EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
a v a i l a b l e a t w w w. s c i e n c e d i r e c t . c o m
w w w. e l s e v i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / e c o l e c o n
METHODS
The rebound effect: An evolutionary perspective
F. Ruzzenentia , R. Basosia,b,⁎
a
Center for Complex System Investigations, University of Siena, Italy
Department of Chemistry, University of Siena, Italy
b
AR TIC LE D ATA
ABSTR ACT
Article history:
The rebound effect presents a major flaw in to energy conservation policies that aim to
Received 11 October 2007
reduce energy consumption through energy efficiency development. Economics and energy
Received in revised form 7 July 2008
related disciplines have thus far developed tools to measure such a phenomenon. This
Accepted 1 August 2008
paper attempts to explain this seeming paradox using a thermodynamic-evolutionary
Available online 1 September 2008
theoretical framework in addition to the traditional economic approach. We here propose
that evolutionary systems, such as biological or even economic systems, may rearrange
Keywords:
themselves in a more complex fashion under the pressure of an increasing flux of energy,
Rebound effect
driven by the higher conversion rate of greater efficiency. Higher complexity, due to a
Energy efficiency
greater energy density rate, counteracts the positive effects of energy efficiency. We
Energy density rate
investigated this hypothesis in the context of the road freight transport system and the
Complexity
productive structure. The qualitative analysis in this paper, further substantiated by figures,
Evolutionary approach
provides a link between the dynamics of production patterns and the effect of efficiency in
Globalization
the light of the macro-economic effects of increased energy demand. The analysis departs
Road freight transport system
from a rigorous investigation of the actual energy efficiency evolution in the road freight
transport system to develop through a survey of the subsequent worldwide economic
revolution in the production system. It is then shown how outsourcing, the key feature of
globalization, can be identified as the main source of traffic density growth. Finally, four
paradigms are used to stress how the shift in the production system must be considered a
leap in structural complexity that consequently serves to increase the frequency of
components’ interactions.
© 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
1.
Introduction
The rebound effect is portrayed by economic literature as a
price-adjusting phenomenon that counterbalances, partially
or thoroughly, the conservation effects expected by the
adoption of a more efficient technology (Khazzoom, 1980;
Brookes, 1990; Saunders, 1992). It involves an upswing of new
costs brought about by the introduction of new energy
conversion technology. Economic theory, however, seems
to focus solely on the problem of estimating the size of the
effect, i.e. the percentage of savings offset by the increased
demand (Greening et al., 2000; Berkhout et al., 2000; Dimitropoulos, 2007). In the present analysis, we address the
rebound effect from evolutionary and thermodynamic perspectives using an approach first envisioned by Alfred
Lotka in the field of life sciences (Lotka, 1956). The aim of
this analysis is therefore to provide unique insight on the
issue in order to achieve a novel explanatory framework of
the phenomenon. We seek this new framework due to our
conviction that phenomena exhibiting significant analogies,
⁎ Corresponding author. Center for Complex System Investigations, University of Siena, Italy.
E-mail address:
[email protected] (R. Basosi).
0921-8009/$ – see front matter © 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.08.001
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
albeit belonging to different fields, can be approached using a
broader theory that is general in terms.
There are indeed similarities between economical and
biological systems. One important analogy, particularly relevant to the present research, is the relationship between
higher efficiency and higher energy level: systems with a better
energy conversion rate also display a higher energy density
rate. If the positive relationship between energy efficiency and
energy density is a constant of thermodynamic evolutionary
systems then the analogy can be broadened to a third feature:
complexity (Odum, 1996). It is considered fundamental knowledge of evolutionary biology that greater complexity is linked
to greater efficiency. Evolution thus awards the highest
efficiency achieved to the highest structural complexity
throughout the system (Alberts et al., 1994). Furthermore, it is
well known that greater complexity entails higher energy costs
and thus, the greater the complexity, the higher the energy
density rate. It is therefore possible that the formation of a more
complex structure may offset the conservation effect brought
about by a more efficient technology. The explanation of the
rebound effect would rest in the complexity leap of the system
following the advent of new technology.
More specifically, the rebound effect addressed here is the
macro rebound effect or wide-economy rebound effect, a specific
type of rebound effect that is considered most crucial in
determining energy consumptions (Sorrell and Dimitropoulos,
2007). The macro rebound effect underlies a long-term adjusting mechanism affecting factors markets. As stated by Sorrell
and Dimitropoulos: “a fall in the real price of energy services
[that] will reduce the price of intermediate and final goods
throughout the economy, leading to a series of price and
quantity adjustments, with energy-intensive goods and sectors
gaining at the expense of less energy-intensive ones" (Sorrell
and Dimitropoulos, 2006). This effect is considered by some
authors to be the main cause of the constant growing trend in
energy consumptions (Ayres, van den Bergh, 2005; Sorrell and
Dimitropoulos, 2007). Nevertheless, the methodology and the
extent of the impact on the economy energy path remain
unanswered questions (Dimitropoulos, 2007). Here, the macro
rebound effect is analyzed in the context of the productive
structure's shape, as a result of the energy efficiency in the
freight transport sector. This work will not tackle the question
of the rebound size, nor the dispute over the proper econometric/theoretical approach. It will propose instead a novel
view on the issue in order to create a bridge between different
disciplines and deal with the broader question of the relationship between energy level, energy efficiency, and complexity.1
Although the analysis is qualitative, it provides a link between
1
We here intended for energy efficiency to mean an energy
conversion process that transforms energy (chemical or thermal)
into work and for complexity to mean a feature of the whole
structure of the system. Two hierarchical levels are henceforth
introduced: the process (the conversion of energy) and the
system. A new, more efficient process with a higher energy
conversion rate may not lead to a lower energy level for the
system, given the same number of components and extent of the
system. If the system modifies its structure in a way that raises
the number or length of interactions between components per
unit of time (intensity) or in other words, if the system alters its
complexity level, then a higher energy level will be achieved.
