Chapter 1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
Daniel Berg
Abstract Before the implementation of an international policy regime with the
aim of restricting the trade in opiates beginning in 1912, the free availability of
opiates in domestic and international trade was the norm. Opiates were not unregulated, however. Another set of policies ruled the day, formed by other preconceptions of the dangers of drugs and by a high degree of consciousness of the limits
of state power. Examining both these preconceptions and limits from a comparative perspective, this chapter describes how a discourse featuring opium as a poison accompanied regulations that took great care not to exacerbate the effects of a
dual market in opium but rather to regulate “on the cheap.” Assessed both by its
own set of goals in a historical context much different from ours and anachronistically in light of latter-day prohibition regulations, this chapter suggests that maybe
the prior approach of regulating opium as a poison should not be deemed a
failure.
Introduction
The signing of the Hague Convention on Opium in 1912 was the irst step on the
road to a global narcotics policy of prohibition. Behind this unprecedented effort to
coordinate trade policy internationally was a strong new political alliance concerning drug use, combining otherwise rather different discourses—military needs,
medicalization of social problems, and moral idealism—into a strong medicomoral-military discourse that would come to dominate drug policy during the twentieth century. Beginning in The Hague, a new problem with opium came to the
fore—the very availability of drugs.
As this chapter shows, the availability of opium until this time had not been seen
primarily as a problem but rather as a precondition for public health. The Hague
Convention was a momentous step in a new regulatory direction. But it was neither
D. Berg (*)
Department of Economic History, Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden
e-mail:
[email protected]
© Springer International Publishing AG 2017
E.U. Savona et al. (eds.), Dual Markets, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-65361-7_1
3
4
D. Berg
the irst effort to regulate opium internationally nor a regulation of a previously
nationally unregulated or free opium market during the nineteenth century.1 The
opium problem was already being regulated, nationally and through international convention, but the older regulation addressed a different problem with opium. This chapter examines what those alternative problems were and how they were regulated.
There are two lines of questioning to follow with these regulations: In what ways
did this former regulatory regime tie into and precondition the later prohibitionist
regime? How can these regulations be assessed in terms of their stated goals and
results? This history of the nineteenth century will describe not only a different kind
of regulation, but will also present a very different image of opium itself.
Using, Abusing, Amusing Opium
A Historical Background of the Culture and Trade in Opium
Before 1912
It is not surprising that opium regulations predate The Hague, not least because opium
itself has a very long history. The opium poppy, Papaver somniferum, from which the
alkaloid-containing juice is collected to produce raw opium, has been used for
5000 years.2 It was regulated through cultural and informal practices long before the
modern nation-state began to cast its judicial gaze upon the plant’s many profound
effects.3
During early modern times, opium was part of a worldwide culture of popular
medicine and a culture of smoking in East Asia. This culture of smoking was as
sophisticated as that of wine in Europe: color, taste, consistence, and potency
were elements of the pricing and appreciation of the drug among consumers in
many classes (Haugne 2009, p. 42). It was this mode of use, aimed at intoxicating
effects, that was the target of the irst attempts at prohibition in 1729 in China, and
again in the Shanghai conference of 1909, the precursor to the Hague Convention
of 1912.
1
The fact that the International Opium Convention of 1912 was the irst binding international regulation on the narcotics trade to focus on the problematization of the recreational effects of narcotics
is often conlated with the notion that this problem is the foremost problem with opium and thus
the only one to be internationally regulated. An example of this understanding of the Hague
Convention can be found in Melissa Bull’s very comprehensive and clear history of opium regulation as a narcotic. “The Hague Opium Convention of 1912 was the irst international convention in
which an attempt was made to regulate opium and related substances” (Bull 2008, p. 64).
2
The early history of opium is described in countless books on the history of drugs, combining
various ancient sources to paint a quite colorful picture, as in Davenport-Hines 2001, pp. 7–14.
Archeological research placing the earliest human use of opium in the Alps during the late
Paleolithic is explored in Gerritsen 2000, pp. 41–48.
3
These informal types of regulation are mostly overlooked in this chapter in favor of discussing
legal opium regulations before 1912.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
5
During “the long nineteenth century,” prohibition to combat intoxication was
clearly an issue subject to iscal, not moral, consideration by the states.4 The
interest of the most powerful states of the day lay rather in the furthering of trade
in intoxicants, since their fast-growing bureaucracies were more or less drugdependent. In Europe, this meant taxing alcohol;5 in Asia, it meant taxing the
opium trade.6
Opium was not more freely traded in Asia than in Europe during this time, but
only in Asia did its use as an intoxicant come to the fore.7 Generally, this whole
century can be characterized by free availability, low prices, and a manifold of popular uses for psychoactive drugs, irst among them the opiates.
The popular types of opiates in Europe during the era before 1912 can be roughly
placed in two broad categories: irst, tinctures and pills where opium was the main
but often not the only ingredient and, second, pure alkaloids, often in a chloral solution to be administered by injection (from 1853 on). The irst category appealed to
users of lesser means, lacking access to (or prescriptions from) doctors; the latter
appealed to users in the middle class, frequently women who were prescribed morphine for various ailments historically considered speciic to women. In both types
of use, the line between palliative therapeutic effect and pleasure was thin or irrel4
“The long nineteenth century” is the focus in this chapter, spanning the years from 1789 to 1914.
