See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228248469
Corporate Governance: Theories, Challenges and
Paradigms
Article in SSRN Electronic Journal · April 2000
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.221350
CITATIONS
READS
16
1,029
1 author:
Christopher S∅ren SHANN Turnbull
Harvard University
123 PUBLICATIONS 820 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
‘Democratising the wealth of cities: self-financing urban development, (Forthcoming, 2017), Environment
and Urbanisation, 29(1), pp.? View project
All content following this page was uploaded by Christopher S∅ren SHANN Turnbull on 06 January 2017.
The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. All in-text references underlined in blue are added to the original document
and are linked to publications on ResearchGate, letting you access and read them immediately.
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: THEORIES, CHALLENGES
AND PARADIGMS
Shann Turnbull
Macquarie University Graduate School of Management, Sydney
This paper provides orientation in understanding the topic of corporate governance to further research,
analysis and reform. Limitations in the theories and practices of the dominant Anglo paradigm are identified.
Various viewpoints used in analysing corporate governance are described with their cultural specificities. To
transcend and subsume other approaches and various institutional contexts, information and control theory is
shown to provide a way of grounding corporate governance, theories of the firm, and the analysis of
organisations in general in the science of cybernetics. Some research and reform opportunities are
considered.
Key words: Agency, Control, Corporations, Culture, Cybernetics, Directors, Firm, Governance, Information
theory, Power, Stakeholders, Stewardship, Theory of the firm, Transaction Byte Analysis, Transaction costs.
This paper can be downloaded from the
Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=220954
Corporate Governance: Theories, challenges and paradigms
Translated and published in French as:
Gouvernement d'entreprise:Théories, Enjeux et paradigmes
Volume 1, Number 1, 2000, pp. 11-43
Shann Turnbull
Macquarie University Graduate School of Management, Sydney
This paper provides orientation in understanding the topic of corporate governance to
further research, analysis and reform. Limitations in the theories and practices of the
dominant Anglo paradigm are identified. Various viewpoints used in analysing corporate
governance are described with their cultural specificities. To transcend and subsume other
approaches and various institutional contexts, information and control theory is shown to
provide a way of grounding corporate governance, theories of the firm, and the analysis of
organisations in general in the science of cybernetics.
Some research and reform
opportunities are considered.
Key words: Agency, Control, Corporations, Culture, Cybernetics, Directors, Firm,
Governance, Information theory, Power, Stakeholders, Stewardship, Theory of the firm,
Transaction Byte Analysis, Transaction costs.
Classifications:
Journal of Economic Literature: - G3; L2
Encyclopedia of Law & Economics: - 0010; 0400; 0560; 0630; 0760; 0780; 5000; 5600;
5610; 9400.
2
Shann Turnbull
Macquarie University Graduate School of Management, Sydney
Shann Turnbull, MBA (Harvard), B.Sc. (Melbourne), Dip. Elec. Eng. (Hobart) is a
Foundation Life Fellow of the Australian Institute of Company Directors, Honorary Senior
Fellow of the Corporate Directors Association of Australia, Fellow of the Securities
Institute of Australia, Fellow of the Institute of Chartered Secretaries & Administrators,
Fellow of the Australian Institute of Management, and Fellow of the Royal Society for
Arts.
He pioneered the study and teaching of corporate governance internationally as a
foundation author of the first educational qualification for Company Directors in 1975. He
has been chairman of a number of enterprises some of which he founded and became listed
on the Australian Stock Exchange. He is the author of Democratising The Wealth of
Nations and many other writings on economic reform some of which are listed at
http://members.optusnet.com.au/~sturnbull/index.html
PO Box 266 Woollahra, Sydney, Australia 1350.
Ph: +612 9328 7466; Fax: +612 9327 1497; e-mail:
[email protected]
http://members.optusnet.com.au/~sturnbull/index.html
3
There are no agreed definitions or boundaries for defining or investigating corporate
governance. “The lack of a broad defining paradigm has created a sense of intellectual
vertigo in the increasingly intense debate over corporate governance reforms” (Pound
1993b). An objective of this paper is to provide orientation for understanding the topic to
further research, analysis and reform.
This first section presents an inclusive definition of corporate governance used in this
paper. Some limitations in Anglo scholarship are discussed in the second section with
cultural specificities in theories and practices considered in section three. Limitations in the
theory of the firm are considered in section four and compared with the extended
boundaries introduced by using the paradigm of Transaction Byte Analysis (TBA). In
section four two surveys of corporate governance are reviewed which consider: the finance,
stewardship, stakeholder and political models of corporate governance.
Section five
introduces other ways of analysing corporate governance based on culture, power and
cybernetics.
Section six identifies seven areas offering research opportunities with
concluding remarks following in the final section.
In this paper, the term corporate governance will be used to describe all the influences
affecting the processes for appointing those who decide how operational control is
exercised to produce goods and services and all external influences affecting operations or
the controllers. Defined in this way corporate governance includes all types of firms
4
whether or not they are formed under civil or common law, owned by the government,
institutions or individuals, privately held or publicly traded. While this definition is much
more inclusive than others considered by Turnbull (1997a: 181) it separates out
management activities not involved in the processes for appointing the controllers.
The range of influences affecting the governance of publicly traded firms is indicated in
Table 1. The Table includes public sector laws and regulators as well as various private
sector influences.
{INSERT TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE}
Influences affecting the controllers of publicly traded firms
Much of the literature on corporate governance implicitly assumes that only publicly traded
firms are the subjects of analysis, for example Blair (1995: 3). This would limit the topic to
around 60,000 firms world-wide and involve only a fraction of all economic activity in
even the most advanced market societies (FIBV 1993; Economist 1995:116; 1999: 120).
As a result, some of the most influential corporate governance scholarship has limited
application.
Restricting the study of corporate governance to publicly traded corporations could limit
investigation into the most efficient institutional arrangements for undertaking productive
activities. Privately held entities could provide the most efficacious form of enterprise
5
notwithstanding the current ideologically commitment to privatization. This possibility is
supported by Jensen's (1993:869) view of a “proven model of governance structure” based
on the private ownership of Leverages Buy-Out Associations (LBO’s), and the outstanding
economic performance of the stakeholder co-operatives located around the town of
Mondragón in Spain (Turnbull 1995d).
If firms include all social institutions engaged in the production and sale of goods and
services, then both public and private sector organisations such as schools, hospitals, clubs
and societies need to be included. With firms defined in this way, the scope of corporate
governance includes nearly all the economic activity of a nation. It was by asking the
question, “Why is not all production carried on by one big firm?” that Coase (1937) laid the
intellectual foundations for developing a 'theory of the firm'.
Limitations in Anglo scholarship
The relevance of Anglo corporate governance scholarship is much more limited than to just
those firms that are publicly traded. This is because another common unstated implicit
assumption by Anglo scholars is that they are dealing with firms with a unitary board
without an influential shareholder in the tradition of Berle & Means (1934). This stylised
form of firm has limited the relevance of much empirical research because dominant
shareholders act like a supervisory board and are not uncommon.
6
Dominant shareholders are the norm in Europe (Brecht & Roell 1999, ECGN 1997,
Bianchi, Bianco & Enriques 1999) and Japan (Analytica 1992). They are also common in
Anglo countries with extensive foreign investment as found in Australia, New Zealand and
Canada and/or in developing economies which have many founding entrepreneurs and
family groups in control. For example, Stapeleton (1998) reports that 45% of companies in
the ‘All Ordinaries Index’ of the Australian Stock Exchange (ASX) are effectively
controlled by a non-institutional shareholder owning more than a 20% of the shares. Noninstitutional investors with between a 5% and 20% interest control another 33% of
companies in the index. Even in the US, the presence of a dominant shareholder is not
uncommon with the very largest corporations. Zey (1999) reports that around 20% of the
Fortune 500 companies have a dominant non-institutional shareholder. This sample also
includes companies like Microsoft and News Corporation controlled by their founding
entrepreneurs.
A dominant shareholder of a publicly traded firm with a unitary board creates a two tiered
control system such as may be required within a firm by civil law in Europe. Any system
of control with two or more significantly differentiated power centres, within or between
firms, or with an other entity like the founding entrepreneur, will be described in this paper
as a “compound board”.
7
Like a supervisory board in Europe, a dominant shareholder has the power to manage the
many conflicts of self-interest which directors of a unitary board are exposed to as
identified in Table 2. Supervisory boards and/or dominant shareholders not only introduce
checks and balances in managing self-serving activities of directors but also introduce the
decomposition of decision making labour to simplify directors duties and responsibilities,
and so reduce their personal liabilities and work load.
{INSERT TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE}
Corrupting powers of a unitary board
Even greater decomposition of decision making labour is found in some European firms,
which possess three of more control centres. The stakeholder controlled cooperatives of
Mondragón in Spain have five control centres (Turnbull 1995d). They demonstrate how
increasing the complexity of the information and control system of a firm can simplify
decision making to allow ordinary people to produce extra-ordinary results.
Compound boards are also formed by venture capitalists and in joint venture arrangements,
alliances, network firms; LBO’s and they appear to be a condition precedent to sustain nontrivial employee owned firms (Bernstein 1980). However, many scholars do not look
outside the boardroom (eg. Hilmer 1993) of a firm being investigated to ascertain whether
the firm has other centres of control. The existences of such other centres can substantial
change the role and functions of a unitary board.
8
The principal functions of a unitary board in a Berle & Means firm is to select, remunerate,
direct, monitor, control and retire the CEO. While all directors of a unitary board may
technically possess these responsibilities they may not in practice determine how their
power is exercised when the CEO and/or his family are the dominant shareholder. Bill
Gates of Microsoft and Rupert Murdoch of News Corporation provide examples. The
practical responsibilities and powers of directors of such companies are quite different from
those without a dominant shareholder.
However, many Anglo corporate governance scholars and practitioners not only commonly
ignore the existence of two tiered or more complex control systems but consider them alien
to their way of doing business! This denial of reality can be explained by the observation
of Kuhn in considering research into what he described as “normal science”. Kuhn (1970:
24) observed that this type of research does not "call forth-new sorts of phenomena: indeed
those that will not fit the box are often not seen at all".
This is illustrated by the many empirical studies on the structure of unitary boards where
the existence, and so the role of a dominant shareholder has been neglected. The presence
of a dominant shareholder is also commonly neglected in studies investigating the
relationship of board variables to firm performance.
One such example was the
investigation by Gertner & Kaplan (1998) into “The Value Maximising Board”. They
attributed the smaller size of LBO boards that had gone public again as a contributing
factor for their superior performance. However, the presence of a dominant shareholder
9
involving the residual buy-out investors was not considered.
Kang (1998) provided
evidence that a dominant shareholder can increase performance while Chidambaran. &
John (1999), show that they can more constructively monitor executive remuneration.
Cultural specificities in theories and practice
Research into the theory and practice of corporate governance has been heavily focussed on
English speaking countries and the US in particular. “Most of the available empirical
evidence in the English language comes from the United States” (Shleifer and Vishny
1996: 6). Hollingsworth, Schmitter & Streeck (1994: 4) state: “In the 1950s and 1960s,
hardly anyone disagreed with the assumption that the more traditional and, therefore,
backward economies like Japan, Germany, or Europe as a whole would have to adopt
American patterns of industrial organisation”. The lack of research in comparing different
systems of corporate control was only recognised in the US in the 1990's. This neglect was
explained by Gilson (1994: 132) who noted that “the American system seemed to represent
the evolutionary pinnacle of corporate governance, so other systems were either less far
along the Darwinist path, or evolutionary deadends, neither lagards nor Neanderthals made
interesting objects of study”.
This view was exacerbated by the US being the most powerful economy in the world, the
'citadel of capitalism', and a widely recognised role model for other countries seeking to
better themselves. The importance of a study by Porter (1992) is that it provided a counter
view for US academics and policy makers. To make US firms competitive with those in
10
Japan and Germany Porter (1992: 16 & 17) recommended to US policy makers,
institutional investors and corporations that they increase the involvement of employees,
customers, suppliers and host community in their ownership and control structure. Because
no business can exist without its employees, customers, suppliers and host community, they
are described as “strategic stakeholders” (Turnbull 1997g,h).
The US has also dominated the development of the theory of the firm, which was based on
the assumption, some might say paradigm, that “in the beginning there were markets”
(Williamson 1975: 20) and that firms exist because markets fail, ie. “suppression of the
price mechanism” (Coase 1937).
US scholars developed the theory of the firm during the height of the ideological contest
between capitalism and communism.
It would have been unpatriotic to entertain the
possibility that markets were not the natural order of a free society.
The failure of
communism has reinforced the hegemony of market ideology with widespread political
interest in privatisation based on the US model of a firm. The problems of using this model
in the US are identified by Jensen (1993), in Russia by Blasi & Gasaway (1993) and in
Australia by Turnbull (1993a,b; 1995a,c,f). The problems of the US model in either the US
or former socialist economies are outlined by Shleifer & Vishny (1996) and from the
conflicts of self-interest inherent in a unitary board as shown in Table 2. However, faith by
political ideologues in replicating the dominant, but flawed US governance model, has so
far been little inhibited by scholarly research, empirical evidence or the competitive success
of other approaches such as identified by Porter (1992) and Turnbull (1995d).
11
Even in Anglo countries with a well-developed system of property rights, law and
regulatory agencies, major failures in corporate control frequently occur. These failures
commonly occur with clean audit reports, which has created an academic literature on the
“audit expectation gap” (Guthrie 1992, Guthrie & Turnbull 1995, Walker 1991a, 1991b).
As responses to major failures, committees of inquiry are established (Cadbury 1992,
Bosch 1995) and codes of “best practice” recommended as a political palliative and attempt
to patch up an inherently flawed system. However, all such codes for unitary boards are
“misguided, misleading and so misnamed” (Turnbull, 1999c).
Palliatives provided by such codes involve the establishment of audit, remuneration and
nomination committees. However, such arrangements cannot remove the conflicts of selfinterest intrinsic to any unitary board. An additional palliative is the appointment of
external directors with claims that they can be “independent” even when they must rely on
information provided by management to monitor, direct, control, remunerate or retire
management. With many unitary boards, the external directors hold their position at the
grace and favour of management and do not have the will, power or capability to act
independently. It becomes very much in the self-interest of management to have external
directors who meet the test of being independent as such people will have minimum firm
specific and perhaps little industry specific knowledge and authority to challenge
management. Bhagat & Black (1997) provide evidence that independent directors can be
counter-productive.
12
The dominance of Anglo theory and practice has resulted in governments blindly following
the fundamentally flawed unitary control system for privatisation. It has also meant that
Anglo dominated multinational institutions like the World Bank have exported a flawed
system of corporate governance around the world. This has included including the former
socialist economies converting to a market system where the system of property rights, law
and regulatory bodies are poorly developed to compensate the corrupting features of an
unitary board which has absolute power to manage its own conflicts of self-interest.