527
the dynamics of production patterns and the effect of efficiency
increases, in the light of the macro-economic effects of increased energy demand.
2.
The rebound effect in the freight
transport system
In the aftermath of the first Oil Crisis (in the year of 1973),
developed countries underwent a remodeling process in the
fields of energy final use and energy production. Both in the EU
and in the U.S., the road freight transport systems were subject
to major changes. Some measures taken include: engines
technology enhancement, aerodynamics, size and speed limits
and market deregulation.2 A significant change in fuel economy
occurred thereafter in long-distance shipments in the following
decade. However, energy efficiency improvements were initially
employed to reduce fuel economy, but later to reduce both fuel
consumption and improve vehicle performance.
2.1.
Adjusted fuel economy: an experimental basis for energy
efficiency assessment
Unfortunately, a reliable energy efficiency database for the EU
freight transport system fails to exist. Published related figures
have mostly been derived from manipulations of aggregate
data, such as the domestic consumption of fuel and the overall
distance traveled by carriers. Such estimations, however, were
inevitably affected by the driving conditions, load and size
factors and available power of engines. To account for these
influences on energy efficiency data, we measured the evolution
of an adjusted fuel economy of a sample of 100 trucks and 16
different European brands, between 1978 and 1995, grouped
by size, on the basis of road tests taken in the same standard
condition and at the same average speed (Tuttotrasporti, 1978–
2005). The adjusted fuel economy is the fuel economy value
recorded on an even road at 80 km/h and divided by the weight
of the vehicle (full load) and the maximum power of the engine.
It is thus measured in liters per kilometer and multiplied by
tons and HP. The data were organized into four size groups and
the adjusted fuel economy was measured as a mean of small
samples of vehicles (Table 1).
2
Turbocharged diesel engines were introduced in the early
1980’s and traction control systems were also developed during
the same time period to optimize fuel economy. Inter-cooling
systems and aerodynamic advancements (cab air deflectors) were
developed in the mid 1980's, and further improvements were
made to tires (low profile radial tires and multiple trailers). In
many European countries in the early 1970's, new laws raised
speed limits and maximum load size. This trend has been
maintained in the following years, reaching a maximum speed
between 80 and 90 km/h and a maximum truck weight of 40 tons
for international transport. The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 reduced
restrictions on entry and expansion in the trucking industry and
relaxed various regulations. The Surface Transportation Assistance Act (1982) modified state requirements on size and weight
limits for trucks (DOE/EIA 1995). On May 22, 1985, the European
Court ruled in favour of the European Parliament. In the following
years, the European Council submitted many directives that were
in favor of transport market liberalization and integration (OECD,
1997).
528
EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
Table 1 – Fuel Economy and Adjusted Fuel Economy
Vehicle size
Number of trucks evaluated
b 3.5 ton
3.5–5 ton
8–18 ton
N 43 ton
20
21
19
51
Fuel economy:
1978–1990
Fuel economy:
1978–1998
Adjusted f.e.:
1978–1990
Adjusted f.e.:
1978–1998
−16%
−17%
−14%
−21%
−36%
−25%
−16%
−27%
−21%
−38%
−33%
−37%
− 58%
− 46%
− 38%
− 50%
Source: Tuttotrasporti.
All estimations converge towards a 30% reduction between
1980 and 1990. An improvement in energy efficiency of about
30% is remarkable. Nonetheless, it still underestimates the real
efficiency leap that increased economy during the last three
decades.
None of the abovementioned statistics on freights account
for the efficiency improvements conveyed by the steady shift
towards heavier loads. Thus, a bigger truck has a lower specific
consumption per unit of gross weight than a lighter one.3 In
order to draw a definitive assessment of the overall energy
efficiency improvement, we must include the effect of the “size
factor” when considering the adjusted fuel economy.
The size factors depend on the evolution of weight limits and
the composition of the vehicle fleet. Both aspects indeed have
consequences on the average weight of trucks and thus on their
fuel economies. The first factor is difficult to estimate because of
the diversity of national legislations. The second factor affecting
the aggregate fuel economy of trucks is the composition of the
vehicle fleet. In Europe, the balance between single unit trucks
and combination trucks shifted by 33% toward the combination
trucks.4 The latter actually increased in 25 years by 282% and the
former only by 165% (EUROSTAT, 2005). Nevertheless, in the
absence of a sufficient database concerning both size limits and
truck fleet composition, we can still draw some conclusions
based on the fragmented resources currently available (Tuttotrasporti, 1978–2005; CONFETRA, 1998).
If we reasonably assume that in 1980, medium size trucks
weighed, on average, 12 tons and trailers weighed about 30
tons, the shift would have caused an efficiency improvement
of about 7% in the fuel economy of the whole fleet. In addition,
since 10% of the fleet belonged to the last category, we should
add a 1.5% efficiency improvement due to the increase in size
limit from 32 to 44 tons. We may thus estimate that energy
efficiency improvements due to changes in size ranged from
8% to 9% in EU.
Ultimately, the veritable energy efficiency improvement in
the road freight transport sector during the two decades from
the second half of the 1970's to the first half of the 1990's was
about 40%.
2.2.
Trends in the transport system and economic indicators
Despite the drop in specific fuel consumption of trucks, energy
consumption in the freight transport sector increased at a rate
3
The size-effect is mainly caused by aerodynamics because
about 30% of energy loss is due to air resistance.