The phrase was coined by Eric Hobsbawm in his three-volume epic about this period, starting with
The Age of Revolution: Europe 1789–1848, New York, 1962. Since this framing better captures the
homogeneities of an era than the numerological chronology of centuries, it has been widely
adopted. The same is very true for the history of drug regulation: the Hague Convention of 1912 is
a better date to signify the beginning of global drug prohibition than the year 1900.
5
Gerritsen shows how a third of the iscal base in Great Britain, the United States, and the
Netherlands was alcohol tax revenue until the Great War: “… excise on alcohol accounted for a
large proportion of total state revenue – varying from 25% to little over 40% – throughout the
nineteenth century” (Gerritsen 2000, p. 244).
The same proportion of the iscal base is derived from alcohol taxation in Sweden, at least since
the last quarter of the nineteenth century (Gårestad 1987, chapter 3).
Other drug taxation was of less but not insigniicant value: “Colonial empires were built on the
foundation of drug trades. So were many domestic bureaucracies and armies. Tariffs on tea, sugar,
and tobacco accounted for a signiicant part of the revenue of numerous seventeenth- and eighteenth-century states” (Pommeranz and Topik 1999, p. 78).
6
The importance of the opium trade for the European empires in Asia is most poignantly captured
thus: “Opium came to be an essential element, indeed the cash cow, in the inances of every Asian
state structure during the nineteenth century and even during the irst part of the twentieth” (Trocki
1999, p. 9).
7
It is beyond the scope of this chapter to explain this segmentation of the global drug market during
the early modern era, and this chapter only discusses regulatory developments in Europe and the
United States. Sufice it to say that many factors probably were at play (and all are thoroughly
discussed in much of the referenced literature for this chapter): the unique combination of smoking
opium along with tobacco that developed in Southeast Asia in the seventeenth century; the strong
culture of alcohol in the West acting as a competing, much cheaper intoxicant; the closeness of
China and India to the best opium production areas (besides Turkey, these were Persia, India, and
China itself); and inally, the very structure of trade relations in the emerging world system, making exporting opium to China a prime imperative for European traders in Asia and the East India
Company in particular.
6
D. Berg
evant. What was pleasurable with opium was also part of what was deemed the
valuable medicinal effect. What looks like a fast-growing market for medicinal opiates during this long century must thus be understood to contain a great deal of
recreational use as well.
Recreational or not, the market did expand.8 In Britain, the decades before 1870
have been described as the era of the “Great Victorian Drug Bazaar” (Parssinen
1983, pp. 1–58). During this expansion, a more problematic view of opium was
formed.
As these problems became a focus of public debate, doctors and pharmacists
articulated the regulatory answers around their own agenda of professionalization.
Beginning in 1870, an internationally quite coherent regulatory regime of opium
was in place throughout Europe, ending the most bazaar-like part of the long nineteenth century. How pharmacists came to insert themselves in the early problematizing discourse is the irst step in understanding opium regulation before 1912, so
this is the irst subject of inquiry in this chapter.
Opium Regulated as a Poison
Of the two categories of use sketched above, it was the diverse and growing use of
opium tinctures and pills in the lower classes that was seen as a problem to be regulated. Injection of and addiction to morphine did not become a problem of great
concern for the judiciary until more marginal groups in society took up this type of
use around the First World War.9 Several different problems converged with the
popular use of opium in tinctures and pills.
In industrializing Britain, mothers in factory towns had to work outside the
home, leaving their smallest children with nannies. Their use of opium “paciiers”
was the primary concern in the early public health campaigns, even though this use
8
The rise in domestic opium consumption has been calculated from Britain’s parliamentary papers
as doubling in absolute numbers between the 1820s and the 1840s and increasing by 50% again in
the two decades thereafter (Berridge and Grifith 1999, table 2, p. 294).
For the United States, David Courtwright estimates that imports rose especially quickly beginning in the 1840s (though the statistical records are somewhat patchy). In a country with a fastgrowing population, the per capita import may have tripled in less than 20 years. The rise continued
during the last quarter century, for both smokable opium and medicinal opiates (Courtwright 2001,
p. 15–34).
The British export of opium to China took off during the same period, beginning in the mid1820s and growing until 1890 (Trocki 1999, table 5.1, p. 93, and table 6.1, p. 111).
When one notes the gradual stagnation of the British opium trade to China in the late 1800s, it
is important to note the very strong Chinese production, supplying about 80% of the domestic
market at that time (Newman 1995, pp. 765–794).
9
Until then, it was thought to be best handled through medical self-regulation, as was the case with
all the new pathologies of addiction, from the irst medical diagnosis of alcoholism by Swedish
physician Magnus Huss in the 1850s through the discovery of morphinism by German doctor
Levinstein in the 1870s and beyond.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
7
and the accompanying fatal poisonings and stunted growth among the children were
no more concentrated among these nannies than among the stay-at-home mothers of
the more well-to-do (Berridge and Grifith 1999, pp. 97–105).
The recreational use of laudanum and opium pills to supplement alcohol in the
search for inebriation on weekends also frequently had fatal consequences, both
drugs being respiratory depressants with clear poly-pharmaceutical effects. This
same danger was present in cases of self-medication with alcohol-based tinctures of
opiates. Suicides and the occasional murders were also part of the picture that
emerged in the irst half of the nineteenth century.