Absolute power can corrupt both people and the performance of a business. This has
become very evident in Russia (Economist 1999a).
After a fifteen-year study of boards, Demb & Neubauer (1992b: 1) concluded that “At this
point in history, existing mechanism for governing corporations are no longer adequate.
The scale, complexity, importance, and risks of corporate activity have over-run our
institutions.”
Tricker states (1990: 74) "The need for rethinking the system design
parameters of modern corporations is apparent". Both Tricker (1994: 266), and the OECD
(1997, 2.6), see the formalisation of unitary board processes leading to the development of
a two tiered board.
Hatherly (1994) argues the case for a "shareholder panel" to supervise directors in a manner
consistent with the role of a "Corporate Senate" referred to by Turnbull (1992, 1993a,b);
Renton (1994: 36); Guthrie & Turnbull (1995); Monks & Minow (1995: 317), and Tricker
(1996: 75–6). Unlike the European two tiered boards, a Shareholder Panel or Senate does
13
not elect the board. Their relationship is more in line with the “Censeurs” found in French
financial institutions, and in government owned firms (Analytica 1992: 107). In discussing
shareholder committees in the US, Pound (1992: 91) notes that "Currently, there is a
resurgence of this activity". He points out that they "can act like a shadow cabinet in a
parliamentary system, offering shareholders independent analysis and an alternative
agenda".
To manage the inherent conflicts of a unitary board, Latham (1999) has proposed the
development of specialist monitoring firms.
Law Professor Lynne Dallas (1997) has
developed the most insightful analysis and constructive proposal for overcoming conflicts
of interests. She has proposed a dual board combined with a “board ombudsperson”
grounded in her “power” model of corporate governance considered later and illustrated by
Table 6.
Limitations and extension of the Theory of the firm
The assumption made by US scholars that in the beginning there were markets is not
supported by the evidence of history as noted by Ben Porath 1978), North (1985: 558),
Turnbull (1978b: 52; 1994d: 328) and others. In the beginning, economic transactions were
governed by social relationships rather than by markets, hierarchy or even what Williamson
(1990: x) refers to as 'hybrid modes of organisation' combining both markets and hierarchy.
Sociologists, Hollingsworth & Lindberg, (1985: 221–2) state that there are “four distinctive
forms of governance ... market, hierarchies, the clan or community and associations”. Each
14
form relies on a different type of information and control channel as set out in a typology
described by Turnbull (1978b: 6; 1994d: 328).
Two of these additional forms of
governance are outside the discipline of economics and so beyond the field of vision and
analysis by economists.
It was also outside the field of vision of Coase (1937), trained in commerce, which led him
to ask and answer the wrong question when laying the foundations for developing the
theory of the firm. Instead of inquiring why economic transactions are organised through
the “authority system” of a firm rather than through the market, he should have asked when
are economic transactions organised by any combination of the four different ways in
which transactions can be governed.
Each of these four institutional modes for governing human activities have “a separate logic
of collective action and social order” as described by Streeck & Schmitter (1985: 11). The
existence of four rather than two institutional modes of organising human co-operation
means that existing theories of the firm are incomplete (Turnbull 1994a). This does not
necessarily mean that existing theories of the firm are incorrect, only that they may have
limited application, in a way analogous to Newtonian 'laws of motion' providing correct
answers when the effects of relativity are not present. In other words, the theory of the firm
becomes most relevant in cultures committed to competition with strong anti-trust laws and
large scale impersonal publicly traded firms without related party transactions.
This
describes the US economy where it is assumed that firms have ownership separated from
control as reported by Berle & Means (1934), and are not strongly bonded through cultural,
15
clan, trade, industry, vocational or other associations, including strong interlocking
directorships.
The US based theory of the firm becomes less relevant when economic transactions are
mediated by cultural priorities; business related associations, trade, vocational, family,
social and political networks. These are more prominent in continental Europe, Japan and
other Asian countries (Hollingsworth & Lindberg 1985; Analytica 1992; Hollingsworth,
Schmitter & Streeck 1994; Hollingsworth & Boyer 1997).
However, “the social
governance of markets” in the US is not insignificant, as detailed by Bruyn (1991). The
operating advantages of a greater reliance on associations and networks in the governance
of firms has been reported by Franks & Mayer (1993), Gilson & Roe (1993), Kester (1992),
and Turnbull (1995d; 1999a). Blair (1995), Fukao (1995: 74,77,78), and Porter (1992:
16–17) all recommend that US firms involve their strategic stakeholders. In the tradition of
Anglo research, Porter, Blair and Fukao did not identify that the greater involvement of
stakeholders in the ownership and control structure of corporations in other cultures arose
from the existence of a compound board. The introduction of stakeholders on a unitary
board to create what Williamson (1985: 300) refers to as “interest group management”
would introduce unacceptable conflicts of interest. However, the compound boards found
in Japan and Europe can also produce counter productive conflicts of interest from the
involvement of strategic stakeholders with their related party interests. Table 3 suggests
how the property rights of investors can be protected from such conflicts while involving
strategic stakeholders to meet Porters recommendations without compounding the conflicts.
16
{INSERT TABLE 3 ABOUT HERE}
Anglo corporate governance compared with competitive practices
While Street and Schmitter (1985: 1), Hollingsworth & Lindberg (1985: 221) and Turnbull
(1994a: 325–8, 1999a) have outlined a possible theoretical framework for analysing
governance systems between cultures, corporate governance scholars have not yet used
their work.
Hollingsworth, Schmitter & Streeck (1994: 5) state that “Contemporary
mainstream economics postulates essentially two mechanisms of governance: markets and
corporate hierarchies.” They go on to say: “In the limited institutional repertory envisaged
by mainstream economics, corporate hierarchies are the preferred, and in fact the only
‘economic’, alternative to markets”.
Failure by many economists to recognise that there are modes of governing transactions
outside markets and hierarchy, and the hegemony of market ideology, has resulted in there
being “no accepted theoretical framework for comparing systems of corporate governance
within or between cultures” (Demb & Neubauer 1992a). Radner (1992) goes further to
state “I know no theoretical research to date that compares the relative efficiency of
hierarchical and non-hierarchical organisations within a common model”. More generally,
Jensen (1993: 873) observed that “we're facing the problem of developing a viable theory
of organizations”. This problem has been identified by a number of other leading workers
in the field.
17
Coase (1991b: 72) saw the need for “a more comprehensive theory” and stated that “theory
is outrunning our knowledge of the facts in the study of industrial organization and that
more empirical work is required if we are to make progress” (1991a: 451). North (1985:
572) noted that there is an “additional dimension currently missing in the discipline of
economics”. Williamson (1990: xi) sees the need for “observing the phenomena at a higher
level of resolution”. Williamson (1991: 10) noted that “In Demsetz's judgment, however,
recent work—of team theory (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972), agency theory (Jensen &
Meckling, 1976) and transaction cost kinds—has not gone far enough”. Demsetz (1991:
159) stated that “a more complete theory of the firm must give greater weight to
information cost than is given either in Coase's theory or in theories based on shirking and
opportunism which have not gone far enough”.
However, these concerns can be overcome by using information rather than costs as the
unit of analysis. In the Coasian analysis of why firms exist, costs represent a proxy for
information, which is measured in bytes. The ability of individuals to transact bytes has
“neurophysiological limits” as noted by Williamson (1975: 21) who went on to observe that
“The physical limits take the form of rate and storage limits on the powers of individuals to
receive, store, retrieve, and process information without error." Some of these limits are
identified in Table 4, which indicates how Transaction Byte Analysis (TBA) can be
grounded in the physical sciences.
TBA provides a way to subsume TCE and ground organisational analysis in the laws of
cybernetics and other pure and applies sciences. The criteria for evaluating and designing
18
organisations becomes one reducing the bytes transacted by individuals so that they can
operate within their capabilities. That is, to economise bytes rather than costs. In this way
costs can also be economised as they represent a proxy for bytes in the Coasian/Williamson
paradigm. This paradigm is compared with the TBA in Table 5.
{INSERT TABLE 4 ABOUT HERE)
Human constraints in transacting bytes
{INSERT TABLE 5 ABOUT HERE)
Comparison between TCE and TBA boundaries of analysis
The lack of an accepted framework for comparing different systems of corporate
governance has resulted in comparative corporate governance research being principally
empirical. Notable contributions to this relatively recent field have come from scholars
outside the US such as those of Analytica (1992), Demb & Neubauer (1992b), Franks &
Mayer (1993), Isaksson & Skog (1994), Charkham (1994), Gönenç (1994), Tricker (1994),
Wymeersch (1994), Garrett (1996), Turnbull (1975b; 1995a,b,c,d,f; 1997e,f; 1997a; 1999a)
and members of the European Corporate Governance Network (ECGN) like Brecht & Roell
(1999), Bianchi, Bianco, & Enriques, (1999) et.al. US contributions have focused on Japan
or Germany such as those by Kester (1991; 1992), Porter (1992), Roe (1993), Gilson & Roe
(1993) and Aoki (1993), with other countries considered by Black & Coffee (1993), Blasi
& Gasaway (1993), Monks & Minow (1995), Fukao (1995) and Preston (1996).
Theories relevant to corporate governance
19
Hawley & Williams (1996) undertook a literature review of corporate governance in the US
as a background paper for the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD). They identified four models of corporate control: 1. The Simple Finance Model,
2. The Stewardship Model, 3. The Stakeholder Model, and 4. The Political Model. Three
additional ways of analysing corporate governance are also considered in the next section
based on respectively, culture, power and cybernetics.
Another Survey of Corporate
Governance by Shleifer & Vishny (1996) for the National Bureau of Economic Research
was not restricted to the US, but its scope was limited to the finance model consistent with
the specialised definition of corporate governance adopted by the authors. They defined
corporate governance as “the ways in which the suppliers of finance to corporations assure
themselves of getting a return on their investment” (Shleifer & Vishny 1996: 2). However,
their analysis is burdened with the ambiguity inherent in key economic terms discussed by
Turnbull (1997a: 182).
US scholars wrote the two surveys referred to above. Both surveys contain some unstated
culturally determined boundary conditions and assume that the US context provides a
universal reference. Shleifer & Vishny (1996: 6) explicitly state that “while we pay some
attention to cooperatives, we do not focus on a broad variety of non-capitalist ownership
patterns, such as worker ownership and non-profit organizations”. Nor are these types of
firms considered by Hawley & Williams who do not state their boundary conditions.
Tricker (1996: 31) states:
20
Stewardship theory, stakeholder theory and agency theories are all essentially
ethnocentric. Although the underlying ideological paradigms are seldom articulated,
the essential ideas are derived from Western thought, with its perceptions and
expectations of the respective roles of individual, enterprise and the state and of the
relationships between them.
Neither Shleifer & Vishny nor Hawley & Williams define the type of 'capitalistic' firms
subject to their survey, the basis, if any, that their securities are publicly traded and the
characteristics of the securities, which exert some controlling, influence on the firm. In the
tradition of US scholarly corporate governance research, the US legal/political/regulatory
system and the division of power between directors and shareholders, as set out in
corporate constitutions, is mostly implicitly accepted as the given 'state of the world'.
There are, however, important variations between US States (Monks 1996; Gordon 1993),
between Anglo cultures (Black & Coffee 1993) and between other cultures (Analytica
1992, Porter 1992, Fukao 1995, and Charkham 1994).
For example, publicly traded firms in Europe may have two or three tiered boards
(Analytica, 1992). Between and within Europe and the US there are different ways of
publicly trading the securities of a firm. Different stock exchanges have different rules
governing the powers of directors in relation to their shareholders.
These introduce
different regulatory regimes to produce significant differences in the management
discretions of the firm, eg. The requirement to have audit, remuneration and nomination
committees; methods of electing or appointing directors; shareholder approval to pay
21
directors, new share issues, establishing employee share plans, changing auditors, merging
with another firm or changing the corporate charter or place of incorporation, etc. The
voting rights of shares, the rights of shareholders to call meetings, the percentage of votes
required to achieve changes in control, capitalisation or corporate charters may also vary
according to each firm, stock exchange, place of incorporation or national laws and
regulations.
The Hawley & Williams survey is implicitly limited to corporations, which have their
shares publicly, traded and explicitly limited to US based firms. Not being limited to either
US firms or the 'simple finance model' of Hawley & Williams, Shleifer & Vishny consider
additional dimensions of the finance model.
Consistent with their concern of how
financiers 'assure themselves of getting a return on their investment' they also survey how
corporate control is influenced by debt securities and bankers.
Implicit assumptions of both surveys seem to be that all publicly traded firms have 1. The
rights of perpetual succession, 2. Limited liability, 3. Unitary boards, 4. Management
hierarchies without related party transactions, strategic alliances or networks as found in
non-anglo firms, and 5. Unambiguous boundaries.
To provide a perspective of the relative importance of publicly traded firms, it is interesting
to note that around 75% of the 60,000 publicly traded corporations in the world are found
in cultures which have adopted Anglo corporate concepts (FIBV 1993; Economist 1995:
116 & 1999b: 120). The only non-anglo countries with more than 1,000 publicly traded
22
corporations (excluding investment funds) are Japan (2,953), Germany (1,297) and Brazil
(1,129). France and Italy all have less than 1,000 listed companies. The Fédération
Internationale des Bourses de Valeurs (FIBV) records four Anglo countries with more than
1,000 listed companies: the US (10,546), Canada (3,079), United Kingdom (2,412), and
Australia (1,107).
India has around 5,860 listed companies (Economist 1999b) not
included in the FIBV statistics.
1. The simple finance model
“In the finance view, the central problem in corporate governance is to construct rules and
incentives (that is, implicit or explicit 'contracts') to effectively align the behaviour of
managers (agents) with the desires of principals (owners)”, (Hawley & Williams 1996: 21).
However, the 'rules' and 'incentives' considered, are generally only those within the existing
US system of publicly traded firms with unitary boards.
The rules and incentives in the finance model refer to those established by the firm rather
than to the legal/political/regulatory system and culture of the host economy or the nature
of the owners.
The finance view represents a sub-section of the political model of
corporate governance.
The political model interacts with the 'cultural', 'power' and
'cybernetic' models raised in the following section.
It is the nature of the owners, which exacerbates corporate control problems found in Anglo
countries like the US, Canada, UK and Australia. In each of these countries, institutional
23
investors may own the majority of the shares in most of the largest publicly traded firms
unlike in continental Europe and Japan (Analytica 1992; ECGN 1997).