4
Combination trucks are normally twice the size of single unit
trucks and are mainly devoted to international transport.
unmatched by any other sector. Around the world, energy final
use in the industry sector increased between 1970 and 1995 by
45% and in all others sectors between 51% and 58%, while it
nearly doubled, growing by 90% in the transport sector (IEA,
1997; EUROSTAT, 2005). In the transport sector, road mode
showed the highest growth rates. Similarly, the fuel use increased between 75% and 100%, with an average annual growth
rate of 3–4%. In Europe, the related statistics are even more
striking. During the same period in the EU, tonne-kilometers of
goods hauled by road increased by 130%, while the freight
transport sector generally grew by 65%.
However, if we compare trends in the freight transport
sector to some economic indicators like the real GDP and the
industrial production, especially during the first decade between 1970 and 1995, it appears impossible to strictly link the
growth in tkm to the fundamentals of economy. In the EU, tkm
showed growth rates much greater than both the GDP and
industrial production (Table 2).
2.3.
Globalization and outsourcing
Globalization was indeed predominately the driving force
behind most of the changes in the economy that occurred
between the 1970's and 1990's. It reshaped most economic
sectors and also deeply affected society. However, if globalization was the process promoting evolution in the economy, the
transport sector must have been the medium responsible for
developing its changing power. For the sake of this research,
we can consider globalization to be the composition of two
main processes undertaking the productive sector:
1. The integration of markets (any markets, goods, finances,
production means and materials)
2. The shift from a fordian to a postfordian mode of production
We describe a fordian system of production as a model
where the productive chain is mainly set in a unique plant or
place, to and from which materials and products depart. On the
contrary, in a postfordian system, the productive chain is
scattered throughout the territory, often over different countries
(Lipietz, 1992; Kitschelt et al., 1999). This reshaping of the
productive chain mirrors, in physical terms, a different structure
of costs and rights that sprang from a new way of sourcing by
firms. This new form of providing services, materials or
productive means from outside is what is called outsourcing.
As stated in an OECD re port: “Globalization of industry refers to
the operations of firms undertaken to organize their development, production, sourcing, marketing and financing activities.
A distinctive feature of the globalization phenomenon is the
529
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
Table 2 – Freight Transport: EU-15 (4 modes)
Road
Rail
Inland
waterways
Sea
(domestic)
Total,
4 modes
Real GDP
Industrial
Production
489
720
976
1.010
1.124
+47%
+56%
+130 %
282
290
255
234
222
+ 3%
− 23%
− 22 %
103
106
107
107
115
+ 3%
+ 8%
+ 12%
472
781
923
955
1.070
+65%
+37%
+126%
1.346
1.897
2.262
2.307
2.531
+40%
+33%
+88 %
+ 3,6%
+ 2%
+ 2%
+ 1,9%
+ 2,3%
+ 30%
+ 29%
+ 63%
–
0%
+2,1%
−1,4%
+3,7%
+18%
+23%
+56%
1000 millions of
tonne-km
1970
1980
1990
1991
1995
1970–80
1980–95
1970–95
Source: EUROSTAT, OECD.
division of firm operations into separate segments carried out in
different countries.” (OECD, 1996).
Outsourcing can thus be considered a distinctive feature of
the postfordian model of production. On the one hand, it caused
a significant reduction in production costs (especially those
related to the storage of goods and productive means) through
an improvement in activities specialization (cluster of small
firms), an optimization of management costs (downsizing) and
a reduction in labour costs (obtained with the exploitation of
new labour markets). On the other hand, outsourcing dramatically increased both the distance of travels and the intensity
of trades.5 It relied mainly on lower transportation costs, which
permitted an expansion in markets’ physical borders, an integration of markets once isolated and the placement of segments
of production in different places. In other words, outsourcing
transformed trucks into the new warehouses of firms. Globalization has thus most likely affected the factors market more
deeply than the products market.
2.4.
The causal relationship: an efficiency improvement prior
to globalization
It is now possible to question whether any causal relationship
between fuel economy energy efficiency in the freight transport sector and the formerly mentioned change in the productive structure can be established.
During the 1970’s, in Europe, fuel costs amounted to around
30% of total costs in the long distance road freight transport
sector (Tuttotrasporti, 1978–2005). If we thus consider an overall
efficiency improvement of 40%, shipping costs would drop by
12%, which is a remarkable reduction. The efficiency leap would
5
“International sourcing of parts and materials is a major
feature of global production systems and sourcing accounts for a
large part of total trade. There is some evidence that international
sourcing is linked to international investment. Industries that
have high levels of international inward investment are also
more likely to source internationally. OECD work which examined
international sourcing in the manufacturing industries of six
large countries (..) points to the interdependence of their
economies. The study concluded that direct imports of manufactured intermediate inputs from abroad (which range from 50 to
70% of manufactured imports for the six countries) rose more
rapidly than domestic sourcing in all countries, with the highest
growth rates occurring more recently” (OECD, 1996).
have affected transport costs in such a proportion to suggest
that the productive structure was also affected. For example,
efficiency raised the relative costs of storing materials and
products that, in the long run, would foster firms to resort to
outsourcing more than internal production.
Major changes in truck fuel economy occurred in Europe in
the decade preceding 1980. These changes were in fact triggered
by the first oil crisis of 1973. The start of globalization is commonly believed to be in the following decade mainly because of
the dramatic increase in foreign direct investment by international firms (OECD, 1992, 1993, 1996, 2002; World Bank, 2005).
In order to set a defined time for the “dawn” of globalization –
a phenomenon that predominately involved international outsourcing in the productive sector – a guiding indicator must be
discovered among the various possibilities. The best measure
of international outsourcing is therefore the intra-industry rate
on trades. The intra-industry indicator is the rate of trade within
the same industries over the entire trade of goods between
countries. This indicator thus measures the percentage of parts,
components, raw materials, and productive means over the
amount of products exchanged.