The canvas for this picture of opium as a problem was the new state-sponsored
publication of national statistics. Through this modern means of conjuring up the
population of a state as a national body, a new regulatory regime formed all over
Europe. Opium as a poison played a decisive part in this system.10
One regulatory solution to these problems was restricting the sale of all opiates
to people with a doctor’s prescription (today’s accepted solution). This regulation
beneitted the expanding professionalization of physicians and was one that they
favored. But, in the totality of regulations implemented in several European countries, this form of regulation did not win the day.11 It was often seen as too intrusive,
and, by increasing prices, it made opiates unaffordable for ordinary users. Instead,
another part of the picture gleaned from health statistics became central to regulatory solutions, and a profession in a sometimes bitter struggle with medical doctors
became its champion. The prioritized problem: the opaque and inconsistent strength
of doses of opium in the market. The solution: a regulatory mishmash centered
mostly on the well-educated, moral, and professional pharmacist. The goal: to keep
opium available to the people.
The Discourse of Opium as a Poison
Through a narrative including phrases such as impurities, mistakes, incoherent recipes, non-professional, and sloppy producers and merchants, a discourse formed that
made the availability of opium in pharmacies a precondition of its safety, not the
core of its problem. I call this understanding of opium propagated by pharmacists
during the late 1800s the “discourse of poison” (Berg 2016).
This discourse aimed its attack at the state of the market for opiates as a whole,
keeping any critique of the consumers peripheral.
The sale of opiates during the bazaar years was conducted by pharmacists and all
kinds of vendors without any certiied knowledge. In Britain, the sellers numbered
“… between 16,000 and 26,000, although even this number probably did not include
10
“Opium statistics were used as public health propaganda” (Berridge and Grifith 1999, p. 78).
In the discussion below, I present an overview of the regulations, addressing the differences
between countries in the parts of this chapter examining the effects of regulations and in the
discussion.
11
8
D. Berg
small ‘general’ stores dealing in all manner of goods as well as opiates” (Berridge
and Grifith 1999, p. 25). The situation seems to have been similar, although smaller,
in the United States and the Netherlands.12
Opiate sales, whether at pharmacies or at the grocer’s, didn’t feature standardized containers with consistent labeling. Instead, in Britain and Sweden, customers
brought bottles and boxes with them as containers for their purchased opium,
increasing the risk of dosing errors at home.13 Nor were the recipes for the different
opium tinctures consistent, making the habitual dosage for one tincture inappropriate for the wares of a different producer.
Furthermore, the alkaloid content of opium sold in this rather unregulated market
could vary quite a lot, for more than one reason. At any point in the long commodity
chain, the drug could be adulterated to increase proit margins by weight, or the
producer of the tincture could fail to probe and standardize the alkaloid content due
to economic incentives or lack of know-how.14
All these problems in the opiate market were intricately presented in the discourse of opium as a poison to encourage regulations that would steer the entire
trade to the pharmacies.
Through the centrality of acute poisoning in the discourse, “poison” was articulated as the chief semiotic element in any discourse on the opium problem. This, in
turn, made the knowledge of poison—of pharmakon—essential to regulating, managing, and selling opium.15 This knowledge is, by birthright or just by etymology, a
prerogative of the pharmacist. Thus, by centering the discourse on poison, an autonomous ield of expertise was articulated for the pharmacists.
In this discourse, the dangers of having opium on the market didn’t lie in its
availability, but in its handling by inexpert traders. These traders were primarily
responsible for adulteration and the frequent variations in the drug. Only privileges
for pharmacists, enabling them to provide safe, clean doses in as accessible a way
as possible, could solve this problem.
12
“All in all, the consumption of opiates, in both Britain and the United States, was a conspicuous
phenomenon in the irst half of the nineteenth century. And the situation in the Netherlands is
unlikely to have been very different. This widespread use of opiates was not accompanied by any
form of statutory regulation” (Gerritsen 2000, p. 123).
13
This “… method of sale was almost universal” (Berridge and Grifith 1999, p. 31) and was also
motivated by the extra cost to the customer of special pharmacy glass bottles (Berg 2016, chapter
5).
14
“There was indeed no guarantee that the shopkeeper would have any knowledge of poisons at all,
even though some obviously learnt by experience” (Berridge and Grifith 1999, p. 27).
15
Pharmakon in ancient Greek meant drug, poison, or medicine. (It is, of course, the etymological
root of the word “pharmacist.”) This varied meaning of the word for medicinal drugs is often only
mentioned as a curiosity in the mainstream literature on pharmacists. For example, compare the
description by the pharmacy historians Kremers and Urdang in their standard History of Pharmacy
(1951, p. 19) to the elaborate deconstruction of the term by the non-pharmacist Derrida in his “La
Pharmacie de Platon” in La Dissémination (1972, pp. 69–198). But it is meaningful: the pharmacies were general stores for poisons until the twentieth century, selling not only medicines but also
agricultural pesticides and herbicides and poisonous ingredients for industrial use.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
9
Unlike many doctors, the pharmacists emphasized the customer’s own sensus
communis as a valid and adequate form of knowledge about opium. The problem
was not the customer’s unawareness but the market failures making it dificult for
them to learn about safe use.
In this discourse, the customer’s knowledge included the uses for the drug, but
not the formula of the recipe, which was exclusive to the pharmacists. The proposal
to mandate a written recipe from a physician when buying opiates was nevertheless
felt to be unnecessary: the knowledge of the recipe was primarily pharmaceutical.