Institutional
investors, such as pension and mutual funds, collectively owned more than 57% of the top
US 1,000 firms in 1994 (Hawley & Williams 1996: 8). The problem with institutional
ownership is that their investment managers are fiduciary agents of the beneficial owners
and so the situation is created of agents representing agents. Hence the term 'Fiduciary
Capitalism' or what Peter Drucker (1976) more provocatively described as 'Pension Fund
Socialism'.
The problem of agents being responsible to agents is that it compounds the agency costs
identified by Jensen & Meckling (1976). A basic assumption is that managers will act
opportunistically to further their own interests before shareholders. Jensen and Meckling
showed how investors in publicly traded corporations incur costs in monitoring and
bonding managers in best serving shareholders. They defined agency costs as being the
sum of the cost of monitoring management (the agent); bonding the agent to the principal
(stockholder/ ‘residual claimant’; and residual losses. Their analysis also showed: why
firms use a mixture of debt and equity; why it is rational for managers not to maximise the
value of a firm; why it is still possible to raise equity; why accounting reports are provided
voluntarily and auditors employed by the company; and why monitoring by security
analysts can be productive even if they do not increase portfolio returns to investors.
A basic conclusion of agency theory is that the value of a firm cannot be maximised
because managers possess discretions, which allow them to expropriate value to themselves
24
as identified in Table 2.. In an ideal world, managers would sign a complete contract that
specifies exactly what they could do under all states of the world and how profits would be
allocated. “The problem is that most future contingencies are too hard to describe and
foresee, and as a result, complete contracts are technologically unfeasible” (Shleifer &
Vishny 1996).
As a result, managers obtain the right to make decisions, which are not defined or
anticipated in the contract under which debt or equity finance is contributed (Grossman &
Hart 1986; Hart & Moore 1990). This raises the “principal's problem” (Ross 1973) and
“agency problem” (Fama & Jensen 1983a,b). How can publicly traded firms with such
incomplete contracts with their managers be effective in efficiently raising funds?
The “agency problem” is particularly acute in Anglo cultures with dispersed ownership
where corporations do not have a supervisory board or what Monks (1994) describes as a
“relationship investor”. When all shareholders own small minority interests to create
diverse ownership it is not rational for any investor to spend time and incur costs to
supervise management as this provides a 'free ride' for other investors. In any event, small
shareholders may lack the power and influence to extract information, which could reveal
expropriation or mismanagement.
In many Anglo countries, the law may limit the ability of shareholders to become
associated together to form a voting block to influence or change management unless they
make a public offer to all shareholders. Insider trading laws may also inhibit or prohibit
25
shareholders from obtaining the necessary information to monitor and supervise
management.
Monks (1996), an Assistant Secretary of Labour in the Reagan
Administration describes how US corporate managers have influenced law making to
protect themselves from shareholder interventions.
2. The stewardship model
In the stewardship model, 'managers are good stewards of the corporations and diligently
work to attain high levels of corporate profit and shareholders returns' (Donaldson & Davis
1994). Both Lex Donaldson and Davis teach in business schools. Their arguments support
the investment of business schools and their students in the development of management
skills and knowledge. It also reinforces the social and professional kudos of being a
manager.
Donaldson & Davis note that “Managers are principally motivated by achievement and
responsibility needs” and “given the needs of managers for responsible, self-directed work,
organizations may be better served to free managers from subservience to non-executive
director dominated boards”. According to Donaldson & Davis, “most researchers into
boards have had as their prior belief the notion that independent boards are good” and “so
eventually produce the expected findings”. There are influential and powerful sources who
recommend the need for independent non-executive directors such as the Council of
Institutional Investors in the US, Cadbury (1992) in the UK, Australian Institutional
26
investors (AIMA 1995), existing professional directors, and all those would like to become
non-executive directors.
However, supporting stewardship theory are the individuals who contribute their own
money and other resources to non-profit organisations to become a director. In analysing
the welfare distributed to stakeholders through introducing a division of powers, Persson,
Roland & Tabellini (1996) had provisions in their equations to include the welfare
contributed by controllers.
In commenting on stewardship theory, Hawley & Williams (1996: 29) state that “The
logical extension is either towards an executive-dominated board or towards no board at
all”. Donaldson & Davis point out “the non-executive board of directors is, by its design,
an ineffective control device” and cite evidence to support the view that “the whole
rationale for having a board becomes suspect”. Brewer (1996) reported that “One of
Canada's best-known business leaders suggested last month that boards of directors should
be abolished and replaced by a formal committee of advisers”. This view arose from the
businessman in question being sued as a director of an insurance company for over a billion
dollars from actions taken by management.
Boards can become redundant when there is a dominant active shareholder, especially
when the major shareholder is a family or government. One could speculate that some
boards are established from cultural habit, blind faith in their efficacy, or to make
government or family firms look 'more business like'.
27
However, research by Pfeffer (1972) has shown that the value of external directors is not so
much how they influence managers but how they influence constituencies of the firm. He
found that the more regulated an industry then the more outsiders were present on the board
to reassure the regulators, bankers, and other interest groups.
Tricker (1996: 29) points out “underpinning company law is the requirement that directors
show a fiduciary duty towards the shareholders of the company”. Inherent in the idea of
directors having a fiduciary duty is that they can be trusted and will act as stewards over the
resources of the company. Thus in Anglo law, directors duties are based on stewardship
theory. This duty is higher than that of an agent as the person must act as if he or she was
the principal rather than a representative.
Many writers, and especially the proponents of stewardship and agency theory, see each
theory contradicting the other. Donaldson & Davis raise the possibility that there is some
deficiency in the methodologies of the numerous studies they cite which provide support
for both theories. Some possibilities are that the studies did not separate out the affect of
firms being in a regulated industry as analysed by Pfeffer (1972) or possessing a dominant
shareholder acting as a supervisory board or 'relationship investor' as discussed earlier.
Ghosal & Moran (1996: 14) raise the possibility that the assumption of opportunism on
which agency theory is based, “can become a self-fulfilling prophecy whereby
opportunistic behaviour will increase with the sanctions and incentives imposed to curtail
28
it, thus creating the need for even stronger and more elaborate sanctions and incentives”.
Likewise, stewardship theory could also become a self-fulling. This would appear to be the
situation in firms around Mondragón, which have no independent directors. All board
members are either executives or stakeholders (Turnbull 1995d). However, each firm and
each group of firms in the Mondragón system is controlled by three or more
boards/councils or control centres which introduces a division of power with checks and
balances to manage conflicts.
The inclination of individuals to act as stewards or self-seeking agents may be contingent
upon the institutional context. If this is the case, then both theories can be valid as
indicated by the empirical evidence. Stewardship theory, like agency theory, would then be
seen as sub-set of political and other broader models of corporate governance.
Psychological analysis supports both theories. Wearing (1973), a professor of psychology
states that: “differences between individuals are significant and important”. The need for
money and approval, etc. is “determined and limited by the necessity of maintaining the
organism in a state of dynamic equilibrium”. People stand “in an interactive cybernetic
relationship to his/her community and environment, and is changed as a result of any
interaction” and individuals are “sometimes competitive, sometimes collaborative: usually
both”.
The inclination of individuals to act as selfless stewards may be culturally contingent. The
'company man' in Japan may place his employer before family. The voluntary resignation
29
of executives is not uncommon when a firm is disgraced and instances of suicide are still
reported.
3. The stakeholder model
In defining 'Stakeholder Theory' Clarkson (1994) states: “’The firm’ is a system of stake
holders operating within the larger system of the host society that provides the necessary
legal and market infrastructure for the firm's activities. The purpose of the firm is to create
wealth or value for its stakeholders by converting their stakes into goods and services”.
Blair (1995: 322) supports this view and stated:
... the goal of directors and management should be maximizing total wealth
creation by the firm. The key to achieving this is to enhance the voice of
and provide ownership-like incentives to those participants in the firm who
contribute or control critical, specialized inputs (firm specific human capital)
and to align the interests of these critical stakeholders with the interests of
outside, passive shareholders.
Consistent with this view to provide “voice'”and “ownership-like incentives” to “critical
stakeholders”, Porter (1992: 16–7) recommended to US policy makers that they should
“encourage long-term employee ownership” and “encourage board representation by
significant customers, suppliers, financial advisers, employees, and community
representatives”. Porter (1992: 17) also recommended that corporations “seek long-term
30
owners and give them a direct voice in governance” (ie. relationship investors) and to
“nominate significant owners, customers, suppliers, employees, and community
representatives to the board of directors”.
All these recommendations would help establish the sort of business alliances, trade related
networks and strategic associations which Hollingsworth & Lindberg (1985) noted had not
evolved as much in the US as they had in continental Europe and Japan. In other words,
Porter is suggesting that competitiveness can be improved by using all four institutional
modes for governing transactions rather than just markets and hierarchy. This supports the
need to expand the theory of the firm as outlined by Turnbull (1994a) as indicated in Table
5.
However, the recommendations of Porter to have various stakeholder constituencies
appoint representatives to a unitary board would be counter-productive for the reasons
identified by Williamson (1985: 300), Guthrie & Turnbull (1995) and Turnbull (1994c;
1995e). Williamson (1985: 308) states: “Membership of the board, if it occurs at all,
should be restricted to informational participation”.
Such information participation is
provided for in Table 3, which is achieved in Japan through a Keiretsu Council and in
continental Europe through works councils and supervisory boards.
These examples
provide the model for establishing “stakeholder councils” as described by Guthrie &
Turnbull (1995) and Turnbull (1994d; 1997c,e, f) as outlined in Table 3.
31
Hill & Jones (1992) have built on the work of Jensen & Meckling (1976) to recognise both
the implicit and explicit contractual relationships in a firm to develop “Stakeholder–Agency
Theory”. The interdependence between a firm and its strategic stakeholders is recognised
by the American Law Institute (1992). The Institute states: “The modern corporation by its
nature creates interdependences with a variety of groups with whom the corporation has a
legitimate concern, such as employee, customers, suppliers, and members of the
communities in which the corporation operates”.
Both stakeholder voice and ownership, as suggested by Porter and Blair, could be provided
by “re-inventing” the concept of a firm as proposed by Turnbull (1973, 1975a, 1991a,
1994d, 1997f). This proposal is based on tax incentives providing higher short-term profits
to investors in exchange for them gradually relinquishing their property rights in favour of
strategic stakeholders.
Control of the firm is likewise shared between investors and
stakeholders through a compound board to remove conflicts of interest and so agency costs
in a manner similar to that found in continental Europe and especially in Mondragón.
4. The political model
The political model recognises that the allocation of corporate power, privileges and profits
between owners, managers and other stakeholders is determined by how governments
favour their various constituencies. The ability of corporate stakeholders to influence
allocations between themselves at the micro level is subject to the macro framework, which
is interactively subjected to the influence of the corporate sector.
32
According to Hawley & Williams (1996: 29): “the political model of corporate governance
has had immense influence on corporate governance developments in the last five to seven
years”. However, Hawley & Williams focus their discussion only on the micro aspects of
how shareholders can influence firms. Firms have also been influential in moulding the US
political/legal/regulatory system over the last few centuries. According to Justice Felix
Frankfurter of the US Supreme Court, the history of US constitutional law is “the history of
the impact of the modern corporation upon the American scene”, quoted in Miller (1968:
1).
Roe (1994) provides an elaboration of the historical evolution of the political model and
like Black (1990) and others, argues that the finance model's nearly exclusive reliance on
the market for corporate control, was primarily the result of the political traditions of
federalism/decentralisation dating back to the American Revolution.
However, these
traditions have been subject to substantial changes.
After the Revolution, there was concern that newly won political freedoms could be lost
through foreigners gaining control of corporations (Grossman & Adams 1993: 6). As a
result, all corporate charters were limited to a life of 50 years or less up until after the Civil
War. Nor did these charters provide limited liability for the owners. Most states adopted a
ten-year sunset clause for bank charters and sometimes they were as short as three years.
“Early state legislators wrote charter laws and actual charters to limit corporate authority,
and to ensure that when a corporation caused harm, they could revoke the charter” (p.1).
33
However, “During the late 19th century, corporations subverted state governments” (p.1)
and according to Friedman (1973: 456), corporations “bought and sold governments”.
In 1886 the US Supreme Court ruled that a private corporation was a natural person under
the US constitution, sheltered by the Bill of Rights and the 14th Amendment. “Led by New
Jersey and Delaware, legislators watered down or removed citizen authority clauses. They
limited the liability of corporate owners and managers, then started handing out charters
that literally lasted forever” (Grossman & Adams 1993: 21).
“Political power began
flowing to absentee owners intent upon dominating people and nature” (p.15). Grossman
& Adams (1993: 26) went on to say “No Corporation should exist forever”.
As a reaction to the corporate power extant at the end of the 19th century, a number US
States introduced cumulative voting to allow minority interests to elect directors (Gordon
1993). Gordon describes how this initiative was subverted by competition between states
to attract corporate registrations or what Nader, Green & Seligman (1976: 44) describes as
“chartermongering”. Monks (1996) describes this as “the race to the bottom” and explains
how contemporary corporations are influencing the determination of accounting and legal
doctrines and promoting a management friendly political/legal/regulatory environment.
Monks (1996) states that “The hegemony of the BRT (Business Round Table) is not a
sustainable basis for corporate governance in America”.
During the beginning of the 20th century, at the federal level, laws were introduced in the
US to limit bank ownership of corporations and related party transactions between
34
corporations. This forced both the pattern of ownership and control of US firms and the
pattern of trading relationships to diverge from that found in continental Europe and Japan.
Kester (1992) describes the latter patterns as “contractual governance” as analysed by
Coase and Williamson while limiting the term corporate governance to the problem of coordination and control as analysed by Jensen & Meckling (1976) and Berle & Means
(1932).
Hawley & Williams (1996: 29) focused on the micro level of the political model as
articulated by Gundfest (1990) and Pound. Pound (1993b) defined the “political model of
governance” as an approach, “... in which active investors seek to change corporate policy
by developing voting support from dispersed shareholders, rather than by simply
purchasing voting power or control...”.
Pound (1992: 83) states: “this new form of
governance based on politics rather than finance will provide a means of oversight that is
both far more effective and far less expensive than the takeovers of the 1980's”.
Gundfest (1993) points out that “an understanding of the political marketplace is essential
to appreciate the role that capital-market mechanisms can... play in corporate governance”.
For example, Gordon & Pound (1991) showed that corporations with fewer anti-takeover
provisions in their constitutions out performed those with anti-takeover measures in place.
While the political form of governance is new to many US scholars, the importance of
“political procedures” (Jensen & Meckling 1979: 481) have been recognised in worker-
35
governed firms by Bernstein (1980), Turnbull (1978a: 100), and many others, including
stakeholder-controlled firms (Turnbull 1995d).