According to this indicator, intra-industry trade grew by
36% from 1970 to 2000 in the OECD countries. For example, the
percentage of parts and components over the total of exports
grew from 2% of the total to 10% in Europe and from 6% to 15%
in USA and Japan between 1980 and 2000 (World Bank, 2005).
The intra-industry indicator indeed displayed a dramatic leap
such as to overshadow a change in the productive systems.
It increased more than any other related figures, such as the
percentage of Export and Import over the GDP, the intra-firm
indicator (OECD, 1993).
Nonetheless, according to the same figures, such a leap
occurred in the second decade of the range of time considered
(Table 3). It was indeed between 1980 and 1990 when this
indicator further grew in all the OECD countries and in Europe
(Table 3). These figures suggest that the main transformation
in economic structure affected international trade after 1980
and therefore, following the abovementioned change in truck
fuel efficiency. Although a temporal sequence does not entail
causality between events, it does provide concrete evidence that
the preceding event cannot be caused by the subsequent one.
The dramatic change in truck fuel economy occurred before
the rise of international outsourcing as a distinctive feature
of globalization. The leap in fuel efficiency was not caused nor
driven by international outsourcing or globalization, but it is
530
EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
Table 3 – Intra-industry indicator (share on international
trade): growth rates and some annual values
1970–80 1980–90 1990–2000 1970 1995
United Kingdom
France
United States
Japan
Italy
Germany
EU (14)
OECD (23)
39%
4%
4%
− 20%
13%
1%
10%
6%
13%
10%
55%
89%
5%
28%
20%
32%
3.6%
2.7%
5%
10%
3%
5%
14%
4%
53%
67%
44%
21%
49%
56%
56%
49%
73%
77%
65%
41%
64%
72%
71%
67%
Source: OECD.
very likely that it was a driving force, among others, of those
events.
3.
The traffic density growth: Italy case study
The shift from a uni-located (fordian) productive chain to a
pluri-located (postfordian) one, together with the integration
of markets, placed an increasing burden on the road transport
system. The fuel use in the freight transport sector grew not
only because the mean distance of travels augmented, but
also because the frequency changed. In other words, the outsourcing system of production is strictly connected with a
more intensive and flexible transport system, which was provided solely by the road modal sector.
According to this thinking, the growth in tkm is not only
due to market integration, but also to the outsourcing process.
Did the traffic density grow along with the tkm? According
to OICA (Organisation Internationale Constructeurs de Automobiles), traffic density of goods vehicles grew more than that
of private cars in Europe. Between 1980 and 2000, truck density
almost doubled in Europe while car density grew much less.
Nevertheless, this approximation fails to be a sound indicator
of how much the traffic density of trucks grew locally, the
desired value in this case.6 These figures actually match the
number of registered vehicles with the length of the road network (Table 4).
In order to get a realistic picture of local traffic density, it is
important to reduce the scope of the analysis. A case study has
consequently been taken into account. For this analysis, it is
necessary for traffic density data to be consistent over time and
space and thus, a single country has been considered. Results of
this analysis can be considered reliable, but we would
recommend an extension of the analysis to a greater number
of countries. We analyzed data from the traffic census in Italy
between 1972 and 1989 (ANAS, 1973–1990). The traffic census
in Italy roughly occurred every five years and was set on 398
tracking points scattered throughout extra-urban roads all
6
It is important to detect traffic density on the local road
network because as the frequency and not only length of
shipments grow, the secondary road network is also affected.
On the contrary, if only the distance of shipments grow, as a
consequence of a mere integration of markets, the highway road
network is predominately impacted.
over the Italian road network. These sites have remained relatively unchanged over the years. Data were collected on eight
days (six working days) and four nights during all seasons.
Vehicles were arranged into eight categories, four of which
were goods vehicles. DAT (Daily Average Traffic) expresses a
weighted average7 of the vehicles on the road every day during
the year. We selected a sample of 44 tracking points scattered
all over Italy that were significant based on location (on roads
connecting either productive sites or big urban conglomerates)
and traffic density. According to these data, while total vehicles
grew by 25% in 25 years, goods vehicles (over three tons) grew
by 132% (much more than the 54% growth in industrial production during the same interval of time). Semi-trailers trucks,
used mainly for international duties, grew by 172% (Table 5).
This statistic matches the growth rate in tkm (180%) that
occurred in Italy during the same time period, further confirming the impression that shipments increased much more for
the density than for the distance of travels.
It is important to demonstrate that freight transportation
grew not just in distance traveled, but also in frequency of
shipments. The density of connections can be considered as a
footprint of structural complexity of the productive system
and the reason why will be addressed in the next paragraph.
These data seem to confirm the hypothesis that both distance
and density of movements grew in the two decades analyzed
here and that integration of markets coupled with structural
change in the production system should be regarded as the
driving factor of such a growth.
4.
The complexity leap
The underlying hypothesis of this work is that higher complexity counterbalances, on a global scale, the effects of higher
efficiency on a process scale. So far, we have focused on
demonstrating the actual extent of efficiency improvements
and the timing with respect to the evolution of the productive
structure. However, the fact that the productive structure, all
through globalization, evolves towards higher complexity was
taken for granted. We now want to stress the extent to which
the economic productive system increased in complexity during
the last two decades.8 It is beyond the goals of this analysis to
ascertain what complexity is or how it should be approached.
The scientific community has been unable to establish or agree
on a universal definition or paradigm of complexity and any
attempt to univocally measure complexity is therefore doomed
to failure. In the present analysis, we will “identify complexity in
two operational ways: as a measure of the information needed
to describe a system's structure and function, or as a measure of
7
The average is weighted over the course of one year in order to
represent the daily traffic of an average day and thus, to balance
seasonal peaks and tufts.