As long as the recipe was prepared by someone with great pharmaceutical
knowledge, no doctor had to intervene as a costly middleman. This part of the discourse did not always carry through all the way. Through prescriptions, doctors
generally did gain a monopoly on the more powerful opiates like chloral solutions
of pure morphine. But the regulations put in place in the middle of the nineteenth
century largely followed the direction set by the discourse of poison, making the
pharmacy central to control and safety until the Hague Convention of 1912.
The Sum of Its Parts
During the period of poison regulations, national regimens were substituted for the
varied earlier regulations by municipalities, cities, and regions. This happened at
rather different times depending on the nation-state. Also, the types of poison and
the pharmacy regulations enacted on the national level varied quite a bit between
countries. These differences are addressed below, but irst I outline a coherent,
Europe-wide, or broader regime of poison regulations, dating from about 1850 to
1912.
The constituent parts of the regime were (1) regulations giving physicians and
pharmacists the exclusive right to handle various opiates as poisonous medicines.
These professions in turn became subject to strict rules on how to (2) store, (3) label,
(4) prepare, and (5) register the sale of these poisons as medicines.
It is fascinating that the sale and handling of poisons remained very lightly regulated by the state until the middle of the nineteenth century. The story of stronger
poison regulations after this time is revealing. Opium, in essence, became regulated
the way arsenic was, not the other way around. This tells the tale of a quickly industrializing world; it is with the new abilities to produce and transport large quantities
of chemicals that the need and the capacity for national poison regulation arose.16
Explaining why opium regulations change is not the aim of this chapter. Having said that, there
is a case to be made that the process of industrialization contains much of the story of how opium
became regulated as a poison freely available at the pharmacy—and how the pharmacy lost this
role. As the local pharmacist stopped producing drugs and was demoted to a mere distributor of
industrial pharmaceuticals around the turn of the twentieth century, this destabilized the underpinnings of the pharmacists’ discourse of opium as a poison, at the same time that the new discourse
of opium as a narcotic, with prohibitionist regulations as a solution, was getting stronger.
Destabilization of one discourse allows another to expand, to explain new problems, and to exert
power.
16
10
D. Berg
Giving the pharmacies a monopoly on the sale of arsenic created a central location in this newly mobile world where they could control the substance and regulate
the different aspects of its use. This, in turn, strengthened the impetus to concentrate
more of the commodity chain with the pharmacist, creating valuable agglomeration
effects. By centralizing the handling of poison in pharmacies, the state gained a
valuable point of departure for all kinds of demands on the regulations written for
many types of poison. Most of the different regulations that were initially directed
against arsenic were gradually pressed into service to regulate opiates. First among
these were the stricter laws on storing and labeling opium.
As described above, accidental poisonings were presented as the main problem
to be regulated. The irst objective for the regulating authorities was often to keep
opiates apart from other substances, in stores as well as in homes. Special cabinets
in which the opiates could be stored under lock and key were thus required, guaranteed safe by the pharmacist’s special ability to identify, isolate, and purify each
poison.
Opiates were placed in those cabinets along with all the other poisons, making
the accidental substitution of opium for arsenic a new danger. Regulations demanding speciic labeling of all containers of poisons thus complemented the rules on
separate storage for poisons as such. This special labeling, on the containers in
which opiates were sold as well as on those in which they were stored in the pharmacist’s cabinet, was not only used to designate the name of the substance but soon
also to distinguish different classes of poisons. The more poisonous drugs regulated
under Schedule 1, for example, could have a distinctive label corresponding to a
speciic shelf in the cabinet.17 The system could become quite elaborate as pharmaceutical knowledge of different poisons became more detailed, making possible
ever more distinct regulations.18
A quite different sort of opium regulation was the gradual homogenization of the
formulas for preparing the opium tinctures and pills sold in the pharmacies. As
mentioned above, different producers of remedies containing opium could use the
same names for tinctures with quite different opium contents, and the opium being
used could have widely varying alkaloid contents because of adulteration or natural
variations in the drug.
Ever since medieval times, physicians have written collections of recipes, sometimes including detailed descriptions of the drugs and their properties, called pharmacopoeias. The professional evolution of pharmacists involved using these books
17
This system of a regulatory taxonomy of poisons based on their different degrees of toxicity was
certainly lexible. Authorities could easily accommodate new scientiic developments or changes
in the socioeconomic context for using different poisons, simply by reclassifying it in a new schedule instead of creating speciic new regulations. The classiication of drugs under different schedules could easily be transferred to other regulatory frameworks for drugs, such as the perceived
dangers of addiction or the anti-social properties of different drugs. Indeed, this seems to be what
happened.
18
In Sweden, the different regulatory classes of poisons were labeled with different colors (in addition to using the alchemical sign for mercury to designate toxicity alone), making a poison cabinet
very similar to a poisonous snake in its striking coloration.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
11
to make their opiates safe from adulteration and naturally occurring variations of
alkaloids, by homogenizing the ingredients and guaranteeing consistency from one
batch to the next.
The formulas the pharmacists used were collected in different pharmacopoeias.
