ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
UDK 336.71:336.76(497.4)
Quantitative easing and
non-bank debt inancing
in Slovenia
Marko Simoneti*
QUANTITATIVE EASING
AND NON-BANK DEBT
FINANCING IN SLOVENIA
The objective of the paper
is to explore why the
development of non-bank
financial institutions has
become a precondition
for Slovenia to increase
the benefits of being a
part of the Eurozone.
The existence of modern
banking integrated with
non-bank institutions
is assumed when
strategic decisions are
made in the Eurozone.
First, we review how
monetary policy works
in the complex financial
system and what are
the main challenges for
implementing quantitative
easing (QE) effectively in
the Eurozone. Second, we
analyse why not many
direct benefits should be
expected in countries like
Slovenia with a small nonbank financial sector. We
conclude by proposing
financial reforms needed
in Slovenia to change this
in the future.
JEL G01 G21 G22
T
here are two big themes for post crisis banking in the
Eurozone: inancial stability and monetary measures to
support growth. The Eurozone solutions are sought in
the context of a modern well-developed inancial system
composed of commercial banking, investment banking, shadow banking, non-bank inancial institutions and functioning capital markets. On the other hand, commercial banks in Slovenia are predominant inancial institutions by holding 75% of all inancial assets
and companies are inanced almost exclusively by bank loans.
Introduction
Stability of the banking sector has been clearly the irst short
term priority with massive government sponsored bank rehabilitation programs in most Eurozone countries. The developed non-bank
inancial institutions are the advantage as they offer the alternatives for inancing at the time when the banking sector is blocked.
They also offer additional opportunities to take actions on time, to
design a broad range of bank rehabilitation instruments and to involve the private sector and banks in rehabilitation process as well:
sale of non-core businesses, sale of tradable securities, securitisation of loan portfolios, sale of bad assets, guarantees on borrowing
and lending, private sector recapitalisations, issuing of preferred
shares, hybrid and other debt funding instruments. In Slovenia the
solutions chosen for bank rehabilitation were late coming, simple
and expensive for taxpayers: the government was the only important player buying bad assets from banks and providing liquidity,
funding and capital for troubled banks.
*
Marko Simoneti, associate professor for money and finance, Faculty of Law, University of Ljubljana.
22
BV 11/2014
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
In the complex financial systems
financial stability by definition has to
take a broader view of banks and
non-banks. We have learnt in the
last global financial crisis that both
types of institutions can be: too big,
too important, too complex or too
interlinked to fail. Long term solutions
for maintaining financial stability
in the Eurozone are the new micro
and macro prudential regulations,
the banking union, separation of
investment banking from commercial
banking and regulation and supervision of shadow banking1. These
rules will change the way how the
banking business is operated in
Slovenia as well, but they should not
have dramatic effects on the overall
financial structure given the simplicity
of the system.
To support growth and to fight
deflation in the Eurozone ECB has
been using conventional interest rate
setting monetary measures, complemented by mid-term low cost financing operations for banks. In Slovenia
these measures have not been
channelled through the banking sector to the real economy. The lending
interest rates remain to be high and
the volume of lending is stagnating
for many years. The low cost ECB
funding was mainly used by troubled
banks for repayments of debt on the
wholesale market. ECB has recently
announced new broad quantitative
easing measures (QE) following the
examples of FED and Bank of England (BoE) in fighting recession and
deflation. Details of this program are
yet to be announced, but securitisation, non-banks and shadow banking institutions will be important as
additional channels for allocation of
new money in the economy.
The objective of this paper is to
explain why the development of nonbank financial institutions and capital
market in Slovenia has become a
precondition to increase benefits
of being part of the Eurozone. The
BV 11/2014
structure of the paper is as follows:
first, we review how monetary
policy works in the complex financial systems and what are the main
challenges for implementing QE effectively in the Eurozone; second, we
analyse why not many direct benefits
should be expected for countries
like Slovenia with limited non-bank
financial sector and last, we propose
what type of financial reforms are
needed to change this.
Conventional monetary policy
Monetary policy consistent with
stable and low inflation target of
around 2% in the modern economy
There is no
automatic
multiplication of
reserve money.
is implemented by setting the nominal interest rates on central banks reserves or the base money. This base
short term rate is then influencing
interbank interest rates and the range
of other interest rates in the economy.