8
In his work, Ayres stresses how, in order to understand the
energy path of developed countries after 1975, it is important to
introduce a “structural shift” in the productive system. He
maintains that energy and GDP growth can be explained as a
result of the energy efficiency improvement up to that date, but a
structural change ought to be taken into account thereafter (Ayres
and Warr, 2005; Ayres, van den Bergh, 2005).
531
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
Table 4 – Traffic Density in EU and Italy
Vehicles per km of Road
1980
1990
2000
1980–00
Europe, CV’s
Europe, Cars
Italy, CV’s
Italy, Cars
3.6
33.9
4.7
60.2
5.6
42.6
8.0
90.2
6.7
50.1
9.1
100
86%
47%
93%
66%
Source: OICA, Europe = 15 countries, CV = commercial vehicles.
the rate of energy flowing through a system of given mass”
(Chaisson, 2001).
It will thus be assumed that a more complex system consumes more (per unit of mass and time) and the complexity
we refer to is a structural or morphological complexity as we
are dealing with systems with undefined boundaries and innumerable components, such as the productive and transport
systems. The two main assumptions regarding complexity
that we are concerned with are:
• A more complex system consumes more energy per unit of
mass and unit of time (higher energy density rate).
• Structural complexity primarily concerns the components'
organization9 rather than the components' variety or number.
Further remarks capture the duality efficiency/complexity.
We should bear in mind that while we are referring to energy
efficiency improvements, we are dealing with a process-scale
analysis, whilst the leap in complexity concerns the globalscale analysis. These phenomena are at two different hierarchical levels:
• Energy efficiency concerns energy converting processes and
is therefore at the components level of the system.
• Complexity (structural) concerns the organization of the
system and is thus at the global level of the system.
In order to shed new light on the complexity change that
occurred in the productive system and in order to establish
whether such a change must be considered augmentative, we
now focus on the two major aspects of globalization. We will
tackle the goal of detecting complexity change through several
points of view, for the concept of complexity is not, as already
asserted, unique. We will dissect the globalization process and
examine each piece through various complexity theories in
order to establish a clear trend in changes. Each complexity
theory will therefore be used as a tool or better stated, a paradigm,
on the basis of which we can make a decision about the direction
of system evolution. The two main features of globalization to be
addressed are:
zation process, is due to the abolishment or the relaxation
of commercial barriers and is affected by both goods (final
consumption) and factors markets. Before globalization, markets were mainly nationwide, but after globalization, the scope
of trade extended to nearly the entire world. Barriers to market
integration are physical (shipment costs) or economical (taxes).
It is important to point out that both flaws curb the rise of
global free market. It would be insufficient to remove custom
borders if transport technology failed to reduce the costs of
shipments (Krugman et al., 1995). Technological and economical aspects together participate in the merge of previously
separate markets. We will focus on the technological aspects
which constitute premises or consequences, according to
different views on the subject, to free trade economic policies.
It is of little relevance whether the former comes before the
latter, or vice versa for the present analysis. It is indeed true that
energy efficiency improvements in the transport sector play
major roles in market integration. If energy efficiency led to
market integration, then to what extent did the productive
system consequently grow in complexity?
There are at least two theories which may assist us in
defining a complexity trend in the present case: one comes
from ecology and the other from economics. In fact, we argue
that complexity grew because of:
1. An increase in hierarchical levels of the system
2. The scale economy effect or the idea that more specialization of economies leads to more integration and interdependence of the system
4.1.
According to hierarchical theory of ecosystems (Odum 1996,
Allen and Starr, 1982), complexity increases when a new,
higher control level is introduced within system components.
According to this view, complexity grows when new parts
are added in such a fashion to “exert new constrains over
the others.” Otherwise, the system grows just in “complexification” (Tainter et al., 2003). That is to say, a system is more
complex when, by adding parts, it increases the number of
kinds of relationships. In contrast, a system becomes more
complicated when adding parts causes a mere growth in the
number of relationships.
Key concepts of hierarchical system theory are: the breakdown of symmetry and reduced degree of freedom for lower
level variables. These two features account for the “growth
Table 5 – Italy, DAT (daily average traffic) in Extra Urban
Road Network
Goods
Single unit Trailers SemiTotal
vehicles
trucks over trucks trailers vehicles
up to 3 ton
3 ton
trucks
1. The integration of markets (factor and goods)
2. The shift from a fordian to a postfordian productive system
We will begin by analyzing the process of market integration. Market integration, which is at the core of the globali-
9
For organizational purposes, we refer to any system’s components acting or arranged in a cooperative, systematic fashion.
Market integration, first paradigm: hierarchical theory
1972
1979
1985
1989
673
669
881
840
24.75%
624
602
639
566
−9.25%
335
296
261
239
− 28.80%
112
171
246
301
169.56%
Source: elaboration on ANAS traffic census, 1973–1990.
12.297
11.451
14.199
15.340
24.75%
532
EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
Fig. 1 – Market integration and hierarchical system theory: symmetry breakdown.
in organization” of the system. The two graphs (Fig. 1) reveal
that the system grew in number of components and connections. Only the second graph, however, illustrates a growth in
organization. Symmetry is broken in the second case and thus
the information that flows from A to B (or from B to A) is the
same, despite the number of “B,” while the information that
goes from 2 to 3 is different from the information flowing from 2
to 1. If you add B to A, you preserve symmetry, but if you add 3 to
2, you create asymmetry in the system. The same is true for the
particles' degree of freedom. If you add a new B to the system,
the degree of freedom of former particles does not change. If
you, however, introduce a new control level, such as 3, the
degree of freedom of both 2 and 1 is reduced.