These books could be very old, though not as old as some of the recipes in them,
which could be ancient. The books could come from all over Europe, or they could
be of peculiar local origin. The ingredients in a similarly named remedy could vary,
as could the doses of opium. As national markets were forged by steel, steam, and
nationally standardized time, this became a problem in the discourse of opium as a
poison: as remedies were sold in more distant locations and as consumers traveled,
accidental poisonings due to confusion about dosage became a possibility; the consumer’s knowledgeable use became more dificult. This threatened the articulation
of free availability of opiates through the pharmacy. After regulations on labeling
and storing poison, the next regulatory route was usually the harmonization of the
formulas for opiates in national pharmacopoeias, turning them into legislative regulations as well as textbooks and collections of recipes specifying the doses for poisons such as opium in each tincture.
As the medical profession laboriously constructed national pharmacopoeias to
address the new reality of the national market, an international market developed. In
1870, the integration of global markets became frantic, as if the booming international cocaine trade at this time not only epitomized the era but also drove it (Spillane
2000; Pommeranz and Topik 1999). Developing alongside the new industries of
steel and motors (electrical and combustion engines), this second industrial revolution was primarily the result of the new chemical-pharmaceutical industry. To apply
the discourse of poison to the new wares coming out of Merck in Darmstadt and
Bayer in Barmen, an international agreement had to be made to harmonize the different national pharmacopoeias.
The irst international pharmaceutical congress was held in Brunswick in 1865 to
discuss these emerging trends, among other things (Kremers and Urdang 1951,
pp. 170–172). Despite its early beginning and nine subsequent congresses, the pharmacists reached no agreement on this before the national governments sent their
medical authorities to Brussels in 1902 and agreed to create the irst international
standards for poison regulation, which were signed in Paris in 1906. The control of
opiates as poison was a major driver of the standards.19 This control of the knowledge of the recipe thus slipped from the hands of the nationally self-regulating pharmacists to the nations, acting on a global stage. The twentieth century had indeed
commenced.
19
In an authoritative study of the emergence of the international system of control of chemicals in
general, a “Chronological list of events selected from the text because of their special importance
for the development of chemicals control” introduces the text. Opiates were the subject of four of
the irst ive (Lönngren 1992, pp. 3–16). This centrality of opiates is not discussed in the text as
such, just as the opiates and their ambiguous role as poisonous and pleasurable non-medical commodities are mostly disregarded in the literature on the history of pharmacy. As already mentioned,
the international regulation of opiates as poisons before the Hague Convention is also not addressed
in the general history of drugs.
12
D. Berg
The last part of the regulatory framework to be implemented was usually the
registry of sales in dedicated accounting books. In these registers, a radically different type of knowledge of poison was required. These books contained the names of
the customers, the amounts purchased, the location, and sometimes the intended use
for the substance.
Tracking and regulating the name/quantity/location/intent was aimed at controlling not the quality of the poison at the point of sale but its quantitative circulation
through society. Neither pharmacists nor physicians had any advantage in this type
of regulation: knowing these things was the specialty of other professions, such as
accountants, police oficers, and customs oficials.
This type of registry-regulation irst brought prohibitionist regulations into the
picture: the Hague Convention on Opium of 1912 started a new era in the history of
drugs by regulating the low of trade internationally and by registering name/quantity/location/intent. If the problem with opium is articulated not as a problem of
lethal poisoning but as issues related to the quantities used (habitual use seen as a
problem of addiction, rising use and imports seen as an epidemic that is an external
threat to the body politic), then regulations that focus on the drug’s availability
become prioritized. This sort of regulation was adopted from the last addendum to
the regulations of opium as a poison, the registry-regulation irst implemented to
control arsenic.
Measuring Effects, Comparing Differences
In what way do the failings of the opium regulations prior to 1912 inluence later
developments? Can the regulation of opium as a poison be said to have been effective in any certain way? In short, how do we measure the regulations that—along
with the belle époque—were left behind as the world marched off to war?
As mentioned, the system of poison regulations is a construct made from very
different parts. The type and the pace of regulations varied among countries. A irst
way to approach our questions is by picking apart this all-too-neat construct. The v
below (Table 1.1) contains rough estimates of these differences, along with some
other qualitative measures for each country. One pattern is discernible when it
comes to the regulation of poisons: France, Sweden, and the Netherlands form one
group and the Anglo-Saxon countries form the other.
The former group introduced stronger and earlier national poison regulations,
beginning in the late seventeenth century, having established a monopoly on the
trade in poisons for the pharmacies in the irst half of the nineteenth century, including all or most of the opiates.20
20
The irst regulations on the trade in opium as a poison were enacted in France in 1680. In 1845,
pharmacies were given a monopoly on the retail sale of opiates, and they and the wholesalers who
served them were subject to most of the poison regulations mentioned above, as well as the extra
regulation of only being allowed to sell opiates to individuals with a written prescription. The
1
13
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
Table 1.1 Regulatory aspects 1850–1900
Strong regulations of opium as a
poison and as a monopoly for the
pharmacya
Strong problematization of acute
poisonings
High opiate consumption per capita
Strong problematization of
recreational use
Clear signs of dual markets
USA
No
Great
Britain
No
The
Netherlands
Yes
France
Yes
Sweden
Yes
No
Quite
Yesb
Yes
Quite
Yes
Yes
Yes
Quite
Yesb
No
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yesb
Yes
No
a
Including labeling, storage, preparation, and accounting, as described above
b
Uncertain estimation
In the United Kingdom, similar pharmaceutical and poison regulations were
indeed implemented from 1851 to 1868, but due to the placement of opiates in
Schedule 2 until their rescheduling in 1908, only the labeling rules affected their
sale (Berridge and Grifith 1999, p. 116, p. 120; Padwa 2012, p. 92). In the United
States, no federal legislation was enacted to regulate the sale of opiates as poison
until the 1906 Pure Food and Drug Act.21 It seems we have a tale of two types of
opium regulations.