While recognising the cultural and contextual contingencies of the US system, the current
political model focuses on contemporary issues such as the US proclivity for market
liquidity over institutional control (Coffee 1991). The political model is also concerned
with the related issue of trading off investor voice to investment exit, and institutional
agents monitoring corporate agent, ie. Watching the Watchers (Monks & Minow 1996).
All these issues are influenced by government laws and regulations and so subject of public
policy debate for changes and reform. Black & Coffee (1993) state that:
According to a new 'political' theory of corporate governance, financial institutions
in the U.S. are not naturally apathetic, but rather have been regulated into submission
by legal rules that—sometimes intentionally, sometimes inadvertently—hobble
American institutions and raise the costs of participation in corporate governance.
Bhide (1994) develops details of this position. Hawley & Williams (1996: 32) state:
The political model of corporate governance (whether Pound's or Gundfest's version)
places severe limits on the traditional economic analysis of the corporate governance
problem, and locates the performance-governance issue squarely in a broader
political context. Political does not mean necessarily imply a government role,
merely that it is non-market.
36
In other words, the analysis of economists needs to be truncated and integrated into the
insights of Ben-Porath (1978) and Hollingsworth & Lindberg (1985) to understand how
both economic transactions and their coordinating institutions are governed. An aspect also
neglected by economists is that national income can be distributed without work or welfare
by spreading corporate ownership directly to individuals rather than through institutional
intermediaries (Kelso & Adler 1958; Kelso & Hetter 1967, 1986; Turnbull 1975a, 1988,
1991b, 1994b).
5. Emerging political issues
On the suggestion of Louis Kelso, Senator Russell Long began introducing tax and other
incentives into the US Congress from 1974 onwards to promote universal share ownership.
Largely as a result of these incentives, “of the approximately 7,000 companies listed on
American stock exchanges, about 1,000 firms are at least 10% employee held” (Tseo, 1996:
66). Blasi (1988) documents the growing spread and size of employee ownership in both
private and publicly traded companies in the US. Ironically, the extent of employee
ownership in publicly traded firms in Russia is higher (Blasi & Gasaway 1993). “In 1988,
more than 90% of all firms listed on Japanese stock markets had an ESOP” (Jones & Kato
1993). The Confederation of British Industry (CBI 1990: 7) found that “60 fund managers
could determine the ownership of British companies” and concluded, “concentration of
power in any democracy is to be discouraged”.
37
Without universal individual ownership, problems arise from “universal owners” as pointed
out by Monks (1996). A 'universal owner' is an institution, which effectively owns a small
proportion of the entire economy. The raises the problem of the same owners participating
in the governance of competing firms. It also raises the possibility that universal owners
may seek to maximise profits in their corporations through transferring the costs of
maintaining the environment, education and health care to the taxpayers whom they also
represent.
Universal ownership avoids the problems of universal owners.
There is also much
evidence that ownership by individual stakeholders can improve performance (Turnbull
1997g,h). Corporate governance scholars such as Blair (1995), Monks (1996), Porter
(1992), and Denham & Porter (1995) support employee ownership, in particular. Porter
(1992) recommended that all strategic stakeholders participate in ownership and control.
Turnbull (1973, 1975a, 1991a, 1994d, 1997g,h) describes alternative mechanisms to those
proposed by Kelso for achieving this objective to promote what Porter refers to as
'expanded ownership'.
Turnbull (1993a,b; 1994c; 1997e,g,h) describes how Porter's
proposals could be implemented to provide operating advantages and a basis for improving
corporate self-governance.
Other ways of analysing corporate governance
38
There are other models of corporate governance based on culture, power and cybernetics.
A synthesis of all models may be required if we are to efficiently develop, construct, test
and implement new approaches.
1. Culture
Hollingsworth, Schmitter & Streeck (1994: 6) provide an example of a cultural perspective:
...transactions are conducted on the basis of mutual trust and confidence sustained
by
stable,
preferential,
particularistic,
non–enforceable relationships.
mutually
obligated,
and
legally
They may be kept together either by value
consensus or resource dependency—that is, through 'culture' and 'community' - or
through dominant units imposing dependence on others.
This statement was made in the context of transactions being governed by networks at the
“mesolevel (eg. The intermediate location between the micro-level of the firm and the
macro-level of the whole economy)” rather than of the firm (p.9). However, it is also
relevant within firms, and in this way it would subsume elements of the stewardship model.
Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, (1997) found that the type of dominant
religion in a culture can affect trust and hence the ability of strangers in large organizations
to co-operate. In particular, they found that trust in large organisations increases as the
proportion of the population involved in hierarchical religions, like Catholicism, decreases.
39
While Japan showed an above average degree of trust is was not as high as Nordic
countries and China. Some scholars have speculated that the Japanese commitment to
employee participation and the forming of strategic alliances between firms arises from
their embedded belief in the inter-dependency of their many Gods. It might be interesting
to research if Christian economists and managers, or other types of monotheists have an
embedded belief in hierarchies rather than alliances and networks.
Williamson (1975: 38) noted the shortcomings of economic analysis in neglecting “the
exchange process itself as an object of value”. He identified the concept of 'atmosphere' to
“raise such systems issues: supplying a satisfying exchange relation is made part of the
economic problem, broadly construed”. However, this insight is not mentioned or used in
Williamson (1985) or in many of his later writings.
The need to consider the cultural context or 'atmosphere' of transactions within and between
firms has been analysed by Maruyama (1991). Mondragón illustrates the importance of
culture as it provides “an environment where there is no perceived threat of opportunism,
even from opportunists!” to use the words of Ghoshal and Moran (1996: 26) in another
context. “Mondragón makes it clear that market or planning decisions are value decisions”
(Morrison 1991: 98). This is seen as an advantage by economists, Bradley & Gelb (1983:
30), from the World Bank. They favourably compare Mondragón with the “enriched
employment relationship extending far beyond the cash nexus” of Japanese firms and Xinefficiency (Leibenstein, 1987) found with “Western” practices.
40
The importance of culture is evident from the view in Mondragón that social adaptability is
the most critical condition in converting a firm owned by an entrepreneur to a co-operative
(Whyte & Whyte (1988: 86). “Mondragón is unlikely to undertake a conversion if the
prospects of resocializing managers and workers appear poor.” In this regard, the Catholic
influence in Mondragón is at odds with the findings of Porta et al. (1997). Morrison (1991:
111) quotes the founder of Mondragón, Father Arizmendi as saying: “A company cannot
and must not lose any of its efficiency just because human values are considered more
important than purely economic or material resources within the company; on the contrary
such a consideration should help efficiency and quality”.
Contrary to the concerns of Ghoshal & Moran, Williamson (1979: 104) accepted that trust
could transcend opportunism when he stated:
Additional transactions-specific savings can accrue at the interface between supplier
and buyer as contracts are successively adapted to unfolding events, and as periodic
contract-renewal agreements are reached. Familiarity here permits communication
economies to be realised: specialised language develops as experience accumulates
and nuances are signalled and received in a sensitive way. Both institutional and
personal trust relations evolve.
The reference to “communication economies” supports the use of TBA and the need to
integrate culture into the research calculus of firm structure and performance as undertaken
by Berger (1976) in evaluating economic development.
41
2. The power perspective of corporate governance,
The explicit use of power seems to be neglected topic. Without the power to act there is
little use in providing either directors or shareholders with the information to act. However,
corporate governance reformers and policy makers who focus on issues of transparency and
accountability commonly overlook this. For any stakeholder to protect their own interest,
or that of any others, they need four simultaneous conditions: (i) the information to act, (ii)
the will to act, (iii) the power to act, and (iv) the capability to act.
A legal scholar, Lynne Dallas (1988: 29) has developed an explicit power theory of the firm
as outlined in Table 6. Dallas points out that “under the efficiency model, the firm is
conceived as a “nexus of contracts” and so disappears as an actor, making questions as to
‘corporate’ responsibility meaningless” (Dallas 1988: 28), refer to line 1 of the Table.
Also, describing managers, as “agents” is inappropriate as legally directors are “principles”
who are the “dominant coalition members” as noted in line 2 of the Table. In line 3 of the
Table, firm objectives are to increase the power and autonomy of the managers. This of
course depends upon achieving some minimum level of profits as required by the efficiency
model.
{INSERT TABLE 6 ABOUT HERE}
Efficiency and power models of the firm
42
Whereas economists assume that the structure and behaviour of firms is determined by
market forces, the power theory of the firm sees their structure and behaviour determined
by management seeking greater power and security by introducing “poison pill” “shark
repellent”, etc, to repel market competition for their position of power. The efficiency
model of a firm considers that directors are contracted by shareholders to act as monitors
for the shareholders to select, direct and control managers as set out in line 6 of the Table.
The power model sees directors being co-opted by managers, because of the superior
information, to coop them to make them a “tool” of an internal power coalition.
The power of shareholders to act is part of the political model of corporate governance.
Hawley & Williams (1996:57-60) identify various inhibitions on the power of shareholders
to act arising from security laws, agenda setting by management at general meetings, proxy
procedures, voting arrangements and the corporate by-laws.
The power of directors to control management is dependent upon there being a sufficient
number of directors who also have the knowledge and will to act to form a board majority.
Even if independent directors have the knowledge to act, they may not have the will and
power to act because they are loyal or obligated to management and/or hold their board
position at the grace and favour of management. Directors are unlikely to act against
management unless they are supported by shareholders.
However, many institutional
shareholders lack the will to act. This was found to be a major problem for US firms in a
report into their competitiveness by Regan (1993). Hawley & Williams (1996: 65) noted
43
that management controlled “the information that does reach the board. The result can be a
board knowing too little, too late and, even if it is willing to act to confront a growing
problem or crisis, it is often unable to do so”.
An appropriate separation of powers to create checks and balances provides a way to
increase the welfare of stakeholders according to Persson, Roland & Tabillini (1996).
Persson, Roland & Tabillini make the point that negative welfare may result if the division
of power is not “appropriate”. Suggestions for an appropriate division of power has been
made by Bernstein (1980), Dallas (1998) and Turnbull (1978a: 100; 1992; 1993b; 1994c,
1998a) and as indicated by Table 3.
The basis for suggesting that Table 3 illustrates an appropriate division of power is that it
provides governors of productive activities with the information, will, power and capability
to act. Information to act, independent of management, is provided by the stakeholder
councils who have access to inside, expert committed sources. The will to act is provided
by electing directors through proportional or “cumulative voting” (Bhagat & Brickley
1984: Gordon 1993) to provide at least some of them representing minority interests with
the “will to act” (Regan 1993). Members of what Australian Senator Murray (1998)
describes as a “Corporate Governance Board” (CGB) have the will to act because they are
elected on the basis of one vote per shareholder instead of one vote per share. The
corporate charter provides the CGB the power to act by being able to veto any of activities
in which the directors have a conflict of interest such as those listed in Table 2. The CGB
gives minority of directors the capability to act even if the company is controlled by a
44
parent company. However, a CGB does not “abrogates the property rights of investors”
(Pejovich 1990: 69–71) because the directors can always seek to reverse a CGB veto by
obtaining the approval of shareholders voting on the basis of one vote per share. However,
the sunlight introduced by disclosing both sides of different viewpoints would inhibit the
more extravagant exploitation of minority interests.
All suggestions for reform of corporate governance processes need to consider the power of
agents to act, or be subject to a veto, when there is a compound board. Pound (1993a)
makes the points: “always have an opposition view” and “there must be an opposition party
and the prospect of insurgency”. However, Pound does not consider the principle of a
division of power in his political model of corporate governance, even though he
participated as co-chair of the shareholders' committee established at USX (Formerly US
Steel) for this purpose (Pound 1992). While the power model of the firm may be but a part
of the political model, it should never be neglected because without the power to take
corrective action, no action can take place.
For any action to be appropriate, the actors also need information which is accurate, timely,
sufficient and yet manageable. While Pound (1993a) talks about “feedback” it is from
institutional investors who do not, cannot, and should not, have specific inside expert
information. This leads us to consider the cybernetic approach to corporate governance.
3. Cybernetic analysis
45
Cybernetic is the science of information and control and so provides a rigorous basis for
grounding the study of corporate governance. As control is dependent upon power, a
cybernetic investigation uses the power model of a firm.
Cybernetics is based on the mathematics of information theory where the basic unit of
analysis is described as a 'bit'. A bit can be thought of as a letter in a language with eight
bits creating what can be considered to be word, described as 'byte'.
The ability of
computers to store, process or transmit information is measured in thousands or millions of
bytes described respectively as kilobytes and megabytes.
Like computers, humans have physical limitations on their ability to receive, store, process
and transmit information as indicated in some respects by Table 4. Williamson (1979: 99)
recognised that “the efficient processing of information is an important and related
concept” to transaction costs and stated in note 4, “but for the limited ability of human
agents to receive, store, retrieve, and process data, interesting economic problems vanish”.
Wearing (1973) observed that an individual has “limited information processing capacity so
prefers slow rates of change, ie. Nearly stable systems,” and “reduces, condenses,
summarises (and thus necessarily loses) information, in addition, an ‘imperfect’
communications network in the environment also restricts and attenuates the flow of
information”.
Another reason for economising information is to reduce the problem of 'bounded
rationality' which refers to human behaviour that is “intendedly rational but only limitedly
46
so” (Simon, 1961: xxiv).
According to Williamson (1975: 21), “Bounded rationality
involves neurophysiological limits on the one hand (refer to Table 4) and language limits
on the other”. Williamson (1975: 45–6) notes that “a change in organisational structure
may be indicated” when individuals are exposed to information overload. This provides a
fundamental design criteria for TBA, not present in TCE.
To undertake tasks, which exceed the capacity of one computer, two or more computers can
be connected together in the same way humans solve more demanding tasks by working in
teams, groups, alliances and networks. Cybernetics considerations cannot be ignored in
understanding or designing teams, divisions, the need for one or more boards and their
structure, or the architecture of external alliances with stakeholders.
The cybernetic perspective provides a basis for evaluating the integrity of corporate
governance information and control systems from a number of aspects. Von Neumann &
Morgenstern (1953) showed how errors in processing information with unreliable
components can be reduced as much as required by employing sufficient plurality in the
number of computational components which in the context of corporate governance could
be individuals or boards. Shannon, another founder of information theory, investigated the
integrity of information channels. Shannon (1949) showed that reliable information could
be obtained from unreliable channels if they are used in parallel. In other words, boards
need to obtain information from strategic stakeholders as well as from management to
avoid bias, distortion or errors as discussed by Turnbull (1993a; 1997d,e,h; 1998a). Downs
47
1967: 116–118), Williamson (1975: 122), and Demb & Neubauer (1992b) have reported
the errors and distortions in management hierarchies.