For example, suppose you want to set up a European
championship. According to the theory, the degree of freedom
of the top teams participating in the national championships
is now reduced because the teams must avoid being relegated
as opposed to simply compete for first place. They are therefore competitors instead of champions. If you add more teams
to the groups, you will consequently have more teams running
for the national title. Champions will therefore have to play
more teams, but will retain their title.
This is, more or less, what happened to firms after globalization merged national markets. Firms that were big and
strong enough to access the “world championship” had to
extend and reorganize their network of production and
logistics. International corporations have districts (control
nodes) at any territorial scale (local, national, transnational).
How does this change affect the movement of goods? Suppose
some national supermarket chains merge to form a big
international company. Management at this higher level
must have contracts with a unique international supplier
instead of several local ones. Goods now arrive at all warehouses from the same supplier, regardless of the nation or the
distance of provenience. The same can be said for factors in the
productive system. Market integration nonetheless changed
big companies’ logistics.
4.2.
Market integration, second paradigm:
geographical gradient
Capital intensive sectors, those sectors with a higher burden of
structures and machineries over production than manufacturers, dislike scale economies (Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). For
such sectors, costs are reduced when production is significantly increased because structural costs are higher than
variable costs. Due to economic scale effects, firms tend to
increase in size or productive districts to form. Economic scale
effects were fostered by globalization and market integration
because more competitive firms could access new, large
markets. Economic scale effects brought the new factor of
selection to firms and thus survivors grew and engulfed or
displaced minor firms. One effect on national economies was
the growth of strong national industries and the disappearance of weak ones. In the long run, national economies tend to
be specialized. The increased specialization of economies can
be regarded as a factor of complexity growth.
National specialization can be seen as a geographical
gradient in the productive system.10 This gradient leads to a
breakdown in symmetry, with the rise of a new hierarchical
organization level, and to increased average distances of parts
(production plants). It will therefore augment both the distance
and the frequency of shipments, as already remarked in light
of the hierarchical system theory. An example is shown in the
graph of three countries and three industries (Fig. 2). At the
beginning, there is no geographical gradient, but with specialization, similar industries tend to set themselves apart. As a
result, there are three countries, each with one industry. Like
organs in a body, they now need to become coordinated at a
10
It is a spatial gradient that relates the diversity of the system
to its size and it is an ecological function. In ecology, in fact,
biodiversity it is also related to the size of the ecosystem (Fath
et al., 2001).
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
533
Fig. 2 – Market integration and geographical gradient: the economic scale effect.
higher control level. It is also very simple to show that the
average distance among components thereafter increased.
Complexity, therefore, increased.
4.3.
Productive system shift, third paradigm:
homeostatic theory
When analyzing the structural complexity change resulting
from globalization, of paramount importance is the shift from
a uni-located, national productive chain to one that is plurilocated and international. This process is a complexity leap
because it brought about:
• More specialization and more integration (interdependence)
among system components and suppliers and subsidiaries
became essential (synchronization)
• An increase in interactions among system components due
to changes in the shape of the production chain (which will
be addressed in the next section)
The first feature mainly concerns the outsourcing process
because it affects firms by economically externalizing their
functions. For those firms relying on external resources to
pursue their productive needs, production becomes less costly,
but more subdued due to uncontrollable factors. Part of its
activity, formerly controlled managerially and internally, is
now focused on free market. This shift reduces the stability of
the system and increases its complexity. The homeostatic
system theory provides us with a clear explanation of the kind
of change that occurred in productive systems, thus prompting
economic externalization (Odum, 1997).
The first graph (Fig. 3) represents production regulated
by a feedback loop (El-Samad et al., 2006). The stock of goods in
the warehouse is determined by two fluxes, sales and production volume. In the first, simple example, management
determined production according to one feedback indicator:
the amount of products stocked (which is proportional to sales).
When the stock decreases below a certain level (set point), the
production receives a positive input (stimulator message).
Suppose we now want to regulate the production in accordance
with our sales and profits. We will therefore have two controls
(we increase the production when sales or profits increase) and
one feedback loop (sales and profits are proportional and
cannot be counteractive). This is a strengthened version of the
previous loop based solely on stimulators’ messages. This kind
of homeostatic system works exactly like thermostats and are
quick in positive feedbacks but slow in negative ones. It is
otherwise obvious that such systems tend to grow rapidly in
terms of production but are much less capable of diminishing it.
If we add an inhibitor factor (negative control) to the
stimulator factor (positive control), we create an inner regulatory loop which increases both the complexity and the adaptability of the system. Suppose we now buy part of the
production on the market. Previously, we stocked all the
materials and adjusted the production according to sales, but
now we have to take into account both revenues and costs. We
therefore introduce a negative feedback control into our loop
(costs of parts). In this case, the loop, from a homeostatic
perspective, increases in complexity (Fig. 3). This phenomenon
involved outsourcing because firms dealt with costs (due to
bargain, timing and also delivery) more than ever. How can this
process lead to an overall increase in the movement of goods?
The homeostatic approach provides a sound explanation for
why and how complexity grew when the productive system
shifted towards outsourcing (El-Samad et al., 2006). According to
this view, the amount of information flowing through the
system increased. However, it is much less clear whether this
information is mainly monetary or whether it also has some
content matter. Did the flow of products, semi-products, and
raw materials increase in response to such a complexity leap?
From this analysis, it is impossible to establish any clear tendency and further research is necessary.
4.4.
Productive system shift, fourth paradigm: graphic theory
The last part of this analysis and by far, the most crucial,
describes the shape of the productive structure. It was already
made clear that the main feature of the shift from a fordian to a
postfordian system concerns the location of the productive
chain. Formerly, the productive chain was set thoroughly in one
plant, to which raw materials were delivered and from which
products were shipped. From the 1970's onward, big companies
began disassembling the production chain and placing it in
several, scattered structures, often in foreign countries.