Prohibition Unexplained
This division of poison regulations into two groups has only limited explanatory
power with respect to eventual prohibition. These groupings of poison regulations
do not hold irm, nor can much be inferred from the types of poison regulations to
explain the later adherence to the new narcotics policy in the Hague Convention.
French regulations were clearly the most stringent (Retaillaud-Bajac 2009, p. 30; Padwa 2012,
pp. 109–110).
The Dutch regulations also were enacted early, but in a reverse order from those in other countries. In 1818, stringent poison regulations on storage, labeling, and accounting were implemented
in pharmacies, but it was not until 1865 that the pharmacies were also given a monopoly on the
trade in opiates (Gerritsen 2000, pp. 130–131).
In Sweden, pharmacies were given their monopoly on the opium trade in 1688 and on poisons
in general in 1756 (in the major cities) and 1786 (nationally). The regulation of poisons was
strengthened in 1876 to include all the parts mentioned above, but some popular opium tinctures
were omitted, leaving opiates strictly regulated as pharmaceuticals but not strongly regulated as
poisons (Berg 2016, chapter 2).
21
The US case is, as always, complicated by the fact that the federal government, especially at that
time, did not interfere much in state politics, and some states imposed more stringent regulations
on opium as a poison as early as 1895 (Courtwright 2001, pp. 52–53; Gerritsen 2000,
pp. 134–135).
14
D. Berg
Both France and Sweden had old and rather strong poison regulations with a
centrality initially given to their respective pharmacies; France and Sweden had
signiicantly lower use per capita than the United Kingdom.22 But France problematized the dual market connected to addiction and took up prohibitionist policies
early on, framed in what Howard Padwa calls an “anti-narcotic nationalism” (Padwa
2012, chapter 2). Sweden didn’t have any signiicant opium problem (no disruptive
dual market, no addiction, no acute poisonings strongly problematized) and rather
unwillingly signed the Hague Convention in 1923.
Both the United Kingdom and the United States had high levels of use per capita,
lax poison regulations, and a big patent medicine market. But unlike France and the
United States, there was not as strong a problematization of recreational opiate use
in the United Kingdom, and the country resisted the prohibitionist agenda internationally.23 The United States, of course, was famously the victim of the “American
disease” of heroin addiction, and the United States was comparable to France in its
problematization of recreational opiate use and has been the driving force behind
prohibitionist regulations internationally from 1909 into the twenty-irst century.24
The types of poison regulations in place do not seem to have strongly inluenced
how prohibitionist regulations were adopted. Clearly, other historically speciic factors are more important: the First World War; country-speciic conceptions of class,
race, and empire; geopolitical interests; and shifts in power are arguably more central.25 It seems that the varying eficacy of different domestic regulations in tackling
the fatal dangers of opiates was clearly of secondary importance in the formative
process leading to the international prohibitionist regime at large.26
This does not exclude, however, other interesting questions about the effects of
poison-control regulations and how they handled the potential emergence of a dual
market.
22
Padwa estimated from import igures that consumption of opium was 4.3 times higher in the
United Kingdom than in France at the beginning of the century (Padwa 2012, p. 67). Judging from
the same type of source, Swedish opium use at the same time was smaller still, 10 or 15 times less
than British use (Compare Berridge and Grifith 1999, igure 3, p. 35 to Berg 2016, chart 2, p. 82.).
23
The United Kingdom had a quick “in-and-out” domestic prohibitionist regime during and just
after the war, after which the famously liberal regime of the Rolleston era took center stage.
24
“American disease” is the term coined by Musto to capture the speciically American drug problem taking hold around the turn of the twentieth century (Musto 1973).
25
The argument for these factors being most central to the formation of the new prohibitionist
regime is also well presented in Jay 2000 and Trebach 1982.
26
Actual fatalities from popular use of pharmaceutical opiates didn’t in the least inspire the new
prohibitionst regime, and thus, neither did they motivate the regulations aimed at this problem.
More surprisingly, perhaps, neither did addiction to morphine or heroin at irst; opium smoking
did. David Courtwright makes this point in his account of the US initiatives around 1909. The
problematizing focus was irmly set on opium smoking, not the then-nascent heroin addiction in
some minority groups. But, as he shows, the ban on smoking opium drove the less empowered
addicts to take up the needle and the “white stuff” so pejoritatively named by the smokers, thereby
creating the conditions for the Harrison Act of 1914 (Courtwright 2001, pp. 82–83, p. 111).
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
15
Regulating on the Cheap
As noted above, until the First World War, states relied to a signiicant degree on
taxing drugs, thus reducing their willingness to prohibit drug use. That should be
kept in mind when evaluating opium regulation during this era. But more than that,
nineteenth-century states generally lacked the power to enforce strict regulations of
economic life at the local level. Regulations had to be very cost effective or they
would produce nothing but hot air and a thriving dual market.