Another important insight of cybernetics is the 'law of requisite variety' which states that to
manage any variables an organisation must have matching responses. In other words,
complexity can only be managed through complexity (Ashby 1968: 202).
Complex
organisations, and/or those operating in a complex dynamic environment require complex
control systems. This can be achieved through the use of a compound board and/or a
network of firms (Craven, Piercy & Shipp, 1996) and/or by involving strategic stakeholders
in the governance of a firm as proposed by Blair (1995), Fukao (1995), Porter (1992) and
Turnbull (1994d;1995a,b,e;1997d,e,g,h; 1998a).
The cybernetic concept of 'feedback' is a condition precedent for self-regulation or selfgovernance (Ashby 1968: 53). If a firm is not to adversely affect its stakeholders through
its “actions or inactions” (Donaldson & Preston 1995) it will require governance processes
which allow its stakeholders to participate in establishing performance standards. Such
arrangements are commonly established in quality assurance programs. However, for
stakeholders to have the will to act, they need a power base independent of management to
protect them from being treated as whistle blowers.
Independently elected Stakeholder Councils would represent the “opposition party” sought
by Pound (1993a). As strategic stakeholders would possess inside, expert information, they
provide a way to inform management and their monitors, of any operational shortcomings
48
as sought by Pound. The design of such arrangements would require the use of both the
power and cybernetic perspective of corporate governance. Guthrie & Turnbull (1995) and
Turnbull (1997d,e,h; 1998a) and Table 3 provide an example of this approach.
Research opportunities
1. Limited life.
The governance implications of limited life corporate shares and limited life firms are a
neglected area. The periodic review of managers by owners is an intrinsic feature of firms,
which have limited life charters as commonly exist in joint ventures and in limited liability
partnerships. In the US, limited liability partnerships are formed for six years. They are
commonly used for Research & Development syndication, property development joint
ventures, theatrical and other types of media financing. Longer term limited life enterprises
are frequently formed with international joint ventures, especially those in former socialist
economies.
The need to periodically establish a successor organisation allows all contractual
arrangements to be re-negotiated. In this way management is made accountable in a similar
fashion to those subject to a take-over of a publicly traded enterprise. Dispersed ownership
in this situation increases rather than decreases the bargaining power of owners in the same
way it does for creditors as investigated by Gertner & Scharfstein (1991) and Bolton &
Scharfstein (1996). If the owners do not have confidence in management they need not re-
49
invest their money. This forces managers to provide both adequate information and cash
distributions to retain investor confidence.
Limited life equities and firms were the rule rather than the exception up until the middle of
the last century, except in England where a few hundred firms obtained charters with the
rights of perpetual succession (Turnbull 1997c; 1998b). Limited life firms have particular
value when the business is not large enough to have its shares publicly traded. The need to
periodically re-recapitalise the firm provides liquidity and so an exit opportunity for
investors. It also provides a programmed exit for firms with declining business as sought
by Jensen (1993: 847). There appears to be little research into this topic.
2. Worker ownership and control
Researchers from Anglo cultures have not only neglected the study of corporate governance
found in other cultures but also the governance of firms in their own cultures which do not
have publicly traded securities. These include worker-controlled firms. While employee
controlled firms may not contribute significant value to modern economies, closed or
private corporations add more value to their host economy than publicly traded firms do.
As noted earlier, employees are becoming the largest voting block in many US publicly
traded corporations.
The same situation is developing in Australia (Turnbull 1997b).
While firms which are 100% employee owned and controlled may have small practical
50
significance, the influence of employee ownership is steadily increasing and it raise two
important issues for developing a theory of organisations.
Firstly, the four temporary and eight permanent assumptions of agency theory (Jensen &
Meckling 1976) lose relevance. All 'agents' are also 'principals', so there is little or no
separation of ownership and control.
Secondly, no worker-controlled firm in an international survey undertaken by Bernstein
(1980) had a unitary board, even if this was the dominant form in its host culture.
According to Jensen & Meckling (1979), “We do not have a theory that will tell us how
supervisory boards will behave”. Research is required to discover if the increased conflicts
of interests created in a unitary board with employee ownership provides the reason why
such firms do not survive. Research is also required to investigate the relevance of the
power, cybernetic or other perspective in explaining the operations of firms which are
employee owned or influenced.
3. Compound boards
The existence of two or more boards is not only of interest to employee owned firms but in
understanding corporate governance in continental Europe where two or three boards may
be required by law. Members of the European Union may adopt similar laws, so this topic
has immediate practical interest.
51
Many publicly traded Asian firms are family controlled (Tricker 1994) and so are governed
by a compound board as are firms controlled by venture capital funds and Leveraged Buy
Out (LBO) Associations. Evidence 'that LBOs are efficient organizations' is cited by
Shleifer & Vishny (1996: 45) while Jensen (1993: 869) states:
LBO associations and venture capital funds provide a blueprint for managers and
boards who wish to revamp their top-level control systems to make them more
efficient. LBOs and venture capital funds are, of course, the pre-eminent examples
of active investors in recent US history, and they serve as excellent models that can
be emulated in part or in total by virtually any corporation. The two have similar
governance structures, and have been successful in resolving the governance
problems of both slow growth or declining firms (LBO associations) and high
growth entrepreneurial firms (venture capital funds).
The theoretical significance of compound boards is currently being overlooked in an
analogous way as Multi-divisional (M) form firms were overlooked by scholars for over 30
years until analysed by Chandler (1962: 382–3). Compound boards permit decomposition
in information processing and decision making in a similar way to firms which change from
a Unitary (U) form structure to M form.
While a number of empirical surveys document the existence and operations of two or more
tiered boards (Analytica 1992; Charkham 1994; Fukao 1995; Francis 1997), little analytical
attention has been given to them except by Bernstein (1980); Tricker (1980); Hatherly
52
(1994); Guthrie & Turnbull (1995), Turnbull (1993a,b; 1994c,d; 1995a,b,c,d,e; 1998a;
199a) and Bancaire (1996). Jensen (1993: 863) states “The reasons for the failure of the
[unitary] board are not completely understood”.
While Williamson (1985: 302) and Pejovich (1990: 69–71) note the existence of codetermination in Germany, only Pejovich provides some cursory analysis. He asserts that
co-determination must increase rather than decrease the cost of funds because the
participation of labour in the control of corporations “abrogates the property rights of
investors”. This is the issue taken up by Sternberg (1996).
However, the assertion of Pejovich is inconsistent with the analysis by Persson, Roland &
Tabellini (1996) who pioneered the first formal theoretical framework for analysing the
separation of powers in the context of political institutions. The need for the separation of
powers in corporate boards has also been noted by Tricker (1980; 1994:6, 45-6, 75, 78, 156,
247-8) and Hatherly (1994). The writer has proven the ability of two tiered boards to
reduce the cost of equity in two start up enterprises. In the second venture, a “Corporate
Senate” was established as a shareholder watchdog committee as reported by Guthrie &
Turnbull (1995), Monks & Minow (1995: 317), Renton (1994: 36) and Tricker (1996:
75–6) and Turnbull (1993b; 1998a). Much more empirical research is required into these
issues.
4. Information theory
53
Stafford Beer (1959; 1966a; 1966b; 1979; 1981; 1985) has been a prolific writer as the
founder of management cybernetics and a proponent of using cybernetics in economic
management. However, Beer advised the author in 1996 that to his knowledge, information
theory had not been applied to evaluate corporate governance or the operations of
compound boards. The utilisation of information theory in the theory of the firm arises
because transaction costs are largely, if not entirely, made up of information.
Firms exist because of the cost of “discovering what the relevant prices are” (Coase 1937).
By economising information, costs are economised. However, while costs are a social
construct, information must always be represented in some way, which can be physically
detected and measured. As a physical manifestation, all information processing, storage,
and transmission is subject to the laws of physics. Transaction costs, and economics in
general, are not so constrained as they are based on the social construct of cost. The
distinction between fixed and variable costs of any transaction can be very subjective. In
addition, costs are based on the social constructs of money and value which are not now
defined in terms of physical units.
The use of physical units such as bits or bytes in the analysis of organisations provide a
way for developing a science of organisation, which is based on the laws of nature rather
than social constructs subject to cultural and other interpretations. Bits or bytes provide a
way “for observing the phenomena at a higher level of resolution” as sought by Williamson
(1990: xi). Williamson (1991: 12) later went on to say:
54
There is growing agreement, moreover, with the need to engage data of a much
more micro-analytic kind than was hitherto thought to be necessary. Indeed,
there is reason to believe that the elusive 'science of organization' to which
Chester Barnard made reference fifty years ago (1938: 290) may take shape
during the 1990s.
As the cost of organising economic transactions is based on the volume of information
required, then transaction costs are economised by economising information. The need to
consider “information richness” in organisational design has already been considered by
organisational theorists such as Daft & Lengel (1984). The capacity of communication
channels needs to match the information richness required to govern productive activities.
Markets are efficient because price is not information rich and very narrow
communications channels can be used. However, markets fail because price signals are not
sufficiently information rich to communicate the qualitative aspects governing a
transaction.
From a cybernetic perspective, TCE becomes a special case of TBA when costs are
relevant. Costs have little relevance in boardroom transactions. Transactions costs are
minimised when the information required to activate or reject a transaction are minimised.
Minimising bits rather than costs allows many of the findings of TCE to be extended to
transactions and institutional arrangements where cost may not be relevant or less
important, such as in quality assurance programs, non-profit organisations and social
institutions in general. In this way, TBA can be used to integrate the viewpoints of other
55
theories and disciplines to provide a common framework, which was noted was missing by
Radner (1992), Demb and Neubauer (1992a).
TBA provides a basis for analysing
compound boards as sought by Jensen & Meckling (1979: 503) and demonstrated by
Turnbull (1999a) but much more work needs to be undertaken.
5. Networks
There is a substantial literature on the design of organisations, but it is based on the
assumption that they are ultimately centrally controlled.
There exists the need to
understand decentralised organisations, which are accountable to a number of separate
constituencies. For example, Galbraith (1973), Egelhoff, (1982, 1988), Daft and Lengel,
(1984) focussed on the idea that organisational structures develop to fit information
processing needs.
This approach needs to be extended to entertain decentralised
organisations and networks of firms.
As a network or association of firms may itself be considered a firm (Mathews 1996b: 116),
or “as organizational wholes” (Richter 1994: 24), there is a need to consider the
architecture of networks in the same way theorists have analysed the structure of firms.
When a compound board is created within a firm it represents a network of information
processing and control centres. Networks can then exist both on an intra-firm basis and on
an inter-firm basis. Both exist together in Mondragón and both types of networks need
investigating to understand how they may best be used.
56
The ownership and control structure of firms has been extensively analysed by such
scholars as Grossman & Hart (1982; 1986), Hart & Moore (1990), Hart (1993; 1995) and
Williamson (1975; 1985).
But in the traditions of US research, their work assumed
organisations were centrally controlled through a unitary board. Investment risks of related
parties could be significantly modified by ownership and control structures, which utilised
compound boards to share and manage risk. There is a need to re-visit existing work from
the network perspective of Craven, Piercy & Shipp (1996).
6. Holonic structures
Holons represent an organisational structure identified by Smuts (1926).
They have
intriguing characteristics, which suggest that they could make a contribution in
understanding the most efficient way of governing complex productive activities. This
suggests they deserve investigation in regards to firms, networks of firms, communities,
and the governance of society at higher levels.
Simon (1962) describes what Smuts called holons, as “sub-assemblies“ or “stable
intermediate forms” to create “nearly decomposable systems, in which the interactions
among the sub-systems are weak, but not negligible”. Examples of weak holons are
divisions in a “M-form“ firm, “autonomous manufacturing cells” (Mathews 1996a), and
firms as a “hierarchy of teams” (Conti & Warner 1996). Mondragón firms, groups, and
system, illustrate both a strong holonic structure and a hierarchy of holons described by
Koestler (1967) as a “holarchy”. They are a strong form, because the component firms and
57
groups (“sub-assemblies”) can exist independently of the whole ('hol'), ie. “able to maintain
a separate existence” to represent a “viable system” (Beer 1985: 1).
Williamson (1985: 281) uses an “information processing interpretation” to explain the
operating advantages of the M type of architecture. The same advantages arise in holons
because “the reduction in data transmission, and in data complexity, achieved by the
holonic architecture, is prodigious,” (Mathews 1996a: 30). Both this insight and that of
Williamson (1975: 21) concerning the “neurological limits” of individuals provide a basis
for understanding how compound boards, networks of firms or organisations, and alliances,
can provide operating advantages.
There are many examples in computer programming where the efficient management of
complexity is achieved through holonic architecture as cited by Mathews (1996a) and
described as “ultra-structure” by Long & Denning (1995). Williamson (1985:383) noted
that “the problem of organization is precisely one of decomposing the entire enterprise in
efficient information processing aspects”. Holonic architecture provides a way to introduce
efficient decomposition to allow ordinary people to achieve extraordinary results as
demonstrated by Mondragón by Turnbull (1995d).
Coase (1937) noted that firms exist because markets fail to efficiently communicate
information. Ashby (1960) pointed out that, “prices represent second order information”
dependent on first order qualitative description of what is being transacted. Prices may also
represent inefficient communications because they may lack credibility as analysed by
58
Akerlof (1970). These considerations explain the advantages of using non-market methods
for governing transactions as identified by Hollingsworth & Lindberg (1985).
The
introduction of holonic organisations may provide a way to increase the efficiency of
governing productive activities by reducing transaction costs and costs arising from
'bounded rationality'. Inceasing the informational efficiency of organisations would reduce
the role and so need for markets.
7. Self-regulation and self-governance
The theory and practice of self-regulation and self-governance has been used since
governors were used in the 19th century to control the speed of steam engines. However,
little of this knowledge appears to have been researched, let alone applied to social
institutions or to the role of government. The Vice President of the US suggested that the
reason for this gap in the application of knowledge of the 'information age' is that only nine
of the 535 members of Congress have any professional education in technology (Gore
1996). Another reason could be that social scientists are not sufficiently familiar with the
theory and practice of self-regulation to understand why it cannot work with the dominant
form of institutions in advanced economies. This dominant form is based on centralised
information and control without checks and balances, self-correcting feedback information
and control channels to allow self-governance.
Ignorance in the theory and practice of self-regulation is so widespread among social
commentators and scientists that they assert that it cannot work for institutions in a market
59
economy. Ironically, many of the same people support a market system because they
believe that it is self-regulating. Design guidelines for establishing a “self-managing selfcorrecting power structure”, without markets, for Aboriginal firms are suggested by
Turnbull (1978a: 100).