This base rate is the main input for
setting lending and deposit rates
by banks and for determining the
size of their lending activities. In the
modern economy most of the money
is created by commercial banks’
lending and simultaneously creating
matching deposits in the account
of the borrower. On the other side,
the amount of overall broad money
creation and bank lending is limited
(1) by the profitability concerns of
banks in the competitive financial
environment; (2) by the macroeconomic situation and the behaviour of
bank customers – mainly corporates,
non-bank financial institutions and
23
households - that can destroy newly
created money by paying back old
loans, (3) by micro and macro prudential regulation and (4) above all
by the monetary policy. (BoE, 2014)
In the normal situation the central bank is therefore focusing on
the price of base money and not
the quantity of base money as it
is described by the money multiplier model in most textbooks. The
quantity of broad money is therefore
endogenous, the money multiplier is
not stable and the quantity of base
money depends on the amount
needed by banks to carry out their
business profitably. The oldest central
bank in the world has described
these textbook misconceptions in its
recent report very openly: “Rather
than banks receiving deposits when
households save and then lending them out, bank lending creates
deposits. In normal times, the central
bank does not fix the amount of
money in circulation, nor is central
bank money ‘multiplied up’ into more
loans and deposits.” (BoE, 2014)
Unconventional monetary
policy
In the time of recession and deflationary pressures, once the basic nominal interest rate is set close to zero,
the conventional monetary policy
has reached its natural limit. On the
other side, the short term real interest
1
Former Federal Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke
provided a definition in April 2012: “Shadow
banking, as usually defined, comprises a diverse
set of institutions and markets that, collectively,
carry out traditional banking functions--but do
so outside, or in ways only loosely linked to, the
traditional system of regulated depository institutions.
Examples of important components of the shadow
banking system include securitization vehicles,
asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) conduits,
money market mutual funds, markets for repurchase
agreements (repos), investment banks, and mortgage
companies.” Shadow banking has grown in
importance to rival traditional depository banking
in debt financing and was a primary factor in the
subprime mortgage crisis of 2007-2008 and global
recession that followed. Regulated non-bank financial
institutions like insurance companies, pension funds
and equity mutual funds are not considered to be a
part of shadow banking (see FSB, 2013).
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
Figure 1: Impact of QE on balance sheets of banks and non-banks
Before asset purchase
After asset purchase
rectly to customers and they will not
be automatically multiplied into more
loans and deposits (see Figure 1).
Pension fund
Assets
Liabilities
Assets
Liabilities
How QE works in today´s
complex financial systems?
Government
debt
Other
Deposits
Other
Assets
Liabilities
Economists generally agree that the
interest rate that matters for stimulating investment and consumption
is not the short but the longer term
expected real interest rate. Any real
long term rate is technically a function of the main components: average
expected short term interest rates for
the period (i.e., the one that can in
principal be influenced by traditional
monetary policy every period), a
term (duration) risk premium and a
credit risk premium, and expected
inflation (Fawley and Juvenal, 2013).
The monetary policy, being conventional or unconventional, has to
influence these components through
various channels to be effective.
QE does work on expectations as it
is signalling to markets that economic
conditions are worse than previously
thought and that low short-term rates
will be warranted for longer than
expected. In a sense by QE the
central bank even financially commits itself to easy monetary policy
and low interest rates for the longer
time period. After QE is implemented
the central bank is holding a large
portfolio of bonds and if the interest
rates are to be increased very shortly
the potential losses on portfolio can
be spectacular.2 The effects of QE
on long term inflation expectations
critically depend on when and how
the exit from this policy is to be
implemented which is at present the
main topic in US. Effects of QE on
expectations are generally referred
to as the signalling channel.3
Central bank(b)
Government
debt
Assets
Liabilities
Other assets
Reserves
Reserves
Other assets
Commercial bank
Assets
Liabilities
Reserves
Deposits
Assets
Liabilities
Reserves
Deposits
(a
) Balance sheets are highly stylised for ease of exposition: quantities of assets and liabilities shown do
not correspond to the quantities actually held by those sectors. The figure only shows assets and liabilities
relevant to the transaction.
(b
) Government debt is actually purchased by the Bank of England’s Asset Purchase Facility using a loan from
the Bank of England, so does not actually appear directly on the Bank’s official consolidated balance sheet.