For the authorities regulating opium during this time, the threat of smuggling and
the emergence of a dual market were a constant consideration and indeed a demonstrable outcome of harsh legislation.27 With states facing the problem of a deadly poison at large, on the one hand, and the impotence of prohibitive measures, on the other
hand, the situation could easily have been viewed as hopelessly stuck. This is part of
the scenario to consider when evaluating the effects of poison regulations. The costsensitivity of regulations during this time, however, didn’t mean that there was no
room to maneuver at all. Some regulations were evidently both cheap and effective.
Addiction Without Regulation: Cheap or Cheat?
Regulating opium as a poison, leaving it available for common use, certainly made
habitual use or outright addiction a possibility for consumers. Strong poison regulations with sales restricted to individuals with a written prescription, such as those in
France, did not hinder the emergence of this type of use.28
The two most evident cases of persistent and wide-reaching addiction were
opium eating in the Fens in England, and morphinism in the United States among
former Civil War soldiers and among southern, rural, white women. For these
groups, continuation of their habits was not hindered by regulations and, indeed,
continue they did. But no narcotics epidemic spread from them to society at large.
Their habitual use declined not as a result of prohibitive regulations but due to more
stringent medical and pharmaceutical practices within the system that kept the
opium available at the pharmacy regulated as a poison. Habitual use gradually
27
This can be seen most clearly in the igures for opium imports to the United States presented by
David Courtwright. The correlation between higher customs duties and declared imports is very
strong, and Courtwright has to separate his series into distinct periods with the same customs
duties in order to discuss other trends in the material (Courtwright 2001, chapter 1). In France, the
rigid regulations on opium as a poison were very loosely adhered to, and opium from smuggled
sources was readily available around 1900 (Padwa 2012). Interestingly, it was chiely the threat of
a rampant dual market in smuggled opiates that kept the regulations loose in the United Kingdom,
and since the prices of opiates in the pharmacies were close to the market price, no strong evidence
of smuggling was reported thereafter (Berridge and Grifith 1999, pp. 116–120). Sweden had regulated prices for opiates, but they were regulated mostly to keep the drug as available as possible,
hindering the pharmacists from proiteering from their monopoly (Berg 2016, chapter 2).
28
This is reported in qualitative sources throughout Padwa 2012.
16
D. Berg
diminished as high-use birth cohorts aged and died.29 Demand was channeled
through legal routes, and not much criminal activity can be said to have resulted
from those addictions. It seems like cheating, but regulating opium as a poison
really did seem to thwart most addiction-related crime.
Cheap Labels Versus Proitable Patents
There are some intriguing signs that the mandatory labeling of opiates as poison
seems to have had the intended effect of making opiate use safer. After this single
regulation was introduced in the United Kingdom, fatalities were reduced by
20–25% (Berridge and Grifith 1999, pp. 120–121). Use of opiates also seems to
have been lower overall in countries with earlier and stronger poison-labeling
regulations.
Throughout the period when opium was regulated as a poison, there was a competing market in opiates. Sales of tinctures containing opiates remained free to nonpharmacists in most countries if the tincture had a patent, but nowhere more so than
in the United States and the United Kingdom. This strange loophole in the poison
regime created a spiraling gray market for opiates outside of the pharmacies, a dual
market as far as the poison regulations were concerned, since patent medicines
could be sold more cheaply than tinctures from the pharmacy.
Labeling was inexpensive for the pharmacists, and it cannot have increased consumer prices by much. Therefore, it probably was not the main reason for the legal
or semi-legal gray market in opiates created by the patent medicines. Other aspects
of the system may have been more important. Maintaining a laboratory for testing
and preparing drugs to meet regulatory standards was a big capital outlay for any
pharmacist. The time-consuming work in the same laboratory to prepare individual
or small batches of doses was likewise a cost of production very dificult to get
around without skimping on some regulatory requirement.
Expensive equipment and time-consuming work were essential to secure the
monopoly on poisons and gain the trust of customers. But the patent medicine
makers could gain the same trust without the costly overhead of the poison regulations. By selling patented medicines, they were exempt from the pharmacies’
monopoly; by using massive advertising, they could win the trust of consumers
more cheaply and much faster than a pharmacist could by selling carefully prepared opiates from the laboratory. Labeling poison was cheap and effective for the
regulator; labeling patent medicine with appealing trademarks was more proitable
for the seller.
Mandating the labeling of poison simply added to popular knowledge about
opiates without reducing their availability, and consumers seem to have used
this knowledge to handle opiates from the pharmacy more carefully and to
29
See Berridge and Grifith 1999 and Courtwright 2001 for a history of this habitual use or
addiction.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
17
choose not to use those peddled as panaceas by the patent medicine industry.
When labeling requirements were inally introduced in the United States in
1906, the market in patent medicines containing narcotics experienced a sharp
decline, “by about a third.”30
Assessing Death
Since the central problem with opiates for which the regulations were implemented
during this era was fatal poisoning, it is arguably through assessing the number of
fatalities that the fairest measurement of their effectiveness can be made. Berridge
calculates that from the Pharmacy Act of 1868 until 1914, the rate of fatal poisonings by narcotics in the United Kingdom was stable around or just above ive yearly
deaths per million people; in Sweden there were hardly any reported deaths at all
(Berridge and Grifith 1999, p. 295, table 3).
It seems safe to say, very generally and lacking much in the way of data, that
among all other differing factors between the countries, the different histories of
poison regulations in the United Kingdom and Sweden probably account for some
of the discrepancies in the fatality rates. Viewed in this synchronistic light, the
British igure of ive dead per million seems high and could probably have been
lowered with earlier and stronger poison regulations like the ones in Sweden at the
time.