The need for government bureaucracies to intercede as corporate regulators arises because
those adversely affected by a firm may not have the information, will, power and capability
to correct the problem. Stakeholder participation in governance provides a way of reducing
this deficiency. If the interests of the participating stakeholders are not sufficiently wide to
reflect the concerns of the host society, some government interventions will still be
required.
However, stakeholder participation may also be required in government
bureaucracies to allow policies to be mediated to suit local conditions and performance
standards established and evaluated by those affected (Turnbull 1994d, 1995b).
There are arguments and evidence to suggest that self-regulation and self-governance
provide operating advantages for social institutions generally and competitive advantages
for firms (Turnbull 1997d,e; 1999a,b).
This is a topic, which requires much more
investigation and research.
Concluding remarks
Sociologists have identified four distinctive institutional processes for governing productive
activities. Economic theories of the firm based on only markets and hierarchy provide a
60
limited basis for understanding corporate governance. However, by re-interpreting theories
of the firm, based on minimising transaction information rather than transaction costs,
many insights developed by economists can be applied to governance processes.
TBA has the advantage of providing a common unit of analysis to (i) integrate the various
disciplines involved with corporate governance, (ii) ground corporate governance in the
knowledge of pure and applied sciences, and (iii) allow the mathematical rigour of
information theory to provide a basis for establishing a science of organisation. Corporate
governance might then develop as a part of a more general theory of social construction.
This should offer practical benefits for improving the design of social institutions in the
private or public sector, be they for profit or for welfare.
To this end, corporate governance scholars would need to accept the possibility of people
behaving both as opportunistic self-serving agents and selfless stewards. No one theory or
model of society is likely to be sufficient for understanding, evaluating or designing
governance structures. There are many pieces to the puzzle, which this paper has tried to
encompass. If there is a lesson to consider, it is that reliance on just one perspective is
unlikely to be rewarding in practical terms for improving corporate governance systems.
An interdisciplinary holistic approach is required.
The complexity of the universe is created through holonic structures, which create the
means for living things to manage complexity.
The survival of civilisation may be
dependent upon society adopting the governances systems of nature. The ability of holonic
61
structures to introduce a prodigious reduction in information processing indicates that they
could present a way to govern society with far less reliance on the second order information
communicated by markets.
Prices are dependent on first order information, which describes the qualitative aspects of
the goods and services being exchanged. Markets are also dependent upon knowledge of
the terms and conditions of the exchange and the trustworthiness of the parties involved in
the exchange.
Coase (1937) explained firms exist because markets fail to efficiently
provide the necessary information to minimise costs. TBA provides a corollary that a
market exists only to the extent that social institutions do not adopt the most effective mix
and structure of alternate governance mechanisms. Might it be that markets exist because
organisations fail to utilise holonic structures?
TBA identifies design criteria for improving governance systems at both the micro and
macro level of society as well a identifying design limits. These criteria are based on the
insights of cybernetics such as:
(i)
minimising computational errors through using parallel decision making as
identified by Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1953), ie establishing a compound
board to provide “distributed intelligence”,
(ii)
minimising errors in communications through establishing parallel information
networks (Shannon 1948), and by
62
(iii)
applying the Principle of Subsidiary Function (Schumacher 1975: 203) so no
decisions are taken at a higher level which can be carried out at a lower level by
using a compound board to provide “distributed intelligence” to minimise the need
for communication,
(iv)
managing complexity by establishing as many control centres, through a compound
board, as there are variables in accordance of Ashby’s law of ‘Requisite Variety’,
(v)
minimising ‘bounded rationality’ by decomposing decision making labour and “the
enterprise in efficient information processing respects” (Williamson, 1985: 283) by
using a compound board and/or networks to provide ‘distributed intelligence’,
(vi)
establishing trust and efficient communications and control by minimising power
differentials through using a compound board to provide a division of power with
checks and balances (Perssons, Roland & Tabellini 1996),
(vii)
achieving “prodigious” reduction in data transmission and data complexity,
described by Mathews (1996a: 30), through establishing almost self-governing intra
and inter firm information and control networks describes as “holons” (Smuts
1926), “sub-assemblies (Simon 1962) or “chaords” (Hock 1994: 1) to further
objectives (i) to (vi) listed above.
Through the above principles, TBA provides a basis for grounding corporate governance,
and the design of organisations generally, in scientific laws. It allows cybernetics to be
utilised in a social context for improving regulation, self-regulation and governance in
either the private or public sector. This offers the prospect of identifying opportunities for
partially privatising state regulation to reduce the size, scope, burden and cost of
63
government to improve the quality of democracy. It also provides design criteria for
developing self-governing social institutions and systems as indicated by Turnbull (1978a:
100; 1997d,e). In this way the study of corporate governance could provide a basis for
building a self-governing sustainable global society that “nature can live with” (Marston
1992).
64
References
AIMA 1995, Corporate Governance, Australian Investment Managers' Association, Sydney.
Akerlof, G.A. 1970, 'The Market for "Lemons": Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism', Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 84, pp. 488–500.
Alchian, A. and Demsetz H. 1972, 'Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization'.
American Economic Review, vol. 62, pp. 777–95.
American Law Institute, 1992, Principles of corporate governance: Analysis and
recommendations: proposed final draft (March 31, 1992), The Institute, Philadelphia, PA.
Analytica 1992, Board Directors and Corporate Governance: Trends in the G7 Countries Over
the Next Ten Years, Oxford Analytica Ltd., England.
Aoki, M. 1993, Japanese Capitalism: Past, Present and Future, paper presented to Columbia
university law school's centre for law and economic studies' conference on relationship
investing: possibilities, patterns and problems, New York Hilton, May 6–7.
Ashby, W.R. 1960, Design for the Brain: The origin of adaptive behaviour, 2nd edn, Chapman
& Hall, London.
Ashby, W.R. 1968, An Introduction to Cybernetics, University Paperback, London.
65
Bancaire 1996, 'Two–tier Structure and Corporate Governance', Corporate Governance, A
Special Report by Compagnie Bancaire, pp. 14–6, January, France.
Barnard, C.J. 1938, The functions of the executive, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Barney, J.B. & Ouchi, W.G., eds, 1986, Organisational Economics: Toward a New paradigm for
Understanding and Studying Organizations, Jossey–Bass, San Fransisco.
Beer, S. 1959, Cybernetics and Management, English University Press, London.
Beer, S. 1966a, Decision and Control: The meaning of operational research and management
cybernetics, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, England.
Beer, S. 1966b, 'The aborting corporate plan: a cybernetic account of the interface between
planning and action', in Perspectives in Planning, ed. Jatsch, E., OECD, Paris, pp. 397–422.
Beer, S. 1979, The Heart of the Enterprise: The managerial cybernetics of organization, John
Wiley & Sons, Chichester, England.
Beer, S. 1981, Brain of the Firm, 2nd. edn, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, England.
Beer, S. 1985, Diagnosing the System for Organizations, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester,
England.
66
Ben-Porath, Y. 1978, The F–Connection: Families, friends, and firms and the organization of
exchange, Report No. 29/78, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, (Reprinted in Population and
Development Review, March, 6:1, 1980.
Berger, P.L. 1976, Pyramids of Sacrifice, Pelican, London.
Berle, Jr., A.A. and Means, G.C. 1932, The Modern Corporation and Private Property,
Macmillan, New York.
Bernstein, P. 1980, Workplace Democratization: Its Internal Dynamics, Transaction Books, New
Brunswick, New Jersey.
Bhagat, S. & Brickley, J.A. 1984, ‘Cumulative voting: the value of minority shareholder voting
rights’, Journal of Law & Economics, The University of Chicago, volume 27, pp. 339–65.
Bhide, A. 1994, 'Deficient Governance', Harvard Business Review, November–December, pp.
129–39.
Bianchi, M., Bianco, M. & Enriques, L. 1999, ‘Pyramidal groups and the separation between
ownership and control in Italy’, Working paper, Commissione Nazionale per le Societa e la
Borsa (CONSOB) http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=168208
Black, B. & Coffee, J.C. 1993, Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behaviour Under Limited
Regulation, paper presented to Columbia University Law School's Centre for Law and Economic
67
Studies' Conference on Relationship Investing: possibilities, patterns and problems, New York
Hilton, May 6–7.
Black, B. 1990, 'Shareholder Passivity Re-examined', Michigan Law Review, vol. 89, pp.522–66.
Blair, M.M. 1995, Ownership and Control, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C.
Blasi, J.R. & Gasaway, J. 1993, Corporate Governance and Employee Ownership: Comparing
The United States and Russia, paper presented to Fifth Annual Conference of the Society for the
Advancement of Socio–Economics, March 28th, New School for Social Research, New York,
Institute for Management and Labour Relations, Rutgers University.
Blasi, J.R. 1988, Employee Ownership, Ballinger, Cambridge, MA.
Bolton, P. & Scharfstein, D. 1996, 'Optimal Debt Structure and the Number of Creditors',
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 104, pp.1–25.
Bosch, H. 1995, Corporate Practices and Conduct, 3rd edn, FT Pitman, Melbourne.
Bradley, K. and Gelb, A. 1983, Cooperation at Work: The Mondragón Experience, Heinemann,
London.
Brecht, M. & Roell, A. 1999, ‘Blockholdings in Europe: An International Comparison’
European Economic Review, 43:4-6, 1049-1056.
68
Brewer, J. 1996, 'Editorial', Corporate Governance Quarterly, Hong Kong Institute of Company
Secretaries, 2:1, March, p.1.
Bruyn, S.T. 1991, A Future for the American Economy: The social market, Stanford University
Press, Palo Alto, CA.
Cadbury, Sir A. 1992, Report of the Committee on The Financial Aspects of Corporate
Governance, The Committee and Gee, London.
CBI, 1990, A Nation of Shareholders, Report of the CBI Wider Share Ownership Task Force,
Confederation of British Industry, London.
Chandler, A.D. 1962, Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise,
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Charkham, J. 1994, Keeping Good Company: A study of corporate governance in five countries,
Claredon Press, Oxford.
Chidambaran, N.K. & John, K., 1999, ‘Managerial Compensation and the Efficiency of Large
Shareholder Monitoring’, Working Paper, No. 99-006, New York University, Centre for Law
and Business, March. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=164503
Clarkson, M.B.E., 1994, A Risk Based Model of Stakeholder Theory, The Centre for Corporate
Social Performance & Ethics, University of Toronto.
69
Coase, R.H. 1937, 'The Nature of the Firm.' Economica, vol. 4, pp. 386–405.
Coase, R.H. 1991a, 'Contracts and the activities of firms', Journal of Law and Economics, vol.
34, October, pp. 451–2.
Coase, R.H. 1991b, 'The Nature of the Firm: Meaning', in The Nature of the Firm: Origins,
Evolution and Development, Williamson O.E. & Winter, S.G. eds., Oxford University Press,
New York.
Cochrane, P. 1997, Head of Research, British Telecom, private e-mail message to the author,
December 21, via http://www/labs.bt.com/people/cochrap/
Coffee, J.C. 1991, 'Liquidity versus Control: The Institutional Investor as Corporate Monitor',
Columbia Law Review, 91:6, October, pp.1278–367.
Conti, R.F. & Warner, M. 1996, 'Technology, teams and Theories of the Firm', Human Systems
Management, vol. 15, pp.101–12.
Craven, D.W., Piercy, N.F. & Shipp, S.H. 1996, 'New organizational forms for competing in
highly dynamic environments: The network paradigm', British Journal of Management, vol. 7,
pp. 203–18.
Daft R.L. & Lengel, R.H. 1984, 'Information richness: a new approach to managerial behaviour
and organization design', Research in Organizational Behaviour, vol. 6, pp. 191–233.
70
Dallas L.L. 1997, 'Proposals for reform of corporate boards of directors: The dual board and
board ombudsperson', Washington and Lee Law Review, 54:1, 92–146 (Winter).
Dallas, L.L. 1988, Two Models of Corporate Governance: Beyond Berle and Means, Journal of
Law Reform, University of Michigan, 22:1 19–116, Fall.
Demb, A. & Neubauer, F.F. 1992a, 'The Corporate Board: Confronting the Paradoxes', Long
Range Planning, 25:3, pp.9–20.
Demb, A. & Neubauer, F.F. 1992b, The Corporate Board: Confronting the Paradoxes, Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Demsetz, H. 1991, 'The Theory of the Firm Revisited', in The Nature of the Firm: Origins,
Evolution and Development, eds Williamson O.E. & Winter, S.G., Oxford University Press,
New York.
Denham, R. & Porter, M.E. 1995, Lifting All Boats, Report of the Capital Allocation Subcouncil
to the Competitiveness policy Council, Robert Denham & Michael Porter, Co–Chairmen,
Competitive Policy Council, Washington, D.C.
Donaldson T. & Preston L.E. 1995, 'The stakeholder theory of the corporation: concepts,
evidence, and implications', Academy of Management Review, 20:1, pp.65–91.
Donaldson, L. & Davis, J.H. 1994, 'Boards and Company Performance – Research challenges
the Conventional Wisdom', Corporate Governance: An International Review, 2:3, pp. 151–60.
71
Downs, A. 1967, Inside Bureaucracy, Little Brown & Co., Boston.
Drucker, P. 1976, The Unseen Revolution: How Pension Fund Socialism Came to America,
Harper & Row, New York.
ECGN (1997), ‘The Separation of Ownership and Control: A Survey of 7 European Countries’,
Preliminary Report, Volume 1, European Corporate Governance Network, October 25, Brussels.
http://www.ecgn.ulb.ac.be/ecgn/docs/pdf/eu97report.pdf
Economist 1999a, ‘Sick patients, warring doctors’, The Economist Newspaper Limited,
September 18-24, pp. 81–2, London,
Economist 1999b, ‘Emerging-market listings’, The Economist Newspaper Limited, September
18-24, pp.120, London,
Economist, 1995, ‘Listed companies by country’, The Economist Newspaper Limited, September
9, p.116, London.
Egelhoff, W.G. 1982, 'Strategy and structure in multinational corporations: an informational
processing approach', Administrative Science Quarterly, vol. 27, pp. 435–58.
Fama, E. & Jensen, M. 1983a, 'Agency Problems and Residual Claims', Journal of Law and
Economics, vol. 26, pp.327–49.
72
Fama, E. & Jensen, M. 1983b, 'Separation of Ownership and Control', Journal of Law and
Economics, vol. 26, pp.301–26.
FIBV 1993, Fédération Internationale des Bourses de Valeurs, Annual Report, Paris, France.
Francis, I. 1997, Future Direction: The Power of the Competitive Board, Australian Institute of
Company Directors & FT Pitman, Melbourne.
Franks, J. & Mayer, C. 1993, Corporate Control: A Synthesis of the International Evidence,
paper presented to Columbia University Law School's Centre for Law and Economic Studies'
Conference on Relationship Investing: possibilities, patterns and problems, New York Hilton,
May 6–7.