Source: Bank of England (2014)
rate and other longer term real interest rates can still be too high. One
possible response to provide additional stimulus to economic activity
by the central bank is to undertake a
series of asset purchases, increasing
the amount of central bank reserves
in the system or so called quantity
easing.
The BoE report (2014) is describing
the basic logic behind this measure
very clearly: “QE is intended to
boost the amount of money in the
economy directly by purchasing assets, mainly from non-bank financial
companies. QE initially increases
the amount of bank deposits those
companies hold (in place of the
assets they sell). Those companies
will then wish to rebalance their
portfolios of assets by buying higheryielding assets, raising the price of
those assets and stimulating spending in the economy. As a by-product
of QE, new central bank reserves
are created. But these are not an
important part of the transmission
mechanism.” Therefore, the same as
in the conventional monetary policy,
these reserves cannot be lend out di24
2
For example, FED and BoE have increased
their balance sheets five times during the current
economic recession and they hold respectively
about one third and one half of the outstanding
government issued securities.
BV 11/2014
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
Figure 2: Key channels for the impact of The Bank of England´ gilts purchases on domestic demand
Portfolio substitution
channel (always operates)
Gilt yields ↓
Bank of
England gilt
purchases
Term premia ↓
Yields on long-dated
risky assets ↓
Wealth ↑
Cost of accessing
credit in financial
markets ↓
Credit risk
premia ↓
Bank deposits and liquid
assets ↑
Domestic
demand
Availability of
bank credit ↑
Bank funding channel (may operate in
conditions of stressed bank funding)
Source: Miles, D., Bank of England (2012)
QE may also directly impact term
and/or credit risk premiums on the
financial markets for the range of
debt instruments. If the central bank
purchases longer term bonds, removing them from the market, prices will
go up and required long term returns
down. New money issued to investors in exchange for bonds acts like
“hot potato”. It is pushing the investors out of balance in their chosen
portfolios and they start to buy other
more risky assets like non-government bonds and equities, raising their
price, reducing the required returns
and the spreads above risk free returns. There are wealth effects for the
owners of these financial instruments
and reduced rates for new issuing
of these instruments, both stimulating
consumption and investment. With
reduced returns on longer term and
more risky assets the moral hazard
and negative selection problems on
the bank lending are mitigated as
well, improving the bank lending
conditions in support of economic
activity. Effects of QE on premiums,
or relative asset prices, are referred
to as the portfolio rebalance
channel (see Figure 2).
There is another possible bank
BV 11/2014
funding channel through which
QE works, particularly at times of
stress in bank funding markets. This
happens when banks themselves
take advantage of lower long term
interest rates on the market to obtain
more stable and low cost funding for
themselves (e.g., as a result of banks
issuing new bonds or taking in long
term deposits from non-bank institutions selling the bonds) which is likely
to facilitate bank lending, particularly for those entirely dependent on
banks for credit, for example SMEs
(see Figure 2).
QE in the market based
financial systems
There is strong empirical evidence
that the portfolio rebalance channel
of QE is working well in the current
recession in the economies with welldeveloped non-bank financial sector.
Miles (2012) is reporting for UK that
the purchase of longer term government bonds has reduced not only the
longer term returns on government
securities (changing the yield curve
for government bonds), but reducing
the spreads for more risky debt instruments of financial and non-financial
25
corporations as well. Therefore,
premiums for longer maturity and for
credit risk in debt instruments were
both reduced to support economic
activity and resume economic growth
in UK. The same channel has worked
strongly in the USA as well where
due to the size of the intervention
the impact of additional liquidity on
the markets has been felt globally
by reducing long term interest rates
for foreign sovereign debt as well
(Neely, 2012).4
The evidence for the working of bank
funding channel on economic activity
is less convincing. The banks might
well choose to participate in this new
asset price really on the financial
markets instead of looking for new
opportunities in the financing of the
3
The best example of effectively using the
signalling channel to influence the selected markets
was the statement of the ECB President Mr. Draghi
at the pick of the euro sovereign bond crisis that
ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to protect euro.
This OMT program from 2012, with potentially
unlimited capacity to buy sovereign bonds, has
never been even implemented in practice but
market participants reacted with substantially lower
required returns for troubled euro member countries.
4
Slovenia was a non-intended beneficiary of this
policy, selling new bonds when this window of
opportunities opened on the high yield market and
avoiding the international financial assistance that
would include conditionality by troika (IMF, ECB,
EU).