Fatal Anachronisms?
There is another way to measure the effectiveness of the regulation of opium as a
poison, though, one that startlingly leads to a reassessment of the British igures.
Acknowledging all the risks of anachronistic comparisons, a look at contemporary
statistics still gives food for thought. The European average today of fatal poisonings from narcotics is 16 per million.31 That is strange.
Europe today is much, much richer than during La Belle Époque, not to mention
during the preceding era of the Victorian drug bazaar. There was no social safety
30
“… [T]he Act required the listing of narcotics, including cannabis, on the labels of patent medicines shipped in interstate commerce. Within a few years of the inclusion of this simple device, it
was estimated that patent medicines containing such drugs dropped in sale by about a third”
(Musto 1973, p. 22).
31
Opiates are behind most of the fatalities from “narcotics” in Berridges’ statistics as well as in
those for contemporary Europe. Countries with very good health-care systems, that score highly in
other measures of public health but that today keep regulating narcotics prohibitively, such as
Sweden and Norway, have tragically much higher fatality rates—70 per million—than the
European average and, obviously, than in the United Kingdom during the era of regulating narcotics as poisons (EMCDDA 2015, p. 57).
18
D. Berg
net, no welfare state, no Naloxone, no Methadone, nor much in the way of medical
specialists on drug dependence. This ought to have been a time ripe for dying from
opium use: the drug was very freely available; in countries such as Sweden and the
United Kingdom, its popular use was combined with an alcohol culture of heavy
drinking; since both alcohol and opiates are respiratory depressants, combined use
increases danger.
Viewed in this anachronistic light, the regulation of opium as a poison even in the
United Kingdom must be considered to have been comparatively effective in achieving its main purpose, to save people from dying of an overdose. Effective—and
cheap.
Epilogue: The Death of a Discourse
With the twentieth century, a new discourse on opium gained prominence, instituting
a new regulatory regime. As this paradigm grew stronger, the discourse of opium as a
poison diminished in importance, and even though its regulatory framework remained
in place, it was subsumed under the new statutory laws on narcotics. Considerations
that had been central to the discourse and the regulatory framework surrounding
opium as a poison—a high sensitivity to cost and adverse dual market effects, fatal
poisoning as the most severe problem with opium use, reducing the temptation of
opium through control of labeling and advertising—became secondary, negligible, or
even counterproductive policy goals when availability itself was declared public
enemy number one. Later chapters in this book will illuminate how this shift in regulatory focus affected these older, cheaper problems with opium as a poison.
References
Berg, D. (2016). The value of poison: The understanding of opium among Swedish pharmacists,
1870–1925. Doctoral thesis in economic history, Stockholm University.
Berridge, V., & Grifith, E. (1999). Opium and the people; Opiate use in nineteenth-century
England. London: Free Association Books.
Bull, M. (2008). Governing the heroin trade, from treaties to treatment. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Courtwright, D. (2001). Dark paradise. Cambridge, Massachusetts, and London: Harvard
University Press.
Davenport-Hines, R. (2001). The pursuit of oblivion: A global history of narcotics. London:
W.W. Norton.
Derrida, J. (1972). “La Pharmacie de Platon”, La Dissémination.
EMCDDA. (2015). European drug report. Trends and developments. Retrieved from http://www.
emcdda.europa.eu/publications/edr/trends-developments/2015
Gerritsen, J.-W. (2000). The control of fuddle and lash: A sociological history of the regulation of
alcohol and opiates. Leiden: Bril.
Gårestad, P. (1987). Industrialisering och beskattning i Sverige 1861–1914, Dissertation in
Economic history, Uppsala University.
Haugne, R. (2009). Rus og rusmideler gjenom tidene. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.
1
Pre-Hague History of Opiates Control
19
Jay, M. (2000). Emperors of dreams. Sawtry: Deadalus Books.
Kremers, E., & Urdang, G. (1951). History of pharmacy. A guide and a survey. Philadelphia,
London, Montreal:Lippinkott.
Lönngren, R. (1992). International approaches to chemicals control. Stockholm: The National
Chemicals Inspectorate.
Musto, D. F. (1973). The American disease, the origin of narcotics control. New Haven Yale
University Press.
Newman, R. K. (1995). Opium smoking in late imperial China: A reconsideration. Modern Asian
Studies, 29(4), 765–794.
Padwa, H. (2012). Social poison: The culture and politics of opiate control in Britain and France
1821–1926. Baltimore:John Hopkins University Press.
Parssinen, T. M. (1983). Secret passions, secret remedies: Narcotic drugs in British Society, 1820–
1930. Philadelphia:Manchester University Press.
Pommeranz, K., & Topik, S. (1999). The world that trade created: Society, culture, and the world
economy 1400 to the present. New York: M.E. Sharp.
Retaillaud-Bajac, E. (2009). Les paradis perdus — Drougues et usagers de drougues dans la
France de l’entre-deux-guerres. Resnne: Presses Universitaires de Rennes.
Spillane, J. F. (2000). Cocaine: From medical marvel to modern menace in the United States,
1884–1920. Baltimore and London: John Hopkins University Press.
Trebach, A. S. (1982). The heroin solution. New Haven:Yale University Press.
Trocki, C. A. (1999). Opium, empire and the global political economy: A study of the Asian opium
trade 1750–1950. London: Routledge.