Friedman, L.M. 1973, A History of American Law, Simon & Schuster, New York.
Fukao, M. 1995, Financial Integration, Corporate Governance, and the Performance of
Multinational Companies, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C.
Galbraith, J.R. 1973, Designing complex organizations, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.
Garrett, B. 1996, The Fish Rots from the Head, Harper Collins, London.
Gertner, R. & Kaplan, S.N. 1998, ‘The Value Maximising Board’, proceeding of conference on
Alternative Perspectives on Corporate Governance, Columbia Law School Sloan Project on
Corporate Governance, January 23rd, New York City.
73
Gertner, R. & Scharfstein, D. 1991, 'A Theory of Workouts and the Effects of Reorganisation
Law', Journal of Finance, vol. 46, pp. 1189–222.
Ghoshal, S. & Moran, P. 1996, 'Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory',
Academy of Management Review, 21:1, pp.13–47.
Gilson R.J. & Roe, M.J. 1993, 'Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps between
corporate governance and industrial organization', The Yale Law Journal, vol. 102, pp.871–906.
Gilson, R.J. 1994, 'Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency', in Aspects of Corporate
Governance, eds Isaksson, M. & Skog, R., Juristoförlaget, Stockholm, pp.131–41.
Gönenç, R. 1994, 'Comparing National Corporate Governance Systems', in Aspects of Corporate
Governance, eds Isaksson, M. & Skog, R., Juristförlaget, Stockholm, pp.127–29.
Gordon, J. 1993, What is relational investing and how cumulative voting can play a role, paper
presented to Columbia University Law School's Centre for Law and Economic Studies'
Conference on Relationship Investing: possibilities, patterns and problems, New York Hilton,
May 6–7.
Gordon, L.A. & Pound J. 1991, Governance Matters: An Empirical Study of the Relationship
Between Corporate Governance and Corporate Performance, John F. Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University, June, mimeo.
74
Gore, A. 1996, The Technology Challenge: What is the Role of Science in American Society?
prepared remarks delivered to American Association for the Advancement of Science, February
12, Baltimore, Office of the Vice President, Washington, D.C.
Grossman, R.L. & Adams, F.T. 1993, Taking Care of Business: Citizenship and the Charter of
Incorporation, Charter Ink, Cambridge, MA.
Grossman, S. & Hart, O. 1982, 'Corporate financial structure and managerial incentives', in The
Economics of Information and Uncertainty, ed. McCall, J.J., University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, pp.123–55.
Grossman, S. & Hart, O. 1986, 'The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and
Lateral Integration', Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, pp.691–719.
Gundfest, J. 1990, 'Subordination of American Capital', Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 27,
pp.89–114.
Gundfest, J. 1993, 'Just Vote No: A Minimalist Strategy for Dealing with Barbarians Inside the
Gates', Stanford Law Review, vol. 45, pp857–973.
Guthrie, J. & Turnbull, S. 1995, 'Audit Committees: Is There a Role for Corporate Senates
and/or Stakeholders Councils?' Corporate Governance: An International Review, 3:2, April, pp.
78–89.
75
Guthrie, J. 1992, Critical issues in Public Sector Auditing, Managerial Auditing Journal, 7:4, pp.
28–34.
Hart, O. & Moore, J. 1990, 'Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm', Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 98, pp.1119–58.
Hart, O. 1993, 'Theories of optimal capital structure: A managerial discretion perspective', The
Deal Decade: What Takeovers and leveraged buyouts mean for corporate governance, ed. Blair,
M., Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C.
Hart, O. 1995, Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, Oxford University Press, Cambridge.
Hatherly, D.J. 1994, 'The case for the shareholder panel in the U.K.', The European Accounting
Review, 4:3, pp.535–53.
Hawley, J.P. and Williams A.T. 1996, Corporate Governance in the United States: The Rise of
Fiduciary Capitalism, Working Paper, Saint Mary's College of California, School of Economics
and Business Administration.
Hill, C.W.L. & Jones, T.M. 1992, 'Stakeholder – Agency Theory', Journal of Management
Studies, 29:2, pp.131–54.
Hilmer, F.G. 1993, Strictly Boardroom, Information Australia, Melbourne.
76
Hock, D.W. 1994, ‘Institutions in the age of mindcrafting’, Paper presented at the Bionomics
Annual Conference, October 22, San Francisco. http://www.cascadepolicy.org/dee_hock.htm
Hollingsworth, J.R. & Boyer, R., eds. 1997, Contemporary Capitalism: The embeddedness of
institutions, Cambridge University Press, England.
Hollingsworth, J.R. & Lindberg, L.N. 1985, 'The governance of the American economy: the role
of markets, clans, hierarchies, and associative behaviour', in Private interest government: Beyond
market and state, eds Streeck, W. & Schmitter, P.C., Sage, London, pp. 221–67.
Hollingsworth, J.R., Schmitter, P.C. & Streeck, W. 1994, 'Capitalism, Sectors, Institutions, and
Performance', in Governing Capitalist Economies, eds Hollingsworth, J.R., Schmitter, P.C. &
Streeck, W., Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 3–16.
Isaksson, M. & Skog, R., eds, 1994, Aspects of Corporate Governance, Corporate Governance
Forum, Juristförlaget, Stockholm.
Jensen, M.C. & Meckling, W.H. 1976, 'Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency
Costs and Ownership Structure', Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, pp. 305–60.
Jensen, M.C. & Meckling, W.H. 1979, 'Rights and Production Functions: An Application to
Labor-Managed Firms and Codetermination', Journal of Business, 52:4, pp.469–506.
Jensen, M.C. 1993, 'The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control
systems', The Journal of Finance, 48:3, July, pp.831–80.
77
Jones, D.C. & Kato, T. 1993, 'Employee Stock Ownership Plans and Productivity in Japanese
Manufacturing Firms', British Journal of Industrial Relations, 31:3, Sept., pp.331–46.
Kang D.L. 1998, ‘The Internal Control of Organizations: How Large-Block Ownership by
Insiders Leads to Increased Firm Performance,’ proceeding of conference on Alternative
Perspectives on Corporate Governance, Columbia University Law School Sloan Project on
Corporate Governance, January 23rd, New York City.
Kelso, L.O. & Adler, M.J. 1958, The Capitalist Manifesto, Random House, New York.
Kelso, L.O. & Hetter, 1967, Two–Factor Theory: The economics of reality, Vintage Books, New
York.
Kelso, L.O. & Hetter, 1986, Democracy and economic power: Extending the ESOP revolution,
Ballinger & Co. Cambridge, MA.
Kester, W.C. 1991, 'Japanese Corporate Governance and the Conservation of Value in Financial
Distress', Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 4:2, pp. 98–104.
Kester, W.C. 1992, 'Industrial Groups as System of Contractual Governance', Oxford Review of
Economics Policy, 8:3.
Koestler, C.O. 1967, The Ghost in the Machine, Hutchinson, London.
78
Kuhn, T.S. 1970, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, The University of Chicago Press,
Second Edition.
Latham, M. 1999, ‘The corporate monitoring firm’, Corporate Governance - An International
Review, 7:1, January. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?ABSTRACT_ID=50564
Leibenstein, H. 1987, Inside the Firm: the inefficiencies of hierarchy, Harvard University Press,
Cambridge.
Long, J.G. & Denning, D.E. 1995, 'Ultra–structure: A design theory for complex systems and
processes', Communications of the ACM, Association for Computing Machinery, 38:1, January,
pp.103–20.
Marston, A. ed. 1992, The Other Economy: Economics nature can live with, LBD Publishers,
Auckland.
Maruyama, M. 1991, 'Contracts in Cultures', Human Systems Management, vol. 10, pp.33–46.
Mathews, J. 1996a, 'Holonic organisational architectures', Human Systems Management, vol. 15,
pp.24–54.
Mathews, J. 1996b, 'Organizational foundations of economic learning', Human Systems
Management, IOS Press, Netherlands, vol. 15, pp. 113–24.
Miller, A.S. 1968, The Supreme Court and American Capitalism, Free Press, New York.
79
Monks, R.A.G. & Minow, N. 1991, Power and Accountability, Harper Business, New York.
Monks, R.A.G. & Minow, N. 1995, Corporate Governance, Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.
Monks, R.A.G. & Minow, N. 1996, Watching the Watchers, Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.
Monks, R.A.G. 1994, 'Relationship Investing', Corporate Governance: An International Review,
2:2, pp.58–76.
Monks, R.A.G. 1996, The American Corporation at the End of the 20th Century: Outline of
Ownership Based Governance, Arthur Andersen Lecture, The Judge Institute, July 8, Cambridge
(http://www.Lens–inc–com).
Morrison, R. 1991, We Build the Road as We Travel, New Society Press, Philadelphia.
Murray, A. 1998, Minority Report: Company Law Review Bill 1997, Australian Senate,
Canberra, March.
http://www.aph.gov.au/senate/committee/corp_sec_ctte/companylaw/minreport.htm
Nader, R., Green, M. & Seligman, J. 1976, Corporate Power in America, Norton, New York.
Neumann J. von, & Morgenstern, O. 1953, Theory of games and economic behavior (3d. ed.).
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
80
North, D.C. 1985, 'Transaction Costs in History', Journal of European Economic History, vol. 4,
pp.557–72.
OECD 1997, ‘Institutional Modernisation for Effective and Adaptive Corporate Governance’,
Background paper for the OECD Business Sector Colloquium on Corporate Governance, Organisation
for Economic Cooperation and Development, June 10–11, Paris.
Pejovich, S. 1990, The economics of property rights: towards a theory of comparative systems,
Kluwer, Netherlands.
Persson, T., Roland, G. & Tabellini, G. 1996, Separation of Powers and Accountability:
Towards a Formal Approach to Comparative Politics, Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for
Economic Research (IGIER), Working Paper, No. 100, July, Milano.
Pfeffer, J. & Leong, A. 1977, 'Resource Allocation in United Funds: An Examination of Power
and Dependence', Social Forces, vol. 55, pp.775–90.
Porta, R.L, Lopez–de–Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R.W. 1997, Trust in Large
Organizations, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5864, Cambridge,
MA.
Porter, M.E. 1992, Capital Choices: Changing The Way America Invests in Industry, A Research
Report Presented to The Council on Competitiveness and Co–sponsored by The Harvard
Business School, Boston.
81
Pound, J. 1992, 'Beyond Takeovers: Politics comes to Corporate Control', Harvard Business
Review, March-April, pp.83–93.
Pound, J. 1993a, Creating Relationship Institutional Investors and Corporations: A Proposal to
Restore Balance in the American Corporate Governance Process, paper presented to Columbia
University Law School's Centre for Law and Economic Studies' Conference on Relationship
Investing: possibilities, patterns and problems, New York Hilton, May 6–7.
Pound, J. 1993b, 'The Rise of the Political Model of Corporate Governance and Corporate
Control', New York University Law Review, 68:5, November, pp.1003–71.
Preston, L.E. 1996, Redefining the Corporation: Stakeholder Theory in International Perspective,
Centre for International Business Education and Research, Occasional Paper #78, July,
University of Maryland at College Park.
Radner, R. 1992, 'Hierarchy: The economics of managing', Journal of Economic Literature, vol.
30, September, pp.1282–415.
Regan, E.V. 1993, 'The Will to Act: Report of the Sub-council on corporate governance and
financial markets to the Competitiveness Policy Council', Competitiveness Policy Council,
Washington, D.C.
Renton, N.E. 1994, Company Directors: Masters or Servants? Wrightbooks Pty. Ltd. Victoria.
82
Ritcher, F-J. 1994, 'The emergence of corporate alliance networks – Conversion to selforganization', Human Systems Management, vol. 13, pp.19–16.
Roe, M. 1993, 'Some Difference in Corporate Structure in Germany, Japan, and the United
States', The Yale Law Journal, vol. 102, pp. 1927–2003.
Roe, M. 1994, Strong Managers Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate
Finance, University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Ross, S. 1973, 'The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem', American Economic
Review, vol. 63, pp.134–9.
Schumacher, E.F. 1975, Small is beautiful: A study of economics as if people mattered, Abacus,
London.
Shannon, C.E. 1949, 'Communications theory of secrecy systems', Bell System Technical
Journal, vol. 28, pp. 656–715.
Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R.W. 1996, A Survey of Corporate Governance, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Working Paper 5554, Cambridge, MA.
Simon, H. 1961, Administrative Behaviour, 2nd. edn, Macmillan, New York.
Simon, H. 1962, 'The architecture of complexity,' Proceedings of the American Philosophical
Society, vol. 106, December, pp. 467–82.
83
Smith, A. 1937 (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Cannan
Edition, New York.
Smuts, J.Ch 1926, Holism and Evolution, Macmillan, London & New York.
Stapledon, G. 1998, ‘Share Ownership and Control in Listed Australian Companies’, University
of Melbourne law faculty working paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=164129
Sternberg, E. 1996, 'Stakeholder Theory Exposed', Corporate Governance Quarterly, Hong
Kong Institute of Company Secretaries, 2:1, March, pp. 4–18.
Streeck, W. & Schmitter, P.C., 1985, 'Community, market, state – and associations? The
prospective contribution of interest governance to social order', in Private Interest government:
Beyond Market and State, eds Streeck, W. & Schmitter, P.C., Sage, London, pp 1–29.
Tricker, R.I. 1980, Two Tier Boards, The Corporate Policy Group, Nuffield College, Oxford.
Tricker, R.I. 1990, ‘The Corporate Concept: Redesigning a Successful System’, Human Systems
Management, 9, pp.65–76.
Tricker, R.I. 1994, International Corporate Governance, Simon & Schuster, Singapore.
Tricker, R.I. 1996, Pocket Director, The Economist Books, London.
84
Tseo, G. 1996, 'Employee stock ownership firms, producer co–operatives and the forgotten
model of Mondragón', Journal of Co–operative Studies, Society of Cooperative Studies,
Manchester, 29:1 (No. 86), May, pp.65–92.
Turnbull, S. 1973, 'Time Limited Corporations', ABACUS: A Journal of Business and
Accounting Studies, Sydney University Press, 9:1, June, pp.28–43.
Turnbull, C.S.S. 1975a, Democratising The Wealth of Nations, The Company Directors'
Association, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1975b, 'Wider Aspects of Company Direction', Chartered Directors' Course, The
Company Directors' Association of Australia Limited, Study Guide No. 19, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1978a, Economic Development of Aboriginal Communities in the Northern
Territory: Second Report, Self–sufficiency (with land rights), June 1978, Parliamentary Paper
No. 438/1978, The Parliament of the Commonwealth of Australia, Canberra.