We will use graph theory in an attempt to illustrate how the
productive structure evolved in complexity. In order to apply
534
EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
Fig. 3 – Productive system shift and the homeostatic paradigm: decentralization of controlling.
this tool to the economic structure, the system has been drawn
to define and portray its shape. The graphs sketched are intended to be approximate, but not exact representations. Graph
theory, however, helps to establish whether a determined shape
can be considered more complex than another. It is therefore
suitable to compare the complexity of abstract structures, but
cannot be considered a tool for measuring complexity.
Graphs A and B (Fig. 4) display some sketches of the productive
structure. They solely focus on the inflow of materials, the supply
and productive chain, and assume that the outflow, the product
distribution chain, is not affected by the structural change being
analyzed. Graph A shows a “fordian” factory in which the
materials of semi-products flow from suppliers to the center
where the productive chain is concentrated (the star-like graph).
Graph B (Fig. 4) shows a “postfordian” factory in which the
suppliers become part of the “spread” productive linear chain (the
square-like graph). The dashed line indicates that we can consider
it to be both an open loop (no main plants) and a closed loop if the
final assemblage occurs in the plant where the process started.
Graph B is more complex than graph A even though it has the
same number of points (and lines, in the open loop case) because:
I. The minimum degree (minimum number of incident
lines to each point) of graph points is higher in the closed
loop case.
II. Connectivity (minimum number of points whose removal
results in a disconnected or trivial graph) is higher in the
closed loop case.
III. The path length is four (three if open loop) times that of
graph A.
IV. The number of possible path-cycles across the points is
two times that of graph A. In other words, there are, at
least, two non-isomorphic graphs (graphs B and C) that
connect the points in a chain, while there is only one in
a star-like structure like graph A.11
V. The number of non-isomorphic graphs increases if we
consider a chain of more than four points (graphs 1 to 4),
while the number of star-like graphs remains the same.
This means that there is just one structure that connects
many points to a center while there are many different
11
In other words, there is just one way to go from the periphery
to the center, regardless of the number of nodes considered, while
there are many ways to connect the same number of points in the
path. Furthermore, the number of different ways increases with
the number of points. This does not mean that, in a scattered
productive chain, factories (points), are connected randomly, but
instead that there are multiple ways for a chain to develop its
pattern and just one for a centralized system.
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
535
Fig. 4 – Productive system shift and graph theory: the shape of the productive chain.
structures that make a chain (open or closed) out of the
same number of points.
All of the above statements suggest that the second
structure (postfordian) presents a higher degree of freedom
(an increase in multiplicity of the system) and thus relates to a
more complex system.
If we generalize this approach to the entire productive
system, we draw two different pictures: one system resembles a
sky of scattered stars and the other, a web. In fact, each chain
opens branches to side-suppliers, which, due to increased
specialization, are connected to other productive chains (Fig. 5).
The web-like structure ultimately increases the degree of
freedom of the system because it presents an even higher
minimum degree of graph points, more point and line
connectivities (which are unchanged in the star-like structure), and longer graph paths.
Although the fordian structure depicted in Figs. 4 and 5
may seem overly simplified, as it is reasonable to assume that
connections occur also among suppliers or from suppliers to
various factories in such a way that the first picture would also
resemble, to a lesser degree, a net, the conclusion regarding
the degree of freedom of the two systems remains the same. In
the second structure, the degree of freedom is higher. A
system with a higher degree of freedom is a more complex
system in the sense that, as for any physical system, it has
increased multiplicity or number of different available states.
In other words, a more complex system has more ways to
dispose of particles, in this case, goods or raw materials, and
therefore to dissipate energy.
5.
Conclusions
It has been shown by several qualitative approaches that the
complexity of the productive system has grown in the last
three decades. According to all but one (Fig. 3) of these
approaches, complexity growth also caused the major
536
EC O LO GIC A L E CO N O M ICS 6 7 ( 2 00 8 ) 5 2 6 –5 37
Fig. 5 – Productive system shift and graph theory, bis: generalization to the whole productive system.
circulation of materials, in terms of distance and frequency.
Such a complexity leap was augmentative of the number, in
time, of relationships among its parts and explained the growth
in energy density rate thereafter. Figures (Table 4 and 5) reveal
that traffic density growth occurred during the interval of
time here considered and reflect the transformation of the
productive system in the direction of increasing the number of
relationships within its components (and not solely the
length). This transformation is therefore consistent with
the hypothesis so far investigated. It is here suggested that
the complexity leap was, under these circumstances, the
strategy for the system to dispose of the increased energy
made available by the efficiency change. Such a strategy, however, does not arise from nothing. It represents a particular
disposition and organization of system components previously available, yet not economical. When boundary conditions change such that more economical paths are no longer
exploitable and if there is an energy inflow such that a constant pressure exists upon the system, the system will thereby
explore new settings in order to dissipate energy flow. In the
words of Chaisson: “The phenomenon is also sometimes called
‘self-organization,’ although that term and others like it (those
with the prefix ‘self-’) are deceptive in that such ordering is
actually occurring not by itself, as though by magic, but only
with the introduction of energy” (Chaisson, 2001). Therefore, in
our opinion, we should approach the question of the rebound
effect, in light of the dynamic relationship between energy
efficiency of the process and complexity level of the system.
Such a relationship concerns both biological and economical
systems. In nature, more efficient processes correlate to more
complex systems (and energy costs). This analogy probably
underlies a more general thermodynamic mechanism common to many evolutionary systems. Such a mechanism boils
down to the geometrical features of the system and the way
it molds itself as to host the larger energy influx. In the words
of the great biologist and pioneer of evolutionary thermodynamics, Alfred Lotka: “The physical geometry and environmental conditions select the path for the energy flow; if
the crack under the door is large, it will rapidly dominate the
other two paths, and the out flowing energy will soon return
the room to equilibrium with its surrounding” (Lotka, 1956).
