, 2005, Real options, agency conflicts, and optimal capital structure,
Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 1405-1428.
Turnbull, Stuart M., 1979, Debt Capacity, Journal of Finance34, 931-940.
Vasicek, O., 1977, An equilibrium characterization of the term structure,Journal of Financial
Economics 5, 177-188.
308
www.macrothink.org/ijafr
International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting
ISSN 2162-3082
2012, Vol. 2, No. 2
Zhou, C., 2001, The term structure of credit spreads with jump risk, Journal of Banking And
Finance 25, 2015-2040.
309
www.macrothink.org/ijafr