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
real economy. There are many other
side effects of these measures on
foreign exchange and equity markets
as well. Only the future will tell if
this general inflation of asset prices,
which has been the key part to revive
the growth in the short term, will be
translated into long term and sustainable growth of US economy as well
or it is only the beginning of the next
asset price bubble. For the rest of the
world, including EU, this is more or
less an academic issue as they have
practically no choice but to follow
the US and UK lead in this area.
interventions during the crisis had to
take these structural and institutional
limitations into account. The largest
ECB programs - long term repurchase operation (LTRO) and the new
targeted LTRO, being conditional on
new financing of non-financial sector
- can hardly be compared with QE
programs in US and UK. ECB is creating additional reserve money by
providing banks with medium term
financing at low cost and expending
its balance sheet with wider range
of eligible assets taken as collateral.
The purchase of sovereign bonds
from banks is therefore indirect and
QE in the Eurozone with
no “Eurobonds”?
It is interesting to note that the real
intention of QE programs is to lower
interest rates for private debt, while
the purchase in US and UK is made
almost exclusively of risk free government debt. Why the central bank
is not buying these private debts
directly? This would imply that the
central bank is taking on the balance sheet not only the market risk
associated with the change in the
interest rate level but the credit risk of
individual issuers as well. This is very
relevant for the ECB as there are no
bonds issued on the level of the Eurozone while they are institutional limits
on buying bonds of the member
countries. In addition, at present sovereign bonds of some of the member
countries are not really risk free.5 The
financial system in the Eurozone (and
Japan as well) is also much more
bank based than in US and UK and
the portfolio unbalance effect in the
non-banking sector will be automatically smaller (Fawley and Neely,
2013). The banking channel has to
play more direct and important role
in fighting the deflationary pressures
in the Eurozone as this is the only
large enough channel that exists in
many member countries.
The ECB unconventional monetary
ECB measures
can hardly be
compared with
QE in US and
UK.
temporary. But additional reserves in
banks do not automatically multiply into cheaper new lending and
money creation as in the textbook
money multiplier model.
Precondition for this bank funding
channel to work at all is that banks
are financially stable and new
lending is profitable. Many of the
banks used this ECB facility simply to
refinance their liabilities on the wholesale banking market (including the
banks from Slovenia) but the overall
lending to non-financial corporate
sector has remained stagnant. In
addition, the fragmentation of the
banking sector in the Eurozone in this
period has been further increased
with wider dispersion of bank interest
rates for corporate clients. On the
other side, it can be argued that with26
out the ECB intervention in providing
refinancing for over-leveraged banks
the credit crunch in the Eurozone
would be much deeper (Rant and
Gregorič, 2014). It should not come
as a surprise that banks with capital
adequacy concerns would be very
reluctant to increase lending as well.
The non-participation of the EU banks
in the first round of TLTRO in the fall
2014 is the case in point. Systemically important banks are waiting for
the final results of stress tests and they
find little interest in new funding and
implicit commitments to new lending
before they now how much additional capital will be needed for existing
portfolio of loans.
QE measures in the US and the UK
are targeted at non-bank financial
institutions holding large portfolio of
government bonds and banks serve
only as intermediaries to unbalance
their asset mix. For participating
banks (prime dealers in the US) this
“dancing with the central bank” is
rather lucrative and low risk activity
as long as the program last as promised. Therefore, banks willingness
to participate in QE to unbalance
the portfolios of non-banks is really
not a problem, but willingness of
banks to increase their own lending
depends on many other factors in the
economy.
QE in the Eurozone
and securitisation
The ECB has already announced the
beginning of its own version of QE
that will be focused on purchasing
5
Buying such bonds in large quantities for monetary
purposes would be far from neutral operation for
member countries. As critics are quick to say this
would be the same as bailing out troubled countries
and subsidizing their banking institutions which are
usually holding a large portion of domestic sovereign
bonds. One can argue that similar credit risks are
present at least partially in US where government
agencies guaranteed mortgage backed securities
(MBS) were part of the QE purchase as well. FED
has already announced the exit from QE program
at the end of 2014 with the intention to hold
accumulated assets till maturity. This in turn means
that FED will be an important participant in housing
finance in US for many years to come.