Acknowledgments
We would like to thank Professor Sergio Ulgiati and Professor
Eric Weeks for their comments and advice. We are also very
grateful to Farrah Elchahal for her kind and meticulous revision of the manuscript.
REFERENCES
Alberts, B., Bray, D., Lewis, J., Raff, M., Roberts, K., Watson, J.D.,
1994. Molecular Biology of the Cell. Garland Publishing, Inc.,
New York.
Allen, T.H.F., Starr, T.B., 1982. Hierarchy: perspectives for
ecological complexity. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
ANAS, 1973–1989. Censimento della Circolazione Lungo le Strade
Statali ed Autostrade, A.N.A.S., Direzione Centrale Tecnica.
Ayres, R., van den Bergh, J., 2005. A theory of economic growth with
material/energy resources and dematerialization: Interaction of
three growth mechanisms. Ecological Economics 55, 96–118.
Ayres, R., Warr, B., 2005. Accounting for growth: the role of
physical work. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 16,
181–209.
Berkhout, P., Muskens, J., Velthuijsen, J., 2000. Defining the
rebound effect. Energy Polici 28, 425–432.
Brookes, L., 1990. Energy efficiency and economic fallacies. Energy
Policy March 783–785.
Chaisson, E., 2001. Cosmic Evolution — The Rise of Complexity in
Nature. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts,
London, U.K.
CONFETRA, 1998. Effetto Serra, Emissioni di CO2, Trasporto Merci,
Quaderno N. 109/1 — Novembre 1998, Centro Studi Confetra.
Dimitropoulos, J., 2007. Energy productivity improvements and
the rebound effect: An overview of the state of knowledge.
Energy Policy 35, 6354–6363.
DOE/EIA, 1995. Measuring Energy Efficiency in the United States'
Economy: A Beginning Distribution, Category UC-950, Energy
Consumption Series.
El-Samad, H., Prajna, S., Papachristodoulou, A., Doyle, J.,
Khammash, M., 2006. Advanced methods and algorithms
for biological networks analysis. Proceedings of the Ieee 94 (4),
832 Postprint available free at: http://repositories.cdlib.org/
postprints/1474.
EC O L O G IC A L E C O N O M IC S 6 7 ( 2 0 08 ) 52 6 –5 37
EUROSTAT, 2005. Energy & transport in figures 2004, European
Commission, Directorate General for Energy and Transport.
Fath, B., Patten, B., Choi, J., 2001. Complementary of ecological goal
functions. J. Theor. Biol. 208, 493–506.
Geening,, L., Greene,, D., Difiglio, Carmen, 2000. Energy efficiency
and consumption – the rebound effect – a survey. Energy Policy
28 (6/7), 389–401.
IEA, 1997. Indicators of energy use and efficiency. IEA, Paris.
Khazzoom, J.D., 1980. Economic implications of mandated
efficiency in standards for houshold appliances. The Energy
Journal 1, 21–40 No.4.
Kitschelt, H., Lange, P., Marks, G., Stephens, J.D., 1999. Continuity
and Change in Conteporary Capitalism. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge U.K.
Krugman, P., Cooper, R.N., Srinivasan, T.N., 1995. Growing world
trade: causes and consequences. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Vol 1995, No. 1, 25th Anniversary
Issue, pp. 327–377.
Lipietz, A., 1992. Towards a New Economic Order, Posfordism,
Ecology and Democracy. Polity Press, Cambridge U.K.
Lotka, A., 1956. Elements of Mathematical Biology. Dover
Publications, Inc, New York.
Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., 1992. Economics, organization and
management. Prentice-Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Odum, E.P., 1997. Ecology: A Bridge Between Science and Society.
Sinauer Associates, Inc., Publishers, Sunderland,
Massachusetts 01375 U.S.A.
Odum, H.T., 1996. Environmental Accounting. Emergy and
Environmental Decision Making. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.,
New York, USA.
View publication stats
537
OECD, 2002. Intra-industry and intra-firm trade and the
internationalisation of production. Economic Outlook, vol. 71.
OECD, Paris. Part VI.
OECD, 1992. Economic Regionalisation and Intra-Industry Trade:
Pacific-Asian Perspectives, OECD DEVELOPMENT CENTRE,
Working Paper No. 53
OECD, 1993. Globalisation and Intra-Firm Trade: an empirical note.
OECD Economic Studies, Paris. No. 20.
OECD, 1996. Globalization of Industry, overview and sector reports.
OECD, Paris.
OECD, 1997. Liberalisation and Structural Reform in The Freight
Transport Sector in Europe. OECD, Paris.
Saunders, H., 1992. The Khazzoom–Brookes postulate and
neoclassical growth. The Energy Journal 13 (4), 131.
Sorrell S., Dimitropoulos J., 2006. The rebound effect:
micro-economic definitions, limitations and extensions.
UKERC Working Papers, SPRU, University of Sussex.
Sorrell, S., Dimitropoulos, S., 2007. The rebound effect:
microeconomic definitions, limitations and extensions.
Ecological Economics, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon. 2007.08.013.
Tainter, J.A., Allen, T.F.H., Little, A., Hoekstra, T.W., 2003. Resource
transitions and energy gain: contexts of organization.
Conservation Ecology 7 (3), 4 [online] URL: http://www.consecol.
org/vol7/iss3/art4.
Tuttotrasporti, 1978–2005. Editoriale Domus S.p.A., Via Gianni
Mazzocchi 1/3, 20089 Rozzano (MI).
World Bank, 2005. Global Economic Prospects 2005. Washington,
D.C.