Turnbull, S. 1978b, Impact of Mining Royalties on Aboriginal Communities in the Northern
Territory: First Report, October 1977, Parliamentary Paper No. 135/1978, The Parliament of the
Commonwealth of Australia, Canberra.
Turnbull, S. 1988 'Another Amercia', Mainstreet Capitalism: Essays on Broadening Share
Ownership in America and Britain, ed. Speiser, S.M., New Horizons Press, pp.107–22, New
York.
85
Turnbull, S. 1991a, 'Re–inventing Corporations', Human Systems Management, 10:3, pp.169–86.
Turnbull, S. 1991b 'Socialising Capitalism', Equitable Capitalism: Promoting Economic
Opportunity Through Broader Capital Ownership, ed. Speiser, S.M., New Horizons Press, New
York, pp.97–113.
Turnbull, S. 1992, 'Positions Vacant, Wanted: corporate whistle-blowers', JASSA The Journal of
the Securities Institute of Australia, no. 4, pp.2–6, December, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1993a, 'Flaws and Remedies in Corporatisation and Privatisation', Human Systems
Management, 12:3,pp. 227–52.
Turnbull, S. 1993b, 'Improving Corporate Structure and Ethics: A Case for Corporate "Senates"',
Director’s Monthly, National Association of Company Directors, May, 17:5, pp.1–4,
Washington, D.C.
Turnbull, S. 1994a, Beyond Markets & Hierarchies: Extending the theory of the firm, paper
presented to the Twenty–third Conference of Economists, Gold Coast International Hotel,
September 28, Queensland.
Turnbull, S. 1994b, 'Building a Stakeholder Democracy', in Ambitions for our Future: Australian
Views, Economic Planning Advisory Commission, Australian Government Publishing Service,
pp.83–90, October, Canberra.
86
Turnbull, S. 1994c, 'Competitiveness and Corporate Governance', Corporate Governance: An
International Review, 2:2, April, pp.90–6.
Turnbull, S. 1994d, 'Stakeholder Democracy: Redesigning the Governance of Firms and
Bureaucracies', Journal of Socio–Economics, 23:3, Fall, pp.321–60.
Turnbull, S. 1995a, 'Best Practice in the Governance of GBEs', The Australian Public Sector:
Pathways to Change in the 1990s', ed. J. Guthrie, IIR Pty. Limited, pp.99–109, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1995b, 'Corporate Governance', Harvard Business Review, May–June, pp.169–70.
Turnbull, S. 1995c, 'Corporate Governance: What is World Best Practice', Australian Company
Secretary, Chartered Institute of Company Secretaries in Australia Limited, Sydney, December,
pp 485–91.
Turnbull, S. 1995d, 'Innovations in Corporate Governance: The Mondragón Experience',
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 3:3, July, pp.167–80.
Turnbull, S. 1995e, 'The Need for Stakeholder Councils in Social Audits', Social &
Environmental Accounting, The Centre for Social and Environmental Accounting Research,
University of Dundee, 15:2, September, pp.10–3.
Turnbull, S. 1995f, What is World Best Practice in corporate governance? paper presented to
Corporate Governance Conference, March 6th, The Boulevard Hotel, Sydney.
87
Turnbull, S. 1997a, ‘Corporate Governance: Its scope, concerns and theories’ Corporate
Governance: An international review, 5:5, pp.180–205.
Turnbull, S. 1997b, 'Employee Ownership: Opportunities and threats, Reward Management
Bulletin, FT Law & Tax Asia Pacific, 1:3, pp. 51–2, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1997c, Evolution of business and the corporate structure, in Corporate Directors'
Diploma Course, University of New England, Armidale, Australia, Study Guide 1.1, (revised).
Turnbull, S. 1997d, ‘Making Self–regulation Work’, paper presented to Finance and
International Competitiveness Seminar Series, School of Economics and Finance, Queensland
University of Technology, March 6, Brisbane.
Turnbull, S. 1997e 'Self-Regulation', Ninth International Conference on Socio-Economics,
University of Montréal, Québec, Canada, July 6th, and 26th Annual Conference of Economists,
University of Tasmania, Australia, October 1st.
Turnbull, S. 1997f, 'Should companies have external directors?' Board Report, Corporate
Directors' Association, 2:4, May, p.5, Sydney.
Turnbull, S. 1997g, 'Stakeholder Co–operation', Journal of Co–operative Studies, Society for
Co–operative Studies, Manchester, 29:3 (No.88), January, pp.18–52.
Turnbull, S. 1997h, 'Stakeholder Governance: a cybernetic and property rights analysis',
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 5:1, January, pp.11–23.
88
Turnbull, S. 1998a, ‘Corporate Charters with Competitive Advantages’, proceedings of
conference on Alternative approaches to corporate governance, Columbia University Law
School Sloan Project on Corporate Governance, January 23, New York City. (Forthcoming, St.
Johns Law Review, St. Johns University, Winter, 2000, New York City)
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/paper.taf?ABSTRACT_ID=10570
Turnbull, S. 1998b, 'Should Ownership Last Forever?', Journal of Socio–Economics, 27:3, pp.
341–63. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=137382.
Turnbull, S. 1999a ‘A Framework for Analysing Pluralistic Organisations’, Proceedings of the
Second Annual Workshop on Complexity and Organisation, The European Institute for
Advanced Studies in Management, Brussels, June 25th.
Turnbull, S. 1999b, ‘Competitive Deconstruction’, presented to the 19th Annual International
Conference of the Strategic Management Society, The Free University, October 6, Berlin
Turnbull, S. 1999c, ‘Governance Codes Misleading’, Australian Company Secretary, Chartered
Institute of Company Secretaries in Australia, 51:8, pp. 350–2, September, Sydney.
Walker, R.G. 1991a ‘Audit Excuses Rest on the Expectation Gap’, Business Review Weekly,
pp.59–61. January 11, Sydney
Walker, R. G. 1991b, ‘Why so many audits have been failing’, Business Review Weekly,
pp.82–84. January 18, Sydney.
89
Wearing A.J. 1973, Economic Growth: Magnificent Obsession, paper presented to 44th
Australian and New Zealand Association for the Advancement of Science Congress, August,
Perth, Australia.
Whyte, W.F. & Whyte, K.K. 1988, Making Mondragón: The growth and Dynamics of the
Worker Cooperative Complex, ILR Press, Ithaca, NY.
Williamson, O.E. 1975, Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti–trust Implications, Free
Press, New York.
Williamson, O.E. 1979, 'Transaction cost economics: The governance of transactional relations',
Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 22, pp.233–61. (Reprinted in Barney & Ouchi 1986.)
Williamson, O.E. 1985, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press, New York.
Williamson, O.E. 1990, Industrial Organisation, Gower House, London.
Williamson, O.E. 1991, The Nature of the Firm, Origins, Evolution & Development, Oxford
University Press, NY.
Wymeersch, E. 1994, 'Elements of Comparative Corporate Governance in Western Europe', in
Aspects of Corporate Governance, eds Isaksson, M. & Skog, R., Juristoförlaget, Stockholm.
90
Zey, M. 1999, Major Changes in Corporate strategy and structure of the Fortune 500 in the
1990s, presented to the 11th Annual Meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socioeconomics, University of Madison-Wisconsin, July 11th, Working Paper, Texas A&M
University.
91
TABLE 1.
Influences affecting the controllers of publicly traded firms
Private sector influences
Customers
Competitors
Shareholders
Corporate charter
Employees
Unions
Suppliers
Bankers & financiers
Auditors
Stock Exchange rules
Market for shares
Media
Professional associations
Trade associations
Directors & Advisers
Public sector laws/regulators
Trade practices
Anti-monopoly
Corporations and Securities
Common law
Labour & Equal Opportunity
Arbitration courts, etc.
Fair trading
Credit & bankruptcy
Corporate
Federal/State/Local tax
Health & safety
Environmental
Quality
Building
Community
92
Table 2
CORRUPTING POWERS OF A UNITARY BOARD
Directors have the power to further and protect their self-interests by:
1. Transfer value from the firm to themselves through:
(a) Determining their own remuneration and payments to associates
(b) Directing business to interests associated with themselves.
2. Reduce shareholder value through:
(a) Issuing shares or options to one or more directors at discounted value
(b) Selling of assets of the firm to one or more director or their associates at a discount
(c) The firm acquiring assets from directors or their associates at an inflated value
(d) The firm trading with related parties, who can appoint the directors, on favoured terms
(e) Not allowing the firm to compete with related parties who can appoint them
3. Obtain other private benefits such as:
(a) Use resources of the firm for their own pecuniary and non-pecuniary gain
(b) Use their status and influence for pecuniary and non-pecuniary advantages.
4. Control independent advisers by:
(a) Awarding them work
(b) Negotiating their fees
(c) Determining their terms of reference to support director’s interests.
5. Control or influence the auditor by:
(a) Advising shareholders on the appointment or dismissal of the auditor;
(b) Negotiating their fees:
(c) Giving them more profitable non-audit business.
6. Determine reported profit by:
(a) Selecting basis for valuing or writing off trading and fixed assets
(b) Determining the life of assets and so the cost of depreciation;
(c) Selecting basis for recognising revenues and costs in long term contracts
(d) Selecting accounting policies within accepted accounting standards
(e) Control of auditors and valuers.
7. Determine how director performance is reported by:
(a) Reporting on their own activities and deny or frustrate other reports;
(b) Controlling the auditor and other "independent" advisers
(c) Controlling the conduct of shareholder meetings.
8. Maintain their board position by:
(a) Reporting on their own performance
(b) Filling casual board vacancies with people who support their own position
(c) Nominating new directors who support them at shareholder meetings
(d) Controlling the nomination and election procedures and processes
(e) Controlling the conduct of shareholder meetings
(f) Using uncommitted proxies to vote on resolutions to protect and further their interests
93
Table 3
Anglo corporate governance compared with competitive practices
1
ACTIVITY
2
Select, direct, control, remunerate, & retire management
Nominate directors
Appoint directors
Remunerate management &
directors
Retire directors
Appoint Auditor
Control Auditor
Determine accounting practices
Evaluate business
Monitor management
Appoint specialist advisers
Control specialist advisers
Remunerate CGB members
Remunerate stakeholder reps.
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
ANGLO
PRACTICE
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Board
Not Applic.
Not Applic.
COMPETITIVE PRACTICE
Board with advice and consent of
Corporate Governance Board (CGB)
Shareholders with advise of CGB
Shareholders
CGB using performance indicators
established by Stakeholder councils
CGB with advise from Stakeholders
Shareholders & CGB
CGB
CGB
Board with advise from Stakeholders
Board with advise from Stakeholders
CGB with advise from board
CGB
Shareholders–% of dividends
No remuneration
A Corporate Governance Board (CGB) is the name adopted by Senator Murray
(1998) to describe a form of “watchdog board” found in Europe and introduced
into Australia as a “Corporate Senate” by Turnbull (1992; 1993b, 1994c, 1998a).
Directors elected by cumulative voting (Bhagat & Brickley 1984, Gordon 1993)
to provide some directors with ‘the will to act’ by securing their board position
even if there is a parent company.
Members of the Corporate Governance Board (CGB) elected on the basis of one
vote per shareholders instead of one vote per share to make members independent
of any dominant shareholders.
CGB can report to shareholders independently of the board but only have power
to veto board decision when a conflict of interest is present such as identified in
Table 2.
94
Table 4
Human constraints in transacting bytes
(K= Kilobytes, M=Megabytes)
INPUT
CHANNELS
Channel
capacity in
bytes/sec
Smell
Taste
<10
<15
Touch Sound
<15
100K
Sight
1,000M
1
2
NATURE
OF
TRANSACTING
BYTES
IN
HUMANS
RECEPTION through organs
STORAGE through nervous system
PERCEPTION/UNDERSTANDING
3 through the activation and strengthening
of neural networks which correlate
current patterns with previous ones
4
INSIGHTS/KNOWLEDGE through
sequential processing in neo-cortex
5 EXTERNAL RESPONSES transmitted
by movement and vocal chords
OUTPUT
Touch Signs Writ Sound Speech
CHANNELS
-ing
Channel
capacity in
<15
<15
<15 <100K <100K
bytes/sec
CONSTRAINTS
IN HUMANS TO
TRANSACT
BYTES
CREATED BY:
Physiology
Physiology
Physiology plus
experience,
training and
motivation
As above plus
size and
architecture of
neo-cortex and
psychological
status
Proximity/
distance,
environmental
conditions,
culture, literacy,
& numeracy
Information is received 10,000 times greater than the rate at which it can be transmitted.
Source of channel capacity: Cochrane 1997
95
Table 5
Comparison between TCE and TBA boundaries of analysis
1
2
3
4
5
Framework of
analysis
Type of social
institution
Subject of
analysis
Relationship of
people
People
behaviour
Objectives
6 Modes of
governance
Coase/Williamson,
et. al. (TCE)
For-profit firms not
labour managed
Transactions and
their costs
Master/servant or
competitive
Self-interest
TBA based on the information &
control architecture (cybernetics)
Any social organisation, including
any type of firm
People and the quanta (bytes) of
information they process
Any. eg. family, co-operative,
competitive, associative, etc.
Any. eg. Altruistic, self-interest, etc.
Economising costs
Anything. (For firms, economising
the transaction of bytes by
individuals while compensating for
errors with plurality of transactions)
Clans & communities, associations,
hierarchies, & markets
Markets &
hierarchies and
hybrids of both
7 Communication Markets &
& control
hierarchies
through:
Senses, semiotics, language &
numbers
96
Table 6
Efficiency and power models of the firm
Source: Dallas (1988: 29)
MODEL→
Item↓
1 Firm
2 Management
3 Firm objectives
EFFICIENCY(a)
POWER (b)
Nexus of contracts/reactive Power coalitions/proactive
to environment
with respect to
environment
Agent
Dominant coalition
member
Profit maximisation; cost Multiple inconsistent
minimisation
goals; increasing
autonomy and discretion
Competition in markets
Various sources of power
4 Determinants of
structure and
behaviour
5 Management/share- Contract
holder relationship
6 Board of directors
“Monitoring” device
Co-optation
“Tool” of internal
coalition
Notes:
(a) Dallas (1988: 22) describes the “efficiency model” as considering the firm as a
“nexus of contracts” with directors and managers being “agents” of the
shareholders, and perhaps-other constituencies, to maximise profits or minimise
“transaction costs”.
(b)The “power model” is describe by Dallas (1988: 39–44) as recognising the legal
reality that directors are principles with only fiduciary duties to shareholders and
that firms “act to decrease the uncertainty of its environment by increasing its
power over, and autonomy from, its environment” (Dallas 1988: 30). These
objectives being pursued at the expense of profit, although subject to a profit
restraint.
97
View publication stats