BV 11/2014
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
structured products like asset back
securities (ABS) and collateralised
debt obligations (CDO) in support of
financing SME sector in the Eurozone. Paradoxically, securitization of
loans and practice of distributional
banking used for subprime housing loans in US that were the main
reasons for the global financial
meltdown are proposed by the ECB
as a solution to overcome recession
in the Eurozone. It will be interesting to observe what will be the size
of the program and the eligibility
criteria. Will it be possible to include
in the programme the mezzanine
tranche in addition to senior tranche
of these structured securities? More
broad definition of eligibility will be
needed to have large enough volumes to make an economic impact
but that would imply the ECB helping
banks to save regulatory capital and
assuming additional credit risk that
might well be larger than in the case
of buying directly sovereign bonds.
With the fully integrated financial
markets one can argue that simulative effects of increased asset prices
and reduced required returns are
broadly distributed to investors in
all asset classes and to all potential issuers. But the reality of the
Eurozone is that financial sector is
fragmented and capital markets are
less important than in the market
based financial systems. Who owns
the assets to be purchased, who can
generate new assets to be purchased
and who is to be chosen to “dance
with the central bank” in the Eurozone might well become the major
political issue.
Countries like Slovenia, with no
domestic market for corporate debt
securities and limited experience in
securitisation will likely receive minimal direct and indirect benefits. On
the other side, some larger member
countries like Italy have already
made major steps forward to encourage debt financing of SMEs on
BV 11/2014
the capital markets to complement
traditional bank financing. These
policy measures will be reviewed
in the next section as we believe
there are lessons to be learned for
Slovenia. It seems that the future of
corporate financing in the Eurozone
will become much more like in US
and UK, where securitisation, capital
markets, non-bank financial institutions and shadow banking will play
an important role beside commercial
banks. To benefit from these developments Slovenia should, like it or not,
adjust to this new trend as soon as
possible.
Minibonds and
securitisation in Italy
Italy, like most continental European
countries, have had for many years a
typical bank based financial system
with the great majority of companies
almost exclusively relaying on domestic banks for short and long term
financing. Bond financing was used
only by a few large listed companies
and financial institutions which could
attract international investors as well.
With the objective to improve SMEs
and unlisted companies access to
debt financing on the capital market
and support economic growth, Italy
introduced in December 2012 a
special legislation for minibonds and
commercial papers. In December
2013 this was accompanied by a
new securitisation law, regulating
establishing of SPVs to acquire corporate loans and securitise them. The
legal framework to build up domestic
shadow banking is in place. Banks
can now set up investment funds with
securitisation of existing portfolio of
loans by retain a large part of first
loss equity tranche or start new debt
funds with outside investors.6
Minibonds can now be issued by
SMEs that are not listed on the
stock exchange and they are not
intended for retail investors but only
27
for professional investors. Offering
disclosures and regular reporting
requirements for minibonds are lower
than for retail bonds, no prospectus
is needed, and sensitive information
reporting is limited to major events,
all reducing the costs of issuing for
SMEs. To issue short term notes
SME has to nominate professional
sponsor. Minibonds can be participatory providing they have at least
three years duration and they pay
at minimum the ECB base interest
rate. Therefore, bondholders can
participate in the profit of the SMEs
and share the risk with the owners of
the SMEs. Corporate tax treatment
of this profit sharing with creditors is
the same as for regular interest payments, providing that bondholders do
not have more than 2% ownership
stake in SME. Minibonds are traded
on the special segment of the stock
exchange reserved for professional
investors trading in bonds, commercial papers and project bonds. It
should be very easy to use the same
market infrastructure to organise
centralised book building process on
the primary market for minibonds as
well. All these institutional arrangements are making transactions with
minibonds cheaper and more easy
to use by institutional investors who
received also some regulatory reliefs
in Italy to buy minibonds.
The minibond instrument is risky by
its nature as it issued by SMEs and,
in addition, interest payment can be
participatory. As they are not appropriate for retail investors, requirements can be lowered, but some
standardisation is needed to achieve
the main objectives, to support the
program by favourable tax regime
and to promote the broader use of
6
See for example Vestini, Tancredi (2014) and
Linhard (2014). It seems that Italy has anticipated
well in advance the ECB measures focused on the
support to SME financing. In addition, institutionally
Italy is well positioned to take the advantage of QE
program focused on ABS and CDO securities, once
details are disclosed by ECB President Mr. Draghi in
October 2014.
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
new instruments. These instruments in
Italy seem to be well adjusted to the
financing and operational reality of
SMEs as they are half-way between
bank financing and public bond
financing. Extensive financial covenants as in the banking loans are
combined with the standard public
bonds provisions of negative pledge,
“pari passu” and limited restrictions
on asset disposal and extraordinary
transactions.
Debt financing and the
capital market in Slovenia
The size of the Slovenian financial
system has been reduced to 161% of
GDP during the financial crisis and it
remains small compared to the 612%
of GDP in the Eurozone. Banks with
75% of the assets under management are dominating players despite
the contraction of the lending activities in recent years, while the other
non-bank financial institutions have
been underdeveloped in terms of
size, structure and variety of financial
instruments. In addition, the crosslinkages with the banking sector are
not very strong as the main investors
in all non-bank institutions, including the investment funds, are retail
investors. The organized domestic
capital market is small and suffers
from low liquidity and remains off
limits to companies and other entities
as an alternative source of financing. The five most heavily traded
prime market shares accounted for
more than four-fifths of total volume
of trading with 64 listed companies
and two most heavily traded bonds
accounted for nearly one-half of the
total volume of trading. (BoS, 2014,
p. 84- 98)
At present non-bank financial
institutions are not very relevant for
domestic corporate financing as they
mostly invest in government bonds
and foreign assets. The insurance
sector has increased its foreign assets
during the financial crisis from 30%
in 2009 to 45% in 2013. The mutual
funds, mostly equity or mixed funds
are 70% to 80% invested in foreign
securities. A few money market funds
and debt funds have been created
recently but they are still small in size.
Real estate funds and hedge funds
are not present at all. Foreign asset
management companies have mostly
left the country during the financial
crisis. Pension funds have at present
very conservative investment policy
due to legally required minimum
return and they are mostly invested in
government bonds and deposits.
Banks'
deleveraging in
Slovenia was
»brutal«
to corporates.
Contrary to the banking sector this
part of the domestic financial industry was able to survive the implosion
of equity and real estate price bubbles and the long lasting economic
recession without the assistance of
the government. It also showed a
lot of resilience in the recent turmoil caused by the collapse of the
domestic banking sector where the
losses due to investments in shares,
hybrid and subordinated debt instruments issued by domestic banks were
substantial. The consolidation of the
industry is close to complete and
surviving institutions are financially
strong and profitable.
In 2014, the bank deposit rates in
Slovenia were sharply reduced due
to BoS intervention which might induce some bank depositors to switch
their savings to alternative non-bank
28
institutions. At the same time, domestic insurance companies and pension
funds are forced to look for better
returns in alternative investments at
home and abroad. On the regulatory front, the introduction of the new
life-cycle investment policies in pension funds will increase the demand
for shares and corporate bonds,
while the introduction of solvency 2
in insurance industry will likely switch
demand from longer term to shorter
term debt instruments. Therefore, in
the near future some changes in investment policies are expected, some
additional de-satisfied retail and
institutional bank depositors might
be attracted, but the overall organic
growth of the non-bank institutions
will depend mostly from the improvements in disposable income of households due to economic recovery and
reduced unemployment.
Financial crisis always leads to
deleveraging of banks and corporates, but “good” deleveraging
would try to minimise the negative
impact of this process on economic
growth. The deleveraging of banks in
Slovenia was “brutal” to the corporate sector that depends almost
entirely on bank financing. Between
October 2008 and March 2014
the banks´ repayment of debt on
the wholesale markets exceeded
32% of GDP. The main counterpart
of these repayments was reduced
bank financing for corporate sector
and sharp increase in cost of debt
financing (BoS, 2014, p. xii). The LTD
ratio in the banking sector was in this
period reduced from 160% to 103%
and business models of both foreignowned and domestic-owned banks
were transformed into simple savings
and loans institutions on the domestic
market. With the government assistance in the amount of close to 12%
of GDP the banking sector is now
well capitalised and liquid, but the
lending activity is still low and interest rates for corporate lending about
BV 11/2014
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
3% to 4% higher than in Eurozone
(see Figure 3).
The precondition for overall credit
growth is the restructuring of overindebted corporate sector that is
lagging behind banking sector in restructuring of their balance sheets. It
is estimated that this excessive corporate debt might be around one third
of GDP and is not limited only to a
few large debtors but to thousands
of SMEs as well (UMAR (2014)
and Damijan (2014)). It is clear that
organised and coordinated efforts of
the BAMC, banks and the government will be needed to financially
restructure these companies and
secure them new equity financing
before they can take on new loans (
Simoneti and Jašovič (2013), Simoneti (2014a, 2014b)).
Based on the BoS survey on the access to finance from 2011 to 2013
availability of bank loans has deteriorated, bank rejected more applications and companies received fewer
funds than they demanded. They
increased their demand for external
financing in the period while the supply did not follow and the financial
gap has increased. Most companies still do not expect that external
financing in Slovenia will improve in
2014 (Geršak, 2014).
Good companies are trying to escape from this long lasting financial
repression on domestic bank loan
market by borrowing from abroad,
which is available to big traditional
exporters and by issuing debt instruments on the capital markets, which
is limited to large and financially
sound companies. Financial experts
estimate that only 5 to 10 Slovenian
companies can issue debt instruments on international markets due
to minimum size and rating requirements. Additional 50 companies
might have the size and the quality
to issue bonds and notes on the
domestic market. The demand for
these instruments is at present strong
BV 11/2014
Figure 3: Interest rates on corporate loans of more than euro
1 million in percentages in comparison with the euro area
Source: Bank of Slovenia (2014)
even on domestic market as deposit
rates were sharply decreased. There
have already been first transactions
indicating that a handful of qualified
domestic companies will seize the
opportunity to replace expensive
domestic bank financing with debt
financing on the capital market. But
for most of the companies in Slovenia, being SMEs, this is not a solution
unless there is a radical change introduced on the supply and demand
side of the market.
Conclusions
The underdeveloped capital market
and non-bank financial institutions in
Slovenia are by-product of the distributional model of mass privatisation,
non-transparent and bank supported
domestic consolidation of ownership,
large residual state ownership and of
the key role played by state owned
banks in the gradual transition to the
market economy. In the transition and
development model based on strong
relationship among the state and
domestic financial and corporate
sector, supported by the ideology of
“national interest”, transparency and
disclosure rules of the capital market
29
were not really welcomed (Šušteršič,
IER, 2010).
With the banking crisis and the
collapse of this development
model many new opportunities have
opened for the debt and equity
capital market development to assist in solving the main economic
challenges of Slovenia: restructuring
of banks and companies, privatisation, corporate governance in state
owned sector, new equity financing,
foreign financing of domestic economy through non-bank channels,
long term households savings and
pension reforms. An extensive study
from 2010 served to form a broad
consensus of the financial industry
participants what should be done
for the revival of the capital market
in Slovenia.7 A comprehensive and
consistent package of measures to increase confidence in the market and
quality of the market, to strengthen
the supply side and demand side of
7
The new strategy for development of the capital
market was drafted based on the initiative proposed
by the Ljubljana Stock Exchange, proposals by market
participants and the research conducted by the
Slovene Institute for Economic Research (IER) entitled
»Development Opportunities for the Capital Market in
Slovenia Following the Financial Crisis« (2010).
ECONOMIC ACTIVIT Y, BUSINESS CYCLES AND CREDIT GROW TH
the market and to improve market
infrastructure was agreed upon that
is still relevant four years later.8 This
paper only adds one more opportunity for non-bank institutions to play a
positive role in the economy: increasing the benefits of the Eurozone
membership for Slovenia.
The expansionary monetary measures of the ECB have not been transmitted into new lending and lower
interest rates for the real sector in Slovenia. Therefore, the new monetary
policy of ECB focusing on corporate
and SME financing through TLTRO
and QE seems like a very timely and
relevant measure for Slovenia. But
how can these proposals work in the
system which is dominated by banks
that are still burdened with more than
20% of corporate NPLs after the
transfer of bad assets to the BAMC
at the end of 2013? They cannot
because the bank funding channel
does not function if banks are still
under stress and preoccupied with
their internal problems and most of
the companies are still over indebted. But even if Slovenian banks and
companies are once financially restructured there would be a problem
as there is no infrastructure available
to securitise bank loans. For many
years Slovenian banks were using
wholesale market and parent banks´
loans for additional funding and they
have no experience in securitisation. The financial system in Slovenia
is operating so differently that the
proposed instruments cannot be used
effectively in the near future.
Some countries with traditional bankbased systems and a strong SME
sector have already realised that
being different and less developed
in the Eurozone comes at cost and
they are making big steps forward in
closing this gap. Is there a lesson for
Slovenia, to use minibond concept
for alternative new financing of
SMEs and, above all, to use securitisation of existing corporate loans
once the financial restructuring of
over-indebted borrowers is completed. For such a program to work we
need (1) a supportive legal, tax and
institutional environment, (2) motivated and capable issuers in corporate
and banking sector and (3) strong
foreign and domestic demand. With
the ECB announcing QE programs
the main constraint is no more on
the demand side but on the limited
domestic professional capabilities to
design the overall framework and to
execute transactions. The by-product
of the suppression of capital market
development in Slovenia for many
years is that there is a lack of investment banking skills that are needed
today to efficiently restructure banks
and their corporate clients and
to take full advantage of the new
growth promoting initiatives within
the Eurozone.
Linhard, Stefanie: Italy innovates with
minibonds to fill SME lending vacuum,
Global Capital, 03 March 2014.
REFERENCES:
Simoneti, Marko (2014b). »Dobro«
razdolževanje podjetij v Sloveniji po
začetku sanacije bank, Dnevi slovenskih
pravnikov, Podjetje in delo, letnik 40,
oktober 2014.
Damijan, J. P. (2014), Corporate
financial soundness and its impact on firm
performance: Implications for corporate
debt restructuring in Slovenia, Working
papers No. 168, EBRD.
Fawley, B.W. and Juvenal, L.: Quantitative
Easing: Lessons We’ve Learned, The
regional economist, Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, July 2012.
Fawley, B.W. & Neely, C.J.: Four Stories
of Quantitative Easing, Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review, January-February
(2013).
McLeay, M., Radia, A. & Thomas, R.:
Money creation in the modern economy,
Quarterly Bulletin, Bank of England,
(2014).
Miles, D: Asset prices, saving and the
wider effects of monetary policy, Bank
of England (2012).www.bankofengland.
co.uk/blications/Documents/
speeches/2012/speech549.pdf.
Neely, Christopher: “The Large-Scale Asset
Purchases Had Large International Effects.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working
Paper 2010-018D, April 2012.
Rant, V. and Gregorič, J.: ECB policy
measures and their effects during financial
crisis, Bančni vestnik, 2014, letnik 63,
številka 7-8.
Marko Simoneti, Kruno Abramovič, Aleš
Berk Skok, Jože P. Damijan, Igor Masten,
Simon Mastnak, Mojmir Mrak, Matija
Rojec, Janez Šušteršič, Luka Vesnaver:
Razvojne priložnosti trga kapitala v
Sloveniji po finančni krizi - Development
Opportunities for the Capital Market in
Slovenia Following the Financial Crisis, IER
2010. http://www.ljse.si/cgi-bin/jve.cgi?d
oc=12608&sid=oy1xTzkXkWzjxjN3
Simoneti, Marko. Razvojne priložnosti trga
kapitala v Sloveniji po finančni krizi? IB
revija, 2011, letn. 45, št. 1/2, str. 67-83.
Simoneti, Marko in Jašovič, Božo.
Prestrukturiranje podjetij s strani bank upnic
: kako skupaj iz blokade. Bančni vestnik,
2013, letn. 62, št. 7/8, str. 9-17.
Simoneti, Marko (2014a). Prestrukturiranje
dolžnikov po spremembi insolvenčne
zakonodaje. Bančni vestnik, jan./feb.
2014, letn. 63, št. 1/2, str. 13-17.
UMAR, Ekonomski izzivi (2014),
Zadolženost in razdolževanje slovenskih
podjetij, junij 2014.
Vestini Luca, Tancredi Marino: The
“Destinazione Italia” Decree: New life
for Minibonds and Trade Receivables
Securitizations, Diritto Bancario, Gennaio
2014.
Financial Stability Board: Global Shadow
Banking Monitoring Report 2013 (2013).
Geršak, Uroš: Raziskava o dostopnosti
virov za podjetja – Access to finance
survey, Bančni vestnik, 2014, letnik 63,
številka 6.
30
8
See »Slovene capital market development
strategy«, http://www.ljse.si/cgi-bin/jve.
cgi?doc=1468
BV 